ISBN 0-b51,-0e551-?
Socialist Unemployment THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF YUGOSLAVIA, 1945-1990
Susan L. Woodward
PRINCET...
115 downloads
1115 Views
13MB Size
Report
This content was uploaded by our users and we assume good faith they have the permission to share this book. If you own the copyright to this book and it is wrongfully on our website, we offer a simple DMCA procedure to remove your content from our site. Start by pressing the button below!
Report copyright / DMCA form
ISBN 0-b51,-0e551-?
Socialist Unemployment THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF YUGOSLAVIA, 1945-1990
Susan L. Woodward
PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRESS PRINCETON, NEW JERSEY
Copyright © 1995 by Princeton University Press Published by Princeton University Press, 41 William Street, Princeton, New Jersey 08540 In the United Kingdom: Princeton University Press, Chichester, West Sussex All Rights Reserved Library
of Congress
Cataloging-in-Publication
Data
Woodward, Susan L., 1944Socialist unemployment : the political economy of Yugoslavia, 1945-1990 / Susan L. Woodward. p. cm. Includes bibliographical references and index. ISBN 0-691-08645-1 (alk. paper) 1. Unemployment—Yugoslavia. 2. Full employment policiesYugoslavia. 3. Yugoslavia—Economic conditions—1945-1992. 4. Socialism—Yugoslavia. I. Title. HD5811.6.A6W66 1995 331.13'79497—dc20
94-46153 CIP
This book has been composed in Caledonia Princeton University Press books are printed on acid-free paper and meet the guidelines for permanence and durability of the Committee on Production Guidelines for Book Longevity of the Council on Library Resources Printed in the United States of America 1
3
5
7
9
10
8
6
4
2
To Peter Vincent Woodward In Memoriam
Child o f u n e m p l o y e d man: " W h y don't w e have h e a t ? " M o t h e r : " B e c a u s e t h e r e is no c o a l . " C h i l d : " W h y is t h e r e no coal?" M o t h e r : " B e c a u s e your father is out of work. " Child: " W h y is my father out of work?" M o t h e r : " B e c a u s e t h e r e is too m u c h c o a l . " — D r . D i e t e r Steifel, Austria, 1931 O n e gets the impression that as a society we are q u i t e inert w h e n it c o m e s to solving the p r o b l e m of u n e m p l o y m e n t . We have difficulty a c c e p t i n g facts if they do not conform to our conceptions or plans. A progressive, and particularly a socialist society, cannot wait "optimistically" for so important and delicate a p r o b l e m to be resolved spontaneously and cannot e x p e c t its m e m b e r s not to be exposed to great social and e c o n o m i c risk as a result. Security of e m p l o y m e n t is o n e of the significant contributions of socialism, highly valued and popular, particularly in the ranks of the working classes of capitalist countries, s o m e t h i n g that we ought not allow ourselves to question. We are aware of the fact that it is difficult to harmonize e c o n o m i c n e c e s s i t y and political opportunity, but we should not allow those difficulties to d e m o b i l i z e us. — T r i p o Mulina, Yugoslavia, 1968
CONTENTS
List of Figures and Tables Preface
xi xiii
CHAPTER 1
Introduction: The Paradox of Socialist Unemployment
3
CHAPTER 2 The Making of a Strategy for Change
31
CHAPTER 3 Creating a State for Socialist Development
64
CHAPTER 4 Military Self-Reliance, Foreign Trade, and the Origins of Self-Management
98
CHAPTER 5 A Republic of Producers
164
CHAPTER 6 Unemployment
191
CHAPTER 7 The Faustian Bargain
222
CHAPTER 8 Slovenia and Foča
260
CHAPTER 9 Divisions of Labor
310
CHAPTER 10 Breakdown
345
EPILOGUE
371
Appendix: Statistical Data
375
Bibliography
393
Index
427
FIGURES AND TABLES
FIGURES Figure 1-1. Map of Former Yugoslavia
2
Figure 6-1. Employment Growth, 1962-1975
192
Figure 6-2. Unemployment, 1952-1988
193
Figure 6-3. Rate of Unemployment, 1959-1988
193
Figure 6-4. Unemployment: Gross and Net Rates
199
Figure 6-5. Job Seekers and Yugoslavs Working Temporarily Abroad
200
Figure 6-6. Length of Time Waiting to Be Employed
202
Figure 6-7. Length of Time Waiting to Be Employed (proportions)
202
Figure 6-8. Women among the Registered Unemployed
203
Figure 6-9. Unemployment Rates by Republic: The North
204
Figure 6-10. Unemployment Rates by Republic: The South
204
Figure 6-11. Economically Active Population by Republic
205
Figure 6-12. Unemployment by Age Category
206
Figure 6-13. Unemployment by Age Category (proportions)
206
Figure 6-14. Women, New Entrants, and the Educated
207
Figure 6-15. Women, New Entrants, and the Educated (proportions)
208
Figure 6-16. Youth Unemployment Rates: The North
209
Figure 6-17. Youth Unemployment Rates: The South
209
Figure 8-1. Employment in the Social Sector by Republic
292
Figure 9-1. Rate of Unemployment: Kosovo, Slovenia, and Bosnia-Herzegovina
340
Figure 9-2. Rate of Youth Unemployment: Kosovo, Slovenia, and Bosnia-Herzegovina
340
Figure 9-3. Rate of Employment: Kosovo, Slovenia, and Bosnia-Herzegovina
341
xii
LIST OF FIGURES AND TABLES TABLES
Table 1-1.
International Comparison of the Sectoral Distribution of Employment
25
Table 1-2.
Level of Employment in Socialist and Market 27 Capitalist Countries, 1974
Table 6-1.
Rate of Employment by Republic or Province 205
PREFACE
BETWEEN THE Great Depression of the 1880s and the Great Depression of the 1930s, the political systems of modern states were created. Inseparable from that development was unemployment. Mass political parties, governmental activism in the economy, systems of public welfare—all were a response to the phenomenon of mass, industrial unemployment and the efforts by working-class organizations to protect against it. By the 1980s, the solutions that had b e e n in use had failed. U n e m p l o y m e n t began to take on serious proportions even in the wealthiest, most technologically advanced nations of the world. Countries celebrated as models of full e m p l o y m e n t — S w e d e n , Austria, even J a p a n — w e r e dismantling the systems of political decision making in the economy that had managed their success. At the same time, the socialist alternative, which had once inspired political action and a r e m e d y against unemployment, was also under attack. The global defeat of both Keynesian and Marxian programs had its crowning glory in the political revolutions in central and eastern E u r o p e in 1 9 8 9 - 9 0 and their open declaration that the "natural price" for liberal democracy and the prosperity of market economies was large-scale unemployment. In eastern G e r m a n y , the seat of social d e m o c r a c y — w h e r e the Yugoslav socialist story b e g i n s — t h a t unemployment was conservatively estimated at 50 p e r c e n t on the first anniversary of German reunification. Guided by the older v e r i t y — t h a t unemployment was the great, unresolved affliction of capitalism, and socialism was a movement to make it unnecessary—I began this book with what s e e m e d an obvious paradox: a socialist country with high and unremittingly rising unemployment. In the early 1980s, when my research began, socialist Yugoslavia had the highest rate of registered unemployment in Europe. T h e country was acclaimed for its maverick approach to socialism—for defying the ideological blocs of the cold war, helping to organize the nonalignment movement, and creating a domestic order of economic democracy and decentralized, market socialism. But those few who noticed its unemployment—part of the paradox was the great silence toward this unemployment in the Yugoslav public as well as in scholarship on the country—identified the cause as the system of "workers' control." According to this theory, e c o n o m i c democracy gave workers the right to manage their firms, and they chose to maximize their incomes at the expense of new investment. Yugoslavs had made the syndicalist dilemma into an organizing principle of society.
xiv
PREFACE
Before the alternative explanation in this book could appear, the country died. To explain the paroxysm of killing and territorial war that followed, a new e x c e p t i o n a l i s m — o f ancient ethnic hatreds and a Balkan culture of blood r e v e n g e — r e p l a c e d the fame of Yugoslavia's "third way." Yugoslav socialism was ascribed a role in the tragedy for failing to allow political democracy and for repressing national identities and the historical aspirations of the country's peoples for national self-determination. But for the most part, its experiment was assigned to the overnight oblivion of the rest of European socialism. T h e branch of scholarship claiming that Yugoslav politics was always about the national question and ethnic conflict s e e m e d vindicated. In fact, neither the disintegration of Yugoslavia nor the character of its wars can be understood apart from the political-economic and social system created by the Yugoslav League of Communists or the effect of rising unemployment on that system. T h e leaders' approach to employment was a core e l e m e n t of the system. T h e dynamic of governmental policy alternated between two models, which I have labeled (after contrasting wartime administrations in 1 9 4 1 - 4 5 ) "Slovenia" and " F o č a . " T h e first model r e p r e s e n t e d the approach to economic growth—and the economic and political institutions to implement that a p p r o a c h — o f the dominant ideology of liberal, or reform, communism. T h e second model represented the policies and institutions periodically required by the strategic considerations of national defense and of a foreign-trade strategy in contractual markets, or in market conditions where revenues depended on supply increases instead of price competition. A central e l e m e n t in both approaches was the country's foreign economic and strategic relations and its domestic adjustment to international conditions. In the breakup of Yugoslavia, an extreme version of this dynamic played out with the initial, almost surgical secession of Slovenia (to pursue the Slovene model independently in central Europe) and the prolonged, bloody agony of Bosnia-Herzegovina (where the F o č a model had its earliest and most developed expression). T h e ability of Slovenia to exit was inseparable from the political consequences of the republic's nearly forty years of full employment. T h e characteristics of the war in BosniaHerzegovina were, likewise, inseparable from the political c o n s e q u e n c e s of nearly 25 percent unemployment in the 1980s, at the start of another liberalizing, "efficiency-oriented" economic reform for international adj u s t m e n t . Both were the product, as was the broader path of disintegration, of a political system based on the liberal, or reform-communist, model of socialism and on the leaders' system of social protection against u n e m p l o y m e n t — a system that structured the labor force into highproductivity and subsistence sectors of the economy, with corresponding differences in property rights and political participation: one socialist (or public), the other independent (or private).
PREFACE
XV
The understandable focus on the collapse of Yugoslavia and the human tragedy of its wars diverts attention, unfortunately, from the resemblance between its strategy and the one eventually followed in other socialist states. If not a prelude to war, the economic reform of socialist societies for the purposes of global economic integration and economic recovery in a period of worldwide stagflation and then recession has left in its wake a type of social organization and attitudes—described in this b o o k — a b o u t social status, economic rights, and welfare that will shape the path of postcommunist regimes. T h e dismissal of a century of human experience in the case of the Soviet Union and nearly fifty years in the case of E u ropean socialist states also cannot erase the problems socialism arose to solve or its more generally shared dilemma of the declining relevance of the responses to agrarian and industrial unemployment in the 1920s and 1930s to conditions in the 1990s and beyond. Structural unemployment among urban youth, both unskilled and university-educated, and within the administrative and service sectors poses a different problem for economic policy. Nationalism is only a negative manifestation of the political problem it poses; it remains uncertain who will organize the unemployed (and those threatened with unemployment in these conditions) and therefore what economic ideologies and political systems will result. At the very time the Yugoslav socialist system was disintegrating, its key elements were the rage in Western theory: decentralization, rising labor productivity as the route to higher employment, the political and economic incentives of property rights, and social alternatives to budgetary expenditures on welfare. T h e underlying tension of the Austrian paradox in the epigraph to this b o o k — t h e aggregate paradox of Keynes's ideological revolution, the dilemmas of secondary uncertainty and market failure, the relation b e t w e e n individual and social interests, the role of government—was the source of Yugoslavia's most highly contested and unsolved political, as well as ideological, predicament. Like the former Yugoslav state, I have accumulated a very heavy burden of debts in the course of writing this book that can never be fully repaid. Beginning with those who helped financially, I acknowledge with particular gratitude the International Research and Exchanges Hoard, for enabling my research sojourn at the Zagreb Institute of Economics (Ekonomski Institut) during 1982; the American Council of Learned Societies and Williams College, for making possible a research leave at the Russian Research C e n t e r at Harvard University in 1 9 8 1 - 8 2 , when I began to think about the project; Yale University, for a social science faculty research grant and a glorious leave in California in 1987, where I was able to do the archival work and write undisturbed in the true ivory tower of the Hoover Institution and its supporting fellowship from the U . S . D e partment of State's discretionary grant program under the S o v i e t -
xvi
PREFACE
E a s t e r n E u r o p e a n Research and Training Act of 1983 ( P . L . 98-164), Title V I I I , 97 Stat. 1047-50; and, finally, the National Fellows program of the Hoover Institution, for the sanctuary in 1 9 8 9 - 9 0 that gave me the additional quiet n e e d e d to c o m p l e t e the manuscript. E v e n then, without the supportive work environment of the Brookings Institution, the editing necessary to turn a book on a topic I considered of burning i n t e r e s t — i n the face of troubles far more serious—into a work of history might never have been completed. Raghbendra Jha first suggested the topic and reignited an earlier interest in economic developm e n t discovered under the remarkable professional nurturance of Robert T. Holt. No one who studied Yugoslavia escaped its spell of hospitality and endless complexity; no one can escape the painful sense of loss over its tragic death. Among my many hosts, I note especially Olga Supek, Silva Mežnarić, Branko Horvat, Josip Županov, Zagorka Golubović, Radmila Nakarada, the librarians at the Zagreb Institute of Economics, Nikola Uzunov, Boro Škegro, Tripo Mulina, and the late Kiril Miljovski. My gratitude also goes to the many, many experts—economists, sociologists, planners, historians, labor-bureau officials, and retired party officials— who gave freely of their time and knowledge to make this book possible. Daniel T u r n e r produced the charts and graphs for the book, and Milj e n k o Horvat provided informed research assistance. Judith Shapiro, Louka Katseli, Gerry Arsenis, Deborah Milenkovitch, and Shirley Gedeon c o m b i n e d unquestioning friendship with invaluable support on economic issues; Elizabeth Brett, Sara and Nick Ohly, Pat Tracy, Martha Lampland, Gail Kligman, and, above all, Vann Woodward and Don and B e t t y Lampland sustained me.
Socialist Unemployment
c F U>
= f,
/ {{ \
(, z :) ?
(/'\/)
z. o E
o
/ \i \. F ' 0
u) ) I
;
lt
/'
z'rt
:t (
' l / ' "'\/( "t -E a) 0
Y\ ),,
a)/l
-o
3;l\
q
ru(e
)o/
/, J *''"ktQ \/'
\-/----4 See Feher, Heller, and Markus, D ictatorship o v e r N eeds 3(i For a good example in a country that later adopted socialism for the same reason, see Janos, T h e Politics o f B ackw ard n ess in H istorical Perspective: H ungary, 1825-1945. 37 T, C. Koopmans coined the phrase “secondary uncertainty”; see Dobb s exposition in W e lfa re E con om ics a n d the E con om ics o f Socialism , 121-52.
INTRODUCTION
19
all other, unproductive uses of human labor in society.38 Value added in production was not only a monetary category of revenue above costs of production, but necessarily a real category: the wages of those whose la bor created value represented wage goods (goods that workers would con sume in the course of producing other goods, the level of which was based on a conception of subsistence that was set culturally and in social interac tion). The subsistence fu n d for society defined the limit to economic growth. It depended not only on how many were consuming that fund in relation to how many were creating it (the calculation of this ratio incorpo rated both Malthusian considerations of population growth in which eco nomic growth encouraged birthrates to rise, and classical analyses of class structure in which there were unproductive parasites such as landlords, lawyers, clergy, and aristocrats’ servants living off the product of others), but also on the productivity of the industries producing those basic con sumption goods and on the price of the goods. There were two ways to increase growth. One was to encourage bring ing as much of society’s resources as possible into productive use and to reduce to a minimum the drain of resources into unproductive endeavors. In the colorful language of the physiocrats, for example, merchants’ profits were “leeches sucking off” agricultural and industrial producers. All but essential administrators, preferably chosen by examination for professional skill, were “sterile”; bureaucrats only rarely contributed to the increase of productive output.39 Naturally, the way a society orga nized its activities, including the offices and activities of the state, could be more or less wasteful. The second way to increase growth was to “cap italize” labor itself— by increasing individuals’ capacity to raise their mar ginal output through use of machinery, application of science, new production techniques, organizational rationalizations, and education (“human capital”). Labor’s reward should include incentives to higher productivity and capitalization; people would thus be defined in terms of their relative productivity— for example, according to skill, experience, output, or managerial abilities. The goal of increasing the net output of society meant that rights to ownership and to the organization of economic activity should be handed to producers. By reuniting the functions of labor, commerce, manufactur ing, and finance into a single association of workers, they would save on costs while work incentives would rise. A rational economic plan to coor dinate the activities of individual associations and avoid the problems of secondary uncertainty would guide producers’ economic decisions. The 3S J Roemer, F re e to L ose, is a particularly lucid presentation of this guiding concept. 39 Appleby, E con om ic T hou ght a n d Id eolog y in Seventeen th-C en tu ry E ngland, 107, 134; Dobb, T heories o f Value a n d D istribution since A dam Smith, 41.
20
CHAPTER 1
crises of capitalism had taught that the separate role of money— the sep aration of production from finance, and autonomous decision making co ordinated only by the price mechanism— could independently depreciate the value added by labor, whether through falling real wages, unemploy ment, or state debt and financial crises that prolonged resolution of the problem.40 It was in society’s interest to ensure a balance between the goods necessary to production (both producers’ goods and wage goods) and the goods that represented an increase in its standard of living, and to prevent an autonomous role for money and finance. From this economic ideology there also followed a view of the state and political relations. As a political organization in capitalist societies, Marx ist parties argued, government took the guise of a neutral intermediary in the conflict between forces separated by the institution of private owner ship; but its actions were not those of a disinterested arbiter, and so it actually served to mask the real structure of power in society. As an eco nomic organization, it also imposed an additional layer of exploitation (rents and taxes) on labor’s surplus, wasting resources on the coercive instruments necessary to maintain the power of both employers and rulers. Social ownership, on the other hand, would eliminate the need for such an organization. It could therefore eliminate the coercive power ol taxation and police and the wastefulness of unproductive consumption by bureaucracies. The state would become less and less necessary. Eco nomic and social functions could be reintegrated into associations of workers (producers), and although this would not eliminate all disagree ments or conflicts of interest, they would no longer reflect an unbreachable divide between capital and labor. There remained disputes among socialist parties and schools of thought— as there were among schools of classical economists— over, for example, what constituted value in a monetized society and therefore over how to price labor.41 A policy of industrialization and a system of differentiated economic incentives would create differences in a socialist society according to workers’ individual “capital” or the economic branch in which they worked. Disagreements over the optimal scale of produc tion, particularly in agriculture, and over the pace of development and its political implications— for consumption standards and investment prefer ences and for which groups would benefit more from the resulting policy choices— remained unresolved in the socialist legacy and laid the basis for 10 Rucciardi, “Rereading Marx on the Role of Money and Finance in Economic Develop ment, ’ is a rare example of attention to the crucial role of money and the causes of financial crisis in Marx’s political as well as economic analysis and also in later Marxian theorizing. 11 See Dobb, T h eories o f Value an d D istribution, 112-20; and Milenkovitch, Plan and M arket in Yugoslav E con om ic Thought, 21—31, '14-50, 2 30-49
INTRODUCTION
21
factional disputes.42 Even the Soviet model, despite its image as a dog matic blueprint of development and organization forcibly imposed on other societies, contained within it alternative paths and choices on devel opment strategy and its associated policies and organization that reflected these disputes. This was most obvious in the Soviet debates on strategy of the 1920s,43 although the debates revived after World War II and every decade thereafter in competing schools of policy and their political factions. But a major assumption of socialist theory was that no economic con flicts in a society with social ownership would be inevitably unreconcilable in the way that private ownership of property created truly antagonistic relations between classes. Individuals were supposed to be guided by their economic interests— the Smithian assumption was no where rejected— but social ownership removed the artificial obstacles to their natural cooperativeness. Conflict between individuals incomes or jobs and their common interest in economic growth was only a matter of time horizons, and it could be handled by education and the feedback of real growth. The institutions for regulating conflict could presume cooperation. The societies created on the basis of Marxist ideology were organized on principles different from those of market economies with private owner ship. Their politics, therefore, did not follow the market logic. The political correlate of the dynamic concept of the trade-off between capital and labor, investment and employment, was not a contest between parties and orga nized interests representing private owners of capital on the one hand and people who labor on the other. It was instead a range of policies for eco nomic growth and its distribution, proposed by economists and govern ment ministries; these policies benefited certain groups, firms, sectors, and regions but did not result from pressure by them. The swings por trayed in most analyses of socialist policy between utopia and develop ment, vision and reality, “red” and “expert, ”44 were alternations between 12 For a good introduction to the agricultural debates, see Mitrany, Marx against the Peasant, 7-23; see also Cox, Peasants, Class, an d C apitalism On the debates over pace, A. Erlich, The Soviet Industrialization D e b a t e , remains extremely useful; see also Lewin, Political U ndercurrents in Soviet E con om ic D ebates; Dobb, Soviet E con om ic D evelopm en t since 1917; and V. Cligorov, G ledišta i sp orovi o industrijalizaciji u socijalizm u Kitehing, Development an d U n derd ev elop m en t, is particularly helpful in showing the tensions among the Ricardian socialist, Listian nationalist, and Marxian strands within the socialist movement. *3 A. Erlich, The Soviet Industrialization D eb a te; Lewin, Political U ndercurrents; and Dobb, Soviet E con om ic D evelopm en t since 1917, are still particularly useful sources. H Lowenthal, “Development vs. Utopia in Communist Policy,’ is the classic work of this very large genre (most analyses being based on the Chinese case).
22
CHAPTER 1
particular approaches to economic growth and their corresponding party factions. To implement a shift in approach required organizational and regulatory reform, not only of production and exchange hut also of the state. Political authorities attempted to capture savings and control alloca tion not for the purpose of dominance alone45 (although such motives may be found in any system), hut also for the purpose of executing a particular economic theory. The precondition, however, was to obtain and protect political independence over domestic economic decisions; to do so re quired protecting above all national sovereignty, then the system of social ownership of capital, and within that system jurisdictional distinctions in public authority over economic assets. Policy alternations occurred pri marily, it turned out, in response to changing international conditions that affected capital accumulation, the capacity to trade, and national security. The antimilitarism of liberal economists, from the physiocrats on through Marx, left them ill-equipped to conceptualize war readiness as a part of a functioning economy.46 The part of their conceptual tradition that could do so— the mercantilist and cameralist legacy— included a vi sion of the state, however, that the Yugoslav party leaders rejected. Find ing a modus vivendi in the cold-war international order to suit their precondition of independent choice in economic strategy, they devised a peculiar international balancing act among the three camps of that inter national order. But the adjustments required to maintain the country’s balance of foreign payments and those required for defense were often in conflict; similarly, the leaders’ ideological preferences for economic strat egy and political organization often clashed with the requirements of na tional sovereignty and defense. The result was a domestic contradiction that had already emerged during World War I I — between what I will call the “Slovene model” of the ruling strategy and the “Foca conditions” (see chapter 2) that made the strategy possible. That contradiction defined the country’s political dynamic as it altered economic policy in response to changing international conditions. The methods that replaced the market in allocating factors of produc tion varied among socialist societies, and so, therefore, did political orga nization. In the Yugoslav case of the class of reform-communist states, policies were debated in elected assemblies of citizen-producers repre senting autonomous organizations of “associated labor” and among fac tions of the single political party (as tended to be true in hegemonic 15 Verdery, N ational Ideology u n der Socialism, has a very useful summary of these "modes of control” (74-87). 4fi Even Alexander Erlich’s otherwise highly respected analysis of the Soviet debates on development strategy in the 1920s ignores the central role that defense and the army played in these debates and subsequent policy— with the result of crucial misinterpretations, ac cording to Mark von Hagen (personal communication).
23
INTRODUCTION
parties of the same historical period, such as the Liberal Democrats of Japan and the Christian Democrats of Italy). In place of the competitive mechanisms and decision rules of electoral and pressure-group politics, the political system was based on consensual or proportional mechanisms for defining rules by which money, goods, and people would be allocated or redistributed among economic interests. Instead of a choice between wages and jobs, there was a more or less continuous (but not frictionless) adjustment of the methods of employing labor aimed at improving the conditions for increasing both wages and jobs; the reorganization of soci ety to use labor more productively and rules defining labor incentives that aimed to increase productivity would together increase aggregate eco nomic growth. Because all individuals were defined by their labor (and their capacity to create capital, usually measured by their individual contribution to productivity), the way that employment was organized defined the struc ture of society and the main lines of political life and conflict. The mecha nisms of what Claus Offe calls a second logic alongside that of capital— a countervailing political force that people vulnerable to unemployment can wield against those who have power over economic decisions, whether through labor’s organization against capital or popular opposition against the state— did not exist in Yugoslavia.47 Instead, individuals sought to prevent their own unemployment by increasing their personal capital and individual access to employment and by resisting a demotion in their regulated social status. Employers (firms and governments) in turn competed to retain as much autonomy as possible over their assets while increasing their access to additional funds. There were as a result three very separate spheres of political action within the country, as de fined by the leaders’ original political-economic strategy: property owners’ strategies toward capital assets, individuals’ strategies regarding employment and status, and the mass of people left outside this public sector of political activity, including the unemployed. Only the first influ enced policy, but the actions of all three shaped the evolution of Yugoslavia and its similarities with and differences from other socialist states.
Pl a c in g
the
Yu g o sla v C a
se
: S in g u l a r H is t o r ie s
and
Common
R e f o r m St r a t e g ie s
In their comparative project on the size and incidence of unemployment and the response to it in Western Europe, North America, and Australia during the Great Depression, Barry Eichengreen and T. J. Hatton find no 47 Offe, “Two Logics o f Collective Action.
24
CHAPTER 1
common pattern across countries, except that world depression is indeed reflected in large-scale domestic unemployment. Both before and after the Depression, countries varied substantially in the rate of unemploy ment, in the economic and social groups that were unemployed, and in the social consequences of unemployment. “Only in the early 1930s is a common pattern evident,” write Eichengreen and Hatton.4H For the crisis decade of 1 9 7 3 -8 4 , similarly, Goran Therborn finds no general pattern for rates and incidence of unemployment in countries of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (O E C D )— only countryspecific, historically defined profiles.49 This case study of unemployment in socialist Yugoslavia from 1945 to 1990 is based on this finding that countries have their own specific pro files, particularly in patterns of work, employment, and unemployment. It is also intended as a theoretical case study, however, with its assump tion that these profiles are based on variables that are common across countries. The variable of developmental ideology, discussed above, places Yugoslavia in the universe of other socialist states; they had much in common because they shared the same legacy of developmentalist thought, the socialist debates in nineteenth-century Europe, and (for states outside the USSR) experiences with Soviet policy. Thus, despite the attention paid to Yugoslavia’s system of “workers’ control” and “mar ket socialism” as different from state-socialist systems of the Soviet type in Eastern Europe, the similarities in employment structure between Yugoslavia and those countries (with the exception of women’s participa tion in the labor force— related, as will be seen, to the issue of unemploy ment) point to a fundamental commonality. Their differences arose from adapting this common legacy to the local imperatives of political struggle. The socialist parties’ search for allies out side the industrial working class (in agriculture and sections of the urban middle class) as they formed a social movement for revolution and identi fied a domestic enemy, in conjunction with Comintern policy regarding political alliances, defined the social basis of each party when it came to power. Differences also arose from the international conditions under which the party competed for power and from the country’s geopolitical and global economic positions. The effect of these differences in the com position of the party’s political constituency and in international position was substantial variation— within a common ideology— in governmental policy, just as among market economics. It is this variation in governmenm Eicliengreon and Hatton, In terw ar U nemployment iti International Perspective, p. 51, 19 Therborn, W hy Som e Peoples A re M ore U nem ployed than O thers Boltho finds the same variation in European countries’ experience with inflation (The E urop ean Economy). Seharpf uses this variation for his analysis of unemployment in "Economic and Institutional Contraints,”
T
able
1-1
In te rn a tio n a l C o m parison o f th e S e cto ra l D istrib u tio n o f E m p lo y m e n t (p ercen tag es)
M a n ufactu ring & Mining (1) '
Construction i? T reimportation (2)
Trade, Catering, Banking ir Insurance (3)
Other Services (4)
(1) + (2)
(3) + (4)
Yugoslavia
4 2 .6
1 9 .8
1 7 .7
1 9.9
6 2 .4
3 7 .6
B ulgaria
4 4 .8
2 0 .8
1 1 .0
2 3 .4
6 5 .6
3 4 .4
C zech oslo vak ia
4 4 .1
1 9.4
1 2 .7
2 3 .7
6 3 .5
3 6 .4
E a s t G erm a n y
4 7 .1
1 6 .4
11 .5
2 5 .0
6 3 .5
3 6 .5
H u ngary
4 3 .2
2 0 .4
1 2 .2
2 3 .9
6 3 .6
3 6 .1
P oland
4 3 .2
2 1 .8
1 2.2
2 2 .8
6 5 .0
3 5 .0
5 0 .4
2 1 .1
8 .8
19.8
7 1 .5
2 8 .6
4 5 .5
2 0 .0
1 1.4
2 3 .1
6 5 .5
3 4 .5
Austria
3 5 .0
1 7 .0
2 3 .7
2 4 .3
5 2 .0
4 8 .0
B elg iu m
2 7 .9
1 5 .6
2 6 .4
3 0 .1
4 3 .5
5 6 .5
D enm ark
2 4 .0
1 6 .7
2 2 .3
3 7 ,2
4 0 .7
5 9 .5
R om ania A verag e
(■c ontinued)
Table 1-1
Manufacturing &- Mining (1)
Construction ir Transportation (2)
F in lan d
3 1 .0
1 6 .3
F ran ee
2 9 .3
16.4
(Continued) Trade, Catering, Banking 6Insurance (3)
Other Services (4)
(1) + (2)
2 2 .8
3 0 .0
4 7 .3
5 2 .8
2 5 .6
2 8 .2
4 5 .7
5 3 .8
(3) + (4)
G re a t B ritain
3 2 .1
1 3 .5
2 4 .6
2 9 .8
4 5 .6
5 4 .4
Irelan d
2 9 .2
1 8 .4
2 4 .4
2 8 .0
4 7 .6
5 2 .4 4 9 .5
Italy
3 2 .4
1 8 .2
2 4 .7
2 4 .8
5 0 .6
N eth erla n d s
2 3 .7
1 7 .9
2 7 .4
3 1 .0
4 1 .6
5 8 .4
Norway
2 4 .0
18.1
2 5 .0
3 2 .9
4 2 .1
5 7 .9
Portugal
3 7 .2
1 8 .4
1 9 .0
2 5 .1
5 5 .6
4 4 .1
Spain
3 3 .7
1 8 .5
2 9 .6
1 9 .2
5 2 .2
4 8 .8
Sw ed en
2 6 .3
1 4 .2
2 1 .1
3 8 .4
4 0 .5
5 9 .5
Sw itzerland
3 5 .7
1 3 .3
2 9 .8
2 1 .2
4 9 .0
5 1 .0
W e s t G e rm a n y
3 9 .6
1 4.3
2 1 .6
2 4 .7
5 3 .9
4 6 .3
3 0 .7
1 6 .5
2 4 .5
2 8 .3
4 7 .2
5 2 .8
A verag e
S ou rce: International Labor Organization, Y e a rb o o k o f L a b o r Statistics (1981), cited in Mencinger, T h e Yugoslav E con om y, 20.
27
INTRODUCTION T a b l e 1 -2
Level of Employment in Socialist and Market Capitalist Countries, 1974 (percentages) M a r k e t C a p it a l i s t Socialist C o u n trie s
P ercen ta g e
C o u n trie s
P ercen ta g e
Yugoslavia
2 1 .0
Austria
4 0 .1
Bulgaria
3 9 .3
B elg iu m
3 8 .8
Hungary
4 8 .5 4 2 .7
F ra n c e
4 0 .3
East Germany
W e s t G erm a n y
4 1 .4
Poland
5 1 .6
U n ited K ingdom
4 4 .3
Romania
4 7 .9
Japan
4 7 .4
USSR
4 5 .7
U n ited States
4 0 .6
Czechoslovakia
5 0 .1
Sw ed en
4 8 .6
Source: Daviđović, “Nezaposlenost i društvena nejednakost u Jugoslaviji," 4
tal policy, within different social and international contexts, that produces country-specific histories. Among countries ruled by political parties whose social base among wage earners and alliances with small-property owners lead to a sustained commitment to full employment, the governmental policies that matter in achieving full employment, according to the literature on advanced industrial societies, are national strategies for international trade and ad justment. The fact that mass unemployment occurs during global depres sions and that unemployment tends to rise about the same time in many countries because they participate in a global economy (for example, both Yugoslavia and the developed capitalist economies had increasing diffi culty with employment in the global crisis after the late 1970s, just as countries showed a common pattern in the early 1930s) has led to an appreciation of the role of national policy in promoting economic growth and employment at home when recessions occur in primary trading part ners or in reserve-currency countries. As James Alt demonstrates econometrically, so significant a portion of domestic unemployment in open economies can result from a contraction in the external environment that the influence of any macroeconomic policy on the level of domestic unem ployment cannot be assessed without first measuring those external influ ences.50 The regulation school takes such empirical findings to a theoretical level, by arguing that strategies for capital accumulation and their accompanying patterns of employment are international regimes.51 50 Alt, “Political Parties, World Demand, and Unemployment.” 51 For example, this school characterizes the period after 1973 as one of “global overac cumulation of capital in relation to the supply elasticity of both labour-power and primary products” (Itoh, “The World Economic Crisis”). See also Noel, “Accumulation, Regulation, and Social Change.”
28
CHAPTER 1
A country’s niche in the international economy matters critically in this regard, and for a small state dependent on trade for some necessities of industrial growth— such as japan, Sweden, Switzerland, or Austria— the primary issue, according to the scholarship on full employment, is its political capacity to formulate, agree upon, mobilize support for, and im plement a strategy of adjustment to the international economy— to changes in demand for the country’s exports and in its relative terms of foreign trade— in ways other than by adjusting levels of unemployment.52 The key element of Yugoslav exceptionalism was not the country’s sys tem of worker self-management or its multinational state, but its interna tional position— its attempt to retain socialism at home and a vigilant national independence while being open to the world economy, which required constant adjustments in the use of labor and organization of em ployment.53 It was partly in order to make those adjustments at the level of workers’ wages and benefits that workers’ councils were introduced. Yugoslavia’s trajectory differed from that of other socialist countries above all in its earlier move to the economic and political reforms associated with global market integration and export orientation— to what the Hun garians called the “new economic mechanism” and to what R. W. Davies called the “new orthodoxy” in the USSR in 1985, the policies of reform communism that most characterize Leninism.54 Introduced in Hungary after 1 9 5 9 -6 1 , intermittently in Poland, in Czechoslovakia after 1963, and in the Soviet Union most recently and explicitly under Mikhail Gor bachov in 1985, the program had its most sustained experience in Yugoslavia. This book is a study of the attempts to maintain and imple ment that reform program under changing international conditions. W hile the primary difficulty for employment lay with the effect of open ness on the country’s institutions of economic management— the central regulation of financial indicators based on the closed accounting system of Soviet monetary planning (though with origins in German cameralism)— Yugoslav experience suggests that, in analyses of countries that have suc cessful national strategies toward external markets, their international po sition should receive as much attention as is currently paid to their political institutions for economic management. In contrast to Yugo slavia’s position of national independence outside both the Eastern and W estern blocs, the full-employment countries not only were advanced industrial democracies but were fully incorporated into Western trading 52 Alt, “Political Parties, World Demand, and Unemployment"; Katzenstein, C o rp o r a tism a n d C h an ge; Therborn, W hy Som e P eople A re M ore U nem ployed than O thers; Cam eron, "Social Democracy”; Eichengreen and Hatton, In terw ar Unemployment 53 William Zimmerman also sees the domestic-international linkage as critical to the un derstanding of socialist Yugoslavia, but his argument differs from the one presented here; see O pen B ord ers, N onalignm ent, an d the Political Evolution o f Yugoslavia 51 Davies, “Soviet History in the Gorbachev Revolution."
INTRODUCTION
29
alliances, and they had made a choice for neutrality within Western secu rity alliances and for conventional territorial defense. In attempting to explain the political paradox of unemployment in so cialist Yugoslavia, this study came upon a social organization and political dynamic entirely different from that common in most views of the coun try. It was as if the question of unemployment had unlocked doors to the Yugoslav system in the same pivotal way that Marx ascribed to it in the analysis of capitalism. That process of discovery began with an exami nation of the early choices on political and economic strategy made by the Yugoslav Communist party leadership in the course of revolution and early state-building. These choices are the subject of the next two chapters. The leaders decision for political and economic independence from Moscow, although not their choice alone, made the party’s pro cess of consolidation particularly intertwined with international condi tions. That process, prolonged until 1949—52, and the founding period are described in extensive detail in chapter 4 because they were critical to the system that emerged and because the argument presented here dif fers substantially from previous scholarship. Chapter 5 then summarizes the principles of the political system that were put in place in 1952 and that governed the periodic adjustments in subsequent constitutional reforms. As a result of the choices made in that founding period, the Yugoslavs moved ahead of the other socialist states on a path they all eventually took. Incorporating openness into their economic strategy and treating foreign aid, imported machinery, advanced technology, cheaper wage goods, and eventually foreign investment as critical supplements to do mestic resources, they accepted Western food and military assistance, asserted national sovereignty outside of secure cold-war alliances with an independent defense, and moved to integrate into international markets by opening their borders to labor migration, participating in Western cap ital markets, and joining global trade and financial institutions— the G e n eral Agreement on Tariffs and Trade, the International Monetary Fund, and the World Bank (they also had association agreements with the E u ropean Community and the Council for Mutual Economic Assistance). This openness in turn required domestic economic and political reforms. Governmental policy toward employment and unemployment, discussed in chapters 7 and 8 (after the characteristics and meaning of unemploy ment in socialist Yugoslavia are presented in chapter 6), was driven by the need to respond to changes in the country s international environment in the areas of both trade and defense. The result was an increasing ineffec tiveness of the institutions of macroeconomic regulation essential to the leaders’ strategy for employment growth, and a growing disjuncture b e tween the labor policy adopted for international adjustment and the char acteristics of the labor supply at home.
30
CHAPTER 1
The political consequences of the policies of adjusting labor and em ployment to international conditions are discussed in chapters 9 and 10: why there was public silence on the subject of unemployment; why no collective action to change economic policy could he mounted; and how unemployment nonetheless had political effects by corroding the princi ples underlying the political system and leading to a rebellion against it by people who were threatened not by capitalist unemployment but by so cialist unemployment— a loss of social status and political rights over eco nomic assets. As in European social democracies, the most vexing employment problem in the 1980s was not with industrial workers but with civil servants, white-collar administrators and staff, and the social services55— in the language of Yugoslav socialist ideology, “unproductive” people on “guaranteed salaries” from “budgetary employment.” Property owners in the socialist sector fought to retain their rights— either individ ual rights to their social status with its political rights and economic b en e fits, or the collective rights to control economic resources belonging to governments and enterprises. But unlike in market economies, their eco nomic interests, under rapidly changing international conditions, were expressed not in political organization and demands for policy change but in the arena of, and the methods of, the system of employment: redis tribution of labor (of individual incomes and people among jobs and prop erty sectors) and autonomy over capital. The result was a competition over both citizenship rights and governments’ jurisdiction over money and finance; those struggles led, by way of constitutional contest and its competing visions of the state, to the country’s dissolution. v' See Tarschys, "Curbing Public Expenditure, on the "scissors crisis in publie finance ill O E C D countries since the mid-1970s. See also Esping-Audersen, Politics against M ar k e ts, on the significance lor policy change of the political alliance forged by the Swedish Social Democrats with white-collar unions after the late 19(i0s and these unions' “wildcat” opposition when the process of European integration began to displace civil-service jobs abroad (tile significance of the housing problem, also critical in the Yugoslav case, is dis cussed as well)
Chapte r 2 THE MAKING OF A STRATEGY FOR CHANG E
p o l i t i c a l and economic system in socialist Yugoslavia was the prod uct of a strategy in motion, in the process o f becoming. Its institutions never stablized in the sense that most analytical approaches to politics and policy— whether the pressure-group, competitive-party, bureaucratic, or rational-actor approach— take for granted, treating institutions as given conditions in no need of examination. To understand the country’s social order and explain the policies adopted, therefore, one must be more aware of the assumptions and mentality of the leaders who guided policies and institutional reform in response to environmental pressure— assumptions that remained constant (if not fully visible) throughout the period of their rule, as I will argue in the course of this book. The leaders’ strategy for change had much in common with those of other Marxist Leninist parties in Europe, which in turn borrowed much from, or were in reaction to, the policies and institutions of developmentalist govern ments in Europe in the nineteenth century. But strategies were also shaped by the process of acquiring power, and therefore each was particu lar to its own locale— the political questions it had to face, the potential constituencies and political allies within the society, and the level and character of economic development. In contrast to the view that Marxist Leninist political parties are dogmatic, obsessed with “totalitarian” con trol and obedience to the dictates of the center of some hierarchy of power, their strategies were— like the ideology of any other political party— a set of “beliefs or ideas materialized in action, often in political conflict.”1 They were not fixed beforehand, but shaped by the time and conditions in which they were formed. The strategy that the Yugoslav Communist leadership pursued after World War II was a composite of political choices made between 1928 and 1949. Like the approach to unemployment that began to crumble and change in the 1980s in advanced industrial states, such as Sweden, the United States, or France, the Yugoslav system had its origins in the 1930s.2 In making these political choices, the Yugoslav leaders confronted
The
1 Verdery, National Id eolog y u n d er Socialism , 9, 2 The Swedish corporatist system formed by the Social Democratic party between 1932 and 1938 was dismantled during the 1980s, a process completed with the moves for acces sion to the European Community, On the alliances of the New Deal and its Employment
32
CHAPTER 2
two tactical problems. The first was how to construct a single program for 1 a country of such heterogeneity, where political parties, unions, and po tential constituencies differed substantially across regions, where pro found differences of industrial and capitalist development exacerbated the dilemma about how to apply Marxist theory to largely agrarian and pre bourgeois conditions,3 and where the country itself was engaged in great quarrels over how to integrate its preunification territories and socio political orders. This chapter will argue that the early shift of ideological dominance to political forces from the more economically and organiza tionally developed areas of the country, reinforced by the Marxist predi lection to favor that which was most progressive or most advanced, was decisive in defining such a program. The second tactical problem was the fact that the political struggle, to a far greater extent than electoral dy namics in developed economies, played out simultaneously on two fronts: within an international power structure and requirements for interna tional recognition, and within a domestic contest. Equally decisive for ultimate choices was the fact that moments of decision were most often determined by international events, from the founding of the party in 1919 to the end of that formative period, when after 1949 the statebuilding process began to stabilize— because, as its architect Edvard Kardelj told the third party plenum on D ecem ber 29, 1949, the “most important battle of socialism now, ” that of national independence through W estern recognition, had been won.4 The resulting program for transformation did not eliminate the tensions and differences between alternatives and factions. That thorn was still felt by Marshal Tito near the end of his life in 1980; Ivo Banac cites the leader’s reminiscences: “The struggle we began more than fifty years ago for the resolution of party affairs was very hard, since factionalism was deeply rooted, and it went on a long time, practically from the founding of the KPJ [Communist Party of Yugoslavia].”5 Some elements within the package of tactical and strategic choices were mutually contradictory, while substantive differences tended to be submerged in arguments about the appropriate pace of change or hidden in name-calling against political enemies. Act, enacted in 1946, see Hicharcl Bartel’s 1992 interview of James Tobin in “The Economic Pendulum/’ For Franee, see Piore’s review of the Salais group study, in “Historical Perspec tives and the Interpretation of Unemployment 3 See Hoston, Marxism an d the Crisis o f D evelopm en t in P rew ar Ja p a n , as a good exam ple of how central this problem was to the formation of strategy and tac tics within Marxist parties in the twentieth century* 4 Petranovic, Koncar, and Kaclonjic, S edn ice Cen traln og kom iteta KJ}J (1948—1952), 474, r> W ith Stalin again st Tito, 45. Shoup emphasizes this factionalism as well in his careful study, C om m unism a n d the Yugoslav N ational Q uestion, especially 13-59.
THE MAKING O F A STRATEGY FOR CHANGE
33
In contrast to the tendency in the literature on Yugoslavia to character ize conflict in terms of political power only, this analysis attempts to re store attention to what it considers those conflicts to have been about— at base, about a search for the optimal development of material life and the corresponding organization of social life, then about control over eco nomic resources, and only in that context about the political instruments necessary to those goals. For example, the literature interprets both ac tual conflicts over domestic economic policy and contests by which strat egy was formulated and redefined as fights among leaders for personal power (elite conflict);6 among ethnic groups for dominance or autonomy (national conflict);7 or among layers in the party and state hierarchy for the location of power (conflict between center and republics, statism and pluralism, plan and market, conservatives and liberals).8 But none of these classifications can explain its political construction of the problem of unemployment. Turning points considered politically decisive turn out to be far more ambiguous if one focuses on political-economic strategy. For example, the argument that 1940 is critical because the party was then fully “bolshevized,” meaning that Tito succeeded in consolidating his leadership and imposing iron discipline,9 looks different in light of the material in this chapter. The year 1948, universally recognized as decisive because Tito secured independence for his leadership and his country in a contest with Stalin in the famous quarrel that established the principle of “national communisms” (the ability of countries governed by Communist parties to follow their own path independently of Moscow),10 seems far less important than 1946, 1947, and 1949, according to the material in chapters 3 and 4. For some, the interlude of the world war in 1 9 4 1 -4 5 is 6 See especially Burg, C onflict a n d C ohesion in Socialist Yugoslavia Rusinow, The Yugoslav Experiment, is far more nuanced, though he does weave his story around the contest between liberals and conservatives. 7 Most studies of postwar Yugoslav politics pay obligatory obeisance to the national ques tion as the underlying character of the state. The most undiluted version is in Banac, The National Question in Yugoslavia; see also Ramet, N ationalism a n d F ederalism in Yugoslavia; and Cohen and Warwick, Political C oh esion in a F ragile Mosaic. 8 Comisso, Workers' C on trol u n d er Plan an d M arket; Burg, C onflict a n d Cohesion; Milenkovitch, Plan an d M arket in Yugoslav E con om ic T hought (in her discussion of eco nomic thought, not political factions); Rusinow, The Yugoslav E xperim ent 9 Banac, With Stalin against Tito, 78. 10 See especially Campbell, T ito’s S ep arate R oad; Radonjić, Su kob KPJ s K om in form om i društveni razvoj Jugoslavije, 1948-1950, 108ff.; Ulam, Titoism an d the C om in form ; Clissold, Yugoslavia an d the Soviet Union, 1939-1973 , 4 2 -4 3 ; Auty, “Yugoslavia and the Cominform and Banac, "Yugoslav Cominformist Organizations ” A. Ross Johnson s study The Transformation o f C om m unist Id eolog y is also based on the concept of ideology as being shaped and reshaped in the process of critical political conflicts, but his choice oi timing and critical event— before and after the Cominform resolution of June 28, 1948— creates a pic ture of a process very different from what I think occurred.
34
CHAPTER 2
decisive because of the leadership’s decision to organize a peasant, “all national” following with the battle cry of national liberation from foreign oppressors11 and because of the leaders’ troubled relationship with Stalin, which provided the resources for their independence— a popular follow ing at home and the doubt necessary to disobedience. But this interlude was far more important in defining the army’s postwar role and the leaders’ political tactics abroad than in granting the party legitimacy at home. In fact, the underlying theme in the entire literature on Yugoslavia of national independence and difference from the Soviet bloc distracts from all these countries similarities in economic strategy and in the influ ence of their international position (in relation to Moscow as well as the W est and the third world) on policy choices and political reform. To get away from these characterizations of what will still be familiar pieces (though told from a different perspective), I propose a different labeling shorthand for, on the one hand, the dominant package of the leaders’ chosen design for a state and a social order and, on the other hand, the tensions that remained unresolved in the conditions in which the leaders operated and the disagreements among them. In keeping with the territorial organization of economic and political power that was so critical to the postwar state and the influence of its wartime origins, I will call these two tendencies (after the Partisans’ wartime rules of order) the Slo vene and Foca models. W e begin with the choices made before the war.
Id e n t it y
and
O
r g a n iza t io n a l
Bo u n d a r ie s
The most fundamental decisions for a party and its strategy are those about identity: Who are we? W here do we draw our boundaries terri torially and socially? With whom will we ally? How do we view our role in history? It was critical that these questions were posed for the Yugoslav Communist party in the interwar period when the national question drove political conflicts and the language of conflicts even when they were about other matters. The new Yugoslav state joined territories and peoples with separate identities and social orders, and their commitment to the common state and some common identity varied.12 In addition, 11 C, Johnson, P easant N ationalism an d C om m unist P ow er. 12 Because the government was identified with the Serbian monarchy and its seat in Belgrade, and because the country was multinational, it was common to fight government policy in terms of national assertion and charges of national discrimination. Since histories of that period tend to focus on the national question, it is difficult for scholars even fifty years later to see a different story, and the wars of 1991 and 1992 will reinforce this difficulty. See, for example, Banac, T he N ational Q uestion; and Cohen and Warwick, Political Cohesion, In N ation al Id eolog y u n d er Socialism (especially pt, 2), Verdery argues that in socialist Ro mania, this preoccupation of the intellectuals came, over time, to capture the discourse and ideology of the Communist party.
THE MAKING OF A STRATEGY FOR CHANGE
35
those party leaders who tried to maintain the Marxist position that na tional consciousness and nation-states were secondary to and even diver ted from the class struggle came under the most criticism from the Comintern, which focused on the national question as a resource for revolution— such as when its tactics demanded the right to self determination of peoples and the anticolonial struggle of “oppressed na tions” to break up empires in the cause of “workers’ and peasants’ states.”13 The fact was that the Yugoslav party, from its founding in April 1919, was also an alliance of preunification socialist parties and left-wing cultural clubs that had different political legacies (the German social dem ocratic and Austromarxist influences in Slovenia, for example, were very different from the Chernyshevskian Marxism ofSvetozar Markovic’s party in Serbia) and different national consciousnesses. Although Paul Shoup and Walker Connor argue that the party’s eventual success lay in its very ambiguity on the national question,14 the issue was decisive in the choice of constitutional program for the new state and in the consequences of the choice of party leaders, in contrast with the equally compelling but less influential events of the agricultural crisis of the 1920s, the Great D epres sion of the 1930s, or the king’s suspension of the democratic constitution in 1929. Moreover, in the extensive literature on the party’s frequent shifts, quarrels, and attempts to avoid the question, the usual distinction drawn between internationalists (who saw national identities as a useful weapon in the service of revolution) and committed nationalists tells us little about how nationalism was defined, recognized, and authorized in the Yugoslav space .15 For example, internationalists could follow Lenin or Stalin, and nationalists could believe, with the Austromarxist Karl R en ner, in a “democratic nationalities federal state” recognizing that cultural identities were as fundamental as economic ones for social organization;16 or with the German social democrats of the 1875 (Gotha) program that nation-states were the natural organizational unit for an economy; or with 13 Connor, The N ational Q uestion in M arxist-Leninist T heory a n d Strategy, 1 3 7 -4 2 and chap, 3; Carr, T he B olshevik Revolution, vol. 1, note B, “The Bolshevik Doctrine of Self Determination,” 410-28. 14 Shoup, C om m unism a n d th e Yugoslav N ational Q uestion, in the contrast he draws (in the conclusion) between the relation o f Communist rule and the national question in the period of state formation and the relation that had evolved by the 1960s; Connor, T he N a tional Question, 168. 15 Connor’s statement that Tito was an internationalist, calling frequently on patriotism but always subordinating national goals to that of the revolution (The N ational Q uestion, xiv), is disputable at many points in the leader's long career. 16 Culick, Austria f r o m H ab sb u rg to H itler 2:1369. Convinced of the Austrian influence on debates in the northwest of Yugoslavia, despite my critics, I was particularly grateful to Benjamin Ward for suggesting this work and the relevance of the Second and a Half International.
36
CHAPTER 2
the Slovene Edvard Kardelj and many Croat Communists that the prole tarian struggle was first of all a national struggle and the best way to achieve national aspirations.17 The first major choice came with the rout of the right faction from the party leadership (the faction was outvoted in 1924 and purged by the Comintern in 1928) in lavor of a revolutionary approach that was against working within the state as then constituted. The shift in party leadership from Serbian to non-Serbian (especially Croat and Slovene) dominance was particularly decisive, because it forever after confirmed federalism for both party and government, as well as a strongly anticentralist concept of the state (often tinged with opposition to Great Serbianism or Serbs in general). For example, despite the Comintern’s shift to united-front tac tics after 1935 and the party’s attempt to build that front on a Yugoslav identity for all sections of the party and for its revolutionary objectives, the party followed through on its commitment in 1934 to national self determination: when the Slovenes applied for their own section in the Comintern, the Yugoslav party gave full organizational autonomy to the Communist party of Slovenia (in 1937) and then to the Croat party (in 1938). The federal units of the constitution adopted provisionally in 1943 were to be defined nationally, but the concept of national identity that emerged and its meaning for political tactics were also a result of the influence on party thinking of the intellectual milieu in Croatia and Slovenia in the 1920s and 1930s. As Silva Meznaric recounts it, intellectuals from these former Ilabsburg territories felt themselves trapped, in limbo in both national and class terms: they were in a backward state that was using mercantilist policies to protect the less competitive and less developed Serbian bourgeoisie and thereby preventing the full domestic develop ment of capitalist forces; and in European space, their reality of pettybourgeois peripherally and international “nonposition” due to the stunted development of an indigenous bourgeoisie separated them from the world of great nation-states and the advance of global capitalism.18 The proletarian revolution would be simultaneously a national revolution— against the exploitative tax and foreign-trade policies of the Serbian state and carsija , 19 against its increasing dependence on foreign connections 17 Basoin, “Socialism as National Liberation,” provides a useful analysis of Kardelj s writ ings and pronouncements on the national question. 18 Meznaric, “A Neo-Marxist Approach to the Sociology of Nationalism: A Quest for The ory” (published in Praxis In tern ation al as “A Neo-Marxist Approach to the Sociology of Nationalism, Doomed Nations, and Doomed Schemes”). 19 Political slang for the links among merchants, bureaucrats, and state-protected indus tries centered in Belgrade.
THE MAKING OF A STRATEGY FOR CHANGE
37
and capital to maintain that power at home, and against the political chains of absolutism that prevented those in the former Habsburg territo ries from completing their process of nation-building and the democratic, republican revolution that would make the bourgeois stage of develop ment possible. But these intellectuals tended to define the problem of revolution largely as one of consciousness and political action. Steeped in the tradition of Hegelian “positioning,” they were aware that both Marx and Engels categorically dismissed the Slavic nations as “relics of peoples,” “nonhistoric nations” that would disappear with the march of capitalism, “barbarians” incapable of civilization and without the right of self-determination that was due the great, historic nations.20 In the intellectuals’ interwar debates, as Meznarič records them, many be came obsessed with asking, “Who are we in Europe?” What role could a working-class party of Slavs in a land of “vagabonds, travelling salesmen, smugglers” play within this historical process, to escape their pettybourgeois peripherally? Both their explanation for this economic and po litical reality and the source of their emancipation were to be found in the sphere of consciousness and cultural identity, with the “ideology of small ness,” deference to the major “historic” nations and the latter’s cultural hegemony in Europe, and a sense of community characterized by a sklavenmoral (slave culture) in subordination to this external herrenmoral (master culture). Cultural backwardness maintained and perpetuated their economic backwardness and global nonposition because it hindered any internal sources of innovation, whether economic or cultural, thus making them forever vulnerable to great-power designs on their territory. Economic weakness in turn brought political impotence and subjection and led to cultural insignificance, which then returned full circle to eco nomic exploitation.21 For these activist intellectuals, the historic mission of the Communist party was to take on the creative, revolutionary role played elsewhere by the bourgeoisie: to overthrow the Serbian monarchy, build a republic, emancipate the mass of the population from their petty-bourgeois mental ity of inferiority by making them conscious of their collective power to alter their fate with their own hands, and bring “national equality to Serbs, Croats, Slovenes, Macedonians, Montenegrins.”22 This substitute 20 Meznarič, "A Neo-Marxist Approach," 11-12; see also Connor, The N ational Q uestion; and Slioup, Communism a n d the Yugoslav N ational Question. 21 Meznarič, “A Neo-Marxist Approach,” 9 The terms of reference are shared through out the region; ior a slightly different approach, see Janos, The Politics o f B ackw ardn ess in Historical Perspective: H ungary, 1825-1945 22 Josip Broz Tito, at the fifth party conference, October 19-23, 1940, cited in Connor, The National Question, 147.
38
CHAPTER 2
bourgeoisie would begin the process of economic emancipation with cul tural and political emancipation. The fight for national independence by all the Yugoslav peoples against imperial powers, foreign capital, and their domestic agents and collaborators would achieve self-determination for the working people as national communities. The concept of a nation in this critique was first of all a historical one, implying a set of class stages and a view of progress for peoples (nations) that were defined by the historical and territorial characteristics of states. Nations were also economic units and communities o f common culture and language — the mix so common to the German sphere of reflection, developmental thought, and critique to which Marx, Engels, Herder, List, and Hegel all contributed.23 Whatever the permutations of the idea of self-determination in the shifting Soviet, Comintern, and Yugoslav po sitions (autonomy, self-rule, the right to secession, full sovereignty), it always meant self-government of territorial units that had historical con sciousness as nations— “free cultural and economic development” of an “administrative character. ”24 From this perspective, however, the nations within multinational Yugoslavia were not at the same stage of development. This was a prob lem tactically; as late as 1940, delegates to the fifth party conference in Zagreb could not themselves fully agree on what level of national forma tion had been achieved by each.25 Capitalist development was very un evenly spread over the Yugoslav territories— from Slovenia, where commercial agriculture, public education and roads, and light manufac turing had begun to develop with the mid-eighteenth-century Theresian reforms in the Habsburg empire, to Bosnia and Macedonia, where Ottoman-type feudal relations on the land still marked political as well as economic and social life in the 1930s. Smallholding dominated agricul ture, with the exception of the large estates of the plains of Vojvodina and 23 The attempt (as in Szporluk, Communism an d Nationalism ) to counterpose commu nism and nationalism, especially in the sense of Marxism and Listianism, as polar opposites does not work for central Europe. In the Yugoslav debates and perceptions in the interwar period, the two were opposite sides, perhaps, but of the same coin. Hroch, “How Much Does Nation Formation Depend on Nationalism? and Kitching, Develojnncnt an d Under d ev elop m en t in H istorical P erspective, demonstrate the interaction and frequent interde pendence o( the two ideologies. 21 Tito, discussing the character of the new Yugoslav federation in B o rb a , May 22, 1945, citcd in Shoup, Comm unism a n d the Yugoslav National Question, 116n. 25 In the notes on the debate that remain, Milovan Djilas appears to have taken a mediat ing role, arguing that "the Croatian national question still exists.” Tito replied that "the Croatian question is solved as a bourgeois question. But it is not completely solved even for the bourgeoisie (who are fighting in treacherous ways). There exists a clique with great Croatian oppressive tendencies (Damjanović, Bosić, and La/.arević, Peta zemaljska kon fer en c ija KPJ, 214 ).
THE MAKING O F A STRATEGY FOR CHANGE
39
Macedonia, but these were held by absentee foreign owners or the churches (especially Roman Catholic and Muslim). Each region had been governed until 1918 by a different regime (or by a mixture, as in BosniaHerzegovina, which had a layer of Austro-Hungarian on top of Ottoman institutions after 1878), and the differences persisted because nearly all efforts by the Belgrade government to integrate the country— in financial institutions, roads and communications, educational policy, and industrial investment— had foundered on interminable political conflicts, local ob struction, or heavy-handed imposition of state policies in response.2fi Peoples in the south, such as in what would become the republics of Bosnia and Macedonia, were in many (but not all) instances still mired in precapitalist relations with respect to religion, colonial oppression, and the nation embodied in the feudal power of a landholding class. Kardelj’s insistence that the basis for national divisions on the historical map of Europe lay with communication and language27 made it possible to grant at least the Bosnians recognition as a nation, a matter subject to dispute throughout the interwar (and even postwar) period. Tito, intervening in the rancorous debate at the last party conference before the war (in Octo ber 1940) regarding the national status of Muslims and the basis of nation hood for the ethnically mixed population of Bosnia, insisted that “Bosnia is a single unit because of centuries of communal life, regardless of reli gious beliefs.”28 But the national position of the Macedonians was a source of continuing dispute, revealing clearly that the Croats’ and Slovenes’ view guiding their policies toward national identity reflected only one of many class realities, with direct political consequences. The Macedonian party section’s perspective in 1940 was not a nation ally defined territory in relation to European power (as it was to be de fined in the federal structure after the war), but of class divisions within the Macedonian territory along national lines, divisions created by the colonizing policies of the Serbian state. According to Metodija Šator Sarlo, the secretary of the temporary regional committee formed for M ac edonia in February 1940,29 the national question of Macedonia was pri marily a question of land, and this was an issue of class exploitation, despite the party leadership’s position that it was not. It divided the party section between Macedonians and Serbs— not only the Serbian “gen erals, gendarmes, and spies,” but all colonists who were “given the best 26 I am grateful to István Csillag for emphasizing (in relation to debates in the 1970s about the level of economic integration among the Yugoslav republics) the failure o f the interwar royal government to integrate not only physical infrastructure but also the financial institu tions necessary for a unified market. 27 Meznarič, “A Neo-Marxist Approach.” 28 Damjanovič, Bosić, and Lazarevič, Peta zem aljska kon feren cija, 214. 29 Shoup, Com m unism a n d th e Yugoslav N ational Q uestion, 5 2 -5 3 .
40
CHAPTER 2
land,” all of it taken from Macedonian peasants and their common pas tures and forests. In Sarlo’s view, the Croat position (and thus that of the party program) was “sectarian, Trotskyist”— telling the Macedonians that they would resolve their national question only after the proletarian world revolution and taking Lenin’s position on the solidarity of all nationalities— whereas the Macedonians had to proceed immediately with developing their national consciousness, through culture and lan guage, and emancipating their land from Serb rule.30 “W e can’t go to the Macedonian peasant and tell him that colonists are the brothers of the Macedonian peasant, Sarlo insisted. “Whoever knows the psychology of the Macedonian peasant knows that he is fighting for blood revenge against the colonists.”31 The same argument applied to the Albanians in Kosovo-Metohija, where the colonists were “the pillar of hegemony [Great Serbianism],” where “feudal remnants” were still large, and where the “struggle for national rights of the Arnauti [Albanians]” was just beginning.32
The provisional government of 1943 created a federal republic of “na tions” that represented historical communities, territorially defined, with extensive economic and cultural administrative autonomy; it thus autho rized the dominance of the “progressive” sections of the party from the more-developed northwest. The importance to them of retaining each nation’s individuality at each stage of their common struggle even pre vented the use of “Yugoslav” labels. The war, for example, was an “all national liberation struggle” under the slogan of “brotherhood and unity. ” The Macedonian section of the party coidd be a united, “nationalrevolutionary” front “cooperating with liberal bourgeois groups” because of their role in questions of culture and language; the working class would lead the struggle for this cultural self-determination, but it was not to take land from colonists— “only from those who oppress the Macedonian na tion.”33 This rejection of the Macedonian (and Albanian) national concept led Sarlo to take the Macedonian section to the Bulgarian party, where Georgi Dimitrov continued to hold Stalin’s view; likewise, the Albanians from Kosovo-Metohija joined the Italians, who were also more limber in their use of the colonial argument. Moreover, it was only after the war, at the fifth party congress in July 1948, that the four “communities”— Bosnia, Macedonia, Montenegro, and Serbia— gained the full status of separate party organizations (“national committees”) to conform with the nationally defined territories of the new federal state. 30 31 32 33
Damjanovic, Bosie, and Lazarevic, Peta zcm aljska kon feren cija, 210-11. Ibid., 210. Ibid., 213. Djilas, at the fifth party conference, ibid., 212.
THE MAKING OF A STRATEGY FOR CHANGE D iv is io n s
w it h in
Un
it y
: T
he
Labor Q
41
u e st io n
The political victory of the Communist party after World War II is usually attributed to its redefinition of the national question as peasant patriotism against foreign invaders and to its insistence on an all-Yugoslav program, operating in all areas of the country. The party was the sole Yugoslav organization that appealed to the peoples’ common interest in a better life and in putting behind them the conflicts of the interwar period with the resulting wartime horrors. But the party’s actual approach to the national question— recognizing the differences in national development by allow ing economic, cultural, and political autonomy, and recognizing all the nations’ right to self-determination with their voluntary (at least in theory) union in a common state after 1 9 4 3 -4 5 (what Connor calls “retroactive self-determination’’ on the Leninist reasoning)34— was the source of ex traordinary difficulty. A working-class party committed to economic de velopment and social revolution would necessarily have to have a single plan for all areas, while operating politically in the different contexts of each of the national territories. The differences in national consciousness across these territories paled in comparison to their differences in socio economic conditions and level of organizational development, and were in part a result of them. The party’s Marxist focus on what was most economically advanced and politically progressive— “the organization of the most advanced elements of the proletariat” as “the greatest productive force in society”35— did give a direction that would likely have prevailed even without the choice of leaders in 1928 and especially after 1937, with Josip Broz and his circle. The overwhelming portion of the organized working class and the strong est industrial unions with the longest tradition were in Slovenia and Croatia. The Slovene proposal for a constitution in the bitter conflict of 1919-21, although rejected, contained a replica of the social legislation of the Weimar constitution, including the Bismarckian social-insurance pro grams and the workers’ councils favored by the German Social D em o cratic party.36 The 1921 constitution and the 1922 Law on Workers’ Social Insurance did incorporate for those workers who belonged to registered unions the benefits that Slovene and Croat workers had won under the 34 The N ational Q uestion, 161. 35 Rankovic, "Referat o sindikalnom pitanju/’ 4 9 -5 0 . 36 Beard and Rad in write: “Betraying perhaps the influence of the new German constitu tion, the Slovenian project declares that the age o f the military and police state is over and that the time has come for the social state. Some industries are to be placed in the hands of an economic council representing employees, employers, and consumers. In certain se lected industries, the workers are to be empowered by legislation to take part in administra tion and to share in the profits” (The B alkan Pivot, 4 9 -5 0 ; see also 55-56).
42
CHAPTER 2
Habsburgs (guaranteeing health care and material assistance for illness, injury, old age, and death, for insured workers and their dependents).37 Zagreb workers gained notoriety for their militancy during the interwar period, which the government repressed quite severely on occasion. There were important pockets of radical workers elsewhere, such as those employed in the munitions factories ot Kragujevac (Serbia), the to bacco workers in Macedonia, the printers in Montenegro, and the mem bers of the famous soccer club of Split, but the real strength of the party outside of Slovenia and Croatia was not in industry. In Belgrade, for ex ample, its strength was in the state sector and services (postal workers and unionized white-collar employees in banking, insurance, commerce, and construction). As late as 1940, at the fifth party conference, a delegate from Serbia noted that their party cadres “still undervalue the unions” and had “not posed the question of unemployment, or the starvation it threatened, as sharply as they ought.”38 Even after a particularly success ful period of organizing workers and militant protest, in 1936-40, the report on the trade-union question at the 1940 conference admitted that the party remained weak among “miners, monopoly-sector workers, transport workers, and the industrial proletariat."39 While organized workers had the right to assistance during unemployment, and the gov ernment contributed public funds to that aid after 1937,40 the approach to unemployment in Belgrade at the time consisted of police roundups of beggars to do what amounted to forced labor, in conditions closer to me dieval than modern. Most cities became depots for abandoned children of unemployed and uninsured families, who lived by begging or in appren ticeship to master workmen under near slavery conditions.41 The sense of degradation and powerlessness among apprentices from peasant homes pervades the memoirs and interviews of one of their kind who was to become the leader of the Yugoslav Communist party— Josip Broz.
37 Sce Has, "DruStveno-ekonomski osvrt na problem zaposlenosti,' 135-36; and Parmalee. “Medicine under Yugoslav Self-Managing Socialism,'' 3 8 -42. 3S Damjanović, Bosić, and Lazarević, Pela zem aljska kon feren cija, 206. Vl Ranković. “Referai o sindikalnom pitanju, ’ 51. 1,1 In 1927 the workers’ chambers, responsible for unemployment insurance, wer obliged to be “self-managing’ (i e., financially autonomous); but during the second wave ol intcrwar unemployment after 1936 (in the first wave, in 1930-34, every fifth insured worker was thrown out of work, and the real incomes of those who kept their jolis dropped 20 percent), that compensation was so paltry that the government granted public funds. The number of registered unemployed grew from 139,382 in 1928 to 1,069,443 in 1940 (M. Radovanović, “Različita shvatanja uzroka i oblika nezaposlenosti,” 47; Dukanac, Indeksi kon ju n kturn og razvoja Jugoslavije, 1919—1941, 2 7-2 8; Has, “Društvcno-ekonomski osvrt,’ 134-36; Ranković, “Referat o sindikalnom pitanju ’; Vuković, “Uticaj svetske privredne krize, ” 213-15), 11 Kalembcr, “Siromaštvo i pitanje besposličenja.’’ 440-44
THE MAKING OF A STRATEGY FOR CHANGE
43
The rural population had declined only to 74 percent by the end of the interwar period, and this figure rose as one traveled south; in Macedonia, it was 90 percent.42 It is true that this agricultural sea included areas of large landed estates with agricultural laborers, numbering 400,000 in the Vojvodina plain, for example. The cyclical industries of mining, construc tion, brickmaking, and timber continued to depend on the ancient tradi tion of seasonal migration by unskilled peasants called polutani,43 who left their land temporarily to seek cash-paying industrial jobs; these com posed more than half the industrial labor force (in 1 9 2 9 -3 4 , only 46.5 percent of industrial workers were in full-time positions, and only half of those were insured). As the delegate from Dalmatia reported at the 1940 party conference, the land question was “as important as the union one. ”44 The Macedonians’ conflict with the party’s definition of the na tional question, which Sarlo and others found impossible to separate from the agrarian question, arose from their view, with Stalin, that the op pressed, colonized peasants were the revolutionary force. But organiza tion among agricultural workers and small farmers was greatest, too, in Croatia and Slovenia, where the cooperative tradition was well-developed and peasant parties were strong. To simplify this complexity, the party leaders used three political ideol ogies. The first was a national one. In Croatia, such an ideology was hard to avoid because the Communists’ main competitor, the Croat Peasant party (CPP), based its successful appeal on Croat nationalism and identi fying the Croat rural population as the true “people” (narod). The Slovene Peoples’ party was also nationalist and clerical, in the Austrian Christian Social tradition. But the largest of the Serbian parties, the Radicals, al though originally a peasant party, had long since become a party of the Belgrade royal establishment and local notables; and the other major Ser bian parties operated outside Serbia proper, in Croatia or Vojvodina. For others, Lenin’s analysis of rural class differentiation, between rich farmers and poor or middle peasants, served better. Confused over the Macedonian focus on colonial (Serbian) usurpation of the peasant’s right to their land, one Montenegrin delegate at the party conference asked, “Are there peasants, poor ones, who are colonists?” Another criticized the state in Montenegro because the monies being spent to drain Lake Scu tari would benefit the bourgeoisie, while the state paid no attention to the poor peasant and how he lived. The Serbian delegate used the Russian 12 Kostić, Seljaci-indtistriski radnici; Metodija Šator Sarlo, in Damjanovič, Bosić, and Lazarevič, Peta zem aljska kon feren cija, 210, for Macedonia. The agricultural population in 1931, the year of the last prewar census, was 76.5 percent (Tomasevich, Peasants, Politics, and Economic C han ge in Yugoslavia, 303). 43 The word connotes something second-rate or mixed-breed. 11 Damjanovič, Bosić, and Lazarevič, Peta zem aljska kon feren cija, 212-13,
44
CHAPTER 2
metaphor in his focus on the marketing cooperatives that enabled the kulak to hold a village in his fist by controlling the supply and marketing of grain and by retaining the entire profit from the rise in grain prices. Discussing Vojvodina, party members concentrated on the burden of the land tax and the dominance of rich farmers and other bourgeois elements in the credit and flood-control cooperatives. Delegates from Dalmatia also singled out the dominance of wealthy farmers over rural cooperatives, particularly where Communists faced legal obstacles to competing openly or to infiltrating the powerful village cooperatives (Gospodarska Sloga) and cultural organizations (Seljačka Sloga) of the C P P .45 The third ideology was actually a combination of two others and was meant to address the difficult task of forming alliances under these cir cumstances. It included the Leninist idea of a vanguard party, represent ing the most advanced elements of the working class at its core; and revisionism, with its idea of the solidarity of a popular front of exploited forces across poor and middle strata. Even the Slovene and Croat workers were divided among unions organized, in the manner of French ones, along religious, ethnonational, and ideological lines. Slovene workers tended to side firmly with the social democrats or the clericals (and Kar delj admitted at the 1940 party conference that the Slovene party had done little to prevent German-speaking workers from joining the German union and from there siding with Hitler). In Croatia, Catholic unions and the union affiliated with the CPP were strong. W here peasant parties had organized cooperatives, in the north, the Communists’ attempt to create “peasant chambers” on the model of workers’ chambers was unsuccessful. There were divisions between organized and unorganized workers (pri marily women and youth, who faced legal prohibitions on organizing and who filled the classic niche of Marx’s industrial reserve army as low-cost competitors because of their lower skills and the traditional attitudes of employers); between unemployed urban workers and the rising number of peasants kicked off the land by the agrarian crisis after the mid-1920s but blocked from their usual escape route by the anti-immigrant walls around the richer countries after 1923;46 and between Communists and 15 Ibid. 46 The fall in world farm prices in the second half of the 1920s was followed by declining domestic demand during the 1930s because urban wages also tell; growing poverty, indebt edness to moneylenders (who were often also local politicians), increasing liquidation of peasant smallholdings, and even widespread malnutrition bordering on starvation hit all areas of the country (see Tomasevich, P easants, Politics, a n d E con om ic C h an ge, pt, 2, but particularly chaps. 19, 20, and 27 [especially pp. 667-80]). A searing portrait of those condi tions in Croatia— and an explanation of why many who were exposed to them became politi cally radicalized— can be had from an ethonographic diary of the young Rudolf Bićan ić, an influential economist in post-World War II Croatia who before the war was an activist in the C PP, which he kept during a tour of the countryside to get in touch with “the people" after
THE MAKING O F A STRATEGY FOR CHANGE
45
former a||ies in the United Unions о f Yugoslavia (U jedinjenje Sin dikata Jugoslavije), who benefited by collaborating with the corporatist гееиле after 1937 (in the view o f the C om m unists, betraving the S n g class by accepting laws against the strike and by cooperating with hour
/Z s T lT
' ™ e s e ,divis; ons P revented any real action for workers' nghts and demanded political unity as its precondition
71.e common denom inator o f these political ideologies was that workers should be united organized on branch principles instead of by trade and profession into com prehensive unions with sections for youth and women, and unified at local, regional, and countryw ide seats into one working class: one union p er factory, one party for the country. And b e cause the united-front strategy am ong progressive, opposition parties had failed the party would shift (as the C om intern signaled in 1939, to a StratT fr° m be,OW> ° rRanizinK thl T h e political m o m e n to u s n e ss of this decision is perh a p s re fle cted in the fact that
011
th e sa m e day , th e p u blic p r o s e c u to r was told to r e le a se Žujo vie from p riso n — after' lie had b e e n willing,
011
N o v em b er 11, to go b e fo re the c e n tra l c o m m i t t e e and confess to having
e n g a g e d in e n e m y activ ity , and on co nd itio n that hr1 w rite a public le t t e r explain ing that lie Irad b e e n w r o n g to b e liev e in th e U S S R blindly ( published in B orb a
011
N o v e m b e r 25 , 1950,
VI I I . I TA li Y S K L K H K U A N C K
151
later, on the t w e n ty - f o u r t h , 155 and th e N o v e m b e r issue of th e p arty j o u r nal published an a rticle justifying in ternational loans in th e transition to socialism,156 On D e c e m b e r 2 9 , P re s id e n t T ru m a n signed th e Yugoslav Emergency Assistance A ct of 1 9 5 0 g ran tin g food up to $ 5 0 million. The restructuring o f p u b lic-s e e to r e n te rp rise s to re d u c e labor tu rn o v e r and cut the w age bill also re t u r n e d to th e 1 9 4 7 system . E n t e r p r i s e m a n agement once again b e c a m e resp on sib le for e m p l o y m e n t and training; th e economic c oercion
of b u d g e t con train ts a im ed to regain discipine on
wages and provide in cen tiv es to im p ro v e w o r k e r s ’ skills; and y e t a n o t h e r innovation in w ork p lace organization to k eep w ages in line with real p r o ductivity began. In th e fall o f 1 9 4 9 , th e tim e o f this n e w policy, th e c o u n try was at the h eigh t of the lab or-b rig ad e cam p aign (only th e p revious April called the “n ew s ystem of lab o r”); n e w sp a p e rs from S e p t e m b e r to December 1949 con tain little else than stories o f b rigad es from all areas of the country, acco lades for th e w o r k e r s ’ advisory com m ission s that told factory administrators how to in crease p rod u ctiv ity , and the location of the hero of the h o u r, Alija Sirotanovie, w h o was on tou r with his b rigad e to teach miners all o v e r th e c o u n tr y th eir n ew m e th o d for in creasin g o u t put.157 But the lesson lead ers d re w from th e “Alija Sirotanovie M o v e m e n t for Higher L ab o r P ro d u ctiv ity ” was that th e re re m a in e d im m e n s e “i n te r nal reserves ’ of labor in in du stry that justified a series of “rev isio ns’ in th e number of em p lo y ed . The new system was in tro d u ce d in a cam p aign o f t h r e e battles d uring 1950: the “battle to stabilize the labor fo rc e ” with e m p lo y m e n t c o n tra c ts ; the ‘battle to b alance goods and m o n e ta r y fu nds” th ro u g h e n t e r p r is e level balances a m o n g w ages, labor plans, and g u a ra n te e d provisions; and the "battle to e x e c u t e th e p ro d u ctio n plan with re d u c e d quotas o f l a b o r .” Their sum was the s ystem later known as s e lf-m a n a g e m e n t in w orkp laces, which began in D e c e m b e r 1 9 4 9 with th e election o f w o r k e r s ’ councils. According to th e R egulation on S ettlin g L a b o r o f early Ja n u a ry 1 9 5 0 , workers would not b e p e r m it te d to work after M arch I w itho u t a w ritten p. I). Žujović ag re e d to t h e s e co nd itio n s w h e n h e h e a r d , in new s r e p o rts o f the p e rio d since ITiis arrest given him by Djilas, o f attacks at th e trial o f Laszlo Rajk on p e rso n s h e kn ew well and on the Yugoslav p arty as fascist, ■ L 5'5 Tomasevich su gg ests, in “C ollectiviz a tio n o f A g ricu ltu re in Y u g o sla v ia ,’’ that d e c o l l e c tivization may have b een a co n d itio n for food aid; bu t th e a r g u m e n t of this book is th a t no p l i condition was n e c e s s a r y . ■Lil5fi Guzina, “M ed ju n aro d n i zajm ovi i socijalistička iz g ra d n ja .’’ O n S e p t e m b e r 6 , 1 9 5 0 , th e Jugoslav represen tativ e to th e I M F m a rk e d th e c o u n t r y ’s e le ctio n to t h e b o ard w ith a ;Spmh maintaining that internatio nal d e v e lo p m e n t aid to p o o r e r c o u n trie s w as n e c e s s a r y for work! peace— an a r g u m e n t th e Y ugoslavs had b e e n pu sh in g sin ce 1 9 4 5 (Borim , S e p t e m b e r f e 1950). B
See, for e x a m p le , th e front p a g e of a lm ost e v e r y issue of B o rb a from S e p t e m b e r 1 0 to
October 10.
152
CHAPTER 4
e m p l o y m e n t c o n t ra c t, and e n te r p r i s e d irecto rs would b e held legally re spo nsible for an y w o rk ers w h o did. T h e c o n tr a c ts — w hich w ere set the p rev io u s April for six m o n th s in basic industrial b ran ch es and three m o n th s in o th e rs and w hich now defined e m p l o y m e n t, in Kardelj’s lan g u ag e, as an “e m p l o y m e n t relationship "
(radni odnos )— had to guarantee
w o rk e rs a jo b c o m m e n s u r a t e with th e ir skill levels. T h e law was thus used to e n fo r c e d i r e c t relations b e t w e e n e m p lo y m e n t, skill level, and the legis lated w ag e for e a c h job classification. U n e x c u s e d a b s e n c e from work was reclassified as e c o n o m i c sabo tage; w orkers w e r e sub ject to criminal pros e c u tio n an d cou ld be p u n ish ed by a m o n e ta r y fine o r up to th re e months’ c o m p u ls o ry labor d oin g rep airs. B e c a u s e the m in ister of labor and the p ub lic p r o s e c u t o r had b e e n too cavalier ab ou t broken contracts, the l ead ers a rg u e d , th e y would use the c ou rts and th e civil and criminal law to p r o t e c t w o r k e r s ’ l ights, e n fo r ce labor and w age regulations, and, not in cid entally, re p la c e a n o th e r g o v e r n m e n t bureau with th e initiative of individual w o rk ers o r m a n a g e r s in b rin gin g claim s. T o e n fo rce the wage plan, th e y w ou ld turn to th e N ational Bank, w hich c on trolled the cash plans an d w a g e funds o f e n te rp ris e s th rou gh its local affiliates.158 While ratio nin g c o n tin u e d , con trol o v e r th e level o f e m p lo y m e n t would be t h ro u g h th e s t a t e ’s allocation of g u a ra n te e d provisions; factories with iarm s had th e ir cash w age fund re d u c e d , thus d irectly balancing wages an d goods within th e firm. P hysical as well as financial stabilization was to be en fo rced by with d raw in g th e right to g u a ra n te e d provisions from w orkers who moved a m o n g e n te r p r i s e s , calcu lating the size ol w o r k e r s ’ rations accord ing to th e tim e th e y s p e n t in stead y e m p l o y m e n t , and fo rcing w o m en “economi c ally” into th e lab or force by d en y in g g u a ra n te e d provisions to workers’ families. I n s u r a n c e benefits would also be d e t e r m in e d not by individuals’ c on trib u tio n s to th e fund but by th e length of t im e th ey had b een regu larly e m p lo y e d (o n e ’s
staz, in which the g o v e r n m e n t now included time
s p e n t in w ar s e rv ic e , im p ris o n m e n t, in te rn m e n t, or rev olu tion ary activ ity), an d benefits w ou ld b e financed by a lu m p -su m state tax on enter p r i s e s . 159 It was as su m e d that to a ttra c t w o m en to p rod u ction and keep 1 *s D e s p it e p r e p a r a tio n s sin ce 194(j, th e jo u rn a l ol th e finance m inistry, Finansije, con c e d e d that th e cash plans b eg an se riously only in S e p t e m b e r 1 9 4 9 (“ Nekoliko zapazanja p o v o d o m obilaska n aro d n ih o d b o r a ,” M a r c h - A p r i l 1 9 5 0 ), 159 T h e re v is e d law on social in s u ra n ce for w o rk e rs, officials, and th e ir families, pro miti g a t e d J a n u a r y 12, 1 9 5 0 , was e n ta n g le d in p a rlia m e n ta ry d e b a t e th e e n t i r e y e a r; o n e reason was its revision ol o ld -a g e pen sio ns. T h e prev iou s law had in clu d e d a w aiting period before t h e in s u re d co u ld d r a w ben efits b e c a u s e lo n g -te rm in su ra n ce had b e e n e n a c te d in prewar Yugoslavia o nly in 1 9 3 7 , thu s leaving o ld e r insured perso ns at a d isadv antag e, Another w e a k n e ss in t h e old law was th e s e p a ra te c o v e r a g e and regu lation s for officials. T h e new law i n c lu d e d all e m p lo y e d p e r so n s an d also th o se not in a radni odn os bu t d o in g "socially useful a n d n e c e s s a r y activ ities, su ch as p e o p le e l e c t e d to r e p r e s e n ta tiv e o rgans and ce rta in social
M11JTAIIY S E L F- RE LI A NO E
153
them there, firms would h ave to take into a c co u n t th eir n eed s , such as day-care c e n te r s. This regulation (H arm on ization o f L a b o r - F o r c e Plans with the W a g e - F u n d Plan and th e G u a ra n te e d -P ro v isio n s Plan, also from early January) r e q u ire d e n te rp ris e s and b ran ch d ire c to ra te s (now h igh er economic associations) to d ra w up lor approval, within eigh t days, d y namic labor plans with c o r r e s p o n d in g w age funds based on th eir gen eral economic and p ro d u ctio n plans. O n ly w h en th e ir m axim u m q uo ta o f e m ployed persons was a p p r o v e d would authorization to issue c o n s u m e r c o u pons be given.
In
the co u n tr y s id e ,
district labor offices signed the
employment c o n tra c ts for m e m b e r s of p easan t labor c o o p e ra tiv e s, issued consumer cou po ns to p e o p le w h o had the right to provisions b u t were« without a p u b lic-s eeto r c o n t r a c t, and w ith d re w that right from persons living in households with two or m o re h e cta re s o f cultivab le land or an income p er h ou seh old m e m b e r o v e r th r e e th ou san d dinars a y ear. T h e people's c o m m i tte e s r e c e i v e d d isc retio n ary au th o rity to disallow th e right to ration cou po ns to p ers o n s earn in g less that that. T h e ir e x e c u tiv e boards assessed eligibility for lin k ed -trad e c ou po ns, d en y in g th em to households that held surplus lab or ( d e te r m i n e d ac co rd in g to th e n u m b e r of a h o u s e hold's able-bodied m e m b e r s in relation to the size o f its landholding and type and m e th o d o f cultivatio n). Finally, the long stru ggle to e n d w orkers' ability to bargain o v e r w ages and benefits th rou gh m a r k e t s tren g th e n te r e d its final battle.
Leaders
complained that th e in trod u ction of e m p l o y m e n t c o n tra c ts in the spring of 1949 had only led w orkers to shift from w age d e m a n d s to negotiation o v e r working conditions and benefits, such as housing and food. But, Kardelj insisted, clauses on th e se m a tte r s
"cannot be sub ject to negotiation in our
conditions.”160 Such n egotiations w e r e also inflationary, e n c o u r a g in g fre quent tu rn over and "disloyal c o m p e tit io n ” a m o n g e n te rp ris e s for s ca r ce labor— as well as p e r p e tu a ti n g the i n c o r r e c t idea, M in ister of L a b o r Arsov wrote in J u n e 1 9 5 0 , th at m a n a g e m e n t and labor did not have th e sam e interests u n d er social o w n ersh ip , that s o m e h o w “the socialist firm is s e p a rate from its w ork c o llectiv e ra t h e r than o n e unified w hole. iH1 I m p r o v e ments in w orkin g conditio ns and w o r k e r s ’ living standards had to be adjusted to th e “real d e v e l o p m e n t of m aterial forces. The p urpo se o f th e w o r k e r s ’ councils in tro d u ce d at th e e n d o f D e c e m -
organizations,” It also o p e n e d th e possibility o f in s u ra n ce for in d e p e n d e n t professionals. T h e primary p u rp ose o f th e n e w legislation, h o w e v e r, was to e n c o u r a g e r e t i r e m e n t s o f o ld e r workers anc! soldiers by e x te n d in g c o v e r a g e to all w o rk e rs insured b e fo re t h e w a r a n d raising the pension to 1 0 0 p e r c e n t o f th e p rincip al; thu s the locus of d e b a te was on o ld-ag e p en sions (see Jelcic, Socijalno p ra v o , 1 8 - 2 0 ) . T h e sa m e sy ste m was in p r a c tic e in the Soviet U n ion after J 9 3 4 (see D av ies, T h e D evelopm ent o f the Soviet B udgetary System, 2 6 5 ) IW) Q uoted in A rso v , "R e sa v a n je pitan ja ra d n e s n a g e , ” 3 0 iril Ibid.
154
CHAPTER 4
b e r 1 9 4 9 was thus to gain w o r k e r s ’ assistance in the w age restrain t and e m p l o y m e n t cuts n e c e s s a r y to restabilize th e e c o n o m y and to restore the a u th o rity of e n t e r p r i s e m a n a g e m e n t and tech n ician s o v e r prod u ctio n, in clu d in g labor. T h e cou ncils would c o m b in e the c ollectiv e incentives and d isciplin e o f th e p ro d u ctio n brigades with m anagerial accountability for e n t e r p r i s e b u d g e ts . At first, this sub stitu te for c ollectiv e bargaining in the m a r k e t a t t e m p t e d sim p ly to e n c o u r a g e an e x c h a n g e of information about th e e c o n o m i c con d itio n s o f th e firm with m a n a g e r s ’ explanations for the b usiness reason s b e h in d th e ir decisions so as to teach w orkers the “per s p e c t i v e ” (lon g-run ra th e r than s h o rt-ru n in terests) ap p ro p ria te to their position in socialism , an d to train a n e w g en eratio n in m anagerial skills. T h e e x c h a n g e o f such information was in te n d e d to e n h a n c e incentives to h i g h e r p ro d u ctiv ity by m aking th e link to ou tp u t m o re tran sp aren t and m a n a g e r s m o r e c r e d i b l e — in the lan gu age o f ratio n al-ch o ice theory, by in creasin g c o m m i t m e n t . At th e sam e tim e, th e councils w ou ld rationalize ad m in istratio n by con so lidatin g into o n e e le c te d b od y th e functions of the lab or in sp e cto rs , ad visory c o m m ission s, p ro d u ctio n c o n fe re n c e s, workers’ in sp e cto rs , an d state labor offices. As specified by th e instructions for w o r k e r s ’-cou ncil e lec tio n s issued jointly by th e F e d e r a l E c o n o m i c Coun cil a n d th e C e n tr a l Board o f th e U n ited Unions in D e c e m b e r to republi can union offices, “th e form ation o f w o rk e rs ’ councils does not lessen the significance o f th e d ir e c to r in m an agin g th e en te rp rise . . . . [His] author ity, obligations, an d responsibilities do not c h a n g e in any way. ”1H2 And alth ou gh th e c o u n c ils ’ p u rp o se was “to in te re st o r activ ate ever-larger n u m b e r s o f w o rk ers in solving p ro b le m s of p ro d u c t io n ,” rep lacin g the b rig a d e s y s te m an d V u k m a n o v i c - T e m p o ’s d e v o te d p rod u ctio n workers, d e l e g a te s w ou ld n o n eth eles s only rev iew th e p rod u ctio n plans, labor al location s, an d work s ch ed u les fo rm ulated by en g in e e rs and technical staff, w h o k n ew b est how to rationalize. A lthough the w o r k e r s ’ councils w ou ld a p p e a r to re p la c e the unions, union chief D ju ro Salaj told the third p le n u m in D e c e m b e r 1 9 4 9 that th e union lead ers had b e e n “blowing this h orn for two years n o w . ”163 In th eir view, p rod u ctio n w orkers had re c e i v e d too m u c h atte n tio n in relation to en g in e e rin g and tech n ical p er son n el an d e v e n , p e rh a p s , e x a g g e ra te d wages. It was en g in e e rs who had to b e paid well; p ro d u ctio n w orkers w e r e only re c e n tly arriv ed from the villages, an d h ig h e r w ages would only e n c o u r a g e th eir faster re tu rn to the land (sin ce it w ou ld take less tim e to earn th e cash th ey sought) and would re in fo rc e th eir p e tty -b o u rg e o is p ro p e rty -h o ld in g instincts ra th e r than tran s fo rm in g th e m into industrial workers. T h e p rob lem of the living s tan d ard c a m e ab ou t n ot b e c a u s e inflation u n d e rm in e d p rod u ctio n incenIf’2 “U p u ls lv o o osnivanju i nulu radničkih saveta državnih privred nih p r e d u z e ć a ," in P e tr a n o v ić and Zečt'vić, Jugoslavija, 1918-1988, 8 5 2 - 5 3 . ir,3 P e t r a n o v ić , K om 'ar, and R adonjić, Sednice, 4 3 3 .
155
MILITARY S E L F - R E L I A N C E
lives as Kidrič had b e e n arguing, b ut b e ca u se of th e m oral e c o n o m y of peasants.1&l I n d e e d , Salaj w e n t so far as to say th at w orkers n e e d e d to b e led by en gin eers as well as by th e p arty organization. B e c a u s e skilled workers and e n g in e e rs d o m in a te d the unions as in th e p r e w a r p eriod , th e line of d escen t for th e w o r k e r s ’ councils from th e K nights of L a b o r and the Austromarxists was i n t a c t . 165 The unions w e r e assigned two functions: to o rgan ize council electio n s and nominate ca n d id a te s , and to d efend w o r k e r s ’ rights to social in su r ance and b enefits— w hich would now d e p e n d on the e c o n o m i c results of firms and on cou ncil d elib eratio n s, with th e en d of w age b argain in g and the close of in su ran ce b u reau s . In th e first ro un d of electio ns, d u rin g the second half of Ja n u a ry 1 9 5 0 , th e councils w e r e lim ited to th e largest firms of the defense d r iv e — 2 1 5 state e c o n o m ic e n te rp rise s that had b e e n u n der federal ju risd iction an d had had brigades; th ese w e r e firms in mining, machine tools, shipbuilding, printing, tran sp o rt, gas and ele c tr icity , iron smelting,
h osiery,
and
c e m e n t . lbfi
As
th e
D ecem ber
instructions
explained: 1,11 Confronting llu; p r o b le m of tu r n o v e r ami a b s e n te e ism , Kidrič a rg u e d the im p o rta n ce ol political work by m anag erial staff instead of e c o n o m i c ince n tive s. W o rk e rs from the vil lages were absent to c e l e b r a t e religious holidays, and b e c a u se th e y w e r e O rth o d o x , C a t h o lics, and Muslim s,
this m e a n t s e p a ra te days for e a ch b e co m p la in e d ; to r e d u c e such
absences, m ine w o rk ers w e r e b e in g given h ig h e r w ages
"I think that it has no p a rticu la r
effect to offer him an e v e r h ig h e r w ag e, b e c a u se as all can se e , the h ig h e r the w ag e he receives, the less h e works. l i e is a c c u s t o m e d to living on a ch u n k of b r e a d and b a con , and when he has this, h e s satisfied. Instead , it s n e c e ssa ry to do political w ork with su ch p e o p le . . . and first ol all, e n ab le him to know w hat his obligation is to the sta te . . . lift [his] cultural standard . . . and in s o m e way tie him to th e fa cto ry ” (K idrič, at th e third p le n u m of the CPY cen tral c o m m i t t e e , ibid ., 4 1 1 ). O n this C hay ano vian analysis, se e J. Scott, T h e
Moral E c o n o m y o f th e Peasant; and C ox 's analysis o f the Soviet d e b a te s in the 1 9 2 0 s (Peas ants, Class, a n d C ap ita lis m ). On the K nights o f L a b o r , see H a tta m , “ E c o n o m i c Visions and Political S tra te g ie s"; and C. M artin,
Pu b lic Policy and I n c o m e D istribution in Y u g o sla v ia ,” 2 7
tromarxist s c h e m e , the
In th e Aus-
c h a m b e r s ol la b o r” lor w o rk ers and salaried e m p lo y e e s w e r e se p a
rate from the “c h a m b e r s o f c o m m e r c e and i n d u s tr y ,” paralleling th e dis tinction
that
developed in th e Yugoslav c a s e b e t w e e n th e w o rk e rs ’ co un cils within firms and the e c o nomic ch a m b e rs , w hich associated firms by bra n ch and repub lic. T h e m o d e l was clearly there in the sim ilar distinction b e tw e e n the works co un cils (organized a cc o rd in g to the shopfloor) and the tra d e unions (o rg anized by branch) in w hich the work s' co un cils w e r e subordinated to tile track1 unions and n e v e r a ch ie v e d any im p o rta n t m anag erial functions (Gulick, A u s t r i a f r o m H a b s b u r g to H i t l e r 1 :2 0 2 , 2 1 .3 - 1 4 ) . Iw’ Branko H o rv a t inform s m e that th e idea lor the councils began sp on ta n e o u sly in the cement lactory in Split, alth o u g h Kidrie s w ritings du rin g W o rld W a r II on w o rk e rs' c o u n cils, the W e i m a r e l e m e n t s ol th e Slo v e n e co n stitu tion al proposal of 1 9 2 1 , and the e x p o su re nl at least S lo v en es and C ro a ts to A u stroin arxism w ould sugg est a lo n g e r g estation. T h e n e e d to rationalize labo r costs in h eav y ind ustry and e x p o rt p ro d u ction was m ost im m e d ia te , however, as o n e can se e in th e beg inn ing s ol industrial reform s in o t h e r socialist s t a t e s — for example, in Poland in th e 1 9 7 0 s (see W o od a ll. T h e Socialist C o r p o r a t i o n a n d T e c h n o c r a t i c
Pmver)
156
CHAPTER 4
F o r now, until t he n e c e s s ar y e x p e r i en ce is g ained, w or k er s ’ council s will be foun ded on ly in a c e r t a in n u m b e r of the bes t and most import ant collectives in our c ount r y. . . . B e f o re the election of w or k er s ’ council s, you need to or ga ni ze c o n f e r e n c e s . . . inviting res pons ible minister s and di rect ors of gen eral , or main, d ir e c t o r a t e s of the enter p r is es in w hich elect ions are being he ld, and also t h e e n t e r p r is e d ir ector s, s ecr etaries of the part y organizations, and pr e s i d e n t s o f t h e s e e n ter p r is es as s ociations .1'’7
F r o m late Ja n u a ry 1 9 5 0 th ro u g h 1 9 5 1 and 1 9 5 2 , unions organized fac tory ele c tio n s of d e le g a te s , from w h ich re p re s e n ta tiv e s to branch-level w o r k e r s ’ cou n cils would then b e ch o sen . T h e s e re p re s e n ta tiv e s would he, a c c o r d in g to th e n e w s p a p e r publicity d rive, th e “b e s t ” w orkers, engineers an d tec h n ician s, an d w ork ers h o n o red as innovators and rationalizers.168 In th e rationalizations o f 1 9 5 0 , h o w e v e r, th e m o st im p ortan t task of the w o rk e rs cou ncils was, as for th e federal councils that rep lac ed the minis tries, to s e c u r e w o r k e r s ’ c o o p e r a t io n — by b e in g allowed to rev iew man a g e m e n t ’s d ecis io n s — in th e u p c o m in g e m p lo y m e n t revisions that would r e d u c e “surplus lab o r” and “hoard in g” and send “on e p art eventually [back] to th e villa g e .” T h e labor quotas for 1 9 5 0 w e r e re d u c e d by more than a million w ork ers, leaving a total of only 1 . 3 million e m p lo y e d in the pub lic s e cto r. T h e c u ts and reallocations w e r e m a d e in tw o waves: pro d u c tio n w o rk e rs in th e spring, and p rim arily g o v e r n m e n t administrative staff in th e fall. A ltho ug h lead ers insisted on “political p re p a ra tio n ” at the third p le n u m , 9 9 , 7 2 2 p ro d u ctio n w orkers w e r e m o v e d from one eco n o m ic b ra n c h to a n o t h e r d u rin g M a rc h and April w ithou t explanation or c h o ic e . F e a r s of u n e m p l o y m e n t raised earlier in political circles were e c h o e d in p o p u lar slogans such as “Surplus lab or!” “U n e m p l o y m e n t!” and “T h e crisis has b e g u n !” C ritics insisted that a r e tu rn to the village was “a step b a c k w a rd ” an d “into u n e m p lo y m e n t. ”169 F a c t o r y d irecto rs ju m p ed at th e o p p o rtu n ity to fire les s-d esired w o rk ers — invalids, w o m e n (especially p r e g n a n t w o m e n ), ailing and o ld e r w orkers. Office staff c u t workers by e lim in atin g w h ole c a te g o r ie s , such as rep air workers, from factory em p l o y m e n t r o l l s , 170 an d local g o v e r n m e n ts elim in ated e n tire activities, such as artisanal and h o s telry firms in Vojvodina. T h e s e cuts led to such u’7 “P o p r a t n o p ism o uz up u t sivo o osnivanju i radu radničkih save ta državnih privrednih p r e d u z e ć a ,” in P e t r a n o v ić and Z e č e v i ć , Jugoslavija, 1918-1988, 8 5 3 . IfiK S e e , for e x a m p l e , Politika, J a n u a r y 2 8 a n d 2 9 , 1 9 5 0 , on e le ctio n s for w o rk e rs’ councils in th e B r e z a co al m in e in B o s n ia -H e r z e g o v in a , th e Hade K o n č a r m a ch in e factory in Zagreb, th e C u k a r i c a sh ipbuild ing firm , th e K u ltu ra prin tin g firm in B e lg ra d e , and sev en firms (in clu d in g th o se for h o sie ry , e l e c t r i c tra m s , and city gas) in Sarajevo,
im A rso v , “R eš a v anje pitanja ra d n e s n a g e ,” 2 1 - 2 2 . J70 I b i d ., 2 3 . A c c o rd in g to H a s, giving this o p p o rtu n ity to m a n a g e rs led to o verly "tech n o c r a tic ” ev alu atio n s in e n te r p r i s e s , a ltho ug h this s e e m s to h a v e b e e n th e l e a d e r s ’ intention (“ D ru S tv e n o -e k o n o m sk i o s v r t ,” 1 4 8 - 4 9 ) ,
MILITARY SELF-RELIANCE
157
dislocation ol s e r v i c e s t h a t w o r k e r s h a d t o h e c a l l e d h a c k to t h e i r f o r m e r jobs several y e a r s l a t e r . M a n y w o r k e r s r e f u s e d to m o v e to t h e i r n e w a s signments (for e x a m p l e , ol t h e f o u r h u n d r e d that t h e S u b o t i c a l a b o r of f i c e sent during t h e s p r i n g t o w o r k in P a n e e v a e k i Hit, o n l y s ix t y w e n t ) , a n d local officials s y m p a t h e t i c t o t h o s e w h o s h i e d f r o m t h e m i n e s o r h e a v v industrial j o b s f o u n d t h e m
o t h e r j o b s r a t h e r t h a n i m p o s e l e g al p e n a l
ties.171 On J u n e 10, 1 9 5 0 , d a y s a f t e r t h e b a s i c a n d d y n a m i c b r a n c h l a b o r plans bas ed
on
enterp rise
production
plans
su bm ilted
in
January—
February w e r e d u e , T i t o w e n t to t h e n a t i o n a l a s s e m b l y w i t h t h e n e w l aw on "the m a n a g e m e n t of state- e c o n o m i c e n t e r p r i s e s a n d h i g h e r e c o n o m i c associations b y t h e w o r k c o l l e c t i v e .
A lthough the work co llective m ean t
everyone in t h e f ir m , a n d t h e la w a s s i g n e d leg al r e s p o n s i b i l i t y t o e n t e r prise m a n a g e m e n t f o r l a b o r a n d “d i r e c t o p e r a t i o n s ,
it w a s , i n t h e h y p e r
bole of th e i d e o l o g i c a l s t r u g g l e , a f u l f i l l m e n t of t h e h i s t o r i c p r o m i s e o f -socialism that w o r k e r s w o u l d r u n t h e i r f a c t o r i e s : " P e a s a n t s in c o o p e r a t i v e s , which they m a n a g e t h e m s e l v e s , a n d w o r k e r s in f a c t o r i e s , w h i c h f r o m n o w on they will m a n a g e t h e m s e l v e s , t o d a v h a v e t h e i r o w n f ate t r u l y i n t h e i r own hands.
1,2 O n J u n e 2 7 , t h e d a y b e l o r e t h e s e c o n d a n n i v e r s a r y o f t h e
f irstComi nfon n r e s o l u t i o n , t h e a s s e m b l y e n a c t e d “w o r k e r s ’ c o n t r o l . ” 171 B y August a nd S e p t e m b e r , w h e n t h e r e n e w a l o f e m p l o y m e n t c o n t r a c t s o f fered a n o t h e r o p p o r t u n i t y f or d i s m i s s a l s , l e a d e r s w e r e e x p r e s s i n g c o n f i dence that " r e s u l t s w ill b e e v e n b e t t e r b e c a u s e of w o r k e r s
councils.
171
Also on J u n e 2 7 , K i d r i č a s k e d t h e a s s e m b l y to c o n f i r m t h e r e o r g a n i z a tion of st ate a d m i n i s t r a t i o n in t h e e c o n o m y . B e t w e e n S e p t e m b e r a n d D e cember, t h e s e c o n d l a b o r r e v i s i o n c u t an a d d i t i o n a l 1 2 2 , 5 0 0 w o r k e r s a nd reallocated o l f i c e w o r k e r s a n d a d m i n i s t r a t i v e staf f, i n c l u d i n g 5 0 , 0 0 0 d e moted i nto i n d u s t r i a l o r a g r i c u l t u r a l p r o d u c t i o n ( t h e s e w e r e p e o p l e w h o s e lack ol pr o f e s s i o n a l q u a l i f i c a t i o n s m a d e t h e m “i n c a p a b l e of p e r f o r m i n g administrative t a s k s s u c c e s s f u l l y " ) . 175 I n t h i s r o u n d t h e l o a d e r s w e r e “e s pecially c a r e f u l , ’' 17'’ a l l o w i n g t h e r e a l l o c a t i o n s to d r a g o n l o n g e r , d i s c u s s ing the tr a n s fe r s in b r o a d c o n s u l t a t i o n s in t h e f e d e r a l l a b o r m i n i s t r y , a n d setting up c o o r d i n a t i n g c o m m i s s i o n s o f “i n t e r e s t e d p a r t i e s ” i n d i s t r i c t s and rep ub l i c s. “T h e p r o b l e m of d e c e n t r a l i z a t i o n is to e n s u r e t h e c o r r e c t allocation of p r o f e s s i o n a l c a d r e s , " r e a d t h e t itl e o f an a r t i c l e in t h e A u g u s t September i s s u e o l
Ekonom ski Pregled.
H e r e , too , h o w e v e r , m a n y w h o
refused to t a k e p r o d u c t i o n j o b s o r r e t u r n 1:1 Arsov. ‘tto šav an jc pitan ja r a d n e sn ago,
to t h e c o u n t r y s i d e w e r e i n-
22-24
■ P - T i t o , "V ru d b en ičk o upravljanje, p r i v r e d o m , ’ 2ft,
m * ibid, ,f_l Vjttcestuv H o ljev ac , w h o took o v e r from A rso v as federal m in is te r o f labo r in J u ly 1950, in “P roblem rad no sn age: N ek a ¡skusiva i/. p rv o g pol ugodiš t a , ” Dular, ‘Stru k tu ra osoblja / a p o s l e n o g n našoj priv redi, * 4 3 3 . 17,5 Kas, “ D iiištv en o -ek o n o m sk i o s v r t ," 14 5 .
158
CHAPTER 4
d u lg ed . M a n y o th e rs took m a tte r s into th e ir own h an d s— such as the h u n d r e d -o d d staff m e m b e r s o f th e M inistry o f L ig h t In d u s try who refused to a c c e p t th e ir n ew a s sig n m en ts and, two m o n th s after th e ministry s April dispersal to th e rep u b lics, w e re seen going d o o r -to -d o o r in search of a lte rn a tiv e offers in th e c a p i ta l.177 T h e r e w e r e substantial criticism s o f this reform p ro g ra m within the le a d e rs h ip , in spite of T ito ’s r e p e a te d a tte m p ts to sway critics with stories o f political e x c e s s in th e p r e c e d in g year. T h e “n arro w in g on the labor
“f o r socialism ," while the “organi m ust b e u n d e rs to o d as n e c e s s a r y in th e given situa
fron t” was b e in g d o n e , K idrič a rg u e d , zational m e a s u r e s ”
tion to s e c u r e th e P la n ”; if “th e y d o n ’t see t h e m as socialism, th en we can go to th e d evil an d c r e a t e a b u r e a u c ra tic s y s t e m . ”178 F o r som e senior p a rt y m e m b e r s , th e c h a n g e was b e in g m a d e too soon and too quickly; the l e a d e r of th e V ojvodina p a rty, Jovan V eselinov, was c o n v in c e d that the p easan ts w ou ld w a n t to join co o p e ra tiv e s if only the g o v e r n m e n t ’s grainreq u isition in g rules w e r e less d iscou rag ing , and th at th e transition to eco n o m ic an d in ten sive m e th o d s and away from state responsibility for labor w ou ld n ot p e r m i t c o m p le tio n o f the plan u n d e r p revailing conditions and c o u ld n ot b e m a d e o v e rn ig h t w itho u t serious e c o n o m ic consequences. D ju ro P u c a r c o n tin u e d to a rg u e on b eh alf o f m an y th at labor problems w ou ld b e b e t t e r resolv ed by assigning p e o p le to job s than by withdrawing g u a r a n t e e d provisions, w hich w ould only c au s e th e loss o f labor already r e c r u ite d . A t o n e final c o n f e r e n c e in th e M inistry of L a b o r on the eve of its elim in ation , in S e p t e m b e r 1 9 5 0 , p articip an ts a g r e e d that this new s y s t e m — in w h ich lab o r was “a p ro b le m that only an e c o n o m i c organiza tion can so lv e” with e c o n o m ic m e a s u r e s — had benefits, b u t b o d e well for e m p l o y m e n t
it did not
at first. ”179 T h e conflicts w e r e particularly
in te n s e at th e fourth p le n u m o f th e c e n tr a l c o m m i t t e e in Ju n e 1951, when p ric e s in retail m ark ets for c o n s u m e r goods w e re freed. Kidrič once again railed again st th e “b u r e a u c r a ti c m e n ta lity ” th at insisted on “socialist de te rm in a t io n o f p lan n ed p rices
and that did not s e e that free prices and
th e o p e ra tio n o f th e “law o f v alu e” w e r e essential in cen tives to increased p ro d u ctio n . O n th e o th e r h and, fo rm e r h ealth m in ister Pavle Gregorič, ad d r e s s in g a d isp u te o v e r th e disposition o f m ed ic in es held in federal w a re h o u s e s , p r e s e n t e d searin g d ata on h o rre n d o u s h ealth conditions; h e q u e s tio n e d th e w isd om o f freely selling instead of rationing scarce 177 A rso v , “R ešav an je pitanja ratine s n a g e ," 23. 178 K id rič, in P e tr a n o v ič , K o n č a r, and R adonjič, Sednice, 3 9 4 . H e did add , how ever, that t h e y w ould n o t “in te rfe re with local initiative w h e r e it is truly b ased on local sources ol m a t e r i a l s .” 179 H as, “D ru štv e n o -e k o n o m sk i osv rt,
147. Arsov also re p o rts that th e se reallocations
r aised fears o f u n e m p lo y m e n t am o n g so m e , bu t that th e con tin u in g sh ortag es in mining and c o n s tru c tio n sh ou ld h av e told th e m that “t h e r e was no d a n g e r of that in o u r econom ic sys t e m ” (“R e ša v a n je pitanja r ad n e s n a g e ,” 21).
159
MILITARY S E L F - R E L I A N C E
goods to people in n e e d , an d then p re d ic te d n ew h orrors in health and social welfare as a c o n s e q u e n c e of e n d in g all central au tho rity for health. Others argued that financial m e th o d s would p rov ide very weak in cen tives to lahor r e c r u it m e n t and labor p rod u ctiv ity , given the goods shortages and the prevailing “c u l t u r e ” o f “transition lrom individual to socialist forms.”1*0 The resolution to this conflict on th e ap p ro p ria te m e th o d s for th e t ra n sition lay, in Kardelj's view, with th e party. T h e transition would be m ad e through “agitation and p ro p ag an d a
by party activists to d ev elo p "socialist
consciousness" (a c c e p t a n c e of sacrifices in the in terest of lo n g -term o b j e c tives); “initiative” (m o re effort with n e ith e r force nor im m e d ia te e c o n o m i c reward, on the promise; of fu ture gain); and “d e m o c r a tic relations in our production" th ro u g h th e forum s for p articipation, such as th e w orkers' councils. This w ou ld also be the b est policy of national d efen se, b e ca u se an international rep u tatio n for d e m o c r a ti c p articipation “is ju st w hat will enable us to show the world th e d ifference b e tw e e n us and t h e m . ’ 1M T h e return of control o v e r ed u c a tio n and c u ltu re to th e rep u blics in 1 9 5 0 would “win s y m p ath y in circles o f intellectuals, scientists, e tc , " 1'’2 P eop le without a p u b lie-sec to r e m p l o y m e n t c o n tra c t but who p e rfo rm e d “socially useful and n e c e s s a r y activities, such as p eop le e le c te d to re p re s e n ta tiv e organs and certain social o r g a n iz a tio n s,” would r e c e iv e rights to social insurance, as in d e p e n d e n t professionals p robably also would later. And, Tito said, “b e c a u s e of o u r policy toward the imperialist world, w e m u st now take special c a r e , p articu larly with y o u n g e r m e m b e r s o f th e P arty, to see that th ey not forget that w e are a socialist c o u n t r y . ” 1’’3 During 1 9 5 1 , Yugoslavia's reo rien tation to W e s t e r n tra d e and aid also led to a reform that e n d e d th e m o no po ly of th e M inistry o f F o re ig n T ra d e over foreign-trade tran saction s, h an d ed to th e E c o n o m i c C oun cil th e a u thority to re g u late tra d e in p articu lar p ro d u cts w h en the social in terest (that is, defen se) d e m a n d e d it, gav e jurisdiction o v e r c u sto m s and tariffs to the finance m in istry, an d b egan an activ e e x c h a n g e -r a t e policy by d e valuing the c u r r e n c y from 5 0 to 3 0 0 dinars to the U .S . dollar. On N o v e m ber 1, the first $ 1 6 million installm en t o f U .S . m ilitary aid u n d e r th e two countries’ M utual D e f e n s e A ssistance a g r e e m e n t 184 arrived in B elg rad e, and A m erican
efforts
to
p e rs u a d e
th e
French
and
British
to
sell
Yugoslavia arm s and tanks m aterialized d u rin g that m o n t h . lsr’ 180 Pe t ran o vic, K o n č a r, a n d R ado njič, S ed nice, 6 6 2 - 6 7 . 1,S1 Kardelj, at th e third p le n u m o f th e C P Y c e n tra l c o m m i t t e e in P e tr a n o v ic, K o n ča r, and Radonjič, S ed n ica , 4 5 4 ; A rsov, “R ešav anje pitanja rudne s n a g e .” l!s2 Kardelj, in P e tr a n o v ic , K o n č ar, a n d R adon djic, S e d nice, 4 8 0 . ^
Ibid,
18,1 Ibid., 4 7 8 . 1,5
B etw e e n m i d - 1 9 5 1 an d 1 9 5 5 , th e U n ite d S ta te s co o rd in a te d aid from th e U n ite d
States, Britain, a n d F r a n c e , B y N o v e m b e r 1 9 5 2 , th e e c o n o m i c and m ilitary aid that had
160
CHAPTER 4
F e w m o n th s had p assed b efore the p red iction o f th e labor conference in S e p t e m b e r 1 9 5 0 p ro v e d c o r r e c t . T h ro u g h o u t 1 9 5 1 and 1 9 5 2 , en ter p rises w e n t o v e rb o a r d in th e stru ggle for profitability ( rentabilnost ), g u id ed b y th e “m aterial in terests o f work c o l le c ti v e s .” F ir m s increased both a c c u m u la tio n and w ages by firing all w h o did not “im m ed iately pro duce
an o u t p u t , ” in cluding th ose
in m a in t e n a n c e jo b s — who would
c le a rly b e n e e d e d la te r — and w orkers c o n sid e re d (as in the spring of 1 9 5 0 ) less p r o d u c tiv e , such as w o m e n , th e infirm, and th e a g e d . 18B Two d ro u g h ts w ithin th r e e years sen t agricu ltural ou tp u t p lu m m e tin g , and the s tart o f t h e K o re a n W a r in J u n e 1 9 5 0 b ro u g h t a disastrous shift in global te r m s o f tra d e against i m p o r te d fuels, strategic m aterials, an d machinery. M a n y in du stries sim p ly c a m e to a halt, and o th e rs re d u c e d production significantly; th e ad ju s tm en ts in th e fields of e n e r g y an d m in in g alone cut e m p l o y m e n t 1 4 . 6 p e r c e n t b e tw e e n Ja n u a ry 1 9 5 1 and Ja n u a ry 1 9 5 2 and 1 7 . 4 p e r c e n t by J u n e 1 9 5 2 . 187 T h e lead ers had d e cla r e d an “e n d to unem p l o y m e n t ” in S e p t e m b e r 1 9 4 7 ; five years later, th e official unem ploym ent o f p u b lic -s e c t o r w o rk ers had surpassed levels “norm al for W e s t e r n E u ro p e a n
c o u n t r ie s ” (referrin g
to the
m o n e ta r ists ’ “norm al
ra te ” of 5
p e r c e n t ) . 188 T h e “c o r r e c tn e s s o f th e n ew e c o n o m ic m e a s u r e s ” was demon s tra te d , a c c o r d i n g to discussion at th e sixth p arty c on gress in November 1 9 5 2 , b y th e c o m p le t io n o f the p rod u ctio n plan for in du stry “at th e same tim e [that] th e n u m b e r o f w orkers has notably l e s s e n e d .”189 Delegate S im o K ok otic r e p o r t e d , “N o t only has th e B o r m in e successfu lly com p l e t e d its plan tasks, but it has also re d u c e d its costs o f production in p ro p o r tio n . T h e B o r m in e n ow c o m p le t e s its plan tasks with about three t h o u sa n d fe w e r w o rk ers than it had in 1 9 3 8 . ”190
C
o n c l u sio n
T h e r h e to r ic o f th e Y u g o slav -S o v iet p rop agan d a w ar o f D e c e m b e r 1948 to N o v e m b e r 1 9 5 2 e n c o u r a g e d an in terp retatio n of the Yugoslav system as
a rriv e d from the W e s t to taled $ 2 8 6 . 6 million in g ra n ts, $ 2 6 7 . 2 million in credit.s (from the U . S . E x p o r t - I m p o r t B ank , I B R D , I M F , L o n d o n C lu b , a n d individual co u n trie s), and $51 million in w a r re p a r a tio n s, m ainly from G e r m a n y
M ilitary aid c o n tin u e d until 1 9 5 8 ; and by
m i d - 1 9 6 2 , U . S . aid h ad r e a c h e d $ 2 . 3 billion, o f w h ich $ 7 1 9 million w as m ilitary aid (Mugoša, “O d n osi J u g oslavije i S A D - a ”; T o m a s o v ich , “Yugoslavia d u rin g th e S e c o n d W o rld W ar,’’ 1 0 5 - 7 , 1 1 2 ; H offm an an d N eal, Yugoslavia a n d the N ew Comm unism , 8 8 - 9 1 ) . 180 H a s , “D n iš tv e n o - c k o n o m s k i o s v r t , ” 1 4 8 - 4 9 . 187 E kon om ska Politika, A u g u st 2 8 , 1 9 5 2 , 4 2 2 , 188 H as, “ D r u štv e n o -e k o n o m sk i o s v r t ,” 1 4 1 . S e e also K rstu lov ić, “S taln o podizanje pro izv od no sti r a d a ,” 189 C alić, “E k o n o m s k a p ro b le m a tik a na V I. ko ng resu sa v e z a k o m u n is ta ,” 3 2 5 , 190 Ib id .
161
М П Л Т Л Н У SKI .K -H K I .I AN 'C K
an al te r n a t i v e
to
the
Soviet
system ,
an
alternative
characterized
bv
workers' c o n t r o l , a n t i l m r e a i i e r a t i e s o e i a li s t d e m o c r a c y a a n d d e c e n t r a l i z a tion. In its i n t e r n a t i o n a l p o s i t i o n , it d id d if f e r s u b s t a n t i a l l y Iro m t h e p a t h followed in E a s t e r n
E u r o p e l r o m t h e e n d o f 1 9 4 7 ( and e s p e c i a l l y e a r l y
1949) until 1 9 5 3 . T h e c o u n t r y c r e a t e d an i n d e p e n d e n t a n d p o l i t i c a l l y s i g nificant a r m e d f o r c e s , r e c e i v e d W e s t e r n m i l i t a r y a n d e c o n o m i c ai d a n d trade, a nd as a r e s u l t w a s a b l e to r e t u r n to t h e g r a d u a l i s t p o s i t i o n on agricultural s o c i a l i z a t i o n a n d t o t h e m e t h o d s ol e c o n o m i c c o n t r o l c o n s i d ered a p p r o p r i a t e t o l ig h t m a n u f a c t u r i n g a n d p r o c e s s e d g o o d s l o r d o m e s t i c consumpti on a n d e x p o r t . T h e n e w c o u r s e r e e m e r g e d
in H u n g a r y .
Po
land, and t h e U S S R in 1 9 5 3 a n d , f o l l o w i n g a d e t o u r , a l t e r 195fi ; a n d w h i l e their re fo r m s a n d t h o s e in C z e c h o s l o v a k i a in t h e 19b() s d i f f e r e d f ro m t h e Yugoslav o n e s in p o li t ic a l t r a j e c t o r y a n d i n t e r n a t i o n a l t i m i n g , t h e s i m ilarities in e c o n o m i c c o n c e p t i o n s , t h e c o m m o n l e g a c y o f L e n i n i s t i n s t i t u tions and t h e N L P ' s “ r e g im e : ol e c o n o m y " in i n d u s t r y a n d a g r i c u l t u r e , an d even th e p a r a l l e l s w i t h S o v i e t i n d u s t r i a l r e l a t i o n s of t h e 1.930s a r e u s u a l l v
ignored.191 Dece n t r a l i z a t io n a n d w o r k e r s ’ co n t r o l w e r e also no t w ha t t h e y ar e c l a i m e d to have b e e n . O n e of t h e p u r p o s e s of d e c e n t r a l i z a t i o n w as to “s t r e n g t h e n centralism by d e v e l o p i n g its d e m o c r a t i s m ,
15,2 a n d o n e o f ' t h e p u r p o s e s o f
workers c o n t r o l w a s t o r e d u c e t h e p o w e r o v e r w a g e s t h a t t ig h t l a b o r m a r kets and t h e n t h e p r o d u c t i o n - b r i g a d e s y s t e m h a d g i v e n to w o r k e r s . T h e dynamic ol t h e p e r i o d w a s n o t b e t w e e n c e n t r a l a n d local p o w e r a n d a u thority, o r b e t w e e n m o r e o r le s s p a r t y p o w e r ; it i n v o l v e d t h e d i f f e r e n t
kinds of a u t h o r i t y p o s s e s s e d b y e a c h of t h e t h r e e l e v e l s — f e d e r a t i o n , r e public, a n d c o m m u n e (as l o c a l i t i e s b e g a n to b o c a l l e d ) — w i t h e a c h c h a n g e of poli cy. T h e “e c o n o m i c " m e t h o d s ol w h a t I h a v e c a l l e d t h e S l o v e n e model ol K a r d e lj a n d K id r ic w e r e m o r e c e n t r a li z e d an d “a d m i n i s t r a t i v e — in the s e n s e
that they
em phasized
central
regu lation s on
w'ages a n d
capital -l abor r a t i o s , v e r t i c a l li n k s in e c o n o m i c a n d p o li t ic a l c o o r d i n a t i o n , and m a n a g o r i a l - t c c h n o e r a t i e a u t h o r i t y — t h a n
w ere
the
" p o l i t i c a l ” a nd
“cam pai gn ’ m e t h o d s d u r i n g 1 9 4 8 - 4 9 ol t h e К о с а m o d e l , w i t h i ts radi cal d e m o cr a ti z a t i o n in p r o d u c t i o n , p o p u l a r s u p e r v i s i o n a n d c h e c k s a g a i n s t all admin i str a tor s t h r o u g h and
lo c a l a s s e m b l i e s ,
m edia,
and vo ters' m e e tin g s ,
local i m p r e s s ol p a r t y c a d r e s a n d m i l i t a r y . T h e d i f f e r e n c e in t h e r o l e
ol “b u r e a u c r a c y " in t h e s e t w o a p p r o a c h e s w as m o r e a m a t t e r o f w h e r e than h o w m u c h .
T h e s y s t e m ol w o r k e r s
councils transferred authority
from w o r k e r s t h e m s e l v e s b a c k to s tall — m a n a g e r s , e n g i n e e r s , a n d u n i o n s . “E c o n o m i c
m e t h o d s l e d t o t h e c o n c e n t r a t i o n ol p l a n t a n d a r e d u c t i o n in
li,i F o r th e y e a rs o f d ir e c t parallels, s e e C a r r and D avies, / ' oundationx o f a Planned Щопоту, 1926-1929, vol. I, no. 1; and D o b b , Soviet E con om ic D evelopm ent since ¡917 I liJ~ ln jon n ativn i Prirucnik Jug o slam jc, 19 5 0 1 3 2 3 .
162
CHAPTER I
th e p ro p o rtio n o f w ork ers actually in p rod u ctio n (to re d u c e costs of pro duction). A nd th e g en eral fa r m e r s ’ c o o p e ra tiv e s, re s to re d to the c e n te r of agricu ltural policy as th e lead ership had in ten d ed in 1 9 4 6 , e m p lo y ed pri m arily
ad m in istrato rs ,
not
farm ers:
in
195 5 ,
of 5 1 ,3 9 3
perm anent
“w o r k e r s ," only 8 , 4 7 1 w o rk ed exclusively in a g ricu ltu re; 4 , 5 9 3 worked in shops c o n n e c t e d to ag ricu ltu re, while 3 8 , 3 2 9 w e re e m p lo y e d in non p ro d u ctio n ta s k s .193 T h e idea that “e c o n o m ic c h o i c e for th e “m a r k e t
m eth od s rep resen ted a
was tru e only in the sense that p rices w ere freed
in retail goods m ark ets ; and in c o n tra s t to th e e x ten siv e labor mobility and t u r n o v e r o f th e 1 9 4 8 - 4 9 e x tra c tiv e policies, th e re was no m arket alloca tion o f factors o f p ro d u ctio n in the “n ew e c o n o m i c s y s te m ”— th e employ m e n t c o n t ra c ts , c o n c e p t of socialist work c o m m u n itie s, and workers’ cou ncils all a im e d to imm obilize the w orkforce. T h e real aim o f th e s e c h an g es was to diminish th e federal government: to r e d u c e its b u r e a u c r a tic offices and m o v e ministries to the republics, to c u t th e size o f p u b lic -s e c to r e m p lo y m e n t in o r d e r to cut the cash-wage bill and th e n u m b e r ol p eo p le prov isio ned by state supplies, to eliminate c e n tr a l supply allocations and giv e au tho rity to firms and th eir branch a s s o c ia tio n s ,194 to c u t th e federal b u d g e t for stabilization purposes by tran sferrin g tasks and ju risd iction s to low er levels, to retu rn responsibility for lab or supplies and au th o rity o v e r hiring and firing to en terp rises, to c u t fu rth e r th e federal g o v e r n m e n t ’s role in p rod u ctio n and investment, to use “lean
m o n e ta r y in stru m e n ts o f e c o n o m ic d irectio n , and to nudge
foi-ward th e p ro c e s s o f th e “w ith erin g aw ay ” of th e state. And whereas historically, as J o y c e A p p leb y w rites, “th e s o c ie ty ’s d e p e n d e n c e upon the food sup ply p ro v id ed , after all, th e rock b o tto m reason for political control of e c o n o m i c activ ities, 195 th e le a d e rs ’ c o m m i t m e n t to a gradual transfer o f lab or from a g r icu ltu r e to in d u stry— tem p orarily re v e rs e d in 1 9 4 8 - 4 9 by t h e ir e v e n g r e a t e r c o m m i t m e n t to build a stron g d efen se, through th e ir ow n efforts if n e c e s s a r y — led in th e op p osite d irection: to reducing 'in p rivre(la FN RJ u p eriod u 1947-1056, se ction on th e ag ricultural population, 164-65. I!" A lth ou gh p rices w e r e freed in retail m ark ets in 1 9 5 1 . th e form er d ire cto ra te s— now b r a n c h p r o d u c e r organizatio ns, o r e c o n o m i c c h a m b e rs (p rivred n e ko m o r c )— assumed au th o rity o v e r allocating s c a r c e p ro d u ction m aterials b e c a u se , as an a rticle in F.konomska Poli-
tikn re p o rt e d f'S p o r a z u m n a d is lrib u cija ,” D e c e m b e r 17, 1 9 5 3 , p 1 0 1 2 ), th e "m a rk e t" would give c e m e n t , steel, wool, e tc , only to the e co n o m ica lly stro n g est r a th e r than to those whose n e e d w as g re a te s t. T h e p riv red n e kom orc would a ct as in te rm e d ia rie s am o n g producers, c r e a ti n g a forum to estab lish a g r e e m e n t s a m o n g th e m on priorities (what c a m e to he called in th e 1 9 7 0 s th e c o n tr a c tu a l, o r dngovorna, e co n o m y ), w hile leaving s o m e room lor contracts b e tw e e n individual firms ("tho ug h also not forg etting the peasant m arket '). They would “e v e n tu a lly ” solve the p ro b lem o f supplies with im po rts in the fii st half o f 1 9 5 4 and then, by e x p o r tin g p ro d u c tio n in the secon d hall of th e y ear, pay for the im ports. A cco rd ing to Ward, th e s e p r o d u c e rs associations w e r e esp ecially im p o rta n t in "co n tro llin g th e allocation of for eig n e x c h a n g e a m o n g firm s’' (“Industria l D e ce n tra liz a tio n in Y u g o sla v ia ,” 171n). 11,5 E con om ic T hought an d Ideology in Seventeenth-C entury England, 101.
M I L I T A KY S K U ' - K K U A N C K political c o n t r o l a n d c u t t i n g t h e p u b l i c s e c t o r in t h e f a c e ol n e a r f a m i n e . a reversal m a d e p o s s i b l e w i t h A m e r i c a n c r e d i t s . 11" ’ To the e x t e n t t h a t t h e r e w a s an “a d m i n i s t r a t i v e p e r i o d
in t h e i m m e d i
ate po stwa r y e a r s , it b e g a n in J a n u a r y 1 9 4 8 w i t h t h e c r e a t i o n o f ' a l a b o r ministry a n d t e m p o r a r y f e d e r a l c o n t r o l o v e r l a b o r , s u p p l i e s , a n d m a n y industries in o r d e r t o b u i l d d e f e n s e w i t h d o m e s t i c r e s o u r c e s , a n d i t e n d e d with the c l o s i n g o f t h e s t a t e l a b o r o f f ic e s in S e p t e m b e r 1 9 5 0 a f t e r c o m p l e tion ol th e l a b o r r e v i s i o n s o r d e r e d t h e p r e v i o u s D e c e m b e r . T h e f u n d a mental d i f f e r e n c e b e t w e e n t h a t p e r i o d a n d t h e p o l i c y o n e i t h e r s i d e ol it was the a p p r o a c h t o t h e e m p l o y m e n t o f la b o r . But t h e r e d id e m e r g e , o u t ol w h a t w as in f act a m o r e c o m p l e x f o u n d i n g period ol c o n s t a n t l y c h a n g i n g m e t h o d s a n d i n s t i t u t i o n s , tw o t e n d e n c i e s that woul d r e s u r f a c e a l t e r n a t e l y in t h e n e x t f o r t y y e a r s . T h e s e t e n d e n c i e s were d ef i n ed b y t h e d i f f e r e n t e m p h a s e s in p r o d u c t i o n — w i t h t h e i r d i f f e r ing systems ol e c o n o m i c in c e n t iv e s , e m p l o y m e n t s , an d p olitical o r g a n i z a t i o n — that re sul t ed as in t h e f o u n d i n g p e r i o d , f r o m p o l i c y r e s p o n s e s t o c h a n g e s in i n t er n a ti on a l c o n d i t i o n s . T h e a v a i l a b i l i t y a n d r e q u i r e m e n t s of f o r e i g n financing, sh i ft s in t e r m s o f t r a d e a n d m a r k e t a c c e s s as t h e y a f f e c t e d b o t h foreign d e m a n d f o r Y u g o s l a v g o o d s a n d f a c t o r p r i c e s lo r d o m e s t i c m a n u facturers, a n d t h e n e e d s o f d e f e n s e a l t e r n a t e l y f a v o r e d t h e c o n d i t i o n s o f supply c o n t r a c t s ( m i l i t a r y p r o c u r e m e n t , p r o d u c e r s ’ i n p u t s , b i l a t e r a l t r a d e a greements , o r a d v e r s e t e r m s ol t r a d e u n d e r w h i c h g a i n s c o u l d c o m e o n l y through i n c r e a s e s in s u p p l y ) a n d t h e c o n d i t i o n s o f d e m a n d in re t a i l m a r kets (both d o m e s t i c a n d e x p o r t , a n d t h e r e f o r e m a r k e t n i c h e a n d pri ce. more than q u a n t i t y a d j u s t m e n t s ) . In the first c l u s t e r , t h e e m p h a s i s w as on t h e p r o d u c t i o n of f n e l a n d foo d grains, t h e e x t r a c t i o n o f m i n e r a l s a n d o t h e r p r i m a r y p r o d u c t s , ca p i t a l goods, a n d m i l i t a r y e q u i p m e n t a n d s t o c k p i l e s ; in t h e s e c o n d c l u s t e r , t h e emphasis wa s o n p r o c e s s e d g o o d s a n d l ig h t m a n u f a c t u r i n g , g a r d e n f a r m ing, and o t h e r c o n s u m e r g o o d s . T h e S l o v e n e m o d e l p r e f e r r e d t h e p r o d u c tion pr ofil e of t h e s e c o n d c l u s t e r , a n d th a t m o d e l c o n t i n u e d t o s h a p e t h e dominant e c o n o m i c a n d p o li t i c a l i n s t i t u t i o n s f or t h e e n t i r e p e r i o d . N o n e theless, t h e i m p o r t a n c e of a n i n d e p e n d e n t d e f e n s e , t h e p r i v i l e g e d p o s i tion of m a n u f a c t u r e r s of final g o o d s , a n d t h e u n p r e d i c t a b l e f l u c t u a t i o n s in foreign d e m a n d a ls o k e p t a l iv e t h e F o c a m o d e l , P o l it i c a l d i s a g r e e m e n t s over po l i c y c o n t i n u e d , a n d t h e d i f f e r e n t i a l e f f e c t s o n r e g i o n s a n d e m p l o y ment s e c t o r s w e r e s i g n i f i c a n t . B u t it w as t h e u n c o n t r o l l a b l e i n t e r n a t i o n a l en viro n m en t t h a t r e m a i n e d d e c i s i v e f or g o v e r n m e n t a l p o lic y . IA)iVT h e lead ers g ave tw o reasons for not w a n tin g to u n ite with Bulgaria (d e s p ite S talin’s pressure) that r ein fo rce th e in te r p r e ta tio n in this hook oi t h e i r l o n g -te rm s tra te g y ; that B u l garia was on th e less ind ustrialized a n d p o o r e r e n d of th e Yugoslav s p e c tru m and w ould shift the domestic b alan ce nway from th e d e v e lo p e d n o r th w e st; and that as a m o r e urban p a r ty o f industrial w o rk ers , th e B ulgarian C o m m u n i s t p a rty w as m o r e willing to c o lle ctiv iz e a g ric u l ture (see, for exa m p le
Kardelj in \
D e d ije r, Nniti, prilozi 3 : 3 0 2 ) ,
C h ap te r 5 A REPUBLIC OF PRODUCERS
T
h e
c h a n g es
in th e organization o f th e e c o n o m y in 1 9 5 0 and of foreign
t ra d e in 1 9 5 1 had to b e c o n firm e d constitutionally, b e ca u se economic rec o g n itio n o f Yu goslav s o v e re ig n ty p e r m it te d norm alization at home an d b e c a u s e e c o n o m i c re s tru c t u ri n g (the “n ew e c o n o m ic system ) re q u ir e d political re s tru c tu rin g . T h e Basic L a w a d o p te d by th e national as s e m b ly on J a n u a ry 13, 1 9 5 3 , was only th e seco nd o f five constitutions; a b attle o v e r th e sixth, b eg in n in g in 1 9 8 2 , led to th e final disintegration of th e Y u go slav state in 1 9 9 0 . M ost analysts o f its collapse, particularly do m e s t i c critics o f th e r e g im e , a s crib e its e c o n o m i c and political downfall to th e 1 9 7 4 con stitu tion and th e related constitutional d o c u m e n t on la b or relations o f 1 9 7 6 , th e L a w on A ssociated L a b o r (colloquially called t h e “w o r k e r s ’ c o n stitu tio n ”). B u t th e principles o f th e 1 9 7 4 constitution h ad a lread y b e e n established before 1 9 5 3 , in th e p eriod chron icled in th e p re v io u s c h a p te r ; and e a c h successiv e con stitu tion after 1 9 5 3 was a f u r th e r s te p in th e p ro c e s s o f realizing th e original l e a d e r s ’
idea of a so
cialist s o c ie ty — a s ystem in th e p ro c es s o f b e co m in g th ro u g h constitutive laws. T h e d ifferences in th e con stitu tion s and in sy s tem ic laws in intervening years reflect th e unfolding o f this idea as th e lead ership c on fro nted differ e n t in tern a tio n al con d itio n s — in th e areas of national secu rity, term s of tr a d e , and t e r m s for finance, refinan ce, and ex p o rt earn in g s — by alternat ing b e t w e e n tw o b asic a p p r o a c h e s to p rod u ctio n with re s p e c t to labor in ce n tiv e s , industrial organ ization , and priority secto rs. This is because th e institutions o f th e d o m e s tic o r d e r c o n tin u e d to be defined by the con d itio n s o f its origin, w h en national i n d e p e n d e n c e was defined in terms o f m ilitary th re a ts to te rr ito ry and w h en th e capital n e e d e d for industrial ization was in short sup ply— b oth m a c h in e r y and trad e finance, and hu m an capital (skilled tech n ician s,
m an ag ers,
and w orkers with steady
industrial habits). This sca rcity defined a m en tality toward th e economy t h at n e v e r c h a n g e d . 1 D e s p ite th e o n e -p a rty state and the political purges 1
A co n tin u in g d isp u te in th e lite r a tu r e
011
socialist sy ste m s, prim arily those of Easlcrn
E u r o p e and th e U S S R , c o n c e r n e d w h e t h e r th e y w e r e best un d e rsto od by H ungarian econo mist Jan o s K ornai's c o n c e p t of “sh orta g e e co n o m ie s " I do not e n t e r this discussion here, e x c e p t to r e m a r k that th e r e is p e rsu a siv e em pirical e v id e n c e against th e argu m e n t (see
165
A REPUBLIC O F PRODUCERS
of op p o n en ts , d isp u tes o v e r h o w to resolv e those sh o rtag es and how to increase capital c o n tin u e d b e c a u s e of the p e rs iste n t conflict b e tw e e n the Slovene m o d e l, w hich won institutionally, and th e F o c a reality arising from th e l e a d e r s ’ m u ltiple goals, th e c o u n t r y ’s h e te r o g e n e it y , and its c o m plex in tern atio n al position. T h e political s y stem b e c a m e critical to the leaders
o b je c tiv e s b e c a u s e c h a n g e s in th e ap p ro ac h to p rod u ctio n r e
quired institutional a d ju s tm e n ts an d b e c a u s e th e political system was e x p ected to m a n a g e and h a rm o n iz e th e rem ain in g conflicts. U n d e rs ta n d in g th at political m o del is p articularly im p o r ta n t to u n d e r standing Y u go slav u n e m p lo y m e n t, as well as the u ltim ate collapse o f the system itself, b e c a u s e m o st exp lanations o f b oth focus
011
the political
system. F o r a d h e r e n ts o f th e original W a r d m o del (elab o rated in th e next chapter), Yu goslav u n e m p l o y m e n t was g r e a te r than it n e e d e d to be b e cause o f t h e d ecis io n -m ak in g rights at th e w o rk p lac e— b e c a u s e o f th e in stitutions for con su ltation b e t w e e n m a n a g e m e n t and p rod u ctio n w orkers in the p ub lic s e c to r (w h e th e r e c o n o m i c e n te rp rise s o r social s erv ices and institutions) o v e r w ages,
b enefits,
in v e s tm e n t, and e m p lo y m e n t.
For
others, th e b argain in g a m o n g rep u blican d e le g a te s within councils of the federal g o v e r n m e n t as a resu lt, it is arg u ed , o f the 1 9 7 4 con stitu tion caused th e d e clin e of th e e n tire e c o n o m y and with it the s y stem itself (although w e h ave seen th at th e se councils had alread y b egu n to rep lace the min isterial s t r u c t u r e by 1 9 5 0 and even tu ally would re p la c e all o th e r go vernm ental offices in th e e c o n o m y ). In th e first in stan ce, it was m ark et socialism (as th e Yugoslav s ystem was often labeled) that failed; in th e second it was d e c e n tra liz a tio n — to th e gre a t d isa p p o in tm e n t of th e m an y who c o n tin u e to s u p p o rt both. This b ook arg u e s that it was n e it h e r w o r k e r s ’ councils with an inability to im pose w a g e re s tra in t n or th e conflicts a m o n g the re p u b lic s ’ political elites w ith th e ir inability to a g r e e on policy th at was th e c au s e of u n e m p loym ent and d isin tegratio n ; it was instead th e effect o f c o n trad ictio n s in the le a d e r s ’ s tra te g y for d e v e lo p m e n t and national in d e p e n d e n c e
011
eco
nomic p olicies, social organization, and political action. To u n d e rs ta n d these o u tc o m e s , th e w orkers councils and fed eral decision making m u st be seen in th at b r o a d e r c o n te x t, as th e lead ers in ten d ed th em and as th ey interacted with o t h e r parts o f th e system .
Burkett, ‘ S e a r c h , S e le c tio n , and S h o r t a g e ,” for a discussion and r e fe r e n c e s to th e e m p irica l research b y R ich a rd P o r te s a n d o th e rs). A la rg e part o f t he actu al sh o rta g e s was a result of rationing
111
r e s p o n s e to internatio nal p r o b l e m s — a p r o b le m that m igh t o r m igh t not have;
been reso lvab le by o p e n m a rk e t e c o n o m i e s . T h e p o s tc o m n u m is t p e rio d will pro vid e b e t t e r answers. M o re im p o rta n t to this stu d y is th e e a rly e x p e r i e n c e in th e h istory o f socialist regimes w ith s h o r ta g e s o f p ro d net ion inputs and skilled la b o r a n d th e institutionalized stru c
turing of t h e s e so cieties th e r e a f te r as if th e p r im a ry p ro b le m w e r e su ch shortages*
166
CHAPTER 5
M
is u n d e r s t a n d in g s
T h e first th ing th at m u s t b e clarified ab ou t this n ew system is th at it was not, an d n e v e r b e c a m e , a s ystem of w o r k e r s ’ control. T h e c o n c e p t of a la b o r-m a n a g e d firm and an e c o n o m y organ ized aroun d lab or-m anaged firms, on w h ich an e n t ir e th e o re tic a l literatu re later aro se, does not a ccu rately reflect th e rights an d p o w ers assigned to p rod u ctio n w orkers in Yu go slav e n te r p r is e s o r th e p u r p o se o f w o r k e r p articip ation in en terp rise m anagem ent.
In fact, th e s y stem no lon ger re c o g n iz e d u np ro pertied
w a g e e a r n e r s , e i th e r as a class or a status. T h e c o n c e p t o f labor as an actor s e p a r a te from capital c e a se d to exist. It was re p la c e d by th e cen tral c on c e p t o f a p r o p e r t y o w n e r w h o was a p r o d u c e r of value and by its operative p ri n c i p le — th e
incentive to increase produced value (that is, productivity,
o r n e t value), an in ce n tiv e that would d e riv e from rights of political and e c o n o m i c d ecision making. T h e s e units of p ro p e rt y -o w n i n g p ro d u ce r s w e r e actually associations of p e o p le d efin ed individually by t h e ir e m p lo y m e n t c o n tra c t placing them in a lo n g - te r m e m p l o y m e n t position ( radni
odnos), w h ich was a right to
re c e i v e i n c o m e in p ro p o rtio n to work as d efined by th e legally regulated job classification o f that c o n tra c t. T h e e s s e n c e of socialist em p loy m en t (th e
radni odnos), K ardelj told th e s e co n d p le n u m of th e cen tral c o m m it
t e e in Ja n u a ry 1 9 4 9 , was “the m e th o d o f p a y m e n t . ”2 As collectivities, th e se associations of p ro d u c e r s w e r e defined by th e p r o d u c e r s ’ political rights to p articip a te in decisions on th e creation and disposition of net
income (“surplus v a l u e , ” o r gross re c e ip ts m inus costs). T h e ir particular organization o f associated labor
“lab ors’ th at th e y jo in ed to g e th e r in an
distin gu ish ed t h e m a c c o rd in g to functions within the organization and a c c o r d i n g to th e rights and relativ e shares to in co m e and benefits within th e w ork (capital) c o lle ctiv e ( radna
zajednica). B u t th e re f e r e n c e in policy
d e b a te s to d i re c t p ro d u c e r s o r to th e w o r k e r s ’ c olle ctiv e m e a n t not w o rk ers b u t e n te r p r i s e s , w h o s e r e p re s e n ta tiv e s w e r e alm o st always from m a n a g e m e n t or th e p arty organization. M o r e o v e r , alongside this organi zation of th e p ublic s e cto r, t h e r e was a p rivate s e c to r of p ro d u ce r s — individuals o r hou seh old s also defined b y th e right to d raw in co m e on t h e i r n e t earn in gs an d lim ited in th eir rights to dispose o f capital assets— b u t th e y could “join th eir lab or” (associate and co n tra c t) only with socials e c t o r firms, and t h e ir political rights to p articip ate with o th e r producers in th e allocation o f surplus w e r e con fin ed to th e local level w h e re they paid fees an d in c o m e tax. W h a t jo in e d th e se p ro d u c e r s /w o rk in g p e o p le c o n cep tu ally was the c o r e id ea o f this e c o n o m i c and political system : the early liberal idea of 2 P e tr a n o v ić , K o n č a r, and Kadonjić, Sednice Centralnog kom iteta KPJ (1948-1952), 32,
167
A HKP UBL IC O F P R O D U C E R S
economic interest as th e m o tiv e o f social good (an idea often associated with A d am S m ith , alth ou gh c u r r e n t ly alive in ratio n al-ch o ice th e o rie s of behavior) and th e re fo re the s o u rc e of right. T h e p ro p e rty -rig h ts school, in the A ustrian school version o f Carl M o n g e r , defined the philosophical underpinnings o f this individualist-societal link: The
state
can
g reatly
harm
th e
citiz e n 's
in terest
by
in te rfe rin g
to o
m u c h . . . . B e i n g r e s p o n s i b l e a n d c a r i n g (o r t h e w e l l - b e i n g o( o n e s s e l f an d fa m ily is a p o w e r f u l i n c e n t i v e f o r w o r k a n d i n d u s t r y . T h e d i s c h a r g e ol t h e s e d u ties b e c o m e s th e p u r e s t jo y and tr u e s t p rid e o f th e fre e c itiz e n , . .
Any
i n c e n t i v e w h i c h m a k e s t h e w o r k e r s w o r k h a r d e r m a y b e r e g a r d e d as a g a i n to t h e e c o n o m y . T h e m o s t e l l e c t i v e i n d u c e m e n t ( o r t h e w o r k e r s lie s in t h e i r re co g n iz in g th at (h e ir re w a rd d e p e n d s on th e ir ow n d ilig e n ce . 1
Tito p r e f e r r e d to call this in d u c e m e n t “p e r s p e c t i v e ”:4 w o r k e r s ’ eflort and short-term w ag e re s tra in t followed from th e k now ledge that th ey had p o litical con trol (the “p e o p l e ’s p o w e r ” that, K idrič insisted in 194 6 , d istin guished th e ir socialism from
state capitalism).
T h e conflict b e tw e e n
capital and lab or was n ow only o n e of tim e horizons (and th e re fo re in v e s t ment), as classical th eorists often saw i t / ’ It is the c ase, as th e la h o r- m a n a g e m e n t literatu re stresses, that the effective focus o f p r o p e r ty rights, and thus th e work c o ll e c ti v e ’s e c o n o m i c incentive to maintain and e n h a n c e th e value o f its assets, was the c o lle c tive’s
income (w h a te v e r th e s o u r c e — p rod u ctio n realized in sales, or b u d
getary grants from c o r p o r a t e tax r e v e n u e s ) / ’ B u t the p u rp o se of b u d g e ta r y autonomy (th e c o r e idea o f “s e lf -m a n a g e m e n t’ ) was w h at that literatu re treats as its c o n s e q u e n c e — to in crease gain by c u ttin g costs of p rod u ction so that in c o m e rose only in p rop ortion to real gains in p rod u ctiv ity . M o r e over, the a s s ig n m e n t of responsibility for b u d g e ta ry discipline to m a n agers and th e banks, to p r o te c t against the moral hazard possible given this freed o m , c r e a t e d th e p otential for conflicts b e tw e e n w orkers and 3 T h e s e e x c e r p t s a r e from th e p rim a ry s o u r c e o f M e n g e r ’s ideas, the 1 8 7 0 l e c t u r e n o te books o f C ro w n P r in c e H ud olf o f A u stria, cite d by S tre issle r in “ W h a t Kind ol E c o n o m i c Liberalism M ay W e E x p e c t in ‘E a s t e r n ’ E u r o p e ? ” 1.98. S tre issle r identifies t h e s e ideas with the p ro p e rty -rig h ts school w ithin liberal th o u g h t. 4 Tito, at t h e third p le n u m of th e C P Y c e n tra l c o m m i t t e e , in P e tra n o v ic, K o n ča r, and Radonjič, Sednica, 4 0 4 . ’’ In the e v e r -d e v e lo p in g , sp ecialized lang uag e for this sy ste m , cap ital w as increasingly referred to afte r th e m i d -1 9 6 0 s as minuli r a d ( past la b o r”); the. t e r m becam e, official with the 1974 co n s titu tio n . O n th e d is p u te critical to th e o rie s of'labor m a n a g e m e n t o v e r w hat c o n s t i tuted the o b j e c ti v e function for w o rk e rs u n d e r s e lf -m a n a g e m e n t, and w h e t h e r w o rk ers would take a lo ng tim e h o rizon , s e e T y so n , “A P e r m a n e n t I n c o m e H y p o th e sis for the Yugoslav F i r m . ” (i T h e la t t e r s o u r c e would b e for g o v e r n m e n t s (called
sociopolitical c o m m u n i t i e s ”) and
financially a u to n o m o u s p ro v id e rs of pu blic goods and s e rv ice s su ch as e d u ca tio n o r roads [eventually calle d “c o m m u n i tie s of in t e r e s t ”).
168
CHAPTKR5
t h e ir e l e c t e d r e p r e s e n ta ti v e s , b e tw e e n w orkers council and m an ag em en t b o ard , and b e t w e e n th e e n tire w ork c ollectiv e and outside regulators, s uch as th e social a c c o u n tin g s e rv ic e within th e banks and o th e r adminis trato rs of legislated rules. d e n c e (the w o rd
S e lf-m a n a g e m e n t m e a n t financial in d ep en
sovereignty was used for rep u blics)— as it did in 1927,
w h en the g o v e r n m e n t w ith d re w its c o n trib u tio n from financing for u n e m p l o y m e n t c o m p e n s a tio n and left w o r k e r s ’ c h a m b e r s solely responsible, and in 1 9 3 7 , w h en T ito strov e to p u t th e C P Y on its own financial footing b e c a u s e th e C o m i n t e r n refused to s u p p o rt it further. In te r f e r e n c e with th at i n d e p e n d e n c e , w h e t h e r th e “d e p e n d e n c e ” of d e b t o r th e reduced fr e e d o m o f p ub lic claim s on the c o lle c t iv e ’s in co m e , c a m e to be seen as a limit on th at s o v e re ig n ty , on se lf-m a n a g e m e n t. T h e le a d e rs ’ p u rp o se after 1 9 4 7 in localities, rep u b lics, e n te rp ris e s , and social services, however, was to e n fo r c e e c o n o m i c responsibility w itho u t res o rt to state power, u sin g (as th e lan gu age of th e early 1950s called the b u d g e t con strain t of an e n t e r p r i s e ’s n et realized in co m e) th e “a u to m a tic con trol o f the m a r k e t.”7 “W o r k e r s ’ c o n tr o l” was only o n e a s p e c t of the retu rn to “e c o n o m ic c o e r c i o n ” after A ug ust 1 9 4 9 in o r d e r to stabilize th e “m a r k e t”; th e behavioral p rin cip le o f individual e c o n o m ic in t e re s t was, in the explanation offered in M ay
1 9 5 2 by e c o n o m is t and party r e p la c e m e n t at F in a n c e
Kiro
G ligo rov , in te n d e d to bring co n su m p tio n o f w ag e goods back into line with existin g (dwindling) supplies while stim ulating p rod u ctio n , and to r e s t o r e value to th e c u r r e n c y as an in stru m e n t of e c o n o m i c calculation an d policy. “ By th e logic o f his own i n t e r e s t ," th e p easan t w h o was forced to pay cash for industrial goods and m e e t h ig h e r tax obligations would in c r e a s e p ro d u ctio n for th e m ark et, and this in cre a se d supply would in turn b rin g p ric e s dow n. Similarly, Gligorov exp lained , devaluation of the d in ar w ou ld ac t as a stim ulus to i n cr e a se d p rod u ction for exp ort, given the obligation to k eep e x p e n d itu r e s (including w ages and benefits) within the limit o f a firm ’s r e c e i p ts . 8 C u ts in public ex p e n d itu re s (in v es tm en t, offi cials’ salaries, and g u a ra n te e d provisions) would au tom atically release re s o u rc e s for m an u fac tu rers. I n d e e d , th e a r g u m e n t that financial accoun tability was m o re effective than state c o n tro l was the reason given for e n d in g the “administrative p e r i o d ” and tran sferrin g “c o n c e r n for finding labor from state organs to 7 A ty pical e x a m p l e ca n h e found in G o n i pie, “ U lo g a e k o n o m ista u našoj priv red i ; see also M lad ek , Š tu re, an d W yezalkow ski, “T h e C h a n g e in the Yugoslav E c o n o m i c S y ste m .” E n th u s ia s ts in th e n o r th w e s t, p articu la rly , c riticiz e d th e “d o m in a n t n o te in the co n te m p o r a ry e c o n o m i c th o u g h t of b o u rg e o is c o u n t ri e s ’ — th e d e m a n d for a “str e n g th e n in g of the e c o n o m i c function s o f th e s ta te ”— as “an exp re ssio n o f the g ro w ing d ish a rm o n y betw een p r o d u c t i v e forces a n d p ro d u c tio n relation s in capita lism and a reflection o f th e g e n e ra l crisis o f ca p ita lis m ” (D a b č e v i ć , “Neki su v r e m e n i e k onom isti o ekonom skoj ulozi d r ž a v e ,” 37) 8 K, G ligo rov , “F a c t o r s iu O u r E c o n o m i c Stab ilizatio n .”
169
A REPUBLIC O F PRODUCERS
the firm, w h ich u n d e rta k e s m e a s u re s for the m o re c o r r e c t utilization of labor.”9 As an official in th e M in istry o f Social Policy exp lained , th e state labor offices “had led to th e e x p e n d i tu r e o f financial re s o u rc e s for the employment in th e e c o n o m y of n ew labor that after a short stay left the firm, often not ev e n c o n trib u tin g en o u g h to c o v e r th e costs of its e n g a g e m ent.”10 T h e first in stan ce of e x te n d in g th e financial discipline o f self m anagem ent to social s ervices and p ublic utilities that did not “c r e a t e value” but u sed th at c r e a t e d by o th ers , called social se lf-m a n a g e m e n t, was in social in su ran ce, b e c a u s e “th e office o f social in su ran ce and e c o nomic e n te rp ris e s that had use o f th e se funds had not b e e n m aterially interested in th e rational e x p e n d i tu r e of th ese res o u rc es . T h u s it o c c u r r e d that th e re w e r e firms th at m isu sed th e funds, taking from the socialinsurance a c c o u n t sum s that th ey cou ld not justify and that th ey used as their own w orkin g capital. 11 It is also m islead in g to call this system “m arket socialism. concept o f
T h e le a d e r s ’
socialist com m odity production was not a m a r k e t e c o n o m y ,
although final goods (“c o m m o d it ie s ”) m ark ets o p e r a t e d largely by a free price m e c h a n is m and c o n s u m e r d e m a n d was m e a n t to be th e p rim ary incentive to p ro d u c e r s . In c re a s in g p ric e liberalization also o c c u r r e d in the foreign s e c t o r — p articu larly after 1 9 6 1 , w hen th e seco n d stage of reform s for G A T F (G e n e ra l A g r e e m e n t on Tariffs and T ra d e ) m e m b e r s h ip r e placed m u ltiple coefficients with
a uniform
gressively liberalized, an d, after 1 9 7 2 ,
tariff,
d uties w e r e
pro
th e e x c h a n g e rate b e c a m e an
active i n s tru m e n t of p o l i c y .12 Hut the m ark et did not apply to factors of production— labor, capital and in te rm e d i a te goods, raw m aterials, c re d it in the form of w orkin g and v e n tu r e capital— although m o n e ta r y p rices were assigned to facilitate allocation and c o m p a ra tiv e valuation and a re n t was c h a rg e d on fixed capital and b o rro w ed funds. This was not th e m o del of market socialism
id entified with
O scar
Lange,
F r e d e r i c k Taylor,
E. Baro ne, and o th ers , for th e r e was no cen tral calculation o f shad ow prices to im itate a m a r k e t an d in v e s tm e n t c h o ices w e r e increasingly d e centralized. P ric e regulation was used in place of a p ro d u ctio n plan in order to a c h ie v e b alan c ed d e v e l o p m e n t as well as m o n e ta r y eq uilib riu m by influencing in cen tives to p r o d u c e r s , 13 so th at th e g o v e r n m e n t k ept the 9 Has, “D ru štv e n o -e k o n o m sk i o sv rt na p ro b le m z a p o sle n o s ti,’’ 146. 10 M aričić, “N eki p ro b le m i org a n iz a cije i rada biroa za p o sre d o v a n je r a d a ,” 6 6 2 11 M ato vić, “S a m o u p r a v a u socijalnom o s i g u r a n j u / ’ 4 3 0 . 12 'Hie r e is m u c h d is p u te abo ut ho w liberalized tlie foreign transm ission o f p rice s actually was; see T y so n
and
N eu b erg er,
“T h e Transm issio n o f Internatio nal
D istu r b a n ce s
to
Yugoslavia.” O n th e in a p p ro p ria te n e ss of p r ice m e ch a n ism s as a policy in s tru m e n t for for eign trad e, s e e D v k e r , Yugoslavia: S ocialism , D evelopm ent, a n d D ebt, 9 7 - 1 0 1 and passim. 13 S ee L a n g e and T a y lo r, On {he E con om ic T heory o f Socialism, and H e im a n n , “ L i t e r a ture on th e T h e o r y o f a Socialist E c o n o m y . ” Also, co n tr a st th e m o r e c o n t e m p o r a n e o u s ae-
170
CHAPTER 5
p r i c e o f factors o f p ro d u ctio n , n e cessities (such as grains), and strategic goods relativ ely low and allowed p rices o f m an u fac tu red and consumable g ood s to re s p o n d to d e m a n d . T h e m a c r o e c o n o m ic c o n ce p tio n of an econ o m y b e h in d th e m arket-socialist m o d el (the “ K eynesian rev olu tion ”) did not inform its institutional c o n str u c tio n , n o r d oes th e m o d el pay much atte n tio n to th e goals assigned to th e Yugoslav state (the federal govern m e n t): d i r e c t e d d e v e l o p m e n t for stru ctu ral c h a n g e in e c o n o m ic capacity, and m a n a g e m e n t o f foreign relations (including defense). P a rt o f th e confusion lies in w h at to call a socialist e c o n o m y that is not a p lan n ed e c o n o m y . T h e p lann ing system th at e m e r g e d by 1 9 5 2 was only a s e t o f policy goals for p ro d u ctio n and i n v e s tm e n t in th e c o m in g plan pe riod (goals w e r e s et annually until 1 9 5 6 and at five-year intervals thereaf te r, b u t with in terru p tio n s) that w e re sup po sed to define c red it, price, and fo re ig n -tra d e policies, an d a fo recast o f the actual grow th path of eco n o m ic a g g re g a te s b ased on th e p rod u ctio n plans of firms and develop m e n t plans o f localities and rep u blics. It was not a set of commands, q u an tity c on trols, o r d ire c te d allocations, n o r was it th e apparatus to ef fec t t h e m , 14 alth ou gh th e g o v e r n m e n t did re s o r t to ad h oc quantity con trols w h e n th e n e e d for im m e d ia te re s p o n se p re c lu d e d use of financial in s t ru m e n ts (w hich took lon ger to show results). E n t e r p r is e s w e re opera tionally a u to n o m o u s , although s u b je ct to substantial regulation; but the m o n e ta r y s ystem did c o n tin u e to o p e ra te on th e sam e principles as mone tary p lan n in g in th e S oviet sy s tem , including non co nv ertib ility , account ing p rin cip les in th e p ublic s e c t o r , 15 and a tte m p ts both to maintain social c o n tro l o v e r m o n e y an d finance and to c a p tu re re s o u rc e s from th e private s e c t o r an d foreign so u rc es for p ublic use in o r d e r to in su re public deter m in ation o f in v e s tm e n t. A n on p lan n ed socialist e c o n o m y is not neces sarily a m ark et-socialist e c o n o m y , and its principles of allocation may e v e n vary across t im e and e c o n o m i c secto rs (as w e saw in th e previous c h a p t e r ) . 16 A n o th e r p a rt o f t h e confusion o v e r c h a r a cte riz in g th e Yugoslav system a ro se from th e s y s t e m ’s use o f m a n y m ark et e le m e n ts and from its fre q u e n t r e f e r e n c e s to th e m ark et, re f e re n c e s that in fact had varying mean c o u n t from a C h in e s e au th o r, w hich parallels m o r e d ire ctly th e Yugoslav p r a ctice (Jiang, 'T h e T h e o r y o f an E n t e r p r i s e - B a s e d E c o n o m y "). 11
T h e plan ning co m m issio n s b e c a m e advisory c o m m itte e s to re pub lican governm ents,
and th e p la n ’s goals w e r e not legally binding. 15 S e e L a v i g n e , “T h e C re a tio n o f M o n e y by th e S tate Bank of th e U S S R ," for a cleai discussion o f this sy stem . P o r te s , “C e n tr a l Plan ning and M o n e t a r i s m ,“ gives an interesting i n te r p r e ta tio n o f th e relation b e tw e e n this system o f m o n e ta ry plan ning and monetarism. 16 This variation and the u n se ttle d c h a r a c te r o f th e Yugoslav sy ste m in th e 1950s are m a d e p a rticu larly c le a r in W a r d ’s d o ctoral d issertatio n, “ F r o m M arx to B a r o n e .” On the a r g u m e n t that th e Y ugoslav sy stem was a form o f m a rk e t socialism , se e also N ove, The
E con om ics o f F easib le Socialism; and Bid e le u x , Communism an d Developm ent
A REPUBLIC O F PRODUCERS
171
ing for different people and at different times. Most com monly, the market m eant th e operation of the “law of value" on which Kidrie insisted, siding with L en in against Bukharin in arguing that the “equilibrium co n ditions o f re pro du ction” would hold under socialism as w e l l .17 T hey b e lieved, namely, that to balance demand and supply one must stimulate supply as well as, in the short run, limit dem and and ration supply; for that, consu m er dem and in retail markets (with free prices for finished goods) was fundamental as the econom ic incentiv e to producers. T h e e n thusiasm for the “m a rk e t” at the first congress o f the new professional association o f econom ists in 1952 was for such “econom ic laws" (and an increased role for their s c ie n c e ) ,18 although some economists, like many party leaders at the third plenum in D e c e m b e r 1949, worried that it might be too soon becau se of severe sh orta ges.19 But the m arket could also mean what Kidrič called the “capitalist principles of accumulation" (commercial profit) and “econom ic coercion, which would continue to govern econ om ic behavio r in relations with W e stern markets and in the private sector of individual producers. In a third use of the word, market was in fact applied to decentralization, perhaps on the assumption that ever less central direction and eve r more autonomy for actors within the economy necessarily m eant that market principles would e m e rg e. It was this idea that led teams of econom ic advisers from the I M F to insist on decentralization as a Trojan horse for niarketization (especially in the 1950s and 1960s), and it could explain in part why each I M F program was followed by further decentralization o f some k ind .20 But decentralization in the sense o f subsidiarity was also critical to the lead ers’ idea that the incentive o f individual econ om ic interest operated b e tte r when the d eci sion making and supervision necessary to macroeconom ic stabilization were closer to those who actually produced. Cheeks and balances o p er ated best within budgetary units, w here financial accountability was as sessed, not in the society at large. D ecentralization along budgetary lines (according to work units that produced market value), profil-and-loss ac counting in the econom y, and balanced budgets in “nonproductive;” aetiv17 S e e S u tela, “Ideology as a Means of E co n o m ic D e b a te .” 18 Gorupić, “Uloga ekonomista u našoj privredi,” This th em e weaves through th e e c o nomic journals in 1.952-54 and also through the discussion on em ploym ent policy in 1954 (reported in Has, “D ruštveno-ekonomski osvrt”). Author’s interviews in J9 8 2 with economists who wore present a( I he third plenum; see Ekonomski Pregled 3, nos. 1--2 (1952). This concern is one o f th e reasons that Mile.nkovitch argues that th e rapid dism antling o f planning in 1 9 5 0 - 5 2 must have been political
(Plan and Market in Yugosl/iv Economic Thought , 7 3 -7 7 ) . 20
Jan Mladek, personal comm unication in Washington, D .C . , 1987; Sanja Crnkovie,
personal comm unication at the Institute o f Econom ies in Zagreb, on h er studies of this pattern, 1982. S e e also Mladek, Sture, and Wye/.alkovvski, “T h e Change in the Yugoslav Economic System/*
172
CHAPTER 5
ities did not mean that this “hard bud get constraint” was achieved by a m ark et-clearing price m echanism or was im m u ne to contradiction for o th er policy priorities. T h e y did mean that macroeconom ic equilibrium was conceived as a sum o f m icroeconom ic behaviors. T h e political links among the socialist units of the econom y were not horizontal, b u t vertical, as D ragolju b Jovanovič complained in the debate over farm ers’ cooperatives in 1946. T h e institutions w ere based on Kard e lj’s image of autonomous socialist com m unities— w h eth er a villagebased cooperative, a c om m u ne, or an organization o f associated labor (workplace and unit o f account)— linked by representation in assemblies and the party hierarchy. E conomically, autonomous producers were linked partly through the hierarchy o f the banking system and monetary control, and partly through cooperative contracts. T h e s e bilateral rela tions w e re primarily for the exchange o f raw materials and industrial goods b e tw e e n farm ers’ cooperatives and public-sector enterprises, so as to bind private suppliers to the social sector and eventually incorporate them into it; or, after the mid-1970s, for investm ent and jo in t ventures b e tw e e n e nterprises in the developed republics and enterprises in the republics or regions classified as less-developed. B u t there was also hori zontal consultation among functional groups within territorial units. For exam ple, the ch a m b e rs o f c o m m e rc e and industry, the unions, and local gov ernm ents consulted on incomes policies, and producers within an industrial branch conferred (cartel-like) over price policy, rationing prior ities when essential inputs were scarce, and economic-policy recomm en dations. B u t these organized “interests” would then aggregate territorially through the hierarchy o f the federal system to participate in policy making or to im p lem e n t central policies locally. Goods would naturally How across borders, and th e re was a divisive debate over citizenship be fore the constitu ent assembly, in order to facilitate labor mobility, chose to m ake Yugoslavs citizens o f the country as well as of th eir republic (as in Swiss cantons) or th eir ethnic nationality and country (as in the USSR ).21 N onetheless, the budgetary system intended limits on the horizontal flow o f m oney and credit; and, as the official complaints from the labor minis try in 1949 show, there continued to be political resistance to border crossings by producers or localities to find cheaper sources of labor or higher profits (in contrast to the purchase of raw or finished goods). The 2i
i thank C arol I.illy for inform ation about this d eb ate, H ondius elaborates on th e history
o f citizen ship laws and th eir outcom e in 1946
(The Yugoslav Community o f Nations, chaps.
1 -3 ) ; he makes clea r that citizen ship in a republic was consid ered prim ary because the federal gov ern m en t did not m aintain citizenship lists sep arate from republican rolls (184). But h e appears to b e unaw are o f th e d eb ate that led to th e reason for what h e calls federal sta te a lle g ia n ce ." T h is d eb ate o ccu rred , o f cou rse, b efore th e leaders' strategy was politically secure (before the 1946 pohtbureau m eeting and 1 9 4 8 - 4 9 purge)
A R E P U B L IC OK P R O D U C E R S
173
leaders’ concern lor social stability through settling labor and households was, however, superseded by the mid-1950s by local and republican gov ernments concept ol econ om ic interest, which aimed to protect their tax base and prevent "expatriation ol profits or the influx of unwanted migrants, One might say that the Yugoslav svstem was a mixture ol liberal and socialist assumptions about econom ic behavior and goals for econom ic and political life. Organizationally, it was a hybrid ,22 based on an idea ol social-property rights that w ere simultaneously econom ic and political; its methods of allocating econ om ic resources and ol making and enforcing public choices relied on n either the com petitive price mechanism of cap italist society nor the planning bureaucracy of statist society, but on the idea ol dem ocratic consultation and a greem ent among autonomous and sell-interested but also cooperative property owners (governments and the work collectives with rights to manage social assets) on com mon rules tor value and d istrib ution,23
l v \ I P L ( I Y M K N '1 '
The new constitutional order was based on the authority o f labor— “all power derived from working p e o p le ,” which meant persons employed in producing value. T h e constitutional right to work was not a right to a jo b , but a right of persons already employed to participate in decisions on the use of assets they help ed create and to receive an income on the basis ol their labor.24 Gu arantees o f this right to work lay not in governmental policy but in the property rights guaranteeing subsistence (and thus p r e venting the un em p lo y m en t associated with proletarianization) that u n d e r lay the leaders’ tw o-sector strategy. By law, firms in the public sector had 22 Iii describing the Hungarian system this way, llankiss assumes that it was a composite of inherited systems, spontaneous changes, and ad hoe adjustments (“In Search of a Para digm ). T h e re was som e o f that also in the Yugoslav ease, but I believe that far m ore pattern can be discerned in th ese two cases o f reformed socialism if one starts with the ideas of economic and political strategy that guided them b oth — with some identifiable d ifferences, such as that one was a unitary and the oth er a federal system and the differences in agri cultural policy and organization resulting from the differences in agricultural organization at the time o f the formation o f dom estic political alliances by th eir respective Communist parties (I thank Juhasz Pal for this information on Hungary). T h e Yugoslav economist Branko Horvat approached the issue in the 1960s from the standpoint of the organi /.at ion of authorily in a system designed to elim inate bureaucracy and hierarchy, which he portrayed with a circular chart. 20 According to Kardelj, th e key social question was how national income (sometimes called surplus product) gets distributed. F o r one ol his numerous statem ents ol this point.
sve Problemi naše socijalističke izgradnje 2:133, In the language of social-choice theory, this is the contractual (in contrast to the exploitative) con cep I of the slate, 21 Krajger, “ Dohodak pr.eduzeca u našem sistemu.
174
CHAPTER 5
to pay the guaranteed wage first, after material costs w ere paid. This min imum wage was calculated in term s of the prevailing prices o f a bundle ol basic com m odities (an index that the governm ent adjusted downward w h en stabilization pressure was intense). Laws also required firms to maintain a reserve fund for basic wages and to contribute to a commune solidarity fund on which firms could draw temporarily if they were short o f cash to pay the basic wage. Adjustm ents to the business residts of a firm w ere made within the annual accounting period by varying income rather than jo b s , until a decision to rationalize led to dismissals or transfers. The private sector, as a reserve to collect and re lease labor for the public sector as the latter adjusted, was guaranteed subsistence by government regulations to protect smallholdings and shops against the concentration and differentiation that this sector’s capitalist principles would otherwise effect on landholdings and private capital. T h e key to em p loy m e n t expansion, and therefore to moving persons from the private to the public sector, was rising productivity. Although productivity was defined in its Marxist sense of declining socially neces sary labor time, and although social control over investm ent was intended to expand capacity and productivity, the system of industrial relations assumed that the primary source of growth was rising labor productivity in existing firms, s upp lem ented by local initiative. In his parliamentary address introducing “workers’ co n tro l,’’ Tito spoke of the “particular im portance for the councils o f the working collectives to use their influence to e n su re as rational a distribution of labour as possible, so as not to allow unproductiv e labour to b e c o m e ensconced in their enterprises . . . [and to] p re v e n t the infectious disease known as bureaucracy becoming en d em ic in our co u n try .”25 In a 1951 closed-door session of the Economic Council (which was assigned what little federal concern for employment would remain), Kidric' specified this right to fire as well as hire: “An enter prise can e xe cu te a rationalization in the interests of savings and the goal o f realizing g reater production and, as a co n se q u e n c e of that, can fire surplus lab o r.”21’ T h e party organization (aktiv) in the firm was tasked primarily with leaching workers the “habit of intensification.” If a firm failed to cov er costs and depreciation with receipts, it would have to ac cept the force o f “e c onom ic law” and close shop. Similarly, private arti sanal and farming households would release their “surplus labor” for industrial, public-sector e m ploy m ent when they could not sustain family m e m b e r s with their own production and the free-market earnings that constituted tlu: household “b u d g e t.” Like workers, they would be taught by “e c onom ic c o e rcio n ” to calculate the use of their own labor in indus25 Tito, Sc lee tad Speeches and Articles, 1941-1961, 111 2ii M irjana I’avlovio, “Boris Kidric o principima trzisne ek onornije,” 1188. T h e first law on bankruptcy was introduced in 1954 (Ward, “From Marx to B aro ne,” c h a p , 1)
A REPUBLIC
of producers
175
trial rather than agrarian term s: they would perceive a direct relation between their consumption preferences and th eir contribution to real (and realized) output. Labor’s price (incomes) in the public sector should, it was believed, be a direct measure of its contribution to productivity (in the real sense o f output above what workers consum ed, and in value term s defined by savings 011 the costs o f production), not a measure o f its scarcity and b ar gaining power on an external market. In fact, labor turnover and co m p eti tion among firms for workers only raised costs of production without contributing to increased output. In place o f labor mobility, there would he a contract with a work com m unity for long-term , stable m em b ership; and in place of the market wage, there would b e legislated job classifica tions and wage scales to reward those who remained with the firm (the criterion of seniority), increased their skills (the criterio n of certified qual ifications), or took on managerial responsibility. In accordance with the principle of self-m anagem ent, each firm’s rule book on wages, although based on republic-level legislation on jo b s and wages, had to b e approved by the workers' council; the proportion of profits (also affected by accou nt ing regulations) distributed as wages and social benefits would b e dis cussed by the work collective at the end-of-year accounting; and managers proposals for hiring or fil ing em ployees would be subm itted for approval to the m anag em ent board (and eventually the workers’ council) along with the plan for production and modernization for the following year. The new wage system that passed the assembly in D e c e m b e r 1951 and was in practice by April 1952 formally ended all central determ ination of wage norms and labor quotas (although the system had never applied to more than a handful of federal industries).27 Already in the first round of free decisions by w orkers’ councils in 1 9 5 0 - 5 2 , skilled production workers on the m anag em ent board did not protest firings o f unskilled workers (who “contrib uted less to productivity "), and workers’ councils approved the wage scales developed by eng ineerin g staffs that gave raises to administrative and technical staff and skilled workers and then cut the wages of unskilled w o rk ers.28 T h e resulting wage explosion led authorities to backtrack and assign regulatory authority to local governm ents, includ ing the authority to set a firm’s statutory wage rates (with the “active participation’ of the union organization and the firm’s management). In 2‘ Wage norms re m ained on the statute books until 1955, not as the guaranteed wage and profit share that succeed ed them , but as a minimum wage and proportional (piece) rates for output, ^ Ward, “From Marx* to B a r o n e ,” 1 6 0 - 6 5 , 169. S e e also his discussion in “Industrial Decentralization in Yugoslavia” on the separate treatm ent of administrators, which pro tected them from dismissal.
176
CHAPTEH 5
1955, the last distinctions betw ee n wages, salaries, and profits fell. Wages w ere redefined as income; they w ere no longer considered a cost o( pro duction b ut w ere paid after material costs, and they were composed ot th ree separate ele m e n ts: (1) output norms, differentiated as incentives to productivity; (2) bonuses for contributions above the average (norm), m easured for production workers by increased effort, cost efficiencies, or technical innovations; in services, by budgetary savings; and for manage rial and technical staff, by market profits; and (3) a share in net profits, distributed at the end o f the year after the firm had paid taxes and contri butions to social services and em ploy ee benefits (for example, the housing fund). Basic wage rates w ere set for each industry by the econom ic cham b ers (privredne komore, the association of producers’ branch associa tions), unions, and republican governm ents, and the profit share in individual wages might well be negative— a reduction in income over several months until budgets recovered losses and were again balanced. R esponsibility for preventing un em ploym ent lay with the unions and local governm ents. Managers w ere obliged to consult the union if tliey planned to dismiss m ore than five workers at once, and when a shortage o f cash to pay minim um wages was clearly only temporary, they could draw on the c o m m u n e ’s solidarity fund to prevent unnecessary layoffs and dismissals. B ecau se the problem o f un em ploym ent was viewed in term s o f the pace at which persons from agriculture could get jo bs in industry and in term s o f the redundancies caused by a firm’s rationaliza tion, it was assumed to be primarily a question o f local ju d g m ent and capacity: localities should assist firms in finding new labor and help per sons tem porarily made redundant; and where the pace of aggregate eco nom ic growth was too slow, they should intervene to develop smaller local industries and services that would be both labor-intensive and consu m ption-oriented . T h e regulatory and tax powers granted local gov e rn m e n ts w ere extensive: to license all productive and trade activities of th e private sector; supervise the accounts o f local enterprises and hold managers of public-sector firms legally responsible for these accounts, assuming e m e rg e n c y authority over internal restructuring if necessary to forestall bankruptcy; use revenue from the profits tax on public-sector enterp rises and from the incom e tax on private-sector households to fi nance new enterprises, grant credits and guarantee bank loans for firms wishing to expand, and invest in local housing, roads, sewers, elementary schools, and o th er infrastructural needs; formulate social policy; and even regulate prices and wages if n eed ed to stabilize the local economy. B eca u se the leaders saw frictional unem ploym ent as normal, they re op ened the “labor mediation b ureaus” (employment service) in 1951 to aid dismissed workers in finding new jo b s and to reduce the “long-term disharm ony” b etw ee n the needs o f firms and the supply of labor. Open
A REPUBLIC O F PRODUCERS
177
unemployment was acknowledged, hut as a m atter o f social, not e c o nomic, policy; it was thus assigned to the Council for Public Health and Social Policy and to the province o f social insurance for the “involuntary, temporarily u n e m p lo y e d ,” including health insurance for those registered as looking for work. This attitude was thoroughly consistent with the ov e r all strategy. No charity, sympathy, or welfare for the unem ployed was appropriate, for it would only red uce the resources going to real accu mulation and give monies to people who w ere not contributing to real output. M o reover, as Tito put it in his attack on the system o f guaranteed provisions in January 1949, “budgets create d e p e n d e n c e .”29 Only persons who had b e e n em ploy ed for a m inimum period w ere eligible for u n e m ployment com pensation, since they had contributed to the tax on the wage fund o f e nterprises that financed it; and it was paid only for six months, on the assumption that reem plo y m ent might take that long. But if they had alternative means of support— in practice, it was usually women and youth, whose “families” (employed male heads o f households) were assumed to provide for them , that w ere considered to have such support— they w ere eligible only for health insurance b ecause their sub sistence was not threatened, and they w ere therefore not considered truly unemployed.30 By the same reasoning, public works w ere not considered an appropri ate response to u n em plo y m en t b ecause they w ere not “ec o n o m ic ”— they drained budgets rather than earning their way. Although the volu nteer labor brigades mobilized the unemplo yed in 1945 and 1 9 4 8 - 4 9 , these were seen not as social m easures, to be rein stituted when open u n e m ployment rose in 1952, but as econom ic m easures— a source o f labor for short-term dem ands for capital construction and a way to p rotect the pu b lic sector from resorting to a policy of extensive e m p lo y m e n t— and as an instrument o f cultural revolution for the young. Tito sought an end to the biigades from 19 46 on, first for fear that the deteriorating physical cond i tions o f the camps interfered with this revolutionary objective, and then because the brigades' dem and on supply stores threatened supplies for the army and e xacerbated budgetary deficits and inflation. B eca u se they consumed m o re wage goods than they produced, they had in effect b e
29 TitH- at *he second plenum o f the CP Y central com m ittee, in Petranovic, Končar, and Radonjič, Sednice , 93. 10 When the econom ic assumptions about productivity com bined with the cultural p re ju dices of the period, h o w c v e i, and a rash o f dismissals in 1 9 5 1 - 5 3 fell largely on war invalids, women, and unskilled workers, the governm ent chose to ignore its grant o f autonomy to films. It decreed prohibitions against the dismissal of workers needing “special consid er ation of personal, family, and o th er circum stances” and, as early as April 12, 1952, imposed fines on enterprises that fired women because they were pregnant (Maričk", "N eki problemi organizacije,” 663)
178
CHAPTER 5
co m e institutions o f “welfare” (ironically, given the horrendous decline in youth h ealth).31 Finally, the e m ploy m ent bureaus had to be selfmanaging as well— free to manage as they saw fit the local grants they received , but responsible for balancing th eir budget. This approach to un em plo y m en t gave the e m ploy m ent bureaus32 a dual identity: as the local social-welfare agency, they d eterm ined eligibility for un em p lo y m en t com pensation, health-care rights, and grants for retrain ing and for travel to prospectiv e jo b s ; and as the agent o f society’s interest in rational em p loy m e n t, they w ere to collect and publish data on jobs and to work with local firms and policymakers to improve e m ploy m ent oppor tunities. T h e ir location, however, reflects the system ’s organization around producers. F irm s w ere the b est ju d ge of em ploym ent, and the bureaus, like the state labor offices in 1 9 4 8 - 5 0 , w ere services for firms in their search for labor. T h e y could contract labor for public-sector firms only, and officials re c o m m en d e d locating them at the point of labor de mand, not supply— w h ere industries w ere concentrated and where their “eco n o m ic in te res t” would generate links b etw ee n the bureaus and local authorities in neighboring areas in which e m ploy m ent levels were lower and w h ere “by nature th e re ought to exist surplus la bor.” Exceptions ac com m od ated , instead o f correcting, the developm ental conditions of the period: w h ere th e re w ere no professionals trained to perform its tasks (a p roblem ev e ry w h e re outside of Slovenia and parts o f Serbia), a bureau could not b e established; on the other hand, the very poor state of inter district transportation links in the less-developed republics, especially M aced onia and M o nteneg ro, required the proliferation of bureaus (de spite the administrative costs) to every locality, so that workers were ef fectively assured their rights to u n em ploym en t assistance and so that temporary u n em plo y m en t did not prevent people from continuing to live w h ere they wished. Local approaches to un em plo y m en t varied substantially in these first years. In Croatia and Bosnia, e m ploy m ent bureaus favored the first strat egy: settin g up in an industrial c e n te r or in a locality w here industry was co n c en trated and then creating a network with the bureaus of three or four neighboring districts in which a rural labor surplus prevailed. In Macedonia, district em p loy m e n t b ureaus frequently faced the problem of substantial seasonal unem ploym ent; they sought to resolve it by collective contracts with e nterprises in other republics, sending hundreds of workers to construction jo b s lasting under two months. In Serbia, many 31 Tito, at the third plenum o f th e C P Y central com m ittee, in Petranovic, Koncar, and Badonjic, Sednice, 4 3 3 - 3 4 , 32 In a later stage o f self-m anagem ent, th ese w ere called “comm unities o f interest for em p lo y m en t-”
A REPUBLIC O F PRODUCEHS
179
local bureaus organized conferences with local businesses to obtain “much greater understanding and willingness to coo p e rate ” on the part o f firms, and to “take g reater account o f firms’ real needs for workers and staff with specific skills and qualifications.” In the Serbian town of Niš, the bureau engaged local firms to organize multiservice workshops to employ u n em ployed skilled artisans, and it called meetings o f the unemplo yed to ask them to establish priorities for who should be hired first. A n u m b e r of other districts also invited the unemployed to discuss solutions for their employment. T h e republic-level e m ploy m ent service in Croatia devised a plan with the cooperation of managem ent boards of public enterprises to solve two problem s at once by substituting female labor for male: creating jobs for women and a supply of “essentially technically qualified and physically a b le " men need ed for priority investm ent projects. O therwise, republican g overnm ents were accused of doing little to assist coordina tion; even though som e published regular bulletins o f em ploy m ent data (Serbia, Croatia, and Slovenia), the information was o f little use b ecause it was in com plete, obsolete, or inaccurate.33 The bureaus resources w ere hardly in proportion to th eir mandate, which was to “eliminate the con se q u e n ces o f structural and long-term disharmony.” In addition to the shortage o f trained professionals and us able data, the budgetary constraints o f their self-management status led frequently to choices that further localized activities. Outlays legally r e quired for the costs o f travel and lodging for jo b searches in other lo calities w ere often considered wasteful because the bureaus estim ated the risk that jo b s would not materialize as too high, thus also making the collection of data on jo b openings o f little u s e .3,4 F u rth e rm o r e , u n e m ployed persons hesitated before looking for work away from hom e b e cause of the serious shortage o f housing, without which one could not accept new work at any w age.35 B ecau se new housing construction was a local responsibility, financed by a tax on the wage fund of those currently employed in local public-sector enterprises, this problem also had 110 ready solution. T h e n u m b e r o f technical training schools declined sharply after 1 9 5 0 - 5 1 for the same reason— local governments saw no reason to spend scarce funds 011 training workers who might move elsew here; and even though jo b vacancies remained becau se the specific skills that local firms sought could not b e found in the area, local governments invested 3,1 Maričic, “Neki problem i organizacije.” Ibid ;V5 ln N o v e m b e r 1947, M inister o f Lab or Vicko Krstulovic toki the fifth plenum o f the central co m m ittee of the unions, ’'T he most difficult problem fin the em ploym ent o f new labor] is that o f housing. Until that is resolved, we cannot solve th e labor problem
It is one
of the main reasons for people leaving th eir jo b s, and th e problem o f instability in the labor supply” (“Stalno potiizanje proizvodnosti rada,” 194).
180
CHAPTEli 5
instead in schools for general edu cation.3'’ T h e managerial side o f selfm a n a g e m e n t— the g ov ernm ent o f soeial-serviee institutions by a manage m e n t hoard com posed o f representatives o f “social interests” (the start, local firms, and local administration)— did not appear to overcom e these constraints with cooperation and initiative, as was intended. In Slovenia, the hoards reportedly dealt largely with clerical tasks; the Split (Croatia) authorities re je cte d the idea of a social-management hoard entirely; and most hoards found their time taken up with hearing appeals from persons denied eligibility for un em ploym en t compensation by the bureau.
T h k State T h e eco n o m ic reforms o f 1 9 5 0 - 5 1 did not resolve political disagreements over m ethods of econom ic allocation or political organization— despite the political purge of the inner circle and o f the entire party, which left large nu m bers o f persons languishing in prison on Goli Otok and in cen tral Bosnia and sent many others into perm anent re tirem en t or exile.37 A revised constitution, b ecause of quarrels over it, took more than a year to negotiate through com m ittees and the national assembly. In D ecem ber 1951, Kardelj instructed Mosa Pijade, the ideological e ld er of the prewar party, to prepare this revised constitution on the basis o f Kard elj’s sugges tions and consultations with a com m ittee of legal experts. Intending to bring it to the assem bly in Ju n e (probably for the symbolic echoes with Ju n e 1948 and 1950), Kardelj presented the draft to the politbureau in April 1952. Pijade, substituting for an ill Kardelj, took it to the central c o m m itte e on May 27, w here he was bombarded with criticisms and sug gested am en d m e n ts rather than the veneration and applause one might have expected. E v e n Tito admitted indecision on several matters, includ ing the choice b etw ee n direct and indirect elections, and Pijade was un able to pre sen t a revised draft to the constitutional commission of the national assem bly until N ovem ber. W h ile Tito and Kardelj expressed in creasing exasperation over the character of d ebate in the press (including the party newspaper, Borba ) and the p u blic’s proposals (which “smell of e n em ie s but are prettily masked ), once the path of public discussion Jh Itsidor Izrael, speaking at t lie discussion on th e labor force held at the Bel grade Insti tute of E con om ics in 195-4 (Has, “Drustveno-ekonomski osv rt,” 1 5 7 -5 8 ),
:il Aleksandar Ran ko vie later admitted that fifty-one thousand persons had been caught up in the purge and e ith er killed, imprisoned, or sentenced to hart! labor (Petranovic, Koncar, and Radonjic, Sethii.ee), S e e also Banac’s study o f this group, who were collectively labeled “Com inform isls” (ibeovci ) even though only a certain portion o f th em actually sided with the C o m in form resolution or Stalin (With Stalin against Tito),
A R IÍPU B U C OF PRODUCERS
181
had been taken, it had to b e allowed to run its negotiated course. Closure was reached only by postponing definition of the property sy stem .38 Although obliged by the party statute adopted at the fifth congress in July 1948 to call a m e e tin g again in 1951, Tito did not open the question until the fifth plenum of the central co m m ittee on May 27, 1952— and not for statutory reasons, but because they w ere “com pleting our Five-Y ear Plan and nearing com pletion of the “entirety o f our internal social c o n struction, and particularly the question o f power [vlast]’'; and despite r e peated assurances that it would convene on O cto b e r 19, the sixth congress finally m et on N ov em ber 7 - 9 . Indecision delayed a new party program, although Djilas admitted that the cu rre n t one “obviously . . . no longer fits. 39 W ith the exception of minor “correctio ns” in the program, such as extend ing the period betw ee n party congresses bevond three years, a new one was not adopted until 1957. The sixth party congress did affirm the political defeat of all those who had argued for centralized allocation of scarce professionals, skilled labor, and consum er goods, and it reinforced the tactic o f justifying or co m b a t ing on political grounds— above all, nationalism— what were in fact choices b etw ee n e conom ic models and growth strategies, and the assign ment of rights and powers each entailed. S p e ec h es at the congress gave short shrift to the econ om ic and political reforms and to dom estic policy (despite the continuation in 1 9 5 2 - 5 3 of extraordinary defense e xpend i tures and stabilization austerities required by reorientation to W e stern markets and military and food aid), so as not to distract from its main theme: T ito ’s sermon on their relations with the Soviet Union and the Cominform and the importance of their national independ en ce. W h e r e Hebrang had b ee n tarred with Croat nationalism ,40 Zujovic with tre a son,41 and all dissenters and waverers with “Com inform ist” loyalty to S ta lin rather than Tito, the charge was now Serb nationalism— the penalty iiS Discussion at th e fifth plenum of th e C P Y central com m ittee, in Petnm ovic, Koncar, and Kadonjic, Serinic T h e system o f proportionality in decision milking gave large producers with large ac counts the primary influence over bank policy in any case. As m em bers o f the banks’ govern ing boards, the managers o f large firms w ere often personally (and politically, through party m em b ersh ip or connections) vulnerable to political pressure from a republic’s leadership to take decisions said to b e necessary to protect the republic’s econom y, rather than decide on the basis of banking criteria alone; see the 1982 Start interview with Toinislav Badovinac, th e tem porary m anager appointed to restructure the E co n o m ic Bank o f Zagreb (Frivreclna Banka Zagreba) after the affair that nearly bankrupted this primary bank o f Croatia. In analyzing th e bank's liquidity crisis, Badovinac (and others) focused
011
the lack o f indepen
d e n c e in banking and on the effect o f federal price and trade regulation of the strategic oil industry (84 p ercen t o f the bank’s $ 1 1 billion foreign d ebt was due to the losses of the prim ary oil producer in Croatia, INA, and the primary electricity produce,!*, Eleclroprivreda). O 11 th e o th er hand, little attention was paid to the trouble that Citibank decided to cause for the E co n o m ic Bank when it was tw enty-four hours late on repaym ent of out standing loans on M arch 3, 1982,
T H E F AUS TI AN BARGAIN
231
teract them with Keynesian-like new credit to increase e m ploy m ent because the transactions being monetized had already occurred. Instead of counteracting global m ovem ents, policy exacerbated th eir effect. It b e came restrictive when global dem and fell, tightened further until e n t e r prise d eb t forced m onetary expansion, and was truly expansive only when new foreign m oney was available. T h e first c o n s e q u e n ce o f expansion b e ing a surge in imports, however, the resulting trade deficit would start the cycle a n e w .16 T h e analysis by Gapinski, Skegro, and Z uehlke found that unem ployment grew when the money supply expanded because expan sion created a trade deficit. Increases in nominal g ov ernm ent expend i tures lowered un em p lo y m en t in a “Keynesian-like . . . big, real e ffe c t,” but generated a new round of u n em plo y m en t and foreign d eb t b ecause of the effect on the foreign s e c t o r .17 Fiscal policy could not b e intentionally expansionary in support o f e m ployment becau se its purpose was to supp lem ent monetary policy in maintaining balanced budgets and b ecause deficit financing through do mestic instrum ents was not institutionally possible. As an accounting mechanism, taxation increased when revenues d e c l i n e d .Ifi B ecau se stabi lization policy c o m b in ed dem and repression with trade liberalization and supply-side tax cuts 011 firms, its effect was to re duce dramatically federal revenue— customs duties, the turnover tax (later the sales tax), and grants from the re p u b lics ’ taxes on enterprises. Cuts, not increases, in public expenditures had to follow. To cover essential expenditures (particularly for defense, which was the largest item o f the minimalist federal budget) that could not b e cut, the federal g overnm ent had to search for other sources o f re venue. It had th ree self-defeating choices: to dem and more from republican budgets, reducing monies for developm ental investm ent and em p loy m e n t expansion in the republics; to borrow more monies abroad, only creating the n eed down the road for renew ed stabilization policy; or to print m oney, thus also reviving the impulse for antiinflationary policy. T h e federal gov ernm ent did have means to spend ou t side the b ud get that could expand e m ploy m ent, and it was constitu tionally obliged to do so for purposes o f national security and basic infrastructure. B u t w h ere these monies did not com e from republican lfi S e e D y k er, Yugoslavia: Socialism, Development, and Debt; Horvat, The Yugoslav Economic System; and Bajt, “Lessons from the Labor-M an agem en t Laboratory.” Horvat cites a 1973 study by Marko K ra n jec that shows that fiscal policy after 1965 exacerbated cyclical activity 6 6 to 9 9 p erce n t (251) 17 Gapinski, Skegro, and Z uehlke, Modeling, 2 1 1 - 1 2 . 18 W ith out a bond m arket, the govern m en t could not use fiscal policy to counteract the effects o f th e m arket, foreign or dom estic. Not only could the governm ent not borrow from the population, it actually was th e len d er to the population, through intergovernm ental transfers (from republics and provinces to the federation and from the federal go v ern m en t— through cred its— back to producers and lower-level governments).
232
CHAPTER 7
contributio ns in a direct trade-off with republican investm ent and e m ploy m ent promotion, they w ere largely foreign credits (above all, World B ank d ev elop m en t loans for infrastructure). T h e cycle shows up in the Gapinski, Skegro, and Zuehlke analysis: a period of foreign borrowing was always followed by a period of dom estic taxation, and the availability of foreign cred it d eterm in e d the current marginal tax rate on enterprise in co m e (“profits”) . 19 T h e conflict b e tw ee n the monetary instruments designed for a closed, socialist, and industrializing econom y and the dem ands of international op enness b e co m es particularly clear when one considers the burd en that e xchange-rate policy should have b orne in international adjustment. The questio n o f its role also introduces a more fundamental problem: whether the g o v e r n m e n t’s policies w ere appropriate to the conditions it faced. A constant feature of m acroeconom ic stabilization policy and the “stop” side o f the stop-and-go cycle of international adju stm ent was devaluation of the dinar. In the language o f Kiro Gligorov’s explanation of the 1952 de valuation, it was an instrum ent of “econom ic coercion to force producers to increase supply.30 T h e failure of devaluation as a way to resolve trade deficits and o f exchange-rate policy in the 1970s, when the dinar was allowed to float but b e c a m e overvalued, was attributed to a mercantilist pro tection of d om estic manufacturers. Such protection could b e seen to originate in the lead ers’ early strategy for industrialization and then to be perpetuated over time, in manufacturers’ economic power and the favorit ism shown to exporters because of persistent trade deficits. But the prob lem of devaluation and, later, o f a m arket-clearing exchange rate as instru m ents to manage foreign trade had far more to do with Yugoslavia’s partic ular niche in the international economy.'21 T h e cou n try ’s primary problem was not fluctuating dem and for its ex ports in which price m attered most, but supply shocks— in the price of credit, the prices of imports necessary to production (raw materials, fuels, equipment, and spare parts), and the political barriers imposed unpredictably against Yugoslavia’s exports, regardless of price. Its primary export markets, m oreover, operated not on com petitive dem and principles but on bilateral contracts in the East, the South, and even the W e st (financed by suppliers credits or, by the 1970s, on countertrade terms). The impoit d e p e n d e n c e o f most production for export to W e ste rn markets not only made exchang e-rate policy largely ineffective where it might have oper ated, b u t also m eant that devaluation always fueled inflationary pressures at hom e. B ecau s e Yugoslavia was a small country in the global economy, 19 G a p i n s k i , Skegro, a n d Z u e h l k e , M o d e lin g , 97, 2 ) 5 - 1 6 . 20 K. Gligorov, “Factors in O ur E con om ic Stabilization, 21 On the reasons that devaluation and exchange-rate policy w ere ineffective and inap propriate instru m ents, see especially D yker, Yugoslavia, 9 7 - 1 0 1 .
T H E FAUS TI AN ISAUGAIN
233
with no control over the price of imports or terms ol trade, producers could increase revenues only by increasing supply. But this ran up against the supply b ottlen ecks caused by import restrictions. T h e primary way producers adju sted to the shift in price structures due to devaluation was thus not to expand exports but to cut production or shift temporarily to domestic suppliers where“ possible. As was the case with monetary policy, the segmentation ol markets, accounting character of financial institu tions, and pervasive use of supply networks among firms or vertical in te gration made reliance on price mechanisms for adju stm ent less than effective.22 Instead, the conjunction of the lead ers’ guided Ricardian strategy with foreign cre d ito rs ’ insistence on foreign-trade liberalization and 011 the benefits o f foreign com petition had the effect (without any need tor politi cal pressure 011 the part o f firms) o f transforming exehange-rate policy into an instillm ent of industrial policy. An overvalued dinar favored manufac turers with cheap im ported supplies so that they could be more c o m p eti tive in foreign markets, ju s t as dom estic price policy favored them with regulated raw-material prices. Price liberalization exposed dom estic pro ducers of production inputs (such as farmers) to foreign com petition, forc ing them to produce at lower cost (or go out of business).23 T h e aim ol foreign-trade protection, however, was primarily to safeguard national security concerns (such as the food and energy policy and sectors such as shipbuilding, iron and steel, and machine building— all of which were also export producers, though more often for markets in the East and .South than for hard-curreney W e stern ones). The. aim of liberalization was to force down prices of raw materials at home. As lor em p loy m e n t, the effect of repeated devaluation of the currency was instead to feed the inflationary spiral o f domestic prices; in raising the nonlabor costs o f production, particularly where supply bottlenecks made an im m ediate supply response difficult, it required firms to adjust by low ering labor costs— that is, by cutting (or not expanding) e m ploym ent. The leadership was not oblivious to the ineffectiveness of its instru ments to re duce the balance-of-payments deficit and restore growth, but its interpretation o f the problem (often aided by I M F advisers) was that "financial discipline was missing and that the econom ic incentives had 22
C o m m a n d e r , in "In fl at io n a n d t h e T r a n s it io n to a M a r k e t E c o n o m y ,
a n a l y z e s tile
inflationary c o n s e q u e n c e ol sta bi liz at io n policv from t h e spec ial p e r s p e c t i v e ol socialist e c o n omics in t r a n s it io n to m a r k e t e c o n o m i e s in t h e e ar ly I9i)0s, w h e r e in st it u ti o n a l p a r t i c ularities (su ch as a s e g m e n t e d financial s y st e m ) a n d th e b u r d e n s lelt Irom th e p r e v i o u s r e g im e (s u c h as a st ock ol i u t e i e n t e r p r i s e d e b t ) m u s t he ta k e n int o a c c o u n t in a p p l y i n g s u c h po lic y . 21 A u t h o i s d is c u s s io n s w ith Ži vk o P r eg l a n d I ' e r d n a n d T r o st in Lj u bl ja na . 19S2, a n d w ith Božo M a r e n d i c a n d Borislav Š k e g r o in Z a g r e b near ly a lw ay s o v e r v a l u e d e x c h a n g e ra te
M ost e c o n o m i s t s cr it ic iz e d t h e c o u n t r y s
234
CHAPTER 7
b e c o m e distorted. To restore both discipline and the effectiveness of pro duction incentiv es, the g overnm ent would initiate another round of de centralizing institutional reforms, extend the realm of “self-management” to include m o re activities in the regim e o f econom ic accounting and fiscal responsibility, and attem pt to reassert the role o f enterprises in keeping wages and expend itures within the constraints of actual earnings, against contrary d ev elopm en ts in the interim since the last reforms. F o r exam ple, in place of cuttin g g ov ernm ent expenditures whole categories of ex penditures would b e rem oved from the federal budget and handed to budgetary authorities closer to producers or to independent agencies with autonomous, self-managed funds (as in the case of social services). By 1975, public expenditures and tax authority w ere shared by more than eight thousand parastatal “self-managing com m unities of interest."24 E v e n the federal fund for less-developed areas— the sole remaining di rect role o f the central g overnm ent in econom ic d ev elopm en t— was re stru ctured in the late 1970s to improve financial discipline over the use of th e monies by giving republics more control over their contributions. R epublics could b e absolved from up to half o f their tax obligation to the fund if th e ir firms invested directly in firms in the southern republics and provinces targeted by the fund (bypassing federal, republican, and pro vincial authorities). In the 1980s, authorities replaced the fund’s manag ing board with re presentatives elected from enterprises instead of republican governm ents. In other words, the response to ineffective pol icy was to decentralize and to reduce further the scope of governmental
policy. An unusually difficult problem was to settle on a system for allocating foreign exchange that would allow it to reach those most in need of West ern imports (and that would resolve bitter political fights over access) while not worsening the deficit. T h e primary principle that enterprises w ere most likely to b e financially responsible gave to firms that earned foreign exchange the right to retain a certain (and growing) percentage as an export incentiv e. B u t this left many dom estic producers of raw and inte rm e d iate materials, who nonetheless could not produce without im ports or could do so m ore profitably with che a p e r foreign supplies, with out access to foreign exchange or in the position o f having to bargain for it in p ro d u ce rs’ associations. Bankruptcy was no solution (regardless of the c o n s e q u e n c e s for unem ploym ent) b ecause such firms often supplied goods essential to export producers as well as those serving the domestic m a rk e t.25 Proposals to lower re tention quotas and give more control to 24 “Fiscal System and Fiscal Policy,” 27-28. 25 The primary demand o f the student demonstrators during the events o f 1970-71 in Croatia was an increase for Croat firms in the retention quota for foreign exchange; although
T H E F AUS TI AN BARGAIN
235
the National Bank succu m bed to the politics of econom ic power within the system, d efeated by the obje ctions of powerful export producers and the republics (especially Slovenia and Croatia) into which the largest share of hard cu rre n cy flowed. The g overnm ent s response was to give firms and territorial banks greater freedom to borrow abroad, so as to increase the supply o f foreign currency while getting it into the hands of those best able to guarantee repayment as ju d g ed by the foreign lender. Yet, as a co n se q u e n ce o f in ternational changes after the early 1970s in its regim e toward foreign b o r rowing, the federal g o v ernm ent had to guarantee most of this d eb t and therefore repay a m ounting foreign d eb t that it had had 110 part in borrow ing. Hy 1976, the g o v ernm ent had divided the balance of payments into separate republican accounts in order to hold each re public directly re sponsible for repaym ent. Republic-level “self-managing com m unities of interest for foreign econ om ic relations ’ were established to give pro ducers’ organizations g re ate r control over export policy and foreignexchange allocation, on the basis of a fund created with half o f the federal customs r e v e n u e s .26 In contrast to the pressures toward concentratio n and financial ce n tra l ization found in open market econom ies, the Yugoslav governm ent sought further decentralization, deconcentration, and producer control. The reasons for this choice multiplied with time. In making enterprises responsible for stabilization, the leadership remained com m itted to its the political leadership was rem oved, th e demand was granted. On the difficulties that domestic producers selling on the dom estic m arket had in obtaining foreign exchange to pay for imports o f essential inputs, and th e resulting b ottlenecks for o th er producers— including those earning foreign exchange through exports— see, for exam ple, the article in Bo rim (June 26. 1982) on the ru b b e r and chem ical industry “Balkan” in Suva Reka, Kosovo; and Skrbic. “M anjak— cetiri m ilijard e,' on the steel industry and iron metallurgy complex at Zenica, Bos nia-H erzegovina. A 1982 article in Ekonomska Politika (“P rerada m e tala: St rah od ijiei/.vesnostT) discusses th e pressure from the m etal-processing industry— complaining of rising uncertainty o ver supplies from the dom estic steel industry because of foreignexchange shortages—-to give steel the same priority status as oil in access to foreign ex change. This pressure led th e federal “self-managing com m unity of interest for foreign eco nomic relations” to propose that $ 8 0 million be set aside for steel mills; the National Hank opposed this move unless the resulting export production was sold to coiivertible-currency countries. In 1 9 7 7 -7 8 , banks w e re p erm itted to issue securities. T h e Agrokom erc scandal o f 1987 can be traced to this regulation; the Bosnian conglom erate issued bonds far in excess of its cover, which w ere purchased in large amounts by banks throughout the country— above all Ljubljana Ban k— apparently on the assumption that the im portant political connections of the Agrokomerc d irec to r and the political assurances of the Bosnian political elite were ¿sufficient guarantee. M ajo r W estern com m ercial banks made a similar mistake in lending to Eastern E u ro p e on th e assumption that the Soviet um brella was sufficient guarantee of repayment.
236
CHAPTER 7
strategy ol dismantling the state and com bining political right with eco nom ic interest. T h e I M F campaigned for decentralization and reduced governmental interferen ce in the economy, ostensibly because these would encourage market forces. T h e interests of profitable producers and w ealthier republics in gaining greater autonomy over their resources (above all, foreign exchange) w ere even stronger alter periods of restric tions and recession. And the further decentralization proceeded, the more the political representativ es of the republics and enterprises saw a vested interest in keeping rights over assets, reducing fu rther the compe te n ce and finances o f the federation, and opposing any proposal lor re centralization, even if it meant a more effective policy. Nonetheless, th ese reforms did continue to reduce the federal government's capacity for m onetary control and macroeconom ic management, and therefore for producing the noninflationary growth necessary to prevent industrial un em ploym ent. Alongside the recessionary bias of m acroeconom ic policy, therefore, there was a decline in the federal role in preventing unem plo yment ol the dev elopm en tal kind by seeing to the developmental investm ent and sec toral proportions necessary to absorb the agricultural surplus and demo graphic increase; and this role was in any case also subordinated to foreign policy. T h e first stage of decentralizing reforms after 1952 was the transfer (by 1958) of federal seetoral-investm ent funds and responsibility for de velopm ental investm ent to territorial banks and planning offices in the republics. By 1971, federal authorities had lost all control over credit pol icy .27 As the vacuum in federal investm ent funds was filled by foreign monies, influence on the policies (if not always the consequences) of de velopm ental investm ent cam e increasingly from multilateral and public le n d e rs — above all the W orld B ank— as one can see clearly in the Green Plan for agriculture, which was initiated in 1973, and the priorities of the social plan for 1 9 7 6 - 8 0 . 2K From the early years, however, priority sectors of the social plans w ere defined by the priority placed on reducing the balance-of-paym ents deficit and guarding national security (with actual investm ent prefe re n ce s depending on particular international condi tions). In place of planners’ calculations of investm ent to protect the sec toral balance of dom estic production and maintain steady growth, the 27 D yker, Yugoslavia, 120, 147. 28 On the G r e e n Plan o f 1973, by which the W orld Bank made available 1 billion dinars for in v estm ent credits in agriculture— channeled through contracts with the social sector but available only for approved developm ent projects in the private sector— see Miller, Socialism and Agriculture in Yugoslavia,” 38 n. 64; and D yker, Yugoslavia, 155-56* On the notable similarity b etw een the Yugoslav social plan o f 1976—8 0 and the World Bank pro posals for structural adjustm ent, see the discussion in the W orld Bank’s Yugoslavia: Adjust
ment Policies and Development Perspective#
T H E F AUSTI AN BARGAIN
237
federal plan emphasized a com bination of export promotion and importsubstituting investm ents, whim national security and the external terms ot trade for m anufacturers’ key production supplies favored dom estic pro duction. E m p lo y m e n t rem ained a residual of the plans— but, as we will see in the next chapter, the preferred means for international adjustment directly affected the use of labor in the same way that they had in the first decade o f power.
Po l it ic a l C o n f l ic t a n d
P o l ic y C iio ic k
The influence o f international openness and ad ju stm ent did not only un dermine the governmental capacity to im plem ent the lead ers’ strategy for economic growth and full em ploym ent; it was equally important in its effect on the lines of political conflict over policy. Critics of Yugoslavia’s failure to adopt successful policies of international adju stm ent and to re verse the m ounting foreign debt, persistent trade deficits, and d e p e n dence on borrowing, refinancing, and the I M F and foreign banks tend to focus on elite conflict. Some argue that the problem lay in the lack of consensus (surely exac erbated by— though not originating in— a voting system at the federal level that re qu ired consensus and gave each republic a veto). D is ag re e ments caused prolonged delays in formulating policy and diffident im ple mentation. Y et countries renowned at the time for their success at international ad ju stm ent, such as Japan and S w eden, also w ere known for prolonged gestation periods for formulating policy and reaching co n sensus. T h e weakness ot e n fo rcem en t mechanisms discussed in the p re vious section was due not to elite conflict but to the strategy on which the leaders agreed. Others argue that political leaders were divided b etw een econom ic re formers and conservative antireformers, and that the failure o f econom ic policy was due to the success of conservative forces in preventing lull promulgation o f liberal market reforms. This obstruction, it is said, grew' largely out o f conservatives reaction to the unem ploym ent threat from “efficiency-oriented” reforms. According to this argument, econom ic pol icy in the postwar period had two major turning points: the marketizing economic Reform o f 1965 (it is always capitalized, to distinguish it from other reforms) and the constitution o f 1974 legislating its reversal at the hands of party conservatives. Yet, as with the great divide attributed to 1948 and the Tito-Stalin conflict, as well as with the “end o f the adminis trative s y s tem ’ in 1952, a closer examination of econom ic policy reveals a different chronology than is suggested by political rhetoric. As with 1946 52, the conflict is b e tte r portrayed as one b etw een opposing econom ic institutions and policies intended to facilitate microeconom ic adjustments
238
CHAPTER 7
to a change in international conditions— the tension identified in chapters 2 and 4 b e tw e e n the Slovene and F oca models— than as one between liberal reformers and conservative reactionaries. T h e difficulty was that the existence of elite political conflict did not bring forth policy alternatives to counteract the effect o f openness on the eco n o m ic strategy chosen in the early period. In contrast to the historical origins o f pro em plo y m ent policy in the W est, no political group organized to challenge the c e n t e r ’s growth policy on the grounds that it caused u n em p lo y m en t— not even when this policy of macroeconom ic stabiliza tion, w o rk place-centered measures of productivity, and antigovernment (decentralizing and “socializing”) reforms failed to achieve its explicit ob je c ti v e o f restoring noninflationary growth and reducing trade deficits. Instead, elite conflict focused primarily on the distributive conse q u e n c e s of such stabilization policy: contributions to the federal budget and to the federal dev elopm en t fund, the nature of expenditure cuts, and the regim e for allocating foreign exchange. M ore significant than elites’ disa g re e m en t was their com m on solution to such conflicts over money. By increasing the pie through m ore foreign credits or federal seigniorage and by com pensating for cuts with greater autonomy over the use of funds, they only increased the difficulties in controlling the money sup ply, fed inflation, and added to the financial segmentation that resulted from autonomous, self-managed budgets. T h e vicious circle of such econom ic policy and conflict over distribution was intensified by the political outcomes. T h e more unsuccessful interna tional ad ju stm ent was, the more openness and flexibility among foreign markets w ere valued. T h e more the criteria o f international participation dominated federal policy choices, the less room there was for genuine policy d eb ate among dom estic actors and the less effective becam e the political institutions necessary to successful international adjustment. The more unsuccessful that adju stment was, the m ore important federal pol icy was to the econom ic fate o f republics and localities, and the less eco nom ic authority it retained. W h e re as P e te r Katzenstein argues that Austria’s and Sw itzerland’s success “continuously relegitim ize[s]” the po litical institutions necessary to national policy and strengthens the “com patibility of views” b etw ee n the bargaining parties that precedes such co o p e ratio n ,29 one can see the mirror image in the Yugoslav case. Failure continuously dclegitimized federal institutions and weakened consensus and cooperation. In contrast to the view that there were sharp policy divides in 1965 and 1974, the findings o f the literature on social demo cratic regim es fit Yugoslavia as well: the institutions of political and eco nom ic pow er adopted by 1952 limited later choices. 23 KalzensU'in, Corporatism and Change, 29
T H R FAUS TI AN BARGAIN
239
Thus, although liberals accused conservatives of obstructing market r e forms, they w ere unwilling to abandon the rights of republics and e n te r prises to control econ om ic assets (rights that increased with each stage o f (reform, including stages called reactionary) in favor of market-oriented policy on the grounds that this was recentralization; nor would they r e nounce the policies favoring final-commodity producers (called “profit able” firms) and export production in favor of a real market economy. Although they promoted “westernization” and accused conservatives of an eastward inclination, the econom ic power of most liberals lay in their access to all th ree trading spheres. E ven if full m e m b ersh ip in W estern organizations had b ee n within the country’s reach (through the E uropean Community and N A TO or the neutral states’ E uropean F r e e Trade Asso ciation), the most successful manufacturers w ere those producing for both civilian and military needs30 and able to arbitrage their participation in all three foreign markets when international conditions changed. Unwilling to recognize the co n se q u e n ces o f th eir preferred reforms for domestic producers o f raw and interm ediate goods and for areas lacking a welldeveloped com m ercial infrastructure or geostrategic advantage in foreign markets, and able to obstruct market allocation of foreign exchange and impose territorial restrictions on the m ovem ent o f labor and capital, most liberals contrib uted both to the political necessity of Kaldorian com p en sa tions to the less profitable firms and areas (compensations that they often condemned) and to the ineffectiveness of central policy.31 While it is true that conservatives had no love for marketizing, w estern izing econom ic reform because it resulted in un em ploym ent in 1 9 5 0 - 5 2 and the 1960s and also in econom ic inequality, their influence on e c o nomic policy was secondary once the decisions on the form o f the state had b een made. And although the decisions o f 1965 w ere politically sig nificant, not for e conom ic reform but for security policy, only a minority among the conservatives would have preferred jo ining the Warsaw Pact and the Council for Mutual E co n o m ic Assistance (C M E A ) as full m em 30 Such m anufacturers w ere identifiable by th eir m em bership in the association o f firms producing on military contract created in the 1980s, the Com m unity for Arm am ents and Military E q u ip m e n t o f Yugoslavia (Z IN V O J). 31 In the (Nicholas) Kaldor version o f the compensation principle in welfare economics, “gainers com p ensate losers”: there is compensation “o f potential losers by gainers, so as to leave the form er with al least the same real incom e as they had enjoyed under the original distribution oi incom e before the change- T h e second version is the (Tibor) Seitovsky prin ciple oi “losers bribing gainers”: “T h e payment ol a compensation or b rib e by those likely to he damaged by a change to the gainers from it: a paym ent adequate to dissuade the latter from advocating the change and still leave the potential losers b e tte r off than they were destined to be i f the change w ere to b e made,” (D o b b , W elfare Economics and the Eco
nomics o f Socialism, 8 4 - 8 5 ) , D o b b also discusses the possible contradictions in both ver sions, as well as in the proposal by Seitovsky to jo in the two (8 6 - 1 1 8 )
240
C II AI ’TKR 7
hers. Conservatives w ere in conflict with liberals primarily over invest m ent p r e fe re n c e s — favoring dom estic producers o f fuels, grains, and capital goods— but not over the country’s international position. They w ere unwilling to challenge the Faustian bargain o f “national com mu nism ” that traded in d e p e n d en ce o f Moscow for a special role in world diplomacy and access to W e s te rn finance. F o r most conservatives and liberals, the risks of abandoning this international comparative advantage w ere too great. Y et the policy consensus on a macrosystem s approach to international ad ju stm ent to which scholars attrib ute much o f the success with full e m ploym ent, from Austria to S w e d e n ,32 surely had its source in the choice in the im m ediate postwar period to orient those countries to ward the U .S .-o rg an ize d trading and security regim es while retaining suf ficient in d e p e n d en ce for that macroeconom ic policy. Contrary to the findings o f the literature on econom ic policies of labororiented g ov ernm ents, th en, the initiative for Yugoslav policy came not from dom estic pressures but from international developm ents. Because those events w ere largely unpredictable, felt mainly through a crisis in foreign accounts or a threat to national security, they tended to preempt system atic organization of dom estic political pressure as well. T h e federal gov ern m e n t a ttem pted to re present the interests of labor— in Kardelj’s redefinition, income recip ients in socialist com munities o f work— but its bargaining was with international capital, not domestic organizations of capital. T o prevent un em p lo y m en t— which was defined as being left without means o f su b siste n ce — the governm ent adjusted regulations in the m icroe con om ic sphere to increase labor’s productivity and to rational ize e m p lo y m e n t in accordance with international conditions. (The conse q u e n ce s of these adju stments for unem plo yment are the subject of ch a p ter 8.) T h e data on u n em plo ym en t discussed in chapter 6 reveal the path of central eco n o m ic policy m ore clearly than does the political rhetoric of dom estic party factions and independ en t econom ists. Policy cycles can be identified roughly each decade, as changes in national security, foreign trade, and the supply of foreign capital led to domestic policy shifts. The transitional period continued after 1950 until 1957; the next period was 1958 to 1967, then 1968 to 1978, and finally 1979 to 1989. I f there were defining m om ents, such as 1965 and 1974 were said to be, they were rather 1961, when the proportion of the labor force employed was at its maximum and after which increm ental capital-outputs ratios continued to ris e,33 and 1971, after which the already-rising rate of unem ployment es calated sharply and un em ploym ent was clearly structural. 12
S e e especially
Leh m b ru ch , “L iberal Corporatism and Party G overnm ent ’; and
Scharpf, “E co n o m ic and Institutional Constraints o f Full-K mploy men t Strategies,” ™ Pavle Sich erl, personal com m unication, Ljubljana, O c to b er 1981, based on un-
TI1F, F AUSTI AN BARGAI N
241
1953-1957 Policy in this first postwar period was governed by the availability o f for eign credits (particularly U .S . food and military aid) and the gradual re duction of regional security tensions. T h e y made it possible for the leadership to shift away from the investments of military self-reliance, to proceed with demobilization and cut the defense budget, to increase in vestments in c o n su m e r goods and light manufactures for the urban and industrial population and for export, and to increase trade relations su b stantially. T h e end of the Korean W ar ameliorated international shortages and price inflation o f d efense-related raw materials, and the cou ntry ’s terms of trade began to improve. T h e death of Stalin in 1953 revived dehates throughout the E astern bloc on “ncw -cou rse” policies like the ones the Yugoslavs had begun several years earlier. Regional peace seemed secured in 1954 with the end o f the Allied occupation in G e r many, the resolution of the T ries te crisis (which was largely responsible for delaying demobilization of the Partisan army), and the neutralization of the Tru m an D o ctrin e in the Balkans, marked by the Balkan Pact b e tween Yugoslavia, G r e e c e , and Turkey. In 1955 the peace treaty was signed in Austria, and Yugoslav m e m b ership in the Organization for E c o nomic Cooperation op ened the possibility o f b e tte r trade relations with Western E u ro p e and rem oved barriers to emigration. T h e g overnm ent agreed to issue passports upon demand, making open borders a reality for citizens. T h e founding con feren ce of the nonalignment m o ve m e n t the same year brought favorable agreem ents for oil and strategic materials from developing-country allies.34 R appro chem en t with the new Soviet leadership o f G eorgy Malenkov and Nikita Khrushchev brought an end to the Eastern blockade; trade ag reem ents with the Soviet Union for import of heavy weaponry, other military equ ipm ent, and a nuclear reactor; and, in f9 56, ob serve r status in the C M E A . These international conditions made possible a continuation o f the pol published studies done on contract in possession of the author. D yker sum m arizes a num ber of studies over th e postwar period (Yugoslavia, 46, 104, 140). The m ove to petroleum fuels occurred in Japan and the U S S K as well; but in Yugoslavia the switch caused a m ajor d eb ate am ong technocrats in 1955—5 8 because th ere were substantial dom estic sources o f en ergy (coal and especially hydroelectric power, for which Yugoslavia’s technical innovations w ere internationally respected) and because o f the costs of user conversion and external dependency. T h e d eb ate began with an en g in eer at Elektroprivreda and continu ed with a 1963 study tor the federal E co n o m ic C h am b er (Pri vredna Komora) on capacity use (see the report on the en gin eerin g study in Ekonomski
Pregled, nos. 3 - 5 [1968]). M any accused the main oil company, IN A (Zagreb), o f making profits by im porting m ore crude oil than was needed dom estically and stim ulating demand by getting people to switch. T h e d ebt problem s o f the 1970s and th e persistent political problems with coal m iners, especially in 1968—70, w ere unforeseen.
242
CHAPTER 7
icy toward labor outlinc'd in the program o f the sixth party congress in N o v e m b e r 1952. Able to reduce the defense b u d get’s drain on the econ omy from its high o f 22 p e rce n t of G N P in 1952 down to 8 . 5 percent in 1957, the g ov ernm ent oversaw a boom period from 1954 to 1957 based on foreign credits that enabled the cheap import of grains, other foods, and raw materials from the W e st (52 .2 p e rce n t of the deficit on current ac cou nt up to 1955 was cov ered by grants and only 16.2 pe rce n t by loans).35 Thus “the n u m b e r o f workmen [could] b e reduced in agriculture with mechanization o f state and cooperative farms to improve yields, fn the rest o f agriculture, credits, tax relief, and governm ent regulations aimed to encou rage intensive cropping and the d evelopm ent of small industries to process agricultural goods “in which part of the relieved labor could be engaged. ”:3fi This policy also made possible the idea of a settled citizen soldiery for the territorial defense forces, essential to demobilization of the standing army. In M a r c h - M a y 1953, a second agrarian reform legal ized th e end o f the peasant labor cooperatives and also limited private landholdings to ten hectares (over Bakarić s objections), transferring land above that amount to remaining cooperatives to com pensate them for land withdrawn by peasants retu rnin g to private ownership. As the ave nue to socialization through market control, the general farmers’ coopera tives in the villages w ere given a monopoly over the purchase of private farm ers’ produce and their access to fertilizers, machinery, and improved s e e d s .37 Although the key projects o f the five-year plan of 1 9 4 7 - 5 1 were not com p leted until 1956, in 1953 the leadership confirmed the shift in investm ent policy to light manufacturing and consum er goods and to what Kardelj called a “p re fe re n c e ” for agriculture. T h e adoption ol this policy by th e party’s executiv e co m m ittee in 1954 was accompanied by the trans fer o f in vestm ent planning to independ en t funds at each level o f govern m e n t (the federal fund was called the General Investm ent Fund, or GIF). N onetheless, unsettled international conditions required the policy’s reaffirmation at a high-level m eeting ol party leaders (.savjetovanje kod druga Tita, or con feren ce with T ito — the informal gathering of close ad visers used for the decisions of D e c e m b e r 1948) on S e p te m b e r 25, 1955, 35
M acesich, “M ajor T ren ds in the Postwar Kconomy o f Yugoslavia.” “W h eal imports rose
to an annual average o f 700*00 0 tons in 1952—54 as against only 1 00 ,0 0 0 tons in 1948 -5 1 . , [and] in 1 9 5 5 - 5 8 , . . [to] the very high rate o f over a million tons per annum ” (YVamner,
Revolution in Eastern Europe , 71). An agreem en t in January 195(i (or American wheat, cotton, and lard was the largest Public Law 4 8 0 program for any country to that date, 3fi Kardelj, in his address to the sixth congress o f the LC Y in 1952. 37 T om asevich, “Collectivization o f Agriculture in Yugoslavia”; Rusinow, review of Die
Kooperation zwischen den privaten Landwirt.schaftshetrieben und den gesellschaftlichen Wi-rtschaftso rga n isa t ione n , by Ivan Lon carević; “Poljoprivredna stanovništvo,” in Privreda ENRJ u periodu 1947-1956; Savez Komunista Jugoslavije, Borba Komunista Jugoslavije za socijalističku demokratiju; W arriner, Revolution in Eastern Europe,
T H E F AUS TI AN BARGAIN
243
followed in O c to b e r by a formal consultation with econom ic experts. T h e next year, the lead e rs ’ assumptions about the international political co n juncture of regional security and peaceful coexistence w ere again in te r rupted. T h e formation o f N A TO in 1948 and the Warsaw Pact in May 1955 had already revived internal party disputes over international align ments that the nonalignm ent m o ve m e n t had not fully dispelled. T h e lib erals pressure in favor o f the territorial defense forces in the republics, which would allow the standing army to b e cut, and in favor o f republican authority over manufacturing and investm ent was undercut by the global debate on nuclear warfare and d eterren ce , which gave renew ed life to the YPA and to the institutes and personnel engaged in the dom estic atomieenergy pro g ram .38 T h e prospect that American military aid would end in 1957,39 the growing hostility o f the U .S . Congress at Yugoslavia’s rap prochement with the U S S R and the organization of the nonalignment movement, and then the Suez crisis— which endangered both oil sup plies and the principle o f nonalignm ent— s eem ed to bring a renewal of the threats o f war and isolation o f the late 1940s. Unrest in Poland, the occupation o f Hungary in O c to b e r 1956, and Soviet cancellation once again of new trade ag reem ents and credits the next F e b ru a ry 40 forced a delay in the second five-year plan (intended for 1 9 5 7 - 6 1 ) , and the lea d e r ship re verted to some e le m e n ts of forced self-reliance and defense p re paredness. This included the reinstitution, betw een 1956 and 1958, o f the volunteer youth brigades that had b ee n disbanded “fo rever" only three years before. T h e r e was a renew ed effort in the spring o f 1957 at the “socialist transformatio n” of agriculture, called a “break-through on a nar row front” in the party platform written at the end of the y e a r.41 C om m on or uncultivated lands w ere taken into the public sector (a form o f “e n clo sures”).42 F a r m e r s ’ cooperatives received exclusive control over new in18 Until 19 61 — the high point o f investm ent in nuclear en ergy— this program received 60 percent o f the country's expenditures for research and developm ent S D ed ijer, "T ito ’s Bomb,’ discusses the origins o f the program and gives some data on it. On the Soviet nuclear-warfare deb ate, see Garthoff, “T h e D eath o f Stalin." 39 Most studies (for exam ple, Lainpe, Prickett, and Adamovic, Yugoslav-American Eco nomic Relations since World W ar II) argue that the Yugoslavs requested term ination o f U .S. aid But this must have b een only a formality to protect the idea of ind epend ence, for they knew aid was bein g ended (as it was at the same time for similar recipients, from Spain to South Korea). 1(1 They w ere reinstated in July 1957, and Tito and Khrushchev m et secretly in Bucharest in August. B u t in N ovem b er an “antirevi.sionism" resolution was read at the Moscow c e le bration o f the O c to b e r Revolution and the draft program o f the L C Y platform was criticized strongly— and in D e c e m b e r the credits w ere again retracted, for another five years. 41 W arriner, Revolution in Eastern Europe, 79; the reference again is to Stalin's 192S speech on collectivization 12 This was accom plished with two laws on land use in 1957, the Uncultivated Land Act and the Expropriation Act.
244
CH A P T E R 7
v e s tm e n t in the private sector, to encourage their extension from marketing into production. And private fanners w ere required to join district m arketing hoards (business leagues, or poslovni savezi)43 and en couraged to form jo in t ventu res with social-sector fanners in order to get access to d ev elopm en t credits, agricultural services, and machinery. N onetheless, at the end o f 1956, Kardelj argued that the “lessons of H u ngary’’ required a new “lib eralization.’ T h e econom ic growth in 1957 61 would eventually be based largely on foreign com m ercial loans and suppliers’ credits that had to b e repaid with interest (in 1 9 5 6 - 6 0 , 10.7 p e rc e n t o f the trade deficit was covered by grants, 4 3 p e rce n t by loans) and on revenues from commodity exports. T h e latter seem ed to require trade lib eralization.44
1958-1967 T h e difficulties with aid now forced to a head a d eb ate already in progress about the primary cause o f the persistent trade deficits. Liberals among the politicians, influential economists, and industrialists from the mored ev eloped western republics (above all Slovenia, personified by Boris Krajger) w ere convin ced that the solution was export orientation and link ing up with the process of E uropean trade integration that was taking a leap forward in 1958 with the Treaty o f Rom e (a policy they called “inte gration into the international division o f labor ”).45 F earin g the conse q u e n ce s o f exclusion from this process on the basis o f Yugoslavia’s particular neutrality and governm ent-negotiated trade, liberals pointed to the boom in processing industries that favorable prices and cheap im ported raw materials had brought. This was also the era o f fascination in socialist countries with the potential for econom ic growth and human lib eration prom ised by the “scientific-technological re volution,” a view al ready pre sen t in Kidrie’s Slovene model. Yugoslav liberals accordingly argued that growth should b e based on technological modernization through im ported W e ste rn machinery and cheaper production supplies. T h e latter would eventually be replaced by domestic supplies when for eign price com petition forced domestic producers o f raw materials and wage goods to raise their productivity and cut costs. In opposition to this 13 S e e chap. 3, n, 67 H L ju b o in ir Madžar, personal com m unication.
45
O n the co n seq u en ces for Yugoslavia o f the decisions by W estern European countries to m ake their cu rren cies co nvertible, end the European Payments Union, and create the Eu ropean M onetary Fu nd in 1958, see the article by B Filipović in the journal of the National Bank, Finansije (May 1959). Filipović also discusses the change in 1958 in the role o f th e U .S . dollar and the m ajor influence this change had on world trade, on the IM F , and on econ o m ic aid ►
T H E F AUS TI AN B A R G A I N
245
view, the developm entalists, whose professional base was most closely identified with Belgrade, had b ee n arguing throughout the 1950s that the root cause of the trade deficit was the importation of food, especially wheat,46 as a result o f low agricultural productivity at h o m e .47 In 1958, as the liberals had hoped, the decision was taken to seek m e m bership in the G A T T , to obtain IMP’ standby credits to cover the difficult transition o f trade liberalization (in 1958 and again in 1961 and 1965), and to begin a new stage of e c onom ic reform and institutional change n e c e s sary to m e e t the G A 'IT conditions. Arguing that by 1958 Yugoslavia had reached the “middle level o f developm ent, ” by which they meant that its natural resources w ere fully utilized, its econom y stable, and its industry able to satisfy most d om estic n e e d s ,48 the leaders also announced that there was no longer any need for federal investm ent in developm ent. T h e republics should assume responsibility for their own d evelopm ent policy, and territorial allocation of investm ent, foreign exchange, and supplies should accordingly replace the sectoral plans. T h e socialization of invest ment (as it was called) transferred funds from the G I F and sectoral banks (for industry, agriculture, and foreign trade) to republic-level (territorial) banks operating on com m ercial term s within their territory. Co m m u nes assumed responsibility for financing social services in place of federal grants-in-aid. By 1961, liberalization had replaced the multiple' exchange coefficients in foreign trade and diflerential tax rates appropriate to sectoral planning with uniform customs tariffs and tax rates, removed agricultural p ro te c tion, and reem phasized enterprise profitability. Because full “econom ic independence 49 was b eing granted to the republics while substantial dif ferences in levels of d ev elopm en t remained, the leaders also agreed to create a com pensation mechanism through low-interest loans to republics w In 1 9 5 1 - 5 4 , food m a d e u p 26 p e r c e n t o f total i m p o r t s — t h e t h i r d - h i g h e s t p e r c e n t a g e in Europe, a ft e r G e r m a n y a n d tile U n i t e d K i n g d o m , a n d t h e h ig h e s t p e r c a p i ta (P riv red a FNRJ, 1957, 280). P r iv r e d a F N R J u p e r io d u 1 9 4 7 - 1 9 5 6 la m e n t s , " I t ’s a s h a m e tha t, in th e return to t h e e a r l i e r po si tio n [on c o o p e r a t iv e s ] , t h e re s u lt s a c h i e v e d w e r e n t u s e d at least to co mbi ne f a r m s t e a d s of C o rn ie r c o o p é r a n t s . ” T h e a gra ri a n law ol M a y 1953 d i d i n c l u d e ar o n dacija ( c o n s ol id a tio n o f a s in gl e f a r m e r ’s p a rc el i/. e d ho ldi ngs ) for n e w e s t a t e s a n d e n c l o s u r e s of existing o n e s , b u t it w as n o t e x e c u t e d . I n v e s t m e n t in a g r i c u l t u r e in 1 9 1 7 - 5 6 r e p r e s e n t e d 9 p e rc e n t o f e c o n o m i c i n v e s t m e n t s a n d 7 p e r c e n t of total i n v e s t m e n t s in t h e e c o n o m y (I’r ivreda F N R J u p e r i o d u 1 9 4 7 - 1 9 5 6 , 161), 17 See, l o r e x a m p l e , t h e c o m p e n d i u m by e c o n o m i s t s o f t h e d e v e l o p m e n t a l i s t school edited b y R. St o j an o v ic , Y u g o s la v E c o n o m is ts on P r o b le m s o f a Socia list E c o n o m y ; C o b cl jic , Politika i m e lo d i p r i v r e d n o g r a zv o ja J u g o s l a v i a , 1 9 4 7 -1 9 5 6 ; a n d p a rt ic u la rl y P r iv r c d a FNRJ, 2.957. IS C i t e d in U 'S f o r c e s a r m é e s d e la R S F Y ; this la n g u a g e also p e r m e a t e s th e s p e e c h e s of the e i g h t h p a r t y c o n g r e s s in 1961 (see O sini h o n g r e s SKJ). 19 Ti to, a d d r e s s to t h e e i g h t h p a r t y c o n g r e s s , D e c e m b e r 1964, in O sini k im g r e s S K J , 3S,
246
CHAPTER 7
and regions designated as less d ev elo p e d .50 It would b e based on a 2 p e rc e n t (in place o f the previous 6 percent) capital tax on public-sector firms, and b ecau se these firms w ere within republican jurisdiction, the new federal fund would b e financed by republican taxation. In the third social plan o f 1 9 6 1 - 6 5 , emphasis was placed on “regional grow th.” T h e dual push for im ported technology and export promotion also af fected the army. It chose to modernize technologically by purchasing ar m am ents and licenses in world markets and, in order to pay for this in vestm ent, to increase the export o f arms. T h e policy o f export promo tion e xtend ed to services as well, most importantly the fu rther develop m e n t o f the tourist industry on the Adriatic coast, com mercial extensions o f th e m aritim e fleet, and the export o f labor (remittances from Yugoslav workers abroad soon cam e to cover more than half o f the deficit on cur re n t account). W h ile the dom estic reforms o f 1 9 5 8 - 6 1 were pre occupied with the lib eralizations d em anded by G A I T m e m b ership and the orientation toward E u ro p e a n trade, international price com petitiveness, and export promo tion, Tito e n te re d his most d eterm ined phase o f nonalignment. This in cluded advocating econom ic assistance for poorer countries as a faster road to peace than military blocs and (Tito him self having decided not to pursue a nuclear force) campaigning against nuclear weapons. T h e painful dom estic ad ju stm ent to global markets and to the criteria o f foreign com petition coincided, as in 1 9 5 0 - 5 2 , with two bad harvests (in 1960 and 1961) and with unfavorable conditions abroad, A serious recession oc curred in W e s t e r n econom ies in 1 9 6 0 - 6 1 and again in the mid-1960s, and relations with the superpowers w ere anything but calm in 1 9 6 0 -6 3 . The Yugoslavs party program o f 1958 and th eir choice for liberalization and a human-capital approach in response to Soviet reje ction brought a repeat o f the propaganda war of 1 9 4 8 - 4 9 , with the Moscow Declaration of De c e m b e r 1960 and then the sustained C h inese attack on the Yugoslav “w a y .”51 B u t the United States also o b je c te d to the Belgrade conference o f nonaligned nations in 1961 by cutting off the econom ic aid it had only ju s t granted when Yugoslavia’s quarrel with the U S S R revived. World 50 It was called the Fu n d o f the Federation, later changed to the Federal Fund for More Rapid D ev e lo p m e n t o f Le ss-D ev e lo p ed R epublics and Regions and then to the Federal F u n d for th e C red itin g o f th e Insufficiently D evelop ed Republics and Provinces to empha size its shift from grants-in-aid to repayable credits; finally, "regions” or “provinces” was replaced with “Kosovo”, T h e G I F continued to operate until January 1, 1964, however, until quarrels about the new fund could be stilled. 51 T h e new party platform o f 1958 was published in English as Yugoslavia's Way Criti cism o f M oscow ’s attack was taken up in particular by Veljko Vlahovic in his speech to the fourth party p lenum in 1962; Edvard Kardelj responded to the C h inese in his 1960 Socialism
and War,
T H E FAUS TI AN BARGAIN
247
tensions skyrocketed with the Sino-Soviet split of 1961, the conflict b e tween K h ru sh ch e v ’s pronuclear and aggressive third-world policies on the one hand and K e n n e d y ’s conventional-force buildup and focus on E u rope on the other, and then the 1962 Cuban missile crisis and 1963 nuclear-force disputes within NATO. Once again the g ov ernm ent re acted by shifting the emphasis in invest ment policy b ack to basic industries during 1960 and 1961, and in 1963 the five-year plan for 1 9 6 1 - 6 6 was abandoned in midstream. M oreover, the combination of d om estic stagflation in response to the econom ic r e forms, rising trade deficits after 1960, and disquiet over international events gave new life to the b itter political d eb ate over the reform, the federal g o v ern m e n t’s investm ent policy and its role in directing the rate and structure o f developm ental investm ent, and the remaining monopoly of the YPA over d efense financing. This d ebate end ed soon after relations improved with the U n ited States and the U S S R during 1963 and after the signing of the partial N uclear T e s t Ban Treaty in January 1964. At the m om en tou s eighth party congress of D e c e m b e r 1964, Tito rose to chastise party delegates for failing to com plete the econom ic reform, "although a decision on this m atter was arrived at a long tim e ago.” D e spite one last effort by representatives o f Serbia to have agricultural pro duction valued “a d eq u a tely ,” the congress docum ents referred to federal transfers for agriculture and developm ental investm ent as “wasted aid” to less-developed republics that should be limited to the com pletion o f c u r rent projects and to the kind o f “technical and personnel assistance” that Yugoslavia was sending to less-d eveloped countries. D o m e s tic capitalgoods industries, many built largely for military self-reliance with govern ment funds, w ere labeled “political factories” that ought to b e closed. A reduction in g o v ern m e n t investm ent expenditures, accom plished by transferring to e nterprises far greater responsibility for th eir own invest ment (primarily from internal funds), was called a victory for “workers’ control over “political forces” in investm ent decisions that properly b e longed to “direct p ro d u ce rs .”52 With the end o f the political battle over reforms in 1964 and the c o m pletion of the two-stage liberalization for G A T T m e m b ership, the year 1965 is usually identified as a watershed— the year of the Reform , when the campaign surrounding two currency devaluations, two price revi sions, and a new dinar brought the liberal policies h om e to the urban public. T h e c o n s e q u e n ces o f the reform w ere also felt in a severe re c e s sion in 1 9 6 5 - 6 8 . Probably far more im portant than econom ic reform, though, w ere the drastic worsening in Yugoslavia’s terms of trade and the 52
Osmi kongres SKJ (S ee “P ractice and T heory,'' English version of congress p rocee d
ings, p. 55.)
248
CHAPTER 7
W e s t e r n recession, which dim med hopes for export-oriented growth.53 T h e removal o f tariff protections after 1961 did cause a mass closure of private farms unable to co m p ete with cheap imports. T h e resulting con centration o f landholdings re ceived a boost from the export-oriented pol icy o f agro-industrial com plexes and the intensification campaign for ec o n o m ic rationalization in 1 9 6 5 - 6 7 , which brought further enclosures, com massatio n, and mechanization o f state farm s.54 Restrictions on the purchase o f agricultural machinery for private use cam e to an end in 1 9 6 4 .55 T h e g o v ernm ent chose to end its reliance on farmers’ cooperatives as interm ediaries betw ee n the social and private sectors, removing all rem aining federal rebates, subsidies, and investm ent credits to agricul ture and encouraging direct contracting betw ee n processing industries and private fa nn ers to support agro-industrial complexes (kombinats ). T h e federal fund for loans to less-developed regions began to operate (after quarrels among the republics over redistribution had delayed it four years), b u t th e effect was to red uce sharply interrepublican transfers for investm ent after 1965. At least as important a part o f the liberal victory sealed by the eighth party congress was its decision on defense: to forgo nuclear deterrence and orient military forces to the choice of conventional d eterren c e in E u rope. D e fe n s e policy would thus place the territorial defense forces on a near-equal footing with a smaller, more technologically sophisticated standing arm y (a move marked by forced retirem ents of senior army offi cers in 1964) and woidd choose in 1965 to keep the country outside the W arsaw Pact (a decision revealed by the absence o f Yugoslav delegates at the W arsaw Pact consultative political m eeting in 1966). A massive politi cal purge and dem otions o f military, internal-security, and party person nel (identified with the fall o f Aleksandar Rankovic at the fourth plenum in Ju ly 1966 but in fact having begun in 1964) followed the sharing of the last province o f federal in d e p e n d en ce — jurisdiction over foreign affairs and d efen se — with the repu blics.56 53 R ecession s in th e U .S . econom y occurred in 1 9 4 8 -4 9 , 1 9 5 3 -5 4 , 1 9 5 7 -5 8 , 1960-61, and 1 9 6 5 —6 7 — all years of difficulty in the Yugoslav econom y (Shonfield, Modern Capital
ism, 1 0 -1 8 ) . 54 S e e M iller, “Socialism and Agriculture in Yugoslavia”, and Rusinow, review of Die
Koope ration. 55 Purchases then skyrocketed (Olga Supek, personal communication)
T o judge by
farm ers' com plaints in parliam ent that they found im ported agricultural machinery less suited to th eir conditions than dom estic products, which had b eco m e less available, this was not a policy to sell dom estic inventories when external demand was falling, 5(3 S e e Ilo n d in s, The Yugoslav Community o f Nations, 2 7 0 - 7 2 , 3 3 1 - 3 2 . T h e story behind Rankovic s fall from pow er remains to b e told, but the conventional wisdom— that it was due to im happiness with th e excessive power lie was said to wield domestically through the se c re t police (there w ere charges that lie was even bugging President T ito ’s private chain-
TIIF, FAUS TI AN BAKCAIN
249
At the same time, the policy toward foreign aid and finance e ntered a new era as a result o f the mounting foreign d ebt and the substantial loss of federal re v e n u e due to the successive devolution and socialization o f b ud getary expenditures and the effect of trade liberalization on customs du ties. Instead of a declinin g d ep en d e n c e on foreign capital, as the economic strategy had intended, there was a growing dem and for it. T h e federal g o v e r n m e n t’s increasing reliance 011 foreign monies for domestic investment and its ev e r more frequent resort to refinancing and recycling of its foreign d eb t led it to seek new sources of foreign capital— one re course being liberalization of rules on foreign investm ent. A new round of World Bank loans provided the bulk o f the credits for investm ent in new or modernized infrastructure— roads, harbors, and railroads (the credits were distributed, after negotiation, to republic p ro je cts).57 E nterprises, commercial banks, and republican governm ents gained the right to e n te r international capital markets independently. Legislation revised rules on social ownership to encourage jo in t ventu res that would bring foreign equipment and capital directly to domestic producers, without the need for hard cu rre n cy or new g ov ernm ent debt. Alter 1965, the d ep en d e n ce of dom estic production 011 imports of Paw materials and in term ediate goods (including capital equipm ent) also grew. T h e s e purchases, however, w ere supported not by the favorable terms of public assistance enjoyed in the 1950s, but with com mercial and Eurodollar short-term loans.58 Not alone among developing countries in facing the decline o f public, long-term loans in the 1960s, the maturation of debt assumed in the 1950s, trade deficits, and the need to seek debt relief, Yugoslavia managed to delay paym ent o f E xp o rt-Im p ort Bank debt until 1 9 6 8 - 7 1 by consolidating its d eb t from 1950 and the 1961 program loans. It red u ced the amount of its Public Law 4 8 0 obligations and d e ferred them to 1 9 6 8 - 7 2 , and gained new assistance of $ 1 .2 billion from the U .S. g o v ernm ent (to be repaid after 1970). In 1967 it obtained an other I M F loan, and during 1 9 6 5 - 6 8 managed to persuadí1 many E u ropean g ov ernm ents to refund d ebt until 1 9 7 0 .59 hers) and with his iron-fisted rule over Kosovo province— ignores im portant events for Yugoslav foreign policy and in the dom estic conflict that linked dom estic econ om ic policy with foreign-trade and defen se policy (for exam ple, the conflict in the U S S R o ver n u clear vs, conventional forces; th e term ination in S e p te m b e r 1964 o f K hru shchev’s sovnarkhoz reform and the rep lacem ent o f the regional councils vvitli the m inisterial and branch-indnstry struc ture; and th e beginnings o f Yugoslav participation in Warsaw Pact co m m ittees in mid-1965, which was reversed the next year at exactly the tim e oi Ran ko vic’s purge).
r?7 D ata and background can b e found in Lam pe, Prickett, and Adamovic, YugoslavAmerican Economic Relations, 3 5 - 3 8 , 64, 1 7 4 -7 6 . r,s S e e M. Unkovic, “Inostrani kapital u jugoslovenskoj privredi, 59 Bitterm an , The Refunding o f International Debt; see also Lam pe, Pric kett, anti Ad amovic, Yugoslav-American Economic Relations. On the availability oi new monies because
250
CHAPTER 7
1968-1978 I f th e re w e re any lingering doubts about the advisability o f the devolution o f authority over foreign affairs, particularly defense (and the army cer tainly had them), they w ere erased by external events in 1 9 6 7 - 6 8 . The Arab-Israeli war broke out in 1967, with firsthand participation by a Yugoslav conting ent in the UN peacekeepin g force. In August 1968, War saw Pact troops invaded Czechoslovakia to put a stop to an econom ic reform similar to the Yugoslav one. Finally, there was an escalation of the war in Vietnam . K a rd e lj’s parliamentary address at the end o f 1967 o p en e d the next stage o f “socialization,” which would culm inate in the 1974 constitu tion; that stage began with the army as concern rose over national security. T h e new strategic doctrine o f “all-national d efense” (a relabeling o f the “p e op le ’s war” concept from wartime and 1948—50) gave th e republican territorial forces equal status with the YPA and set in mo tion th e next stage o f decentralization o f national security and socialization o f th e coe rcive functions o f the state (military and police). All-national d efense (initiated in 1964 but formally adopted by the party leadership only in N o v em b e r 1968 and enacted in F e b ru a ry 1969) would make firms and local gov ernm ents th e core o f the defense and security system. Ac cording to the sy stem ’s principles, this integration o f military functions into civilian institutions at the popular level— the next stage in the “with erin g away o f the state” through its socialization— also required fuller party supervision o f the army and coordination with it in central party co u n cils.60 T h e process o f am ending the 1963 constitution b etw een 1967 and 1971 confirmed the change in foreign affairs. It also finalized the transfer to republican party c om m ittees o f control over cadre appoint m ents (in 1969) and the transfer o f the remaining federal bureaucracies to th e republics (in 1971), with coordination at the federal level by com mit tees o f republican delegates. Successful p o stp onem ent o f the foreign d eb t until 1969 m eant that eco nom ic policy could concentrate on rebuilding foreign hard-currency re serves. E xp o rt promotion to W e ste rn markets continued to have priority, so m uch so that in 1967 exporters w ere even required to get prior ap proval to export to the clearing area. A continuin g decline in W estern dem and for Yugoslav exports and the slow growth in developed countries in 1 9 7 0 - 7 1 , 61 however, led firms to seek markets in developing countries o f growing com petition b etw een U .S . and European hanks, see G riffith-Jones, “T h e Growth o f M ultinational Ban kin g.” fi0 T h e use o f in telligen ce from th e party unit within th e arm y lo bring trumped-up charges against Rankovic in 1966 and justify his forced resignation suggests that party control over th e arm y had b een won earlier. f>1 T his period also saw the steep est rise in comm odity prices since 1950 (International L ab o r Office, Employment, Growth, and Basic Needs, 2 6 - 2 7 )
T H E I’AUSTIAN BARGAIN
251
instead (especially India and Egypt). But the global expansion of U .S . and European com m ercial banks in the late 1960s provided a new source of trade financing, and in 1970 Yugoslavia succeeded in negotiating a trade agreement with the E uro pean Com m unity. In 1971, the g overnm ent fur ther liberalized the rules on foreign investm ent and took another I M F standby loan with its condition of a stabilization policy. To prom ote ex ports, it devalued the cu rrency annually from 1971 to 1974 (twice in 1971), and it raised the proportion o f foreign-exchange earnings that firms did not have to sell to the National Bank. Although the new constitution was not promulgated until 1974, the fundamental changes in the international environm ent in 1973— with the unilateral ab ando nm ent of Bretton W oods by the United States in the sum m er and then tin: first O P E C oil-price shock that fall— reinforced the shift already taking place after 1970 among Yugoslav firms to domestic suppliers or to suppliers and export markets in the East and nonaligned world. T h e s e changes also brought a sharp change in econom ic policy. At first the g o v ernm ent continued on the road to currency convertibility, creating a limited foreign-exchange market in May and shifting in Ju ly to a managed floating exchange rate. But the oil-price rise alone increased the trade deficit (or 1974 by 22 percent. T h e rise of W e stern European pro tectionism, with unforeseeable nontariif barriers against Yugoslav goods (such as the outright ban on Yugoslav b e e f imports in 1974 and ad hoc prohibitions on textiles, steel, ships, and b e e f in 1975), followed by the West G erm an recession of 1 9 7 5 - 7 6 , which sent ever-larger num bers of Yugoslav fiastarbciter (guest workers) packing, wreaked havoc with the balance of payments and the westward orientation of governmental policy. In contrast to the concerted effort in the 1960s to red uce the proportion of trade on clearing accounts and increase trade in convertiblecurrency markets/’2 the trade deficit and the needs of dom estic manufac turers forced Yugoslav firms to look east, especially to the Soviet markets, for import of production supplies (above all oil) and for export of the m a chinery, ships, footwear and clothing, electrical e q u ipm ent, and pro cessed foods excluded from W e stern m arkets.63 T h e altered global terms of trade also made domestically produced raw materials, energy, basic chemicals, and minerals less costly than imports and more saleable in Western markets, as evidenced by the rising share of primary com modities in relation to higher-value-added goods in Yugoslav exports after 1 9 7 4 .64 (l"'2 Exports to clearing-aeeount con n in e s w ere virtually stagnant in 1 9 6 5 -6 9 . 6:1 Exports to O E C D countries fell from an average ol 5 5 .2 percent o f total Yugoslav exports in 1 9 7 1 - 7 3 to 4 0 .5 p ercen t in 1 9 7 4 - 7 8 ; exports to C M E A countries rose from an average o f 3 5 , 6 p erce n t in 1 9 7 1 - 7 3 to 43 peree.nl in 1 9 7 4 -7 8 (Tyson, The Yugoslav E co nomic System , 88-91). M E co n om ic Com m ission for Eu ro pe, “T h e Relative Perform ance o f South European Exports,
252
CI I AI ’TKK 7
This shift in investm ent priorities has b een wrongly billed as a conser vative political reaction to the un em ploym ent o f the 1960s and as a policy of import substitution over export promotion. Instead, it re presented a shift in the kinds o f exports the country could and did sell. M oreover, the interruptio n o f d e te n te in E u ro p e and growing international tensions re vived the g o v e r n m e n t’s concern for defensive self-sufficiency. T h e result ing shift in investm ent priorities to defense-related industries and stocks conc urred with the rising dem and from alternate export markets and Yugoslav manufacturers for che a p e r domestic supplies.'’5 By 1969, these international tensions already had the YPA general stafl concerned about d efense p repared ness and financing for modernization. In 1974, the tenth party congress em phasized “the necessity of building up and developing the YPA as the armed force o f the working class and all the nations and nationalities of the S F R Y [Socialist Federal R epublic o f Yugoslavia].’ '’6 Nor was there any reversal in the perceived threats to national secu rity. In 1977, the new American administration refocused defense policy onto E u ro p e and N ATO began another buildup o f conventional troops (m atched by the W arsaw Pact the next year); the Soviet Union in vaded Afghanistan in 1979; and the superpowers failed to complete a nuclear-nonproliferation treaty. T h e se events heightened the Y PA ’s in terest in new weapons systems and its concern over the preparedness of the territorial d efense forces; by 1 9 8 0 - 8 1 , there was even renewed in terest in a d om estic nuclear force and nuclear energy to reduce oil d ep en d e n ce. In contrast to the unfavorable conditions in capital markets during the similar policy shifts in 1 9 4 8 - 4 9 , 1 9 5 6 - 5 8 , and 1 9 6 0 - 6 1 , the supply of recycled O P E C dollars in W e stern capital markets made it possible after 1973 for Yugoslavia to service its d ebt and finance balance-of-payments deficits with escalated foreign borrowing in place of commodity-trade earnings from the W est. That supply also favored the investment policy of the period. W orld Bank loans after 1975 supported investm ent in trans portation and agriculture/’7 and U .S . and European banking consortiums 05 T h e 1 9 7 6 - 8 0 social plan, adopted a year late because o f conflicts am ong republican leaders, aim ed to c orrect the deficit and reduce the import d epen d en ce of dom estic produc tion by investing in shipbuilding, agro-industry, tourism, ferrous and nonferrous metals, basic chem icals, eq u ip m en t, synthetic rubber, infrastructure, electric power, coal, petro leum, and gas (S ch rcn k, Ardalan, and El Talawy, Yugoslavia: Self-Management Socialism and the Challenges o f Development, 209; Chit lie, Industrialization and Manufactured Ex port Expansion in a Worker-Managed Economy, 106). m Les forces années, 861T. Just as the all-national defense doctrine was publicly pro claim ed only five years after its adoption in 1 9 6 4 -6 5 (at the ninth party congress in 1969), th e formal an no u ncem en t o f this course cam e only five years a fter the shift in policy (Bebler, “D ev elo p m en t o f Sociology o f Militaria in Yugoslavia,” 5 9 - 6 8 ) . (’7 Such loans am ounted to $7 50 million in 1977 and 1978 alone.
T I I K F AUSTI AN BARGAIN
253
financed joint ventu res in energy and petro chem ica ls.1’8 liven greater freedom was granted to banks (in 1975) and enterprises (in 1977) to in crease th eir foreign reserves by borrowing directly in foreign capital mar kets, leading major E uro pean banks to complain loudly about the rapid proliferation of unregulated borrowing requests and to demand that the federal gov ernm ent rein them in.*’9 After 1975, as an incentive to improve trade perform ance and d eb t repayment, the governm ent transferred co n trol over half of customs re venues to manufacturing and foreign-trade firms through social funds at the federal and republic levels (“sellmanaging com m unities o f interest for foreign econom ic relations ). As the system's principles required , managem ent of these funds, and therefore a share in Ibreign-trade policy, was handed to the representatives of firms earning export revenues. T h e balance-of-payments account was also sub divided am ong the republics, each of which was assigned a proportion of foreign credits to which it had a “l ight and which it was obliged to repay. A further trade a g re em en t with the European C om m u nity was signed in December 1976, and talks began with the European F r e e Trade Associa tion in 1979.
1979-1989 Both legs o f e c onom ic policy after 1973— foreign trade and foreign finance— buckled under the external shocks of 1 9 7 9 - 8 0 . T h e short-run response was, as usual, to seek further assistance Irom the I M F . T h e E C trade a g re em en t o f 1976, up for renewal in 1979, unexpectedly ran into difficult bargaining. Talks on greater cooperation b etw ee n the C M E A and the E C that had encouraged thoughts of a real end to trade barriers in Europe cam e to an abrupt halt with the invasion of Afghanistan, In spring 1980, the jump in interest rates on the U .S . dollar sent Yugoslavia’s d ebtservice obligations soaring, as most of its d eb t was denomin; ited in U.S. dollars and 5 8 p e rce n t o f that d eb t was in high-interest com mercial loans.70 At the same time, Yugoslav trade in markets in the East and South was hit by the second price rise for O P E C and Soviet oil (by then (,,li Petrol Ljubljan a financed a natural-gas pipeline in the Eurodollar market through Bankers’ Trust International; INA, the Zagreb oil company, lorm ed a joint venture with Dow Chem ical in 1978 to build a petrochem ical-processing plant on the Croatian island of Krk; and a jo in t venture with Westinghou.se built a nuelear-power plant (Krško) in Slovenia. ® G reen , “C o m m e n t,” 2 4 8 - 4 9 , 7n Ledic, "D e b t Analysis and D eh t-K ela led Issu es.” T h e debt went Irom $2 billion in 1969 to S20 billion in J9 8 2 ; the h ard-cuirency d ebt-service ratio ju m p ed to 24 percent in 1978 and to 3 5 p ercen t in 1980; and the average burden o f repaym ent in the period 1 9 8 3 - 8 6 was 85 billion a year. T h e country began repaying princ ipal in 1985. S e e D yker, Yugoslavia, 1)4 -28 ; and Lam pe, Pricket t, and Adamovic, Yugoslav-Anwriran Economic Relations, 148 89.
254
CHAPTER 7
Yugoslavia was paying for it in convertible currency). T h e collapse in the prices o f primary com m odities, in part b ecau se the United States, F r a n c e , and others w ere dumping massive stockpiles of strategic raw ma terials onto the world market, sent prices o f Yugoslav mineral exports such as cop p er and aluminum p lu m m etin g .71 T h e trade deficit reached a record high in 1979, wholesale bankruptcy threatened dom estic industry as capacity utilization fell un der 7 0 percent, and foreign reserves were so low that an I M F cred it o f $ 3 4 0 million was drawn in May, followed by a re q u e st for a com pensatory loan facility.72 T his tim e, how ever, W e s te rn com m ercial banks chose to stop lending to E a s te r n E u r o p e — including in that category Yugoslavia— on the grounds that th e Polish crisis o f 1 9 8 0 - 8 1 would spread. D e sp ite the world recession in 1 9 8 0 - 8 3 (which reduced the net contribution of remittances from Yugoslav workers abroad to only 2 5 percent o f the trade deficit by 1981), th e re was no choice but to reem phasize com modity exports to hard -cu rrency markets and to negotiate with the I M F (now also taking a m u ch firm er stance on d eb t-repay m ent conditions) to “restore foreign c o n fid e n c e ,” as new prim e minister Milka Planinc’s mandate read in 1982. W h ile negotiations proceed ed on what was to b e c o m e the first of the I M F ’s th ree -y e ar standby facilities to developing countries, the gov e rn m e n t sought once again to refinance and reschedule existing debt (against vocal opposition within the assem bly and sections o f the party).73 T h e all-out campaign after 1980 for d eb t repaym ent through stabiliza tion and export promotion included another “econom ic reform ” to reor ient d om estic institutions to W e stern markets and foreign price com petition (“integration into the international division o f labor”) and to increase productivity in manufacturing, again by technological moderniz ation through imports. Ju st as in 1 9 5 9 - 6 0 , planners in Slovenia had be co m e increasingly worried after 1975 over their loss o f world market share, their technological ob solescence relative to W e stern traders, and a brain drain o f technically skilled professionals to Austrian firms that paid h igher salaries, while the drop in world market prices for most raw mate rials o n ce again made it che a p e r to import than to buy from domestic producers. A long-term stabilization program, written by a committee 71 Anton B e b le r (Slovene political scientist and defense expert), personal communication. 72 T h e Yugoslavs m ade th e request on th e grounds that the poor harvest that year, the earth qu ake in D alm atian tourist areas, and the declin e in rem ittances from workers abroad w ere beyond th eir control. 73 Substantial long-term loans w ere obtained in 1981 and 1982. After difficult negotia tions organized by th e U .S . ambassador and State D epartm ent am ong fifteen W estern coun tries, th e I M F , th e W orld Bank, six hundred com m ercial banks, and the Bank of Intern ation al Se ttlem en ts, a $2 billion loan package was arranged in January 1983- T he IMF standby loan o f 1 9 8 1 - 8 3 was followed by a second one in April 1984
T H K F AUSTI AN BARGAIN
255
chaired by the S lovene Se rg ej K raig her,74 was adopted by the federal assembly in July 1983, and a new constitutional com mission established in 1983 produced a set o f 130 altered articles and 29 am end m ents to the constitution to be d eb ated first by the public, then within the party, and then in the assem bly, b eginning in January 1 9 8 6 .75 The d eb a te over reorientation to the W e s t was, as it had b een in 1 9 6 1 63, com plicated by the international situation. On the econom ic side, there w ere again signs o f op ening in the W est. In 1985, the E C began a new stage of m onetary integration (scheduled for com pletion in 1992), the CM EA and the E C resum ed the negotiations stalled in 1979, com m ercial banks reversed their lending policies dramatically, and in the U S S R P res ident Mikhail G orbach e v sped up the process of econom ic reform with perestroika and then glasnost. B u t national security rem ained p ro b le m atic. T h e Croatian assembly and public opinion in Slovenia (especially through the Socialist Alliance-financed maverick youth weekly Mlailina and the opposition intellectu al jo urnal Nova Revija) began to insist that under the prevailing international conditions there was no longer any need for a standing arm y and that the territorial defense forces within the republics w ere sufficient. T h e army perceiv ed a very different world. E n gaged in maintaining martial law in the rebellious province of Kosovo, alarmed at the rising social disorder and political d iscontent over the aus terity policies o f d eb t repaym ent, and fearing the attempts by the north ern republics to transform the territorial defense forces into “parallel armies’’— to the extent that the minister o f defense redrew military dis tricts to cut across republican borders in 1985 and urged the reintegration of major infrastructure such as railroads, electricity grids, and postal and telephone services76— the general staff also saw no apparent reduction in the hostility o f the external environm ent. An escalating arms race and increasing N A TO attention to the southern E uro pean theater (including 74 Not only was this program an obvious parallel witli the m arket-oriented econom icreform policy adopted b ecau se oi difficulties with foreign trade in 3 9 5 8 -6 1 , but that program was written by a co m m ittee chaired by a Slovene liberal oi the same name (though no relation), Boris Krajger. 75 T h e comm ission was initiated by a letter from Najdan Pasic— a political scientist, party member, and at th e tim e c h i e f ju stic e o f the sup rem e co u rt— to th e party presidency in Septem ber 1982, although a co m m ittee along these lines had b een set up by the twelfth party congress in Ju n e of that year. It was eventually named for Jos ip Vrhovec, the chair of the commission that drafted the final report. T h e am endm ents w ere based on an analysis o f the political system by th e commission and on its 3985 report, A Critical Analysis o f the
Functioning o f the Political System o f Socialist Self-Management (Burg, “E lite Conflict in Post-Tito Yugoslavia,” 192 nn, 56, 57). 76 Facing funding problem s for defen se from 1976 on, the arm ed forces sought ways to simplify, im prove coordination, and stream line, including the decision taken in 1983 to become self-sufficient in arms by 1990 (Gow, legitim acy and the Military, 9 7 - 1 0 3 )
256
CHAPTER 7
its m aneuvers in 1985 and 1986) seem ed to demand greater expenditures for d efense when the d ecline in federal re venues, slow econom ic growth, and the stabilization program dem anded cuts. Although political disagreem ents over the best way to repay the debt led th e federal ca b in e t to abandon the I M F program temporarily in 1985 86, the retu rn to the I M F in 1 98 877— and with it the institutional changes to im p le m e n t e conom ic liberalization— culm inated in eighteen new laws that d eclared an end to the system o f self-management and associated lab o r,78 op ened the e conom y to full foreign ow nership and repatriation of profits, and legalized market allocation of labor and capital. But while the I M F supported prime m inister Ante Markovic’s “shock-therapy” stabili zation program in the spring of 1990, the Slovene electorate voted that D e c e m b e r to seek full national ind ep end en ce by Ju n e 1991. D em ands by the Slovene and Croatian governm ents for com plete control in their terri tory over rem aining federal jurisdictions— the police, military, courts, and laws— succu m b ed , in the act of implementation, to civil war.
C o n c l u s io n
T h e first part o f an answer to the paradox o f Yugoslav unem ploym ent lies with the role o f g o v ernm ent in a socialist state. No longer a political force re p re sen tin g labor alone— not only b ecause it had created a one-party state but, m ore importantly, becau se o f the assumptions and institutional co n s e q u e n ce s of social ow nership — the g overnm ent aimed to represent the collective interests of society as a whole in ever-improving economic conditions and a territory free from war. Th e Yugoslav party leadership’s ch oice o f econ om ic strategy and its political prerequisites made this task one o f rep re sen tin g the cou ntry’s interests globally: securing capital for growth, responding to the conseq uences of global business cycles for do m estic growth, and protecting national security. T h e dynamic o f public policy was driven neither by electoral competi tion b e tw e e n political parties representing labor or capital at home, nor by a d om estic busin ess cycle, but rather by the federal response to inter national events: regional security concerns and the superpower contest, changes in foreign demand for Yugoslavia’s goods and in its terms of trade, and changes in the supply o f foreign capital to finance imports and s u p p le m e n t federal revenues and infrastructural investm ent. T h e data on u n em p lo y m en t show particularly clearly that the initiative for and path of central policy originated outside the country, and that elite conflict and 77 T h e federal cabin et cho.sc lo return to the I M F in Febru ary 1987, but the new program — called the May M easures— was not adopted until May 1988 7H Primary am ong them was the Law on En terprises o f January 1989
T1 IK FAUSTI AN BARGAIN
257
(actional debates would follow a poliev decision in which the disputants had little say— except over when it would be ratified and what political purges might b e necessary. E c o n o m ic adju stments required political ad justments, not the o th er way around. Because policy decisions w ere made in response to international condi tions over which the leaders had no control, th eir im plementation was often interrupted unexpectedly, such as when an export-oriented liberal ization was undercut by a W e stern recession or by global tensions that demanded a tem porary retreat to the needs of defense. F ar more signifi cant in explaining the failures o f Yugoslav policy than the com m on accusa tions about elite dissensus is the uncertainty engendered by this vulnerability, which made it very dilficult to plan a response and im ple ment it consistently. T h e fact that policies w ere driven largely by crisis also made it extrem ely difficult to organize domestic opposition to govern ment policy and to act strategically. Yugoslavia’s international niche and its increasing d ep en d e n ce on for eign creditors for d om estic production and e m ploy m ent did put the cou n try in a structural position com parable to that of wage earners in capitalist countries. Instead o f contesting this structure, however. President T ito ’s solution was to seek from within it as much gain as possible through non alignment and through third-world forums demanding redistribution of wealth. This strategy appeared to b e succeeding until the late 1970s, but with so much of d om estic production d ep end ent on imports (including production for export), what one might call a Keynesian-type deficit fi nancing was inappropriate to the country’s position. E ven with another refinancing in 19 82 —85, the conditions ol loreign-debt repaym ent and a long world recession d em onstrated its limits. T h e g overnm ent remained beholden to W e s te rn capital. The c o n s e q u e n c e for policy and politics was a series of vicious circles. The fundamental trap lay in the' leaders Faustian bargain betw een their strategic position internationally and access to foreign capital (both credits and trade). T h e symbiosis betw een the two increased the probability of unpredictable external shocks, b ecause trends in global capital and trade on the one hand and superpower conflict on the other did not run paral lel. As if struck by a series of hurricanes, the country might not re cu p er ate from one shock before the* next one hit, and policies to deal with one were not the same as for another. Yet to abandon one half ol the bargain would have b een to abandon the other. This would have required a funda mentally different internal order and the overthrow of one in which o th e r wise opposing political factions had developed vested interests. T h e vicious circle of foreign policy translated into political conflict. Th e primary difference b etw ee n liberal and conservative policies and interests was defined by the industrial policy (and its organizational prerequisites)
258
CHAPTER 7
requ ired by each side o f this foreign-policy bargain (foreign-trade earn ings in W e s t e r n markets on one side and military self-reliance on the other). This m eant that factional politics and elite dissensus were inevita ble. B ecau se policy shifts w ere defined by unpredictable external events, how ever, n e ith er side could eve r claim a total victory, and consensus was unachievable. This is scarcely unusual for any country, but it negated the fundamental prem ise o f the lead ers’ political strategy and institutions. Instead o f political harm ony and unity against the outside, there was con tinuing tension and weakness. Unable to resolve the policy stalemate, elite conflict focused instead on redistribution and control over capital. T h e result was to translate the political conflict back into econom ic conflict in a continual competition for funds— com petition betw een federal revenues and republican taxes, among potential recip ients o f foreign loans, betw een republics or firms benefiting from foreign econom ic policy and those demanding compensa tion. O n e way to resolve this conflict temporarily was with foreign credits. B u t this built-in, insatiable demand for foreign credits re turned the coun try full circle to its original vulnerability to external conditions and the need to protect its international bargaining strength as a precondition for d om estic stability. T h e political choice o f a gradualist path to protect the party’s domestic coalition and ease the costs o f initial industrialization by supplementing d om estic savings with imported credits and equ ip m ent was in time tu rned 011 its head. B ecau se dom estic production b eca m e more rather than less d ep en d e n t on imports, it also b eca m e more difficult to change d efense policy as liberals dem anded, while econom ic policy was shaped more and m ore by the particular supply of foreign-trade finance and its conditions. Instead of a temporary solution to econom ic development, this strategy b eca m e an econom ic trap, and the difficulty o f escaping it (as witnessed by the many other developm entalist countries in the world that had similar difficulties with shifts in military and d evelopm ent aid, global re cessions, external shocks, and foreign debt) was nonetheless then com pounded by the political conseq uences. T h e idea o f 'socialism in one cou n try ” was to provide a second logic o f collective action in domestic econ om ic institutions in favor of a country of wage earners, as opposed to th e first logic o f capital internationally. Instead, the openness to foreign capita] disto rted the functioning o f those institutions and the capacity of th e gov ern m e n t to adjust internationally and facilitate economic gro w th .79 79 As V ladim ir Gligorov observes, however, the idea o f socialism in one country was for the Bukharinist side th e decision not to export revolution, th ere thus being
110
justification
for a standing arm y (Gledišta i sporovi o industrijalizaciji u socijalizmu ) This fundamental p roblem for liberal reform ers, m entioned in ch ap ter I , was not resolved by the Yugoslavs in the international conditions of the cold war.
T I I K FAUSTI AN BARGAIN
259
The- effect on the- leaders strategy lor lull em ploym ent was adverse. Instead ot preventing the financial crises that lead to industrial unem ploy ment, the g ov ernm ent was pre occupied with external stabilization and therefore built a recessionary bias into policy without the institutional capacity to pre ve n t further inflation and to regen erate growth. T he greater the op enness to foreign capital and to price liberalization as the mechanism for adju stm ent, the less the monetary institutions o f the so cialist econom y w ere able to function as intended. Instead of providing the conditions for growth that would absorb surplus labor from agricul ture as well as new generations, the g ov ernm ent responded to th ese fi nancial crises by seeking to improve the financial discipline o f econom ic actors through decentralization, socialization, and financial autonomy. This undermined further the capacity of macroeconom ic policy to m ain tain a stable currency, In place ol governmental guardianship over s e c toral balance and infrastructural investm ent for sustained growth and declining regional inequality, there w ere social plans and developmental investments oriented to the needs of the foreign sector and the projects lor which external financing could b e found. Here, too, there were vicious circles. T h e I M F policies were partic ularly inappropriate, and each failure required a new dose of I M F credits and policies. M onetary and fiscal policy followed stop-and-go cycles, im posing restrictions to fight inflation that only fueled inflation and required further restrictions. [Expansionary policies w ere able to increase em p loy ment in the short run il they were the result of g overnm ent expenditures rather than simply an increase in the money supply, but b ecause the initial result was a ju m p in imports, such a policy could not b e sustained. The government would then return to cuttin g demand by placing restric tions on credit and imports that required firms and lower governm ents to adjust by cutting production, nonproductive expenditures, and labor costs. These cuts all implied cuts in e m ploy m ent or its redistribution. At each point, the federal gov ernm ent had to face the vicious circle by adjusting with labor. Although it had no jurisdiction over em ploym ent, the federal policy had direct c o n s e q u e n c e s — to which we turn in the next chapter.
Chapter 8 SLOVENIA AND FOČA
L a b o r -o r ie n t e d
governm ents, according to the scholarly literature,
have b e e n able to approach full em ploym ent not only because of their explicit political c o m m itm e n t to bringing about full em ploym ent through the instrum ents o f gov ernm ent policy (particularly in regard to interna tional adju stment), but also becau se they have the political capacity to support those policies with discipline in the labor market. Centrally bar gained social pacts betw ee n organized labor and organized business (usu ally mediated by gov ernm ent representatives) can im plem ent incomes policies that overcom e the inevitable trade-off b etw een wages and jobs. T h e key to these “corporatist” pacts is labor’s promise of wage restraint— in exchange for lower un em ploym ent, governmental assistance in retain ing and relo cating workers when adju stm ent to shifts in market demand creates red und ant labor, a share in profits when they improve, and other benefits. C ontroversy surrounds the claims made for voluntary wage restraint and centralized bargaining m echanisms as guarantees o f fuller employ m ent. O n e o f the m ore telling criticisms is the ease with which monetary and exchang e-rate policies can undo the effect of incomes policies.1 In com es pacts did restrain wages in Yugoslavia, m oreover— real wages fell without re p riev e from 1978 on, at the same time that unemployment was rising fastest. B u t this fact did not influence the reigning explanation of Yugoslav un em ploym ent: labor m anagem ent of firms gave workers power over the trade-off b e tw ee n wages and jobs, and the incentive was to choose h ig her incomes over investm ent in new employment. There was no m echanism for disciplining labor’s demand for ever-higher wages without the threat o f un em ploym en t from profit-maximizing private owners (and therefore an end to self-management). Governments then 1
T h e rb o rn , for exam ple, warns against evaluating such corporatist mechanisms apart
from foreign-trade policy- Fin din g that wage restraint was not correlated with either full em p lo ym en t o r successful international com petitiveness and, further, that the cost ol labor p e r unit o f output as expressed in national currencies had no statistical relation to that cost expressed in international currency, he concludes that for O E C D countries in 1973-84, as least, “incom es policies can b e made as well as unmade by currency policies and changes in th e exchange rates” (Why Some Peoples Are More Unemployed than Others, 17). Waller stein, “C entralized Bargaining and W age R estra in t,” also questions the corporatist argu m ents about wage restraint.
S L OV E NI A AN D F OCA
261
compounded the error by softening the bud get constraints on firms and by m aking new investm ents that w ere politically motivated and uneconomic— b oth policies aimed, it was said, at protecting jobs. In fact, a primary goal o f the introduction of workers’ councils in 1 9 4 9 -5 0 was to depriv e unions of their bargaining power over wages in export-producing firms at a time when skilled labor was scarce. E le c te d representatives o f skilled production workers w ere to b e consulted by managers on how to cut labor costs. T h e aim was to have workers accept limits on wages and benefits within enterprise net revenue, approve capital investm ents even if they cut into incomes, and sanction dis missals o f workers w h en required by budgets or modernization p ro grams. T h e e ss e n ce o f self-m anagem ent as it was extend ed to ev e r more public-sector workplaces over time was this attem pt to enforce incomes policies and financial discipline without state involvem ent or central re g ulation. T h e trade-offs b etw ee n wages and investm ent (or, as the Yugo slavs put it, b etw ee n short-term pay and long-term income) w ere to be left to the “work collectives” o f public-sector workplaces. M oreover, consulting workers on their wages and on e m ploym ent questions within the firm was only one aspect o f the Yugoslav lead ers’ program for full e m ploy m ent. This program aimed both to utilize labor throughout the incom e-paying public sector in ways that kept productiv ity rising above consumption (creating capital and thus the capacity to employ) and to provide, temporarily, subsistence in a free private sector for all those who could not b e employed immediately in the public sector without defeating the first goal. W ithin the public sector, according to the leaders econom ic ideology, investm ents would prom ote capital by expanding productive capacity within a territory or capital intensity within a firm. In investm ent choices, labor productivity and a rising gross national product would take priority over e m p lo y m e n t if the two w ere in conflict.2 F irm s w ere to increase labor productivity— by keeping their bill for wages and benefits in line with productivity gains, capitalizing labor through m achinery and edu ca tion, and intensifying the use o f labor to cut relative costs. “R evalu ation” of labor, ra th er than its “devaluation” (falling wages and unem plo yment), required in v e stm e n t as well in improving the skills and education o f e m ployed workers and in retraining workers in line with technological modernization. T h e system o f direct econ om ic incentiv es also had to b e protected. Thus, the rights to self-m anagem ent o f work collectives had to be p e ri odically review ed and revived. Incom e inequalities within branches, 2
Burger,
Yugoslavia, 208.
K ester,
and den O udem ,
Self-Management and Investment Control in
262
CHAPT ER 8
windfall profits, market-driven rather than productivity-driven wages, and labor tu rnover all had to be counteracted to prevent market allocation o f labor, which would underm ine these incentives. W h ile firms were not to b e penalized by im ported costs over which they had no control, they also had to transfer to social use (through taxation for investment, local wage funds, and social services) a portion o f their income that reflected a m arket advantage o f which they w ere chance beneficiaries. Governm ent standards for wage differentials and jo b classifications aimed to bring in c o m e shares into line with individual “capital’’ (the capacity to raise pro ductivity, called “each according to his abilities” and “equal share for equal work un der equal conditions ”).3 Redundant labor was not to be fired, b ut “reassigned”— w h ere possible— to jo bs more in line with the p e rs o n ’s skills. S ocie ty also n e ed e d to be reorganized periodically to prevent the accu mulation o f unproductive e m ploy m ents— such as g overnm ent bureau cracy and administrative positions— and red uce them instead to a minim um . Social services w ere to b e financed by firms (through direct grants, local taxation, their provision within the firm, or contract) so that expend itures on nonproductive activities would b e governed by the limits o f achieved productivity. E ver-exp and ing socialization, by which employ m e n t in the public sector would expand and g overnm ent budgets decline in favor o f autonomous (self-managed) financing, would incorporate ever m o re o f society into the econom ic regim e o f “incom e relations. ” That is, more and more people would be employed in the system o f productivityo riented work incentiv es o f industrial organization and financial disci pline, in which earnings and benefits would reflect o n e ’s relative capacity to pro du ce and would re p re s en t a share o f realized incom e (though not more). j o b security, therefore, was not a right to a jo b , but a right to a guaran teed minimum wage for people who had publie-sector jo bs. (Temporary jo b security, however, aimed to p rotect the direct link betw een economic in te rest and political rights: there were prohibitions against firing people while they held ele cte d positions— as managers, m e m b ers of workers’ councils, or delegates to assem blies.) Protection against unemployment lay only in the legal limits on private e m ploy m ent and on the sale of land, so that smallholdings in the private sector could act as a safe haven when p u blie-sector growth was not sufficient to accom modate all those desiring e m p lo y m e n t (that is, a public-seetor job). In other words, because new e m p lo y m e n t was to b e limited by real econom ic growth b ut unemploy m e n t was to b e avoided, the relevant trade-off was seen not as the one b e tw e e n wages and jo bs, but as one betw ee n public-sector employment 3 Law on L a b o r Relations of 1965, cited in Yugoslav Survey 8, no. 3 (August 1967): 22.
S LOV E NI A AN D F OČA
263
and the private reserve. Instead of adjusting wages and the level o f e m ployment according to profits, firms and g overnm ent regulations would adjust by moving people b e tw ee n the two sectors. People who had guar anteed smallholdings in agriculture or crafts, w ere supported by families, or were working abroad could await expansion o f the public-seetor with out fear for their subsistence. Unemployment under Yugoslav socialism was not a result o f wage p res sure, guaranteed jo b security, or insufficient savings (the savings rate was comparatively h ig h 4 and investm ent generally ran around 4 0 p e rc e n t of gross material product).5 Its explanation lies with the disconnection b e tween the program for full e m ploy m ent and the two sets of conditions within which it was operating— its international e n vironm ent 011 the one hand (as discussed in the previous chapter) and the dom estic labor supply on the other. G ov ernm ental policy to adjust to that international environment was in fact a set o f param eters for labor use. If trade def icits required cuttin g dom estic dem and and expanding exports— the stabilization policy for thirty-two years out o f forty-two— then incomes and em ploym ents had to adjust. I f difficulties in foreign markets or na tional security requ ired shifts in production or limited growth, then the entire organization o f society might be affected, not ju s t particular firms. Instead o f th e condition posed in B en jam in W a rd ’s Illyrian model o f the backward-sloping supply curve o f labor under labor m anag em ent— how workers’ councils would respond to an increase in dem and for their products— a far m ore com m on condition facing self-managed firms was the opposite: how would m anag em ent and workers’ councils respond to a drop in dem and or to stabilization-oriented restrictions on money, credit, and imports intended to force firms to use internal reserves m ore effi ciently and finance m ore of their own investm ents? Shifts in the cou n try’s terms o f trade in foreign m arkets— such as the market dem and most c o m mon in trade with th e W e s t and long-term supply contracts in trade with the East and S ou th — and in the kinds o f com modities in dem and affected the m easure o f productivity and the accom panyin g incentiv es of gov ern ment regulations. Alongside the n eed for international adju stment, econom ic d ev elop ment led to a rural exodus and population increase. T h e lead ers’ goal of a technologically advanced, highly productive, administratively lean, fullemployment econom y within the context o f the cou ntry’s international position ca m e to b e realized in only a small part o f Yugoslav territory— above all in Slovenia. T h e r e the norm throughout the postwar period was labor shortages rath er than surplus; the agricultural labor surplus had 4 Bergson , "E n tre p re n e u rsh ip under Lab o r Participation,” 207, 5 Babic and P rim orac, “S om e Causes of the Grow th o f the Yugoslav External D e b t , ” 78.
264
CHAPTER 8
b e e n exhausted by early commercialization o f agriculture and early indus trialization, and population increase was low as a result of w o m e n ’s em ploy m ent and rising wages and household incomes. In most of the country, however, the norm was a growing disharmony b etw een govern m ental policies and/or international conditions on the one hand and the labor-supply conditions o f the locality or re public on the other. Institu tional reforms that aimed to improve financial discipline increased this disharm ony. Decentralization and socialization pareelized labor markets and cre a te d e v er-greater differences betw ee n the size o f a local labor sur plus and th e ec o n o m ic resources for its employment. T h e result was growing un em p lo y m en t, which was unevenly spread across regions and social groups.
P r o m o t in g
P r o d u c t iv it y
K id ric’s early insistence on the “law o f v a lu e ,” on an econom y that re spected th e “equilibrium conditions o f growth, ” occurred at a time of dire international conditions and a severe drought. As the previous chapter argued, how ever, these two conditions— insufficient export earnings in relation to im port needs or d eb t obligations, and low productivity of a griculture— continued to requ ire policy adju stments to restore equilib rium conditions. Thus, the reason that data oil un em ploym ent reflect the chronology o f policy aimed at adjusting to international conditions (affect ing trade, capital availability, and national defense) is that those condi tions set the limits o f public-seetor e m ploy m ent and the policies toward labor that, in restoring external equilibrium , aimed to reestablish condi tions for eco n o m ic growth at home. In the very specific adju stments to agricultural policy, government em ploym ent, lines o f industrial production, and income regulations, there non eth eless operated two very different ideological approaches, sometimes in com bination and som etim es in opposition. T h e s e two approaches— the models o f Slovenia and F o c a that e m erged from the wartime and immedi ate postwar period — had differential conseq uences for localities, regions, and eco n o m ic interests b ecause of the territorial organization o f economic m a n ag e m e n t and investm ent. T h e S lovene model, a “liberal” approach to econom ic growth within a socialist econom y , focused on the incentives to manufacturing and pro cessing firms o f export markets and consum er dem and in retail markets. It em phasized “world-market standards o f p roductivity,” price competi tion, and com m ercial orientation with its pressures for technological modernization— lowering unit labor costs while capitalizing labor with m achines and higher skills. Intensification and concentration (through cartels or vertically integrated firms) were pushed both by policy and by
S L OV E NI A A N D F OČA
265
firms strategies to gain market advantage. Policy encouraged the flex ibility to hire and fire in response to market dem and and the market provision o f collective consumption (benefits, welfare, and social services) in the interest o f enterp rise savings and d em and-oriented efficiencies. The F o ca model, a developm entalist approach, focused instead on the production o f raw material, energy, infrastructure, produ cers’ goods, and food for hom e consum ption as well as export, largely on long-term co n tract or in response to price-inelastic dem and. It therefore emphasized quantity increases that d ep end ed more on steady work, labor discipline, skills adapted to production, and shop-floor flexibility. Goods w ere to be allocated within workplaces as incentiv es to com m itm ent, and econom ic and administrative functions w ere to be incorporated (“socialized”) into firms to cut transaction costs and nonproductive services. D ece n tra liz a tion and divisionalization aimed to break-up industrial concentratio n (even w here policy in a liberal phase had encouraged it) so as to improve the directness o f work incentiv es, the visibility o f the relation b etw ee n productivity and reward, and accountability for budget constraints.6 The face o f self-m anagem ent in the first model was autonomy: the rights o f work collectives (enterprises) to retain th eir earnings and the authority o f managers and professional staff. In the second, it was partici pation: the rights of production workers to discuss ways o f raising their productivity while limiting their aggregate income. B u t in both ap proaches to the organization o f production and the con cep t o f produc tivity, the societal approach to econom ic growth through increasing pro ductivity required a progressive reduction or socialization o f no nproduc tive activities— that is, the state and public services. Alternation b etw een these approaches and their corresponding labor policies follows the p e ri odization set out in the previous chapter for international adju stment.
1952-1957 The mixture o f the S lovene and F oca approaches was particularly clear in the first period of th e new reg im e because o f the continuing insecurity o f international conditions. T h e g overnm ent proceed ed with its hopeful commitments to dem obilize the arm y and shift to civilian production and light manufactu ring for export and dom estic consu m er goods, but e x te r nal threats interrup ted on occasion. T h e capital investments o f the fiveyear plan and foreign credits provided the conditions for the lead ers’ preferred liberal policy toward labor within a context o f capital dev elop 6
T h e push for decentralization and divisionalization in the 1970s parallels similar d evel
opments in o th e r countries. S e e , for exam ple, Shapiro and Kane, “Stagflation and th e New Right”; and How ell, “T h e D ilem m as o f P ost-F ord ism .”
266
CH A P T E R 8
m ent: to increase d om estic savings and growth by industrializing both m anufactu ring and agriculture in the socialized sector, favoring mecha nization, few er workers, and a smaller federal budget. T h e fulfillment of K a rd e lj’s prediction that agricultural machinery would begin to roll off production lines in 1953 made it possible to reduce the labor force on state farms and in labor cooperatives. T h e 1953 agrarian reform and gov e r n m e n t subventions encouraged intensive cropping and small rural in dustries so as to b e able to return the “relieved” labor to the private sector. Private artisans w ere granted the right to em ploy up to five wage laborers (o ther than family m em bers), as w ere private farmers (subject to special taxation). In factories, workers’ councils (still only at the level of branch associations) gained more freedom in decisions on wages and em ploy m e n t in ord e r to make the necessary labor cuts and improve wage incentives to productivity. A bankruptcy law e n te red the books, and the discussion o f wage norms and labor rationalization in journal articles be trays the Taylorist ideology o f eng ineers and skilled workers at the time.7 Although th e social plan for 1954 proposed a growth rate of 8 percent for e m p lo y m e n t b ut 17 p e rc e n t for ou tp u t,8 the skilled workers and engi ne ers on the w orkers’ councils had b een so zealous in their firing in 1950 5 2 that e m p lo y m e n t expanded instead when factories found they had to re hire essential m aintenance workers. T h e explosion o f aggregate wages, due to th e h ig her wages voted for managerial staff and skilled workers and unplanned increases in actual e m ploym ent, led the governm ent to rein troduce wage regulations. In line with constitutional jurisdictions, local gov ernm ents w ere given the authority to impose limits on personal in com es w h ere ne cessa ry.9 B u t local g overnm ents w ere at the time faced with two huge tasks: finding em p loy m e n t for dem obilized soldiers and sacked political func tionaries, 10 and providing for the benefits, housing, construction work, and o th e r services perform ed until then by the m ilitary .11 To economize on local finances, governm ental reforms w ere introduced. Smaller com m unes w e re consolidated into larger units, local social services such as e le m e n ta ry education w ere divested onto “self-m anagem ent” footing, and the many local offices created in the fall o f 1948 to im plem ent the fiveyear plan w e re closed. E v e n so, local expenditures soared with the de7 S e e , for exam ple, D ere ta, “O nekim osnovnim pokazateljima rad no snage,” 8 Ekonomska Politika , M arch 4, 1954, 191 9 S e e especially W ard , “Fro m Marx to B a ro n e .” 10 T h e n u m b er o f party functionaries was halved in 1 9 5 2 -5 4 , and the federal bureaucracy was reduced from 4 7 ,3 1 0 workers in 1948 to 10 ,3 2 8 in 1956 (Hondius, The Yugoslav Com
munity o f Nations, 191). 11 F o r exam ple, th e military-party commissions on national security, the KNOJ, were disbanded b etw ee n the en d of 1952 and M arch 1953, and the functions of state security were transferred to civilian agencies.
SL O VE NI A AN D F OČA
267
mand for new housing, pensions, and public-sector jo bs. B ecau se lo calities cop ed by imposing tax rates so high that enterprises w ere left without working capital, the federal gov ernm ent reim posed controls on local fiscal a u th o rity .12 Federal legislation formalized the new system in 1955 with a new wage system and a proposed new Law on L abo r Relations. T h e previous wage norms and p iece rates w ere translated into general regulations to guide the writing o f e n te rp rise statutes on pay, which w ere then s u b je ct to ap proval by w o rk ers’ councils in order to institutionalize fu rther the selfdisciplining role o f “w orkers’ control” in wage decisions. W orkers would receive a guaranteed minim um wage “advanced” e ach month, but beyond that, incomes in th e socialized sector would no longer b e treated as a cost of production b ut as a share o f the net value added in production. M o r e over, personal incomes could not b e paid (or docked, if the net was nega tive) until all costs, taxes, and depreciation had b ee n d educted from the market value o f that output in the end-of-year accounting. Thus, three years b efo re the g o v ernm ent abandoned sectoral investm ent and plan ning by global proportions in favor o f territorial banks and planning within republics, the basis o f e conom ic calculation shifted to enterprise prof itability (net revenue) and end ed the means for econom ywide calculation of labor p ro d u ctiv ity .13 Accordingly, workers’ councils w ere extended to the enterprise itself, and the right to hire and fire workers— not m anag e ment staff— was transferred from the directo r to the workers council (which had two standing commissions, one for hiring and firing and one for discipline). Although the decisions had b ee n made and w ere b eing im plem ented , political quarrels over this change in dev elopm en t strategy and the vic tory o f the incom e school and its marginalist approach did not fully abate, delaying until 1957 th e first congress o f workers’ councils (it had b ee n planned for 1954 to ce le b r a te the new system) as well as the new Law on Labor R elations codifying the changes since 1 9 4 8 . 14 Opposition also d e 12 S e e W a rd ’s discussion o f th e “dead brigades” used in en terprises as a way o f reducing their accou nting profits and therefo re th eir taxes under the steeply progressive profits taxes before 1955 (“T h e F irm in Illyria,’' 5 8 4 -8 5 ) . 13 T h is new wage system is called th e victory o f the incom e school (dohodovna struja, or
dohodoci) o ver th e developm entalists; see D abćević-K u ear e l al., Problemi teorije i prakse socijalističke robne proizvodnje But this Croatian faction also had many m em b ers from Serbia. 14 T h e law was enacted in M arch 1957, It codified each period of labor regulations on the rights and statuses o f em ployed persons, and thus th e principles o f incom e distribution, jo b classification, and hiring and firing according to which en terprise statutes, rule books, and compacts with o th e r firms and governm ents w ere w ritten and enforced. R esearchers in Belgrade com plained, h ow ever, that m any people, such as shepherds (čobani), still had no regulated em plo ym en t status, or radni odnos (Privreda FNHJ u periodu ¡947-1956, 161).
268
CHAPTER 8
layed the seventh party congress, scheduled for 1956, until 1958. Accord ing to political leaders, this opposition cam e from those who considered the renew ed emphasis on labor productivity as the measure of growth to be a strike against the countryside. B u t international security also played a role; th e re was a b r ie f return to defense mobilization in 1 9 5 6 - 5 7 b e cause o f revived insecurities on the eastern front and the impending end o f U .S . military aid. T h e youth labor brigades were brought back, and the em p loy m e n t o f professional party cadres increased in factory subunits. A ste ep ju m p in output norms for coal production at the same time that incom es d eclined under the stabilization of 1957 led to the first acknowl edged postwar labor strike;— at the Trb ov lje mine in Slovenia— at the end o f th e y e a r . 15
1958-1967 N onetheless, by January 1958, institutional changes in the system of wages and investm ent were reaffirmed by international conditions, and the liberal policy cam e much more clearly into its own. T h e application to G A T T , the further opening to W e ste rn trade in line with W estern E u ropean d ev elopm en ts, and the modernization of industrial production through imported technology to improve productivity in existing plants all required massive changes in the e m ploy m ent structure of the social s ector to make it more com petitive and productive. U n der the code word “the human factor” and the slogan o f the “revaluation” rather than “deval uation" o f labor, the labor force in the public sector was to be “modern ized” as well by improving skills through retraining and workers’ education. Policies aimed at increasing the ratio o f skilled labor and engi neers “to operate the new m achines”16 allowed wage differentials to rise and, in order to keep a lid on the aggregate wage bill, allowed the firing of unskilled and otherwise redundant labor Postwar demobilization ex panded to the econom y with the re placem ent o f m e m b ers o f the o ld er,17 “Partisan” generatio n (who had e ntered industrial and managerial posi tions with the m eager education o f th eir prewar opportunities and on the basis o f their war record) by “skilled, schooled cad res.’’ T h e army also 15 T h e parly leadership responded by changing I lu; union leadership, installing Svetozar V ukm anović-Tem po, He had b een m inister o f mining in the mobilization of 1 9 4 8 - 4 9 and the cham pion o f production workers and of the brigade system in J9 4 9 , but he was also a con vinced “liberal” on econ om ic reform and opening. As a prom inent “first fighter” and orga n izer o f the Partisan struggle in Macedonia, he could oversee the dismissals o f unskilled laborers and Partisan veterans. On this and subsequent strikes, see Jovanov, Radnički
št raj ko vi. 16 Yugoslav Trade Unions, 1964. In J9 5 7 , a special tax (“contribution”) was assessed on firms to pay for training programs (doprinos za kadrove u privredi) 17 In th e sen se o f perspective, not age (although this was not always made clear).
S L O VE NI A AND F OČA
269
made massive cuts in personnel (especially in the more highly paid officer corps) in order to pay for its initial investments in technological modernization— the purchase o f armam ents and licenses in the world market.18 F acto ries built largely under federal jurisdiction for defense self-reliance and the production o f capital goods had eith er to close or restructure to m e e t the criteria o f market profitability for international “com petitiveness” and the G A TT-defined program o f liberalization. All firms had to adjust to the market by cutting labor c o s ts .19 By I 9 6 0 , price, tax, and accounting regulations rewarded increases in fixed assets and penalized e m p lo y m e n t.20 The effect of these policies to increase growth by cutting labor, ratio nalizing its use, and investing in new capacity and eq u ip m en t could be seen in rising un em p lo y m en t already in 1 9 5 6 - 5 7 and again in 1 9 5 8 - 5 9 . But the opening of borders after 1955 provided an ou tlet— first perm anent emigration, then te mporary work. By 1960, the g ov ern m e n t’s jurisdiction over foreign affairs had led it to re en ter the field o f e m ploy m ent concerns. A Federal Bureau of E m p lo y m e n t was established with the sole respon sibility o f facilitating and regulating the cross-border flow o f Yugoslavs wishing to work temporarily in W e st Germ any, Austria, B elgium , or Sweden, b ecau se o f the g ov e r n m e n t’s interest in capturing w orkers’ hardcurrency rem ittances and negotiating their welfare rights in foreign cou n tries and also becau se of the receiving cou ntries’ requ irem ents that the flow of workers be carefully regulated.21 An additional outlet for the un employed ca m e with the push for tourist dollars in the early 1960s and the new dem and for services that could be provided by the private sector. Th e most com m on form o f restructuring in this period was vertical in te gration. C o m p etitiv e pressures abroad and especially supply difficulties at home due to d eclining agricultural productivity and recurring stabiliza1S
S e e th e discussion in weekly articles throughout 1957 in th e army newspaper,
Narodna Armijo; and T ito ’s speech to the federal assem bly in April 1958 (Tito, Tito u Skupstini, 295), 19 In Vojvodina, 5 0 p erce n t o f the firms w ere “nonaecu in illative”; they, along with others (such as th e m achine industry and crafts), complained about this damaging shift, which would undervalue th eir output even m ore (Narodna Armijo , issues for August 1957). 20 Horvat argues that until 1960 taxation created capital-saving inducem ents but after 1964 stim ulated labor-saving practices, making thousands of workers redundant; that the shift to payroll taxation in 1965, tog eth er with social-insu ranee contributions, made labor 60 percent m ore expensive “than necessary”; and that the Hat rates introduced a rigidity into econom ic b eh avior that tend ed to intensify business cycles (he cites a study by the eco n o mist Peri) Ju rkov ic in 1972 showing that the levy o f taxes on factors o f production rather than on business results p reven ted “elastic cushions in recessions and boom s”) (The Yugoslav
Economic System, 2 3 6 - 3 8 , 244). 21 T h e 1963 constitution added a new federal agency, the Council for the Question of Expatriates, which essentially dealt with workers abroad (see Hondius, The Yugoslav Com munity o f Nations, 295).
270
CH A P T E H 8
tion restrictions on credit and imports led firms to concentrate assets and to increase technical and com m ercial econom ies of scale for more effec tive com petition in foreign and local markets. T h e stabilization policy of 1961, which included a moratorium on new investment, tightened credit, and the expectation that firms would finance their own capital invest m ents (above all from internal funds), was even accompanied by a political campaign for integration in 1 9 6 1 - 6 2 . 22 To guarantee supplies and prices over a longer period when import restrictions, currency devaluation, and rising costs in agriculture w ere creating production bottlenecks, firms in tegrated th e ir suppliers or established long-term contractual relations, and the p ro du cers’ associations that w ere organized around supply and pricing functions (the branch cartels in each republic) w ere strengthened. Successful conglom erates, particularly the lucrative export-import trade firms, “saved” failing firms by assuming their debts in easy takeovers. Industrial firms enlarged to increase their bargaining power over the new com m ercial banks, which now allocated cre d it— but they did so through m ergers and buyouts instead o f by hiring new employees. In th eir super visory role over public firms, local governments perm itted firms with losses to remain in business if they m erged with profitable ones and ac ce p te d cuts in administrative staff and w orkers.23 T h e same process of rationalization o f resource use through concentration occurred in govern m ental administration, as the n u m b e r o f com m unes was reduced from 3 ,8 1 1 to 7 5 9 in 1962. B urd e n e d with eve r-g rcater tasks in relation to their resources, however, com m u nes b ecam e in fact more d ep end ent on re publican and federal funds. T h e 1963 constitution therefore encouraged the pooling o f budgetary funds among associations o f com m unes; in 1964, richer and poorer com m unes w ere encouraged to unite so as to increase their ability to finance the local infrastructure and social services for which they w ere now responsible. In 1964, the republics of BosniaIle rze g ov in a , Serbia, and M acedonia abolished district governments e n tir e ly .24 In support o f the liberal orientation to the econom ic incentive of con sum er d em and, and in part to relieve some of the burden of liberalized
22
Tliis c a m p a i g n was id e n ti fi e d e sp e c ia ll y w it h T i t o ’s N o v e m b e r 1961 s p e e c h in Skopje
(sec M a c e s i c h , Yugoslavia: The Theory and Practice o f Development Planning, 87), 21 S u c h m o v e s w e r e u su all y re s is te d , s o m e t i m e s succe ssf ull y, b y w o r k e r s councils; see
Yugoslav Trade Ihiions, no. 12 ( A p r i l - J u n e 1964): 6 6 - 6 7 , 7 0 - 7 1 . W o r k e r s in a profitable firm in M a c e d o n i a s t a g e d a s tr ik e la st in g forty-five day s in A u g u s t a n d S e p t e m b e r 1985 when t h e c o m m u n e g o v e r n m e n t (an d p a r t y o rg a niz a tio n) d e c i d e d to m e r g e it w it h an unprofitable firm to re s o l v e t h e l a t t e r ’s e c o n o m i c difficulties (a u th o r s in t e r v i e w s in B el g ra d e , 1985). 21 S e e C a r t e r o n t h e co n fu s io n a n d c o m p e t i t i o n th a t this i n t r o d u c e d in to th e el ect io ns of 1967 b e c a u s e c a d r e d e c i s io n s h a d p r e v i o u s l y b e e n m a d e by t h e di s tr ic t p a rt y c om m it te e
(Democratic Reform in Yugoslavia , 6 1 - 6 2 )
S LOVE NI A AN D FOČA
271
(that is, higher) prices on the population, the g overnm ent introduced co n sumer credit in 1 9 6 0 - 6 1 . B u t such an increase in m oney independ en t of production put an even greater prem ium on controlling labor costs. A semiofficial study in 1 9 6 1 - 6 2 supported the campaign to intensify labor use in existing firms with estim ates o f hidden u n em ploym en t among in dustrial jo b h o ld e rs o f 10 to 15 p e r c e n t .25 In the recession o f 1 9 6 1 - 6 2 , when “factory em p loy m e n t opportunities declined as econom ic activity slowed [and] un em p lo y m en t r o se ,” the g overnm ent “b e ca m e relu ctant to continue to open new, high-cost, labor-intensive industrial capacities . . . [thus] layoffs o f surplus labor w ere sanctioned, political organizations ad vising e nterprises that workers who owned land or had other nonwage income should b e discharged first.”26 Fighting inflationary pressures fu rther in 1962, the gov ernm ent began to negotiate incom es policies at the federal and republican levels in a process that was to b e c o m e the prim e m ethod o f wage regulation. Al though it still set central guidelines for enterprise statutes on income distribution, the g ov ernm ent began with proposals from the produ cers’ associations for wage rates for industrial sectors, sent them for review to the United Unions organization, and then sent them to the republics to be adapted into republic-level social compacts. E n fo r ce m e n t was in cluded in the supervisory role o f local governments, which inspected the cash accounts o f e nterprises from which incomes w ere paid and p e ri odically sent inspectors from the banks’ social-accounting office to exam ine enterprise books. To cut public expenditures and leave enterprises with greater r e sources for investm ent, a new round o f socialization extended self management to public services such as education and health care. E x pected to respond to consu m er dem and (“strengthening the role o f p e r sonal incom e in financing social r e q u i r e m e n t s ”),27 em ployees in social services w e re given rights o f self-m anagem ent as an incentiv e to greater efficiency through voluntary wage rationalization. That is, they w ere now free to adjust salaries within the limits o f their budget (according to the principles of the “in c o m e ” system and “pay according to re s u l ts ”) .28 In turn, g reater efficiency and the market allocation o f social services would make it possible to cut enterprise taxes and re duce internal funds set aside for “collective consumption goods.” 25 Livingston gives th e source o f th ese estim ates only as “unpublished official data” in his careful article (“Yugoslavian U nem ploym ent T re n d s,” 757; see also 760). 26 Ib id ., 7 5 6 - 5 7 . At the sam e tim e that massive layoffs occurred in May 1962, taxes on the private secto r increased sevenfold, elim inating ten thousand artisans— “barb ers, black smiths, cob b le rs, tailors, pastry makers” (M acesich, Yugoslavia, 203). 27 T h e social plan o f 1 9 6 4 -7 0 , 2HYugoslav Trade Unions, no* 10 (S ep te m b e r 1963): 3 0 - 3 5 ,
272
CHAPT ER 8
T h e most explicit statem ents o f the conception underlying the liberal system are found in the s peeches of the eighth party congress, held in D e c e m b e r 1964, b ecau se it marked the end o f the liberals’ domestic polit ical battles against the developmentalists. T h e leaders began with the a n n o u n ce m e n t that Yugoslavia had e n te red the ranks o f the moderately d eveloped countries becau se per capita income had reached about $500. H ig h er wages and a shorter workday w ere victories of the workers’ move m ent, Tito claim ed in ju stifying the campaign to intensify the use o f exist ing capacities. T h e reduction o f the official workweek after 1963 from forty-eight to forty-two hours was their “second industrial revolution-’ be cause it replaced the rural day schedule with industrial (“standard E u ropean ) working hours and forced peasant-workers and moonlighters to make a choice for one work relation. 29 T h e workweek was reduced fur th e r to forty hours in 1965 (with one hour overtim e perm itted), to thirtyeight (plus one) in 1 9 6 6 - 6 9 , and to thirty-six (plus one) in 1970. T h e congress was followed at the beginning o f 1965 by a new Law on L a b o r Relations that codified the changes since 1957 and extended legal pro tections to workers in private hire. T h e first federal (“basic”) law on e m p lo y m e n t attem pted to rationalize the organization and financing of em p loy m e n t bureaus and the principles o f jo b classification and retrain ing. T h e liberal approach was even clearer in the policy objectives of the social plan for 1 9 6 6 —70. It proposed that in order to ensure optimal pro portions with regard to the rate of em ploym ent, available accumulation, the level of labour productivity and living standards, it will be necessary to d ece lera te the rate of e m ploym ent in relation to preceding periods, especially in the first years o f the planned period, when, as a result of the reform, existing relative surpluses of manpower will be the first to he absorbed and more economically e m p lo y e d .”30 T h e emphasis on com m ercial profitability in foreign and domestic mar kets intensified in response to the severe recession o f 1 9 6 5 - 6 6 and declin ing W e s te rn dem and. W ith respect to labor, this emphasis was manifest in pressure on firms to increase middle-m anagem ent staffs and marketing d ep artm ents and give them more autonomy to respond to market condi tions.31 T h e guiding policy line was “to reduce costs o f production in gen eral and costs o f production pe r unit o f output, reducing above all the participation ol labor, in order to increase the com petitiveness of the Yugoslav econom y on the international m a rk e t.”32 T h e managerialist trend was re flected in constitutional am end m ents that sought to free man2” I l o n d i u s , The Yugoslav Community o f Nations. 321, n. 561 ,(1 Yugoslav Federal Assembly 4. n o 7 (1966); 12. 11 F o r a s t u d y o f tw o B e l g r a d e m a n u f a c t u r i n g firms d u r i n g this p e ri o d , s e e Adizes, Indus
trial Democracy, Yugoslav Style. 95. 32 Soškić, "T rži šni s is te m so cijalističke p r i v r e d e i r e f o r m a . ’'
SL OV E NI A AN D F OCA
273
agers from the oversight o f the m anag em ent board (with its two-thirds representation o f production workers). 33 University reform and expansion aimed to train professional strata while diverting youth’s dem and for jo bs into longer education. A new push for vocational education at the liighschool level re ce iv e d foreign assistance.34 Labor regulations re e m p h a sized the responsibility o f enterprises as well in training and retraining their em ployees, and the legal obligation to accept one trainee for every fifty em ployees and to employ them after two years was reinstated. Yet the rise o f skill cre dentials pushed up aggregate wages, because wage rates w ere tied to skill level and educational certification. Thus, additional dismissals w ere ne cessary .35 T h e greater reliance on market allocation o f social services and benefits was also cuttin g the purchasing power o f wages. L ess well paid blu e-collar workers responded with wage strikes, and the union op ened a fight to reassert the principle of “socialist distribution according to work” (that is, in term s of output productivity and thus ad ju sted for inflation).36 Conflicts b etw een m arket-oriented di rectors and workers opposed to their disciplinary decisions,37 and b e tween union leaders and their rank and file over wage inequalities and dismissals, culm inated at the end o f 1967 with the removal o f Svetozar Vukmanović-Tempo from the presidency o f the unions when he polemicized publicly against m arket-oriented managerial in te re s ts ,38 33 T h e trend was reflected above all in A m endm ent 15, adopted in D e c e m b e r 1968. It permitted the transfer o f authority over hiring and firing to the director and professional organs within m anag em en t— such as th e stručni kolegijum, or council o f exp ert advisers to the director
T h at authority was reversed in the am endm ents o f 1971 and in the 1974
constitution.
34 O E C D technical assistance through the M editerranean P ro je ct initiated discussions on reforming secondary education to increase vocational training, discussions that b ore fruit in experiments in Split and Vojvodina in 1 9 6 9 -7 1 and in a major reform o f secondary education after 1972, T h e r e w ere similar developm ents in university expansion and secondary-school reform in W e ste rn E u ro p e at th e tim e (for exam ple, in F ra n c e and Italy). T h e se reforms presumed an ability to plan m anpower effectively, but the linear assumptions o f the manpower-planning m odel on which th e O E C D project was based precluded such an abil ity, according to th e critical analysis by D oran and D e e n , “T h e U se o f L in ea r D ifferen ce Equations in M anpow er Plan n ing.” 35 Adizes’s study of* two Serbian en terprises during this period provides rarely available information on th e choices firms made. W h ile workplaces paid the costs o f em p lo yees’ extra training, Adizes reports that in o n e o f th e textile firms h e studied in 1967, anyone who had not acquired th e desired training by 1970 was to be transferred automatically to another workplace or jo b classification ( Industrial Democracy, Yugoslav Style, 50)
36 Yugoslav Trade Unions, no. 11 (Ja n u a ry -M a rc h 1964), S e e also Rusinow, The Yugoslav Experiment; C a rter, Democratic Reform in Yugoslavia; and Jovanov, Radnički štrajkovi. 37 T h e trade-union newspaper was filled with stories o f such conflicts during 1964. 38 His criticism appeared in the pages o f Ekonomska Politika (E co n o m ic Policy), the liberal Belgrad e w eekly similar in style and views to The Economist o f London.
274
CHAPTER 8
New e m p lo y m e n t stagnated from 1964 to 1967 and the labor surplus in th e social sector rose, as a result o f the policies o f export orientation, e c o n o m ic liberalization, and m acroeconom ic stabilization as well as the response to these policies in industrial concentration, administrative ra tionalizations, and “modernization. ”39 W h ile m ore and more people found incomes in the private sector or abroad, many others simply with drew in d iscou ragem ent from the u n em ploym en t rolls. R evised labor leg islation in 1968 a ttem pted to reverse the situation by requiring firms to give p re fe re n c e in hiring to the unem plo yed (not new registrants but those previously em ployed and let go) when persons o f otherwise equal qualifications applied. T h e law also required firms to rehire within one year persons laid off as a result o f business losses if conditions improved. Both in 1 9 60 and in 1969, legislation sought a way around this problem of a prior obligation to persons employed in the social sector when labor costs dictated dismissals by revising pensions to encourage earlier retire ments. It is also striking, given the legal obligations o f firms to employed pregnant w om en, that a law perm itting abortions was enacted in 1960 and that in 19 6 9 wom en gained the right to contraception. At the same time, however, the changes in defense policy in 1964 fa voring the territorial d efense forces and purging the state security police (the highlight being the purge o f Rankovie in Ju ly 1966), as well as the constitutional am en d m e n ts o f 1 9 6 7 - 6 9 to republicanize the remaining federal administration (followed necessarily by the republicanization of party personnel and finances), increased the n u m b e r of people looking for jo b s in enterprises. T h e s e decentralizations, induced in part by stabiliza tion to cut spending on “nonproductiv e” salaries, w ere accompanied by a nother consolidation o f c om m unes; their nu m ber fell from 759 to 501 in 1968. T h e “socialization” o f parliament, in which representation shifted to “d ele g a tes ” from self-managed workplaces (introduced in 1967 but effec tive only after the last multicandidate elections in localities in 1969), transferred financing for d eleg ates’ salaries and perquisites from govern m e n t budgets to enterp rise in c o m e .40 This change was followed by the extension o f self-m anagem ent autonomy in 1 9 6 9 - 7 0 to the bureaus of civil servants and experts responsible for social s ervices.41 T h e effect o f cutting public expenditures, however, was to shift costs back to firms and reverse 39 O n th e hitler process, see Adizes, Industrial Democracy, Yugoslav Style, 65, '10 T h e "d elega te system " referred to social-seetor workplaces as the “b ase” (baza) o f the sociopolitical system. 11
T h e s e “self-managing com m unities o f in terest” for schools, hospitals and clinics, the
aters, roads, and public utilities w ere to manage th eir services autonomously and receive a budget directly from en terprises, which would send delegates to review expenditure plans and bud gets and to pledge “contributions” in annual meetings.
S L OV E NI A ANO F OČA
275
the process o f cuttin g taxes on enterprise income begun in the early 1960s. Instead o f creating a leaner public sector, moreover, d ecentraliza tion actually accelerated the e m ploy m ent of administrators, as W a g n e r ’s law would predict.*12
1968-1978 W orkers’ strikes, peasants pressure to form th eir own cooperatives, na tionalist eruptions after 1967 in Kosovo, Slovenia, and especially Croatia (the “mass m o v e m e n t”), and student rebellions in Sarajevo, Belgrad e, and Pristina in 1968 and in Zagreb in 1970 occupied public attention in these years. T h e social unrest led most Yugoslavs to assume that the change in economic policies (which they date from 1972, when liberal party leaders in Croatia and Se rbia w ere purged) was a political reaction against this decline in civil order. B u t the conditions for a major change in policy toward labor p re ce d e d the political crackdown and had b ee n developing outside the country. T h e shift in foreign trade after 1969 to markets in the East and South (most o f which was governed by long-term bilateral co n tracts) and the shift in dom estic production to greater concern with e n ergy, raw materials, produ cers’ goods, and strategic supplies for domestic processors and manufacturers, for the army, and for W e stern markets'43 (and therefore greater concern with transport for domestic supply routes) meant that increasing revenues dep end ed on increasing quantities more than on price com petition and marketing. W hat was identified as a co n servative reaction was in many ways a return to the production profile of the developm entalist model and its political correlates— the F o ca model. But b ecau se the changes w ere a result o f liberal policies and in no way implied a reversal of com m itm e n ts to foreign trade, openness, and co n tin uing decentralization, this was not an institutional or ideological victory for the d evelopm entalist faction as much as it was a de facto, practical one that created , as in the 1950s, a mixed system. T h e restructuring and refinancing o f foreign d ebt throughout the 1960s made external stabilization even more critical after 1969, and policy makers now identified the cause o f dom estic inflation with the u n reg u lated m arket o f the 1960s, particularly during 1 9 6 5 - 6 8 . Complaints from enterprises and unions about high turnover and absenteeism among 12
Goati reports that th e n um b er o f officials grew 0 .6 percent annually in 1 9 6 5 -7 2 , when
social-sector em ploym en t grew less than 2 .0 p ercen t a year; but it rose 7 4 percent annually in 1 9 7 2 -8 7 , when social-sector em ploym ent grew 4 .2 percent a year (“Savetovanje”). •n Yugoslav exports in the 1970s w ere increasingly com posed o f primary com m odities and lower-value-added goods; see E co n om ic Com m ission for E u rope, “T h e Relative P erfor mance o f South Eu ro pean E x p o rts,”
276
CHAPTER 8
skilled workers who earned second incomes in the informal market con tribu ted to this vie w ,44 while the anti-inflationary program took particular aim at m anag ers’ high salaries and the bonuses they received for turning a com m e rcial profit. T h e export o f labor services had probably reduced po litical d iscon ten t over un em plo y m en t and provided critical hard cur rency, but by 1970 the gov ernm ent had b e co m e increasingly concerned about th e brain drain o f technical experts and skilled workers to Western E u ro p e . It sought ways to persuade them to retu rn and attem pted to limit labor emigratio n to unskilled workers for whom there w ere no jo bs at h o m e . 43 T h e num erous reasons for renew ed attention to production skills, in cluding a rising rate o f jo b vacancies in the midst of rising unemployment, conv erg ed in a raft o f new legislation on labor and education. T h e 1974 Law on E m p lo y m e n t expressed renewed concern for manpower plan ning, legally obliging firms to p ro je ct their manpower needs and develop training plans, increase the n u m b e r of trainees, and give them permanent positions after they com p leted their training period. T h e new defense d octrine o f all-national defense rein troduced universal conscription and obligatory military-training courses in high schools and universities.46 F irm s and local governm ents b e ca m e the c e n te r of the system of defense; th e y w ere obliged to maintain stockpiles o f necessities and weapons and to re q u ire persons employed in the public sector to undergo regular, ac tive training in the reserves. A reform o f secondary education ended the traditional two-track system o f gimnazije (the university-directed liberalarts high schools, similar to the lycée or gymnasium) and technical schools (for vocational education directed at im m ediate employment). A compre hensive system e xtend ed general education two years beyond elementary 44 S e e D y k er on th e rules against private-sec tor activity, such as the ban on import oí sem ifinished goods for private businesses in July 1971 and the prosecution oí “business crim es” in 1973 (Yugoslavia: Socialism, Development, and Debt, 83).
45 Public discussions on em igration began in early 1970, and legislation appeared in Feb ruary 1973 (Tanić, “Yugoslavia”). Many forces converged in this concern: the Slovene gov ern m e n t faced shortages o f technical exp ertise and was co ncerned about the replacement of Slo ven e em igrants with people from oth er regions o f Yugoslavia; Croat em igres in Germany reputedly had a role in the nationalist “mass m ovem ent” o f 1 9 6 7 -7 1 (a primary charge by the federal party leadership against Croatian leaders Savka D abčević-K u čar and MikoTripalo at th e Karadjordjevo “accounting” o f D e c e m b e r 1971); the YPA leadership was apparently co n c ern e d about the depletion o f essential dom estic skills; and debates in the federal assem bly w ere dom inated by th e general view that the social costs o f educating these skilled m igrants w ere not being recouped. T h e 1973 law on labor migration gave preference to the unem ployed and forbade those who had not com pleted their military service to emigrate. 46 T h e outflow o f reserve and retired officers into the civilian sector was not sufficient to m eet th e dem and for trained military instructors, so that five universities opened depart m ents for national-defense studies in 1975 (B eb ler, “D evelop m ent o f Sociology o f Militaría in Yugoslavia”).
S L O VE NI A AN O F OČA
277
school and required universal vocational specialization thereafter in order to increase the supply o f production-related and technical skills and r e duce the supply o f skills for which dem and was declining .47 F irm s offered high-school youth contracts that would pay their schooling and guarantee them jo b s if they trained as technicians or skilled workers. Authorities also argued that incentives to productivity had b e e n seri ously diluted by managerial in d e p e n d en ce and the monoliths o f industrial concentration and integrated conglom erates. To revive the pressures that self-management was intended to exert on workers to increase output while k eep ing wages within th e limits of their productivity and enterprise revenue, and to red uce transaction costs further, a campaign for division alization began. E n te rp ris es and cooperatives w ere subdivided into the smallest production units capable o f in depend en t accounting because they produced a m arketable product; these units w ere nam ed “basic orga nizations of associated labor” (B O A L s ).48 In a two-decade-long quarrel among econom ists over valuation o f labor, the “specific cost o f production school” won a m om en tary victory, in 1 9 7 4 - 7 6 , over the hegem ony o f the “income school” (dohodoci ) that had lasted since 1955. T h e latter was strongest in Croatia and Slovenia (although there w ere also m e m b ers in Serbia), w here the tre atm e n t o f income as a share in value-added favored firms producing final goods for the market; the “specific cost o f pro du c tion” school, on the other hand, had long decried official disregard both for the prices paid raw-material and intermediate-goods producers and for the need to calculate labor costs in relation to fixed assets and other pro duction inputs as a measure o f efficiency within the firm. L abo r legislation in 1 9 7 4 - 7 6 refocused attention on skilled production workers and the reduction o f turnover. Increases in the salaries o f managers and other administrative or social-serviee staff (“nonproductive” employees) w ere indexed to the gains o f production workers. Although this legislation included m o re-secu re guarantees for pro du c 47
This program was initiated by the O E C D -fu n d e d M editerranean P ro ject in the
mid-1960s and taken up by school reform ers, first in Vojvodina and then in the Croatian littoral. Its m odel in th e final stages was a m ixture of, ironically, the educational system s in Sweden and th e G erm an D em ocratic R epu b lic— the countries with th e highest em ploy ment rates in E u ro p e — although its origins are found in th e polytechnical ideas o f Napoleonic reform s. L a ter, however, it cam e to b e identified with th e unpopular sociologistpolitician Stip e Šuvar, who was m inister o f education for Croatia at th e tim e it was fully implemented. T h e “šuvarica” angered middle-class parents, required local budgetary re sources to provide a fidl range o f vocational schools in accord with a freedom o f occupational choice that was unrealistic, and suffered from the planning assumptions that (as discussed in n. 34 above) characterized all such educational reforms (author’s interviews in Croatia, Slo venia, and Serb ia in 1975, 1978, and 1982). 'iH S e e Sacks, Self-Management, and Efficiency, on divisionalization and the similar trends in other countries at the tim e.
278
CHAPTER 8
tion jo b s , leading many to call the Law on Associated Labor o f 1976 a “w orkers’ constitu tion” that protected workers against unem plo ym ent, its prim ary focus was the stabilizing objectives (also seen in 1 9 4 9 - 5 0 ) o f reas serting direct incentiv es to labor productivity and reducing costly turn over and m arket-influenced wage and salary inflation. Accordingly, it s tre n g th e n e d rules requirin g parity b etw ee n a person’s individual quali fications and j o b classification, and it stiffened penalties against workers who th rea te n e d productivity through ab senteeism , damage to social property, laziness, or lack o f work discipline (in 1977, absence five days running without prior notice required dismissal, according to Article 215 of the 19 76 law; a prison sen ten ce or reformatory confinem ent o f three months or m o re — after 1976, six months or m o re — was sufficient grounds for “te rm in a tio n ,” as was any official decision declaring a person unable to work). Services that had moved out of enterprises into autonomous bu reaus or retail markets during the 1960s, such as marketing and services provided by accountants, lawyers, and doctors, w ere now reintegrated into enterp rises to get m ore control over costs and, in the case of doctors, to p re v e n t w orkers’ use o f paid sick leave as a cover for moonlighting. M o re ove r, despite the b e lie f that there was greater jo b security, e nter prises w e re increasingly cautious about employing new perm anent labor. L a b o r regulations perm itted more flexibility to hire on temporary, part tim e, or specific-p roject contracts when a firm’s need for labor was likely to b e te m p o rary — such as when it had to replace em ployees on military or training leave, respond to an abnormal rise in market demand or a lim ited-productio n contract, or do seasonal work.49 Firm s did not fill positions vacated by retiring employees. T h e governm ent attempted to get g re a te r control over aggregate wages by reviving societywide and repu blic-n egotiated social compacts on incomes policies (largely ignored in the emphasis on managerial autonomy), even though the shift to a flexible-exchange-rate regim e and rising import prices undercut the effec tiveness o f such policies.50 T h e voluntary character o f the compacts also made them un enforceable if firms w ere unwilling.51 Furthermore, w o rk ers’ real incomes began to fall steadily, since prices rose faster than wages and enterp rise incom e was barely sufficient to pay the contractual 49 Specific-p ro ject work was done on freelance term s (honorarno), often by retired pro fessionals. T h e am ount o f part-tim e, contractual, seasonal, and overtim e work jum ped sig nificantly after th e early 1970s (see Zukin, “Practicing Socialism in a H obbesian World”). 50 In co m es policies w ere ineffective worldwide in the stagflation of the 1970s (William Nordhaus, com m en tary in discussion at the Yale University C o n feren ce on the W orld Econ om y, J u n e 1988). 51 In 1977, according to the Z agreb daily Vjesnik , 8 0 p ercen t o f all enterprises in Croatia d isregarded th e social com pacts th ey had signed; Privredni Vjesnik (Business News) re ported in J 9 7 8 that 5 0 p erce n t o f the enterprises it surveyed in Croatia ignored the com pacts.
S L O VE NI A A N D F OČ A
279
wage (som etim es not even that), let alone bonuses or profit shares. T h e rate o f u n em p lo y m en t shot skyward. W hile th e private sector had b e e n intended as a refuge for surplus labor expelled from the social sector, during the 1960s it began to generate increasing w ealth, which th e governm ent, strapped for funds, attem pted to captu re for investm ent in new workplaces. T h e G re e n Plan o f 1973 encouraged private farm ers to pool their resources in cooperatives in e x change for financial assistance to purchase modern e qu ip m ent; th e plan was in fact largely aim ed at getting W orld B ank loans that gave priority to the private s e c to r.52 It was also, however, one o f a n u m b e r o f efforts to encourage Yugoslav workers abroad to return and invest their savings in productive activities— in agriculture, services, and small busin esses— in order, authorities said enticingly, “to obtain work m o re quickly.” E m ployment plans within th e annual federal econ om ic resolutions reserved a specified n u m b e r o f jo b s for retu rnees, giving priority in em p loy m e n t to some o f their occupations. N ew laws on property rights p erm itted re tu rn ing migrants to invest their own funds in small factories in the public sector in exchange for e m p lo y m e n t— essentially, to buy them selves a jo b. In 1978, the g ov ern m e n t began to look to foreign loans specifically for e m ploym ent by establishing a special federal fund “for credits to increase em ploym ent in econom ically less developed regio ns”; the fund was to be based e n tirely on foreign monies and would encourage jo in t ventu res “where u n em p lo y m en t was g rav e.”53 A 1977 law on credit and banking opened m unicipal savings institutions to captu re private savings, e sta b lished favorable rates on loans to marginal firms to pro te ct e m ploy m ent, and g uaranteed deposits and raised interest on individual accounts through the National Bank. Private persons w ere p erm itted to open fo reign-exchange accounts in banks and w ere paid interest in dinars. L o cal gov ernm ents financed infrastructural projects, such as new e le m e n tary schools and hospitals, with bond issues and local campaigns to “increase savings.”54 52 T h e first o f th ese loans was offered in 1971 by the W orld Bank along with the UN Food and Agriculture Organization; it was granted in 1976 after m uch difficulty. T h e second loan came in 1978. T h e story o f th ese loans tells much about the Yugoslav system; see D yker, Yugoslavia, 1 5 6 - 5 7 . 53 T h e fund was established by the Law on the P rocu rem ent and Use of Foreign R e sources for the Purposes o fln cr e a sin g Em ploym en t and Providing Jobs for T hose R eturning from W ork Abroad. Its basic task was to collect resources from oth er countries on a grant-inaid or cred it basis to finance em ploym en t in economically underdeveloped regions and areas of m arked em igration. S e e the press conference of Kiro Gligorov, then president o f the federal assem bly, on Ju n e 18, 1977, cited in R F E iR A D Background R eport no 114 (Ju n e 21, 1977) from the story in Borba (Belgrade), Ju n e 19, 1977. 54 T h e citizens o f Bosnia-H erzegovina voted to pay a 3 p ercen t tax on their personal incom es for the 1984 winter O lym pic games,
280
CHAPTER 8
T h e political coloration of these labor reforms and their obvious paral lels to those o f the 1950s— together with the delay until 1974 in pro mulgating a new constitution to codify the decentralizing am endm ents of 1 9 6 7 - 7 1 and the delay o f the revised law on labor relations until 1976— contrib u ted to the perception that the changes were a reactionary re sponse to political and social turmoil. Yet, as early as 1977, managers began a revolt against the labor regulations, revisions w ere made, and party leaders insisted that managers b e given greater flexibility in dispos ing o f labor. B y 1981, enterprises had taken th eir dem ands to the legisla tures and won. T h e retu rn to an I M F -co n d itio n e d stabilization in August 1979 also initiated a new series o f wage controls and devaluations.
1979-1989 B e tw e e n 1979 and 1982, the full-fledged return to econom ic reform and exports to W e s t e r n markets in order to repay convertible-cu rrency debt necessitated rewriting labor legislation. Although the language o f ratio nalization and dismissal continued to re fer to the need for discipline on th e job, this now m eant the threat of unem plo yment. In the words of an econom ist on the Kraigher Commission, set up to draft a long-term stabi lization program acceptab le to the I M F , “a position o f em ploym ent is not a p riv ile g e .” I f no profit, then bankruptcy.55 Revised legislation now allowed firms to term inate a trainee’s employ m e n t contract after one year and to fulfill their legal obligation by putting multiple trainees into one position and choosing among them according to perfo rm ance on the jo b . L ow er budgets for social services and the mili tary due to d eclining growth forced cuts in th eir staffs. Lim its were placed on university e nrollm ents in fields with the gre atest surplus o f skills— which happened to b e liberal (noneconomic) professions, such as medi cine, dentistry, and the liberal arts and social sciences. F irm s resisted the pressure to hire additional family m e m b ers and generally excluded wom en and youth from consideration by adding the qualification in the obligatory ad vertisem ents o f jo b openings that candidates “must have co m p le te d th e ir military s e r v ic e .”56 New full-time positions carried everh igher re q u irem en ts for prior work experience, often o f a specialized na ture, and d em anded a host o f special internal qualifications and equiva lents o f formal schooling. By 1989, the Law on E nterprises, written to e n cou rag e foreign investment, gave managers fidl rights to hire and fire labor and erased the system o f self-management. Prime M inister Ante M arkovic gave top priority to privatization of public-sector firms. 55
A u th o r’s interview in Ljubljana, O cto b er 1982 Laws facilitating bankruptcy appeared
in 1987; see Knight, Financial Discipline and Structural Adjustment in Yugoslavia Ru/.a First-Dilic- first alerted me to this practice.
S L OVE NI A AN O F OČA
281
D uring the 1980s, ju s t as in the early 1960s, official concern for the em ploym ent c o n s e q u e n ces o f stabilization restrictions and export pro m o tion led to yet a nother reduction in the workday, calls for multiple work shifts, revisions of pension laws to encourage earlier re tirem en t, and some increase in the m inuscule monies for un em ploym ent compensation. Taxation also shifted back from enterprises to personal incomes, and so cial services, housing, and utilities w ere again to be financed through user fees and retail markets instead o f enterprise funds. Social compacts on incomes w ere revised to p erm it lower taxes on e n te rp ris es ’ gross wage bill on the arg u m ent that Yugoslavia’s comparative advantage in exports was in low labor costs. T h e basket o f com modities defining the guaranteed minimum wage rate b ecam e smaller in 1982. At the end of 1984, the terms o f ag re e m e n t with the I M F produced a nationwide com pact on incomes policy, signed by republican governments and sent to all basic organizations o f associated labor. T h e primary proposals for expanding e m ploym ent also relied, as b e fore, on the e n co u ra g em en t of small firms and services in the private sector (mala privredd) and on calls for redundant labor to return to agri culture. This time, however, attempts to rem ove the limits on landhold ings su cceed ed in Croatia, and later in Serbia. O nly Slovenia explicitly held out, arguing that its bord erlands were already in danger o f dep o p ulation and that smallholdings plus tax relief to private peasants w ere necessary incentives to keep the peasants there. Many republics also structured tax-relief packages to encourage em ploym ent. In Serbia, for example, beginning in 1 9 7 9 - 8 0 , tax authorities excused from taxation people in traineeships, small firms in their first year or two of business, and firms that em ployed the handicapped.57 In 1987, the g overnm ent negotiated grants from F ra n c e (30 million francs) and the Federal R e p u b lic of G e rm an y (33 million marks) to assist the return o f Yugoslav profes sionals working abroad by creating projects that would provide them with jo b s . 58 A new policy on federal aid to less-d eveloped areas o f the country al lowed republics to fulfill up to 5 0 p e rce n t of their obligations by e n co u r aging their firms to invest directly in jo in t ventu res in these areas. Like the argum ents made at the eighth party congress in 1 96 4— when liberals and developm entalists clashed on the necessity o f a fund to aid lessdeveloped areas and Tito argued for the latter to receive technical assis tance o f the kind Yugoslavia was then giving to third-world cou ntries— the new policy differentiated the econom ic space of the country accord 57 T . Ha ice vie, personal com m unication, Belgrade, N ovem ber 1982. Set1 M ates, “R ecent T en d en cie s in the Regulation of In co m e D istrib ution,” on changes in accounting rules for taxation of personal incom e 5H “R ates o f Em plo ym en t and U nem ploym ent, 1980—1 9 87 ,” 10.
282
CHAPTER
8
ing to export specialization and corresponding comparative advantage. T h e m ore-d e ve lop e d regions o f the north, as an area o f “highly modern, technically advanced export indu stries,” would invest in the south as an area o f low-wage, labor-in tensive industries “to absorb the problem of e m p l o y m e n t.”59
D is h a r m o n ie s
T h e rh eto ric o f central policy rarely stepped away from employment, but responsibility for im p lem e n tin g central policy and for em ploym ent re sided with republican and local governm ents. T h e primary investors were these republican and local governm ents, enterprises, and, in most cases, the territorial banks, which lay at the intersection o f the three by provid ing c re d it in response to governmental social plans and enterprise appli cations. T h e expansion o f productive capacity and developmental in v e stm e n t was the ju risdiction o f republican governments after 1958, and even w h ere federal investm ents continued, the republics were handed th e com p leted p rojects and thus the obligation to maintain them. E c o n o m ic planning was therefore a republican affair, in which the indus trial and sectoral policies o f structural change w ere focused on regional d ev elo p m en t using the financial resources that a re public could capture— in its territorial bank, from federal grants and subsidies, and from the foreign m onies earned or borrowed by its enterprises. At the same time, re publican authorities, like the federal governm ent, saw employment promotion as a c o m m itm e n t to growth in general. Local governments, particularly through the activities o f e m ploy m ent services that put pres sure on local officials and worked with enterprise directors, performed the function o f a market wage in capitalist countries— adjusting the (local) supply o f labor to the dem and for it. T h e c o n s e q u e n c e was a growing disjuncture over time b etw een policies addressed to th e external environm ent, guided by a particular model of growth, and th e reality o f the labor supply in the country. It was manifest in an increasing disparity b e tw ee n the dem and from the social sector of labor and the pattern o f both agrarian exodus and generational turnover. As a result especially o f th e territorialization o f capital flows (within re publics and in federally mediated transfers b etw een republics) and of hum an-capital formation (system o f schooling), there w ere “vastly differ e n t labor m ark et conditions among the various repu blics.”00 And the in 59 Proposals from the Kraigher Com m ission's working group on em ploym ent (un published version); Branislav Soskic, sp eed ) at the annual m eeting o f the Yugoslav Associa tion o f E co n o m ists, Opatija, Croatia, O c to b er 1982. (’° Sch ren k , Ardalan, and E l Tatawy, first draft o f th eir analysis o f th e W orld Bank mis sion; but see th eir Yugoslavia: Self-Management Socialism and the Challenges o f Develop ment, 2 4 4 - 4 5 , and th e detailed elaboration at 2 4 5 - 4 9 and 28 6- 315.
S LO V E N I A A N D FO ČA
283
creasing disparity over both time and space b e tw e e n dem and and supply created an e v e r-g re a te r disproportion b etw ee n n eed and resources for new in v e stm e n t at th e local level. In the re p u b lic-ce n te re d world o f statistical data and political re p re s e n tation, how ever, the reality of growing un em plo y m en t contrasted sharply with conditions in Slovenia. T h e r e the model underlying governmental policies— an industrially advanced, lean socialist core o f skilled workers and com m ercially attuned manufacturers participating fully in W e s te r n trade, a settled labor reserve o f private farmers and artisans, and a gov ernment o f experts and a local militia— seem ed to b e the cause o f full employment. It was easy to conclude that the choice o f growth strategy and accom panying institutions (including republican econom ic sover eignty) was correct, and that unem ploym en t in o ther republics, rising as one w ent east and south, was due to political in terferen ce with that model or to “cultural” differences. B u t Slovenia was also the one republic w here the initial dev elopm en tal and labor-supply conditions and existing plant on which th e original Slovene model was based actually h e ld .61 The first problem in all the o ther areas was the imbalance b etw ee n the pace o f industrial dem and for labor and the pace at which surplus labor was released from the countryside. T h e historical dim ension of differences among the republics rem ained clearest. T h e contrast was particularly sharp b e tw e e n labor-im porting Slovenia, with its early c o m mercialization o f agriculture and d ev elopm en t o f light manufacturing and its universal ele m e n ta ry education, and areas untouched by industry even in th e 1930s. T h e areas o f greatest population density w ere those where industry was least d eveloped before the war and w h ere land was scarcely arable, such as the Dalm atian hinterland and the D inaric range of H erzegovina and M o n ten eg ro (where population density in th e 1930s was as high as in C h ina or Java). T h e exodus o f Partisan veterans onto the plains o f Vojvodina and Slavonia in 1 9 4 6 - 4 7 was insufficient to p re vent the poorly d eveloped regions from remaining “regions o f e m ig ra tion.” P eople continu ed to em igrate according to prewar traditions and access to external ro utes— to the W e st, to urban c e n te rs in the poorer republics, and, eventually, to Slovenia. Policy con trib u ted to this disharmony. A d ev elop m en t strategy based for political reasons on a gradual approach to capital accumulation that took advantage o f im ported capital and existing capacity in processing and manufacturing and on federal investm ent in new capacity in heavy indus 61
In 1945, 78 p erce n t o f industry in Yugoslavia lay north o f th e D anu be-Sava line. By
1968, the proportion o f industry in th e central and eastern parts o f th e country had grown from 22 p e rce n t to 4 5 p erce n t, b u t m uch o f that was heavy and defense-oriented industry; it was not sustainable in the economically difficult decades after 1965, while light manufactur ing in th e north could b e m odernized (Hamilton, “T h e Location o f Industry in E ast-C entral and Southeast E u r o p e ,” 177, 183),
284
CHAPTER 8
try, raw-material extraction, and infrastructure for defense needs directly intensified th e inherited differences. State policies toward defense, in 1 9 3 8 - 3 9 and again in 1 9 4 7 - 4 9 , located strategic industries in the interior and left vu ln erab le borderlands declared as security zones with little in dustry (such as Vojvodina and Croatian M ed ju m urje) or with only admin istrative towns (as in Macedonia) until the 1 9 6 0 s .62 Investm ents in infrastructure also reproduced inherited geopolitical profiles: federal pro je cts (including the volu nteer brigades) and monies w ere dedicated to d efen se -o rie n te d infrastructure, largely in the interior, whereas republi can expend itures and foreign loans for infrastructure after 1960 were m ore o rien ted to foreign-trade earnings and favored areas with mored ev eloped transportation and com munication links to W e stern Europe, the tourist and shipping industries o f the Dalm atian coast, and inherited infrastructure in river valleys.63 E v e n in the 1970s and 1980s, offshore processing and assem bly w ere purposely located near W estern markets, in Slovenia and parts o f C roatia,64 whereas the energy, mining, and heavy-industry sectors w ere in areas of Bosnia, Kosovo, Serbia, and M a ce d o n ia — which w ere more isolated from foreign markets, particularly co n v e rtib le-cu rre n e y markets. Foreign credits and investm ent for various purposes flowed to m ore-developed areas with b e tte r infrastructure and international co n tac ts.65 62 Borders closed to eco n o m ic exchange by the split with the Co m in for m in 1 9 48 -49 w e re doubly affected— by both federal policy and external hostility. W h ile Croatia and Ser bia b en efited from Hungarian and Romanian openness during the 1960s, Macedonia was particularly harm ed by th e effects o f poor political relations— not only the Eastern blockade (and th e fact that Bulgaria was fully oriented to its Eastern markets until the mid-1980s) but also th e closing o f th e b o rd er with G r e e c e when Yugoslav authorities conced ed to Western demands in 19 4 9 and again in th e 1960s, as relations betw een Yugoslavia and G r e e c e under th e ju n ta tu rn ed hostile. T h e tensions over the b ord er transformed market towns on the M acedonian side into administrative c en ters (for political control, customs inspection, radar stations, and watch towers) without their own econom ic base, discouraged firms from devel oping co m m ercial and export activities, and led many firms to use Slovene intermediaries for th e processing and m arketing o f Macedonian raw materials. Of the thirty communes in M acedonia, fifteen w ere in b o rd er areas; o f the fourteen least developed, seven were on the bo rd er itse lf and th e others w ere mountainous, food-deficit districts. Across two o f Macedo nia’s th re e foreign borders w ere areas even less developed, m oreover— Pirinsko Macedonia in Bulgaria and Albania (author’s interviews with D obri Dodevski and others at the Institute o f E co n o m ics in Sk opje, D e c e m b e r 1982), 63 Rusinow d escrib es the policy conflict produced in th e early 1960s by th e clash between th e “D a n u b ia n ” and “Adriatic” concepts o f econom ic developm ent— th e first favored by Serb ia, with its river transport and links to the east, the second by Croatia, with its maritime transport and access to th e west (The Yugoslav Experiment, 1 3 3 - 3 4 ; see also Wilson, “The B e lg ra d e -B a r Railroad”), 64 Slovenia and Croatia jo in ed a grouping initiated by northern Italian provinces in the 1980s to discuss regional cooperation in th e “Alpe-Adria” area (the name taken by the asso ciation) for tourist, econom ic, and cultural developm ent. 65 T h e w estern republics had far greater success in international capital and Eurodollar m arkets o n ce republics and firms w ere free to borrow (the former after 1965 and the latter
S LO V EN IA A N D FOČA
285
T h e sectoral distinctions in agricultural policy and property also followed th e historical pattern o f geographical differences— b etw ee n private-sector, small-scale and household production o f fruits, vegetables, and livestock for retail markets, with few regulations and free prices, on the one hand; and the social-sector, large-scale production o f basic food stuffs (such as grains and oils) and industrial crops in Bosnia and in the plains o f Vojvodina, Slavonia, and M acedonia on the other. Social-sector agriculture received g o v ernm ent credits, which the private sector did not, b u t it was also regulated by a defense-oriented national food policy that set prices, re qu ired permission for export, and tied the areas w h ere it prevailed far m ore to th e d om estic market and negotiated p rice s.66 C o n seq u en tly , labor-intensive activities in industry and agriculture tended to p red om inate in areas with m o re-developed industry, div er sified activities, and low er agricultural surpluses and birth rates. Highly capital-intensive activities in en erg y , mining, and heavy industry were; located in less-d ev elop ed areas with large labor surpluses in th e cou n try side and high b irth rates. T h e e x tre m e that d em onstrates the pattern was the p ro vin ce o f Kosovo, with b irth rates com parab le to those o f south Asia but industrial investm ent in sectors that are highly capital-intensive, such as energy, metallurgy, and sm eltin g .67 T h e availability o f investm ent r e sources was in inverse proportion to th e dem and for jo b s as a result of price policy, which regulated industries and producers that happened to concentrate disproportionately in poorer areas and which allowed prices and goods to roam freely for final manufacturers and processing firms that tended to c o n c en tra te in m ore-developed areas. T h e policy o f firing women first in a recession, unless they w ere pregnant, com pounded the problem , b eca u se o f the interactive effect and inverse relation b etw ee n female e m p lo y m e n t and b irth ra te s.68 T h e incong ru en ce b etw ee n policy and dom estic conditions was not only geographic and d em ographic but temporal as well. In place o f grow
after 1974); foreign direct investm ent also favored Croatia and Slovenia (including major energy and petrochem ical projects by Dow Chem ical and W estinghouse). Even research monies to firms and institutes te nded to llow along well-established networks; a World Health Organization study o f population control in the early 1980s, for example, was done in Slovenia rather than Kosovo or M acedonia because the Slovene research team was known in international social scien ce and aid circles. 68 T lle differences betw een Vojvodina and Slovenia are discussed in Bookman, "T h e E c o nomic Basis oi Regional Autarchy in Yugoslavia.” 67 T h e birthrate for Kosovo declined from 4 3 .5 per 1(XX) population in 1 9 5 0 - 5 4 to 3 0 .0 per 1000 in 1 9 8 5 - 8 9 , in comparison to 28 8 and 15.2 per 1000 for all o f Yugoslavia in the same periods. Bu t the rate o f natural increase was 2 5 .5 per 1000 for Kosovo in 1 9 5 0 -5 4 , rising to 2 8 .9 in 1 9 6 5 - 6 9 and falling to 2 4.1 in 1 9 8 5 -8 9 ; the Yugoslav average had declined from 17 0 to 6 .1 , while in 1 9 8 5 - 8 9 Slovenia was at 3 .1 , Croatia at 1.5, and Serbia proper at 2 .4 (Statistički (Godišnjak Jugoslavije for the relevant years).
m F o r Yugoslav data (in this effect, see Mihovilović et al., '/.etia izmt’đju rada i porodice.
286
CHAPTER 8
ing dem and in industry for surplus labor released “naturally” from agricul ture, restrictive policies occu rred in all spheres at o n c e — in monetary and fiscal policy for m acroeconom ic stabilization and in labor policy in socialsecto r industry, agriculture, and public services aimed at increasing pro ductivity and red ucing labor costs; the released surplus was thus pushed in th e o th e r direction. Unskilled labor expelled from industry in the 1950s and 1960s did not find the countryside receptive because central policy— in 1 9 5 5 - 5 7 , in 1 9 6 5 - 6 8 , and again in 1 9 7 0 — was also aimed at raising agricultural productivity through concentration o f landholdings, m echa nization, and incorporation o f more land as well as marketing activities into the social sector. T h e s e w ere the same years in which imports of grain, cotton, and oil substituted for dom estic production o f coal and grains, releasing even m ore labor from the land and primary industries. T h e dem obilization and th en “socialization” o f the security apparatus and the arm y (in 1955, 1 9 5 8 - 6 4 , after 1966, and again in the 1970s) sent vet erans, police, and retiring officers hom e to areas that, because of the pat tern o f w artim e fighting and re cru itm ent into the Partisan army, were m ore agrarian and less well equipped with a range o f manufacturing and tertiary e m p loy m en ts (particularly Bosnia-IIerzegovina, Montenegro, and the fo rm er military bord er o f Croatia). Instead o f absorbing the agricultural labor surplus and reducing the p ro blem o f d evelopm ental un em plo y m en t after the 1950s (according to the ju stification for jo in in g G A T T in 1958, this was no longer an issue), the o p enness o f th e econom y during the 1960s and 1970s made the country vuln erable to serious W e ste rn recessions that affected export com modi ties and then labor— at the same tim e that the rural outflow was grow ing.69 M o reover, although gov ernm ent policy in the early 1970s was to induce skilled labor to return from abroad, the receiving countries changed their policies at the tim e in the opposite direction, expelling lessskilled labor and accepting only m ore highly skilled workers and techni cians in their lower quotas. T h e pace o f agrarian exodus actually quick en ed after 1971, only a few years before opportunities in W e stern Europe disappeared and Yugoslav gastarbeiter flooded b a c k .70 Thus, despite em
m Su ch recessions took place in 1960—6 1, in 1 9 6 5 - 6 7 , and m ore or less continuously after 1974. U. S . recessions in 1 9 5 3 - 5 4 and 1 9 5 7 - 5 8 w ere also significant in Yugoslav policy shifts during th e 1950s, when Yugoslav trade with the United States was higher (see Shonfield,
Modern Capitalism, 1 0 -1 8 ) . 70
B e tw e e n 1971 and 1981, the agricultural population countrywide declined 18 percent,
from 3 8 . 2 p e r c e n t to 1 9 .9 p erce n t of th e total population. B y republic, th e 1981 figures were 9 . 2 p e r c e n t in Slovenia, 1 3 ,0 p ercent in M ontenegro, 1 4.5 p ercent in Croatia, 1 6 ,6 percent in Bosnia-H erzegovina, 1 9.2 p ercent in Vojvodina, 2 0 .5 p ercent in Macedonia, 2 4 .0 percent in Kosovo, and 2 6 .6 p erce n t in Serbia proper (calculated from “T h e Non-Agricultural Popu latio n ,” 5).
SL OV EN IA A N D FO ČA
287
ployment growth in 1 9 7 3 - 7 5 , 71 the resident labor force increased in abso lute term s for the first tim e since the m id-1960s recession, and th ere was an explosion in the u n em plo y m en t rolls. By 1982, M acedonia was e m ploying tw elve thousand new workers a year— but the dem and was for eighteen thousand j o b s . 72 In addition to the disparity b etw ee n industrial dem and for labor as d e fined by official policy and the rate o f rural outflow, a second problem for areas outside those fitting the initial conditions o f the Slovene model was the cum ulative impact o f m acroeconom ic stabilization and d evelopm ent policy. D e s p ite th e early com m itm e n t to female equality, which urged women into the industrial labor force, equalized wages for a jo b regard less o f who held it, and em phasized universal education, the approach to welfare and un em p lo y m en t sent women packing first. As a result, w om en’s participation rates w ere (except in Slovenia) closer to those of southern E u ro p e than those o f socialist countries. Yet the secular rise in demand for jo b s , ind epend en t o f dem ographic change and agrarian e x odus, was primarily a response to stabilization policies, as falling hou se hold incom es and living standards pushed second and third family m em bers into the labor force in search o f supplem entary wages. At the same tim e that w om en and youth w ere b eing fired, in other words, they were m ore likely to be seeking em ploym ent. In contrast, the liberals’ enduring battle to demilitarize the state, the economy, and society was in practice often legitimized by the official ap proach to external stabilization. Deflationary policies, which aimed at r e versing the balance-of-paym ents deficits and building up hard-currency reserves, em phasized reducing federal expenditures by cutting co m p e tences and the military budget. B u t the a ch iev em en t o f such cuts cam e at the price o f rising b urdens on local gov ernm ents— and thus an evergreater drain on resources w h ere effective investm ent for em p loy m ent had to occur. M o reover, the world environm ent was not always so a cc o m modating as to red uce military threats when W e ste rn dem and for exports fell and capital markets w ere tight. M ore often— such as the late 1960s, after the m id -1970s, and throughout the 1980s— both situations d e manded a policy response simultaneously. T h e contradictory dem ands on central policy had to b e im p lem e n te d , how ever, at the local level, and the effect was to magnify the existing disparities betw een investm ent re sources and e m p lo y m e n t needs among localities. According to Pavle S ich erl’s dynamic analysis o f econ om ic inequalities in the cou ntry— a measure o f the time need ed by the less-developed republics to catch up 71 1974 was a good year for em ploym en t, and em ploym ent growth in 1975 was the high est in ten years (M enein ger, “U tjeeaj privredne aktivnosti na zaposlenost”). 72 T ripo M ulina, persona] comm unication, Belgrade, O c to b er 1982; Kiril Miljovski, per sonal com m unication, O patija, O c to b er 1982.
288
CHAPTER 8
to the m o re-d e ve lop e d ones in various econom ic indicators— the “most im portant single factor” in the differences in gross material product (G M P ) p e r capita was the level o f industrial, social-sector em ploy m ent.73 T h e d iscrepancy accruing from early advantages w idened substantially b e tw e e n 1961 and 1971. T h e policy-generated temporal disjuncture b etw ee n labor demand and supply also had a generational aspect. T h e great value placed on the “hu man factor” in growth led to substantial attention to education and train ing, b u t again the cycles w ere at odds. Attem pts to retire the Partisan generation to make room for a better-ed u ca ted , younger generation in the second h alf o f the 1950s and the early 1960s sent these often still young veterans into local econom ies at a time when investm ent in the economy and in schooling was b eing decentralized to republican and local bud g e ts .74 T h e postwar baby-boom generation e n tered the labor market in exactly th e same years as the serious em ploy m ent recessions surrounding the 1960s econ om ic reforms, especially after 1965. Instead o f the needed expansion, jo b creation was nearly at a standstill, dismissals w ere rising, and policy requ ired firms to hire first those whose jo b s had been made redundant by the reforms, so that turnover was strictly within the cohort o f persons already e m p lo y e d .75 T h e m ore importance that formal educa tional qualifications took on for em p loy m ent and incomes, the higher was the incentiv e to leave rural towns and villages. T h e ever-larger contingent o f th e rural exodus w ere youth who left, they told rural sociologists, not 73
Sicherl, “T im e -D ista n c e as a Dynamic M easure of Disparities in Social and Economic
D e v e lo p m e n t.” In 1971, according to Sicherl s measure ot time distance betw een the more developed repub lics” and the “less developed republics,” (he latter needed five years to “catch lip” in measures o f productivity, fifteen years to reach the same levels of employment, and forty years to equalize demographic rates. T h e tim e distance for per capita income (G M P per capita) b etw een the two groups of republics was 1 1.5 years, of which employment levels explained 5 .1 years, productivity 4 .4 years, and the demographic component 2 years (ibid.). 7,1 T h e co m m u ne budget for Mostar, Bosnia-Herzegovina, gave first priority and substan tial m onies to housing and schools; the least-funded categories w ere "intervention in the ec o n o m y” and “investm ent in the eco n o m y ,” and funding for them declined after 1965. In 1969, the budget for education was 2.3 million new dinars; for noneconom ic investment, 7 ,2 9 3 ,4 0 0 ; and for the two econom ic categories, a total o f 4 3 1 ,4 0 0 (Rosenblum -Cale, Appro priation P olitics,” 31 n. 41). in the 1980s, Macedonian towns with high female unemploy m en t did invest heavily in textile industries, however, because credits favored exportoriented processing and th ese industries w ere deem ed m ore suitable for women (authors interviews with D obri Dodevski and Olga Dim itrieva of the Institute of Economics in Skopje and T ripo Mulina of the Institute of Econom ics in Belgrade, fall 1982). 75 T his was the period when, according to Estrin, freer wage determination in firms made it possible for urban-sector workers to monopolize control over their job s (Self-Management: Economic Theory and Yugoslav Practice, 2 0 4 - 5 ) Adizes gives a far b etter picture of the actual decisions bein g made by managers for modernization and markets at the time (Indus trial Democracy, Yugoslav Style),
S LO V EN IA A N D FOČA
289
because o f lower wages and insufficient investm ent in jo b s (as the Todaro model would argue), b u t b ecau se o f the lack o f educational op portu nity.7fi T h e reform and expansion o f university education in the 1960s yielded a cohort in the 1970s that sought jo b s com m ensu rate with their certifica tion, but e con om ic policy had shifted in favor of skilled production jo b s for which they had n e ith e r the skills nor the volition. T h e reform o f sec ondary education in the m id-1970s to encourage vocational training in needed technical skills gave localities the responsibility for providing the full range o f occupational training that local youth desired at exactly the point when th e next round o f governm ental decentralization, com bined with the new d efense role of localities, weighed heavily on local budgets for jo b s , housing, and unem ploym en t assistance. Most localities simply could not provide a full range o f choice, thus e ith er limiting the skills that employers could find locally or encouraging a fu rther exodus from smaller to larger towns. Secondary-school students had a choice o f e ith e r studying in the one or two technical schools their town could afford or emigratin g to cities, which could offer a fuller range but w ere accumulating everlarger pools o f un em ployed residents and migrants. This reform c o n tin ued into the period of sharp m onetary contraction with d eb t repaym ent in the 1980s. M o reover, decentralization reduced only the n u m b e r o f “unproduc tive” administrators em ployed at one level, while it increased the total number. Although the expansion in em p loy m ent in services, govern ment, and o th e r administrative tasks in 1 9 7 6 - 7 9 was able to absorb some of the you nger generation and its skills, it was cut short by the renew ed econom ic reform and stagnation in new em ploy m ent after 1 9 79 — a re v e r sal in ten d ed in part to cut back on such “o v erem p lo y m en t.” T h e s e various disharm onies in the path o f dev elopm en t played th e m selves out, how ever, within separate universes in each republic. Most republics contained internal differences. F o r example, there w ere wide differences among M acedonian towns that had traditionally specialized in specific crafts and that varied substantially in birthrates, com m ercial op portunities, and administrative obligations. In Croatia, regional differ 76
D ilie, Seoska omladina danas . Studies in both Croatia and Serb ia have shown that
young w om en left at an earlier age than men because th eir disadvantages in em ploym ent, even m o re than prospects for a successful marriage, drove them to seek b e tte r education in the towns (author’s interviews with Olga Supek and Zagorka Golubovic, anthropologists who did field research in villages o f Croatia and Serbia). T o send them to secondary school, parents spent household savings that would in the past have b een a marriage dowry. O n the b eginning of this change, s e e Trouton, Peasant Renaissance in Yugoslavia. Sociologists also re corded th e increasing aging o f the agricultural population at th e tim e (see th e articles by Svetozar Livada and E d h e in D ilic in D ep a rtm en t o f Rural Sociology, Institute o f Agri cultural E co n o m ics and Sociology, The Yugoslav Village; 011 the same process elsew h ere in E a stern E u ro p e , see H. Scott, “W h y the Revolution D o esn ’t Solve E v e ry th in g ”).
290
CHAPTER 8
e n c es w e re substantial, b e tw e e n the interior (the fo rm er military border, w h ere tim b er, mines, and railroads provided work), the industrial com plex o f th e Z agreb region, the tourist industry o f Dalm atia, and the rich agricultural fields and agro-industry o f Slavonia and B a ra n ja .77 Federal in v e stm e n t in the 1940s and 1950s had an overall conception not limited to particular republics, and military production not only was spread throughout the country, for strategic reasons, but also followed a policy requ iring integration o f production phases among plants dispersed throughout th e country. N onetheless, the econom ic autonomy o f republics over the policies di rectly affecting labor— in education, investm ent monies, regional devel op m en t, incom es and welfare, and military conscription— and the fact that capital for in vestm en t flowed vertically among governmental budgets and the banking system m eant that republics had greater influence over e m p lo y m e n t outcom es. T h e allocation and concentration o f capital and cred it, w h e th e r derived from federal subsidies, foreign credits, taxation, or o th e r transfers, w ere territorially organized rather than sectoral or m arket-driven. In contrast to the flow of semifinished and finished goods, the cross-regional flows o f capital and cred it w ere low. All o f the differential con se q u e n ces o f central policies on inherited ca pacities, geographical position, and composition o f population had their e ffect on the monies available for investm ent. W h e n the republics first gained autonom y over investm ent cred it and began to define their sepa rate d ev elo p m en t strategies after 1958, for example, the cuts in overall in v e stm e n t rates, in the proportion devoted to heavy industry and agri cu ltu re, and in federal investm ent w ere made on the argument that the cou ntry had reached the middle levels o f d evelopm ent and that domestic industry was now able to satisfy dom estic needs. In fact, the republics w ere at vastly different levels of developm ent. T h e less-industrialized re publics w ere left to face the unfinished task o f massive infrastructural and industrial d ev elop m en t when policy favored technological modernization, fuller utilization o f existing capacity, and reorientation to W estern trade. In addition, the G A TT -d efined liberalization betw een 1958 and 1961 e lim inated the capacity for differentiation in federal policy, replacing multiple coefficients with uniform tariffs, progressive taxation with pro77
T h e policy shift in Croatia after 1972 to investm ent in the poor interior— such as in the
alum inum plant at Obrovac, to take advantage o f local bauxite (already on long-term con tract, it tu rn ed out, to the Soviet market)— received heavy criticism as irrational, “political’’ inv estm ent by th e new, m ore conservative Croatian leadership to buy back the allegiance of local S e rb s after the Croatian nationalist tensions in 1 9 6 7 - 7 1 . Bu t a more straightforward e co n o m ic explanation is suggested by the pattern o f similar investment choices elsewhere in Yugoslavia and in the rest o f th e world as a result o f the sharp rise o f commodity prices on world m arkets after 1969, which made the aluminum appear to be a cheaper source for dom estic producers and a m ore profitable export.
S LO V EN IA A N D F O Č A
291
portional rates, and sectoral priorities with foreign price com petition for producers o f raw materials and interm ediate goods.78 T h e fact that larger concentrations o f capital and longer gestation times w ere need ed for capi tal investm ents than for e q u ip m en t modernization m eant that the p ro b lem o f tem poral disjunctures b e tw e e n federal policies o f international adju stm ent and dom estic em p loy m e n t b e ca m e ev e r greater the farther one m oved away from the northw est of the country. In 1963, for exam ple, the “en tire econom ic leadership o f S e rb ia ” was preoccupied with “how to put a stop to S e rb ia ’s further decline into rela tive e co n o m ic b ack w ard ness.”79 Losing the fight to change th e price structure m ore in favor o f agriculture and its contribution to G D P (gross dom estic product) and all m easures based on it, planners tu rned to major capital pro je cts o f “strategic” im portance for Serbian d ev elopm en t, such as the B e lg ra d e -B a r railroad,80 the com pletion o f the D anube-TiszaD anu b e canal (linking Hungarian agriculture and the Iron Gates hydro electric plant on the b o rd er with Romania), the oil refinery in Pancevo, the steelworks at S m ed erevo , the hydroelectric plant at D jerd ap, and regulation o f the Velika Morava River. T h e s e projects, treated as the “to be or not to b e ” for Serbia, w e re com p leted only in 1979, how ever, when the country was on a course o f global-m arket integration favoring light manufacturers and pro cessors.81 Similarly, massive investm ent in M a c e donia in the 1970s went, with th e aid o f federal funds, to several large capital pro je cts (including the F e n i nickel plant and the Skopje ste e l works), which cam e on stream ju s t when producers faced world recession, adverse term s o f trade, liberal e con om ic reforms, and, shortly thereafter, the collapse o f th e E a s te r n m arket altogether. Substantial capital invest m en t in m ining and metallurgy in the interior o f Croatia in the early 1970s (such as the alum inum -processing plant in Obrovac) d ep end ed on a global price stru cture and E a s te r n markets that had already changed by the 1980s. T h e serious business losses that resulted w e re only one o f the rea sons for th e deindustrialization o f entire regions in the 1980s, similar to what o ccu rre d in the central industrial b elt o f Bosnia-Herzegovina. It was a p ro blem not only o f capital, but also of thousands of workers who b e cam e un em plo y ed when the mines and plants closed but who had long ago b e e n displaced from the land. Structurally m ore vulnerable to recession, the less-developed republics 78 Gapinski, Skegro, and Zuehlke found that linear equations w ere very successful in modeling taxes o f all kinds, including sales and personal incom e taxes, and thus revealing that rates w ere effectively proportional, not progressive (Modeling the Economic Perfor mance o f Yugoslavia, 154). 79 Pesakovic, '‘Nisko savetovanje ekonomista Srbije, 1963 i danas.” 80 S e e W ilson, "T h e Belgrad e-B ar Railroad.” 81 Pesakovic, “Nisko sav etov anje.’’
292
CHAPTER 8
F i g u r e 8-1. P e r c e n t a g e o f E m p l o y m e n t in th e Social S e c to r by R epublic. Source: Statistički Bilten Jugoslavije (1977), c ited in Pleskovič a n d D o le n c, “Regional D e v e lo p m e n t, in a Socialist, D e v e lo p in g , a n d M u ltin a tio n a l C o u n t r y , ” 12.
also saw the tim e necessary to catch up in em ploy m ent capacity lengthen with the ev e r more freq uent resort to m acroeconom ic stabilization policy and its approach to structural adju stment. B ecau se the “comparative ad vantage o f regions [was] crucially d eterm ined by the credit potential of sp ecific territorial banks, S2 policies to tighten d iscipline over banks by increasing th e ir reserv e ratios and lim iting cred it for working capital also had th e e ffe ct o f penalizing p o o rer regions and w eaker banks, causing particu lar hardship for en te rp rises with seasonal cre d it needs. T h e repub lican con trol o v er cred it tended to lead as well to duplication o f facilities and a resulting excess industrial capacity.83 This increased the tendency to idle capacity (with its effects on unem ploym ent) and the tendency for H2 Kovač et al.. Privreda Jugoslavije do 1985, 2 1 2 - 1 4 . T ech n ical capacity wus far too grca I for th e d om estic m arket after 1958. as each repub lic huill its own s l e d mills, oil refineries, and consum er-goods fuctorics for refrigerators, textiles, am i footwear. By 1965, for exam ple, th e re were five steel miles in lour republics producing 2 . 2 million tons per year altogether, although one mill had to produce at least 2 million tons annually to break even (llo n d ius.
The YuhusIiw Community o f Nationit, 319).
T his duplication o f Capacity was a primary th em e in the m ounting public criticism of the repuhlicanizatiou o f the econom y attributed to th e 197-1 constitution at the tim e o f the ioreign-debt crisis and the m ore general econom ic crisis beginning in 1979—1982
S L O V E N I A A N D FO ČA
293
large firms to find ways to stimulate dom estic dem and for their unsold inventories (even when federal policy aimed to restrict demand). M o re over, republican banks’ control over credit was disadvantageous for e m ployment b eca u se o f the bargaining power in these banks o f large industrial firms, which w ere m ore likely to enlarge by m e rg e r than e m ployment expansion. Sm aller, m ore labor-intensive firms tend ed , t h e r e fore, to b e m ore risk-averse and m ore d ep en d e n t on internal resources for both rising incom es and e m p loy m e n t expansion. Internally g en era ted resources (w hether for firms or republics) w ere also differentially affected by federal policy as a result o f the structural differences in production across territories. P rice regulation favoring in dustrialization worked to the disadvantage o f the less-developed areas, ironically, b ecau se prices for raw materials and interm ediate supplies were k ep t artificially low while industrial prices w ere high. Tariff policy and foreign-trade liberalization w ere used to expose producers o f such materials to foreign com petition while protecting manufacturers. Policies to prom ote exports with subsidies and rights to retain foreign-exchange earnings b enefited the m o re-developed republics (especially Slovenia and Croatia), w h ere export producers and hard-currency earnings c o n c e n trated; so did advances on clearing trade if one includes Serbia. E xpo rt producers tended to b e price setters domestically also. T h e flow o f prized foreign exchang e from guest workers’ rem ittances and tourist earnings, in addition to fo reign-em ploy m ent alternatives for absorbing the rural surplus, disproportionately b enefited Slovenia and Croatia, which for reasons o f geographical proximity and cultural tradition (especially in Croatia) had the largest conting ent o f tem porary foreign migration. T h e role o f wages in lim iting savings for investm ent was also dispropor tionately harmful to the areas with higher u n em ploym ent. W ages in social-sector firms te n d ed to b e m ore equal across republics than would be p red icted by differences in their gross social product per capita. As a result, in the less-developed republics a higher proportion o f republican and local budgets and o f enterprise earnings w ent to wages and benefits than in th e m o re-d evelop ed republics, th e re by reducing local resources for new in vestm en t and jo b s — particularly when stabilization policies r e q uired m ore reliance on internal resources. C ontrary to the literature on labor m an a g e m e n t and th e regular criticism from northern econom ists and politicians (particularly in Slovenia), this was a result o f the productivity-oriented wage regulations— which had an equalizing influ e n ce across rep u blics— and the fact that the reservation wage for the country was set by upward pressure on wages in full-em ploym ent S lo venia, w h ere the wage was highest. W ages in the less-developed re p u b lics also w e re the target o f protests against budgetary subsidies and d ev el o p m en t credits from econom ists and politicians in the m o re-developed
294
CHAPTER 8
republics, even though the higher aggregate dem and that resulted from such wage levels disproportionately benefited those m ore-developed re publics and in effect created a built-in dom estic m arket for their goods. T h e p ro blem was com pounded by the concentration in poorer regions of low-wage industries, which tend ed to distribute a higher portion of their net receip ts to wages, and a far larger proportion of “nonaccumulative” firms (basic industries) that d ep end ed on budgetary subsidies.84 While social-sector wages w ere higher than strictly marginal rules within firms would predict, they w ere not as high as in richer areas, making it difficult for firms to pay the wages (and particularly benefits) necessary to attract and retain skilled labor. T h o se who em igrated from poorer areas, whether to th e m o re-developed republics or abroad, w ere not the least-productive “surplu s,” but the most skilled and ambitious. Aware o f the biases o f these policies, the leadership and the representa tives o f richer firms and regions conced ed to com pensation for those who w ere losers. It b ec a m e ritual for Tito to point out that the mored eveloped republics had an econom ic interest in the rapid development of th e o t h e r s .85 But the political system was organized around questions of allocation and distribution, and without econom ic growth, the conse q u e n c e o f the socialist m onetary system was that “what [was] a plus in one region [was] necessarily a minus in a n o th e r .”86 T h e federal transfers for d ev elop m en t in the form of low-interest, long-m aturing loans b ecam e the su b je c t of constant criticism, even though they amounted to less than 2 p e rc e n t o f G D P annually. Political debate could, and did, occur over ac tual taxes and transfers, but not over the effects o f invisible redistribution due to the regulation o f econom ic activity through, for example, regulated prices, special funds, selective credits, export incentives, and tariffs— all o f which worked to the n e t advantage o f firms in the more-developed re g io n s.87 And it was at the m om en t of declining growth and restrictive m acro eco n om ic policy for stabilization and d eb t repay m ent— when such fi'1 Vojvodina complained frequently about this problem ; see the discussion as early as 1956 in the pages o f Narodna Armijo (see n. 19 above). s:' S e e the citation from his address to the ninth party congress in 1969 in Wilson, "The B elgra d e-B a r Railroad,'’ 3 7 7 - 7 9 ; and his speech to the eighth party congress in 1964, in which he outlined the new policy for developm ent of the less-developed republics through "technical and personnel assistance from the com m unity” o f the kind Yugoslavia was provid ing o th er countries. l i e also laid out the trickle-down arguments underlying the policy (Osmi honp,res SKJ, 4 1 -4 2 ) . ilfi Miljovski, “Possibilities for the D evelop m ent of U nderdeveloped Areas,” 10 87
E v id e n c e was widespread that the effect o f price regulations “was relatively unfavor
able to the less developed republics” (D ub ey et al,, Yugoslavia: Development with Decen
tralization, 1 9 3 -9 4 ) ; on the bias o f investm ent and liberalization against the less-developed republics, see 200fl, D yker cites Macedonian research on the effect of the policy-dictated price structu re that draws the same conclusion (Yugoslavia, 77).
S LO V EN IA A N D F O Č A
295
compensatory transfers m attered most to poorer and less foreign tradeoriented e n terp rises and areas and when the dem and for em p loy m e n t was rising— that th e fight to red u ce taxation and federal redistribution was at its height. At the least, this wrangling m eant long delays in d isbursem ents while conflicts over priorities and funds w ere negotiated. Alternative m onies, e ith e r from direct federal investm ent or from for eign cred its, w ere always project-specific. B eca u se federal monies w ere limited by jurisd iction to capital projects, infrastructure, and defense, this avenue reinforced th e bias o f investm ents toward capital intensity, single industry towns, and production o f strategic raw materials. M oreover, these p ro je cts — such as the F e n i nickel plant in M acedonia, the O brovac aluminum plant and Knin railroad line in Croatia, and the Sm e d ere v o steel plant in S e rb ia — w ere eventually transferred to republican “m an agem ent” after com pletion, often b eco m ing heavy, long-term burdens on republican b u d g e t s . F o r e i g n credits through jo in t ventures w ere often given on th e condition that the Yugoslav firm import technical personnel from the supplier, and they fed import d ep en d e n ce and foreign d ebt without necessarily enhancing d om estic capacity.89 E v e n though such credits increased local e m p loy m e n t in places, the republicanization o f r e sponsibility for foreign d eb t after 1977 obliged poorer republics to repay with th e ir own resources in a period o f very rapid dinar devaluation and dollar revaluation. T h e A grokom erc financial-corruption affair o f 1987, in which th e Bosnian conglom erate was found to have floated un secu red promissory notes totaling $ 8 65 million to at least fifty-seven banks in four republics b e tw e e n 1984 and 1987, illustrates the use o f one o f the rare domestic alternatives (given the tend ency o f republics to hoard monies where possible), for it was occasioned by the denial o f federal funding for the c o n g lo m era te ’s proposed d ev elop m en t p ro je c ts .90 M oreover, during periods o f liberalization when capital and labor began to move across r e publican bord ers, rich e r republics and towns instituted protectionist poli cies in th e in te rest o f tax revenue to prevent the entry o f new producers from o th e r localities or republics (to which, as final owners, they paid their “in c o m e ” taxes); argued against policies that would allow capital to circulate outside their grasp, such as a m arket would imply; imposed reg88 Author’s interviews» O n Sm ed erevo , see Burger, Kester, and den O u d em , Self
Management and Investment Control . 89 T h e jo in t v entu re b etw een D ow C h em ical and IN A Zagreb to build a petrochem ical plant on th e Croatian island o f Krk im ported everything it n eed ed, did not use or intend to use local labor, and had the effect o f displacing many local occupations (such as tourism, fishing, and agriculture) while bringing in a stratum o f m ore educated outsiders that created local tensions (Cichock, “Reevaluating a D eve lo p m e n t Strategy”). 90 At th e sam e tim e, th e G en era l Accounting Service reported that th ere was $ 8 .5 billion in unsecu red en te rp rise credits in th e country (Rem ington, “Yugoslavia”).
296
CHAPTER 8
illations on immigrants (w hether from other republics or surrounding rural areas); revived discussion about local posting during army service so as to k e ep desired skills at hom e; and in the main acted in ways that fu rthered the segm entation o f capital and labor markets in territorial e n c la v e s .91 Slovenia began the postwar period with shortages of skilled labor. It was ab le to achieve full em p loy m ent rapidly and sustain it for forty years (u nem ploy m ent never e x ceed ed 1 .5 p e rce n t until 1985). Its planners as sessed progress in term s o f international standards o f productivity and growth, and they succeeded in persuading central policymakers to adopt th e se crite ria .92 T h e y argued, for example, that technological moderniza tion should re c e iv e priority b ecause by 1958 the country had reached the m iddle levels o f d ev elop m en t and the dom estic raw-material base was b ein g exhausted; and that declining rates o f relative productivity growth in th e 19 70 s— felt with particular intensity in Slovenia because it was losing skilled professionals across its northern b order and having to fill shortages o f production labor with tem porary migrant Bosnian and ethnic Albanian (Kosovar) workers in the late 1970s and early 1980s— created a d esp erate need for renew ed technological advantage in the 198 0s.93 Slo v e n e planners worried about a serious labor shortage in the 1980s. The re p u b lic ’s unions and firms tended to lead the country in labor strikes, protesting wage controls and restrictive policies; they w ere the first to b rea k ranks over federal wage controls, arguing that b ecause they had shortages o f labor, they should not b e prevented from raising wages to k e ep and attract labor. As a result, they set the reservation wage for the co u n try .94 T h e first instance o f a parliamentary vote of no confidence in th e country, in D e c e m b e r 1966, forced the resignation of prime minister Ja n k o Sm o le when the Slovene assem bly failed to pass the governm ent’s bill to re d u c e the level o f social-insurance contributions by enterprises and increase w orkers’ share. In 1982, under similar reform-oriented and 91 As owners o f capital and primary “venture capitalists” in the country, the republican governm ents sought federal regulation in ways similar to those used by private firms in S tig ler’s analysis o f regulation in market econom ies; those with greater resources won rights to exclud e com petitors, while those with few er resources settled for grants of money (“The T h eo ry o f E c o n o m ic Regulation”). 92 T h e following information was obtained through the author s interviews in October 1982 with Zivko Pregl (then director o f the Slovene planning bureau); Einil Pintar (author of the b ureau's report on th e Slovene D evelo p m ent Plan to the Year 2000); and other Slovene research econom ists and sociologists, including Jo ze M en cin ger, Stane Saksida, and Pavle Sicherl. 93 T h e y estim ated that th e migration o f skilled Slovenes abroad in the 1970s was equiva lent to th e loss o f th irty thousand units o f schooling, while th ey considered tin* budgetary costs o f encouraging migrants from oth er republics too great by 1980 (interviews cited in n 9 2 above; Informativni Bilten). 94 C< M artin, “Public Policy and In co m e Distribution in Yugoslavia.”
S LO V EN IA A N D F O Č A
297
restrictive policies, S lovene accountants made a successful public protest against th e g o v ern m e n t’s attem p t to red u ce the minimum wage by chang ing th e m ea su re o f sub sistence (the price o f a basket o f consumables) on which it was based. Slovenians w ere also the most insistent voices for local postings during military service; in th e early 1980s, they w ent to the e x trem e by d em anding “national arm ies” in which th e re would be no s er vice outside o n e ’s republic. Capital investm ent in Slovenia as well as Croatia in th e 1980s focused on a transportation network c o n n ec te d with international ro utes— th e “B ro th erh o o d and U n ity ” trunk highway co n necting E u ro p e with the M iddle E a st through Yugoslavia, the Z a g re b M aribor links, th e Adriatic coast highway (magistrala ), and the highway to D alm atia through Bosnia. Croatian planners, on the o th er hand, faced far greater internal varia tion am ong subregions and com m u nes than existed in Slovenia b ecau se the process o f d ev elop m en t had b e e n one o f “polarization and co n cen tra tion o f e c o n o m ic activities.”95 D e v e lo p m e n t plans consistently favored the valley o f th e Sava, the Z ag reb-R ijek a link, and the Adriatic coast, w hereas 8 0 p e rc e n t o f th e em ployed in the less-developed interior areas of th e rep u blic worked in traditional branches (lum ber, textiles, food, and industrial construction materials). F irm s in these b ranches, although labor-intensive and m ore efficient in th e use o f materials than firms in the m o re-d evelop ed areas, had low levels o f ne t profit and therefore insuffi cien t resources for new in vestm en t and local d evelopm en t. Zagrebc e n te re d industrialists had succeeded in blocking policy c h a n g e ,96 while politicians focused on the loss o f C roat workers to foreign markets and on d eclining C roa t b irthrates in comparison with the higher rates among na tional m inorities and potential migrants from the south. In S e rb ia, planners and politicians focused far m ore on intra-Yugoslav com parisons and, after losing the fight over d ev elop m en t strategy in 1 9 5 8 - 6 4 , on th e capital and infrastructural projects necessary to th e re p u blic’s industrialization and consistent with its geographic position (in the c e n t e r o f the Balkan peninsula and d ep en d e n t on river and rail trans port, for example). Studies in 1979 for the rep u blic’s long-term plan dis c ov ered that for S e rb ia proper, despite the massive capital investm ent after 1964 to re d u ce disparities, th e “d eg ree o f d ev elop m en t o f its produc tion capacities is at th e level o f th e th ree un derd eveloped republics and [its] social product p e r capita is 5 p e rc e n t below the average for the c o u n 95 B a le tić and M arendić, “Politika razvoja privredno nedovoljno razvijenih područja S. R. H rvatsk e,” 357. 96 O n the study o f Croatian regional econom ic developm ent in 1 9 7 6 - 8 0 that was m ade for the long-term plan to th e year 2000, see Ekonomski Pregled 32, nos. 7 - 8 (1981), especially the articles by M arendić, T určić, and M ates, “M je re n je i analiza razvijenosti o p ćine”; and B a letić and M arendić, “Politika razvoja.”
298
CHAPTER 8
try .” Its tax obligations, how ever, ranked with those o f the developed republics, with which it was still officially classified.97 E v id e n c e that it was “lagging b e h in d ” th e rest o f the country continued to appear in 1981— 84. And, amid serious levels o f unem ploym ent, planners foresaw a new rural exodus b eca u se farm ers still made up 28 p e rce n t o f the population in 1 9 8 1 — a proportion they exp ected to continue falling until it reached the S lo v e n e level o f 10 p e r c e n t .98 T h e d ev elopm en tal profiles o f the republics in the 1980s and the level and c h a ra cter o f their un em ploym en t, despite fundamental econom ic and social change, reflected the decisions o f the late 1950s— to participate fully in global markets, to favor the Slovene model o f developed econ om ies, and to end econom yw ide d ev elopm en t planning except as a by product o f foreign e con om ic and defense policy. T h e farther an area was from n o rthern markets, d eveloped transportation networks, and the b en efits o f early industrialization (light manufacturing, industrial habits, and literacy), and the larger the proportion o f its population em ployed in agri cu ltu re, in “non prod u ctive” occupations (such as the army, security forces, and civil service), in low-wage and “nonaccumulative” industries, and, most important, in th e private sector, the greater its unemployment. Although th ere was m uch variation across towns within a republic, official un em p lo y m en t figures surpassed 2 0 p e rce n t in Kosovo, Macedonia, S er bia proper, and B osnia-H erzegovina by the mid-1970s, and they contin ued to rise. B u t by the 1980s, the registered jo b seekers w ere increasingly urban— often m en assumed to b e heads o f household with skills appropri ate to pu blic-secto r industry, or educated youth from urban homes. The rural basis o f u n em p lo y m en t and the official rem edy had b ee n sub stantially replaced by rapid urbanization and by long-term industrial re c e ssio n — excep t in Kosovo. T h e re people w ere indeed returning to the land. W ith the pooled resources sent hom e by youth working temporarily in the n o rthern republics (prim arily in private shops) or abroad, extended families in the Albanian com m unity w ere buying up land.
Su rplu s L abor
T h e principles guiding the Yugoslav leaders’ approach to labor set in 1 9 4 8 - 5 0 retained their force throughout the period o f socialist rule. Cen 97 Milovan Markovic, speech before the C h am b er of Republics and Provinces of the federal assem bly, February 28, 1985 (printed in Foreign Broadcast information Service, M arch 1, 1985, 1 4). 98 T h e se data did not take into account the immigration of Serbs and Montenegrins from Kosovo at the tim e. T h e num bers o f these immigrants were far less significant than their potency as em otional and political symbols for segments of the Serbian population and the leadership in Relgrade
S LO V EN IA A N D FO ČA
299
tral policy would establish guidelines and standards for em ploym ent. R e publics could not b e consid ered econom ically sovereign without final authority over w h ere and how their population was employed. B u t those responsible for the issue o f em ploy m ent had to b e attuned to the vast variety o f local conditions and had to recognize the point at which political grievances about u n em p lo y m en t would first appear and when they could best b e addressed so that they did not accum ulate and threaten the sys tem. W h e t h e r it was a m a tter o f state-d irected mobilization in 1 9 4 8 - 4 9 or of stabilizing e m p lo y m e n t through workers’ participation in local assem blies and w orkers’ councils after 1949, local authorities (in th e govern ment, th e econom y , and the party) w ere most suited to this highly sensitive political task. W h e n local firms did have to fire people “in the interests o f rationalization” or when “material conditions” did not perm it a sufficient pace in the transfer o f labor from agriculture to industry and from private to socialized sector (at the tim e o f these justifications by Kidric and Kardelj, in 1 9 4 9 - 5 2 , local authorities had the opposite p ro b lem in most o f the country, excep t Macedonia), then the resulting u n e m ployment was seen not as an econom ic problem but a social one. And welfare, too, was the responsibility o f local com m unities. C onsonant with the lead ers’ d ecentralized, e nterp rise-b ased approach to m acro eco nom ic stabilization, th e com m itm e n t to what is called in cap italist cou ntries an “active labor-m arket policy” was also to b e fulfilled at the local level. In line with the distinction b etw ee n industrial and agrar ian u n em p lo ym en t, th e re was a division o f labor among local agents. To minimize industrial u n em p lo y m en t (that is, dismissal o f persons already employed), workplaces w ere legally obliged to find new positions for workers made redundant by rationalization or technological change. To minim ize agrarian u n em plo y m en t, local authorities w ere responsible for econ om ic d ev elo p m en t within their territory that was attuned to e m p lo y m e n t conditions and the pace o f deagrarianization and socialization. W ith in firms, for exam ple, investm ent plans for modernizing produc tion included funds for improving workers’ skills or reassigning them , and the union b ranch lobbied firms to contrib ute to local retraining programs. W h e n layoffs o f m ore than five persons w ere econom ically necessary, m an ag e m e n t was obliged to consult the union branch within the firm on who should go and how to find them new assignments. T h e trade-union jo u rn a l R a d (Labor) is filled with such cases: for example, when workers from a small craft en te rp rise that closed in Toplica, Serbia, w ere trans ferred to a local construction firm in 1963, or when the integration o f two firms into the pharm aceutical giant Galenika the same year created a sur plus o f 160 workers in the Belgrad e area. T h e union’s self-congratulatory re telling o f the latter transfer process illustrates well the principles at work (see th e appendix to this chapter). Youth in traineeships and women
300
CHAPTER 8
w ere let go first (with the exception o f pregnant women, whose employ m e n t was pro tected by law) on the grounds that their families could sup port them . D e s p ite the social norm valuing consultation where possible prior to firing and reassignm ent, th ere w ere legally acceptable conditions for in voluntary d i s m i s s a l." E m p loy e es could b e fired if a work unit was elimi nated, if th e re was no equivalent jo b in the organization for a person whose position was b eing elim inated, if the firm’s business volume de clined for an extend ed period, if an expert commission ruled that a per son’s abilities did not m e e t the needs of the jo b , or if a person slated for reassig nm ent refused to undergo retraining. All w ere instances that up held the formal principles o f parity (betw een a p erson’s qualifications and jo b classification) and labor productivity. Local e m p loy m e n t bureaus thus spent most o f their time and monies on retraining programs. T h e ir staffs negotiated em ploym ent contracts for retrained workers with local firms. In areas of high unem ploym ent, they also pressured firms to hire univcrsity-educated youth and the appren tices from vocational schools whom firms had agreed to train but then did not employ. Local governm ents would, understandably, take a wide range o f m easures to p reven t the bankruptcy of a large local employer b eca u se they w ere responsible for solving the resulting problem s of un em ploy m ent. M o re b u rd en som e in normal times than local dismissals, how ever, was the responsibility for absorbing people released from fed eral jo b s or administration by the policies o f decentralization and social ization. T h e return to localities o f dem obilized, purged, or “retired” veterans or army officers— in 1955, after 1965, and again in the 1970s during the socialization and localization o f d efense— and the return of m id dle-level civil servants and administrative staff from farm cooperatives p re sen ted local pension boards, housing funds, and employers with a dif ficult task. T h e s e surplus gov ernm en t em ployees w ere frequently encour aged to e n te r e le ctio n s— in 1955, when the newly created school boards op ened local posts, and in 1967 and 1969, when th ere w ere multicandi date elections for parliament. But the delegate system, which “socialized” political representatio n (elections w ere based in enterprises, which then
n
m owevor, these conditions on dismissal did not represent the real restraints on man agers, who had far m ore flexibility. In interviews with the author, enterprise directors con sistently d enied the com m only held view that “with the exception o f cases o f criminal or sev ere personal misconduct affecting the whole working comm unity, workers cannot be laid o ff” (S ch ren k, Ardalan, and El Tatawy, Yugoslavia, citing Article 19 o f the 1976 Law on Associated L abor). It was necessary to follow legal procedures preventing arbitrary dis missal, th ey adm itted, but it simply was not the case that workers and em ployees could not b e fired. Articles insisting that th ere was no “right to em ploym en t” or even to a particular jo b appeared frequently in the specialized literature on em ploym ent and in the social sci en c es as well.
S LO V E N I A A N D FOČA
301
paid d ele g ates’ salaries), erased this opportunity after 1969. T h e poorer the area, th e m ore likely it was that many people had left for jo b s in the civil service or army and that it would b ea r a disproportionate b urd en in their reintegration. B eh in d the frequently heard complaints about the ethnic disproportions in governm ental bureaucracies lay a hard reality: as a result o f the concentratio n o f wartim e com bat in poorer regions, the decentralization o f the security apparatus placed a higher burden, per capita, on local e m p lo y m e n t in poor towns or regions in the interior, which w ere m ore often ethnically mixed. In conditions o f declining growth and rising u n em p lo y m en t generally, choices in the rationing of ever-fewer jo b s in relation to the n u m b e r o f jo b seekers could (in fact or in perception) b e made according to eth n ic c r ite r ia .100 E v e n in the fall of 1948, when localities w ere handed many ’’federal and republican tasks” to “readjust th e disproportion b etw ee n capital construction and living stan dards,” party lead er Vladim ir Bakarić worried about the disproportion in the location o f local industries— worst, he said, in Croatia, w h ere 5 6 .8 percent o f “local b u sin esses” were in Zagreb and there w ere “none at all” in thirty-five districts or to w n s .101 Zivan T a n ić ’s analysis o f the 1973 federal legislation to “stimulate the return o f workers from abroad and their em ploy m ent in Yugoslavia through programs o f intensified econom ic d ev elop m en t” applies more generally. T h e program ran into problem s, he writes, b ecau se the e m ployment bureaus w ere not up to the task o f retraining retu rnees, poor com munes lacked the resources for d ev elop m en t programs, and informa tion to migrants was insufficient. In many places, the local authorities simply had not im p lem e n te d the policy— not for lack o f a g re em en t am ong political elites but for lack o f econ om ic re s o u r ce s .102 T h e m ost difficult e m ploy m ent-related problem for local governm ents was actually the problem o f housing. F actories that chose to expand p ro duction w h en they expanded their markets tended to op en new plants in neighboring com m u n e s so that they did not have to build m ore housing at the existing p la n t.103 T im e spent in com m uting long distances to work continued to b e a problem for productivity long after 1 9 4 9 - 5 0 . 104 T h e io° T his was not a topic on which system atic research could h e done, however, because o f its political sensitivity. Such bias was largely inferred from highly aggregated data on ethn ic disproportions in particular occupations, or was simply an untested perception. 101 Bakarić, “Vezana trgovina poljoprivrednih i industrijskih proizvoda,” 106. 102 Tanić, “Yugoslavia.” 103 Such stories from Serb ia and Bosnia are told in Yugoslav Trade Unions, A p r il-Ju n e 1964, 71. 104 T h e re is a large literature on th e exten t and costs o f “daily migration” (dnevne mi gracije) and th e ph en o m eno n called “peasant-workers” (seljaci-radnici ) . Hawrylyshyn calls them a “landed proletariat”; for a summary, see his "Yugoslav D evelop m ent and Rural Urban M igration,” 3 4 1 - 4 2 ,
302
CHAPTER 8
v e te ra n s ’ organization (S U B N O R ) b eca m e infamous for its political pres sure on localities to build housing for retired Partisans. T h e shortage of housing was a particularly serious obstacle to labor migration, discourag ing both individuals’ search for jo b s elsew here and expenditures by em ploy m e n t services on travel costs to facilitate that search (despite the rights o f the un em ployed to such assistance). T h e result was that enterprises w ere vulnerable to pressure from their e m p loy ees to hire family m e m b ers or local friends. T h e more difficult the e c o n o m ic tim es, m oreover, the greater the pressure. Legally required to pay local tax obligations first, before wages and contractual obligations, firms w e re often faced with rising taxes at the same tim e that they were under this pressure to employ, because local welfare and investment need s w e re rising. W h e n the em ploy m ent services b eca m e “selfmanaging com m unities o f in te re s t” after 1967, and thus (along with other public services) financially autonomous o f local budgets, this meant addi tional taxes for enterprises. “Insurance in case of un em ploym ent” was th e n paid by firms out o f the personal incom e o f each employed worker, b u t at rates that varied among republics b ecau se o f differences in levels of un em p lo y m en t. In 1982, the rate was lowest in Slovenia and highest in Kosovo (1.5 p e r c e n t).105 To k e e p local industries and the com munal tax base alive, the com m u n e ’s office o f the social accounting service also requ ired firms to pay the claim s o f o th er local firms before those o f distant suppliers. Local monopolies on trade, agricultural purchasing, and exporting firms often arose for th e same purpose— to prevent firms from outside the territory from capturing “local re s o u r ce s .” To com pensate for higher tax rates or to forestall a firm ’s decision to move, a variety o f concessions to local publicsector firms w ere often necessary, as well as lax en forcem en t of accounts and price regulations. T h e search for credits as an alternative to internally g en era ted rev e n u e s en cou n tered the same vicious circle that produced growing inequalities among republics: the lower the value of a firm’s fixed assets, the lower the chance o f obtaining bank credit and the more cir cu m scrib ed the selective investm ent funds to which firms or governments could apply for building up local fixed assets. Inv e stm e n t choices were thus e v e n m ore likely to be driven by the source o f cred it (and especially by the official priority on investm ents that sought to develop exports for foreign exchange) rath er than by m arket criteria. W h e n using local re sources for explicit em p loy m e n t promotion, local governm ents tended to choo se investm ents according to the characteristics o f the people in need o f jo b s (for example, building textile plants to employ women) instead of according to th e likely profitability o f the products or services. 105 3, 1982.
Author’s interview with Tripo Muliiui, Institute of Econom ics, Belgrade, N o ve m ber
S LO V E N I A A N D F O Č A
303
Th e conflict b e tw e e n central policy and local resources over em ploy ment prom otion was most striking in the central role played in both by the private sector. In all federal proposals after the m id-1960s, and for most leading econom ists, th e only available (and, many thought, th e best) solution to growing u n em p lo y m en t was to develop the mala privreda — the sector o f small-scale, “in d e p e n d en t” firms in services and manufactur ing. M ost local governm ents, how ever, usually resolved increasing p re s sure on local revenues by raising license fees and taxation on privatesector b u s in e s s e s .106 This was not for ideological reasons of antipathy to private activity, as was often asserted, but for lack o f sufficient resources to perform the tasks assigned. To reduce tensions with public-sector firms, local authorities sought monies w here they w ere available, from household savings and private firms that w ere less able to exit. At the local level, therefore, th ere was a growing conflict b etw ee n policies to minimize industrial un em plo y m en t and those designed to employ the rural surplus and d em ographic increase. T h e sector o f in d e p e n d en t smallholdings and trades rem ained essential to full e m p lo y m e n t in the lead ers’ strategy. “Private agriculture collects workers from [industry, social-sector agriculture, and other social-sector activities] when they are redundant and releases them . . . when they are n e e d e d ,” according to Gapinski, Skegro, and Z u e h lk e .107 B ut the most com m on response to u n em p lo y m en t was migration. W ithin Yugoslavia, day-labor exchanges in large cities served new com ers and unskilled la borers, and construction projects attracted migrating unskilled workers from all parts o f the country. Youth left rural towns for higher education and e m p lo y m e n t in cities, primarily in the republic of th eir nationality b ecau se republics defined school curricula and family networks provided housing. Skilled workers and professionals sought the higher incomes (and especially the benefits) available in Slovenia, w h ere labor shortages prevailed during most of the socialist p e rio d .108 B u t the most important outlet for d om estic u n em p lo y m en t was foreign migration. In 1 9 4 8 - 5 3 , roughly 1 0 0 ,0 0 0 persons left the country, followed in the next four years by an oth er 1 9 5 ,0 0 0 (equivalent to 10 p e rce n t o f social-sector em ploym ent 10H An eco n o m ic explanation o f local authorities' attitude toward private entrepreneurs seem s sufficient, but the tendency to explain it as ideologically based antagonism n o n e th e less prevailed. Sacks focuses on the limits to entry in the Yugoslav economy, which are partly explained by the level o f fees and taxes; these fees and taxes usually absorbed the first year’s profits for small firms (Sacks, Entry o f New Competitors in Yugoslav Market
Socialism). 107 Gapinski, Skegro, and Zuehlke, Modeling, 133. By the late 1970s, one-q uarter of the labor force in Slovenia was from elsew here T he
H I»
figure was lower than it would have b een had the Slovene governm ent not regulated the flow carefully to minim ize “social costs’’ (it feared social intolerance if non-Slovenes ex c eed ed an acceptable level, and it would have to expend additional resources 011 infrastruc ture that could otherw ise be directed to improving Slovene living standards).
304
CHAPTER 8
in 1 9 5 7 ).109 After 1960, both p e rm a n e n t and temporary migration to W e s te r n E u ro p e and the U nited States com pensated for the decade of labor-cutting e co n o m ic r e fo r m .110 After 1974, when Yugoslav unemploy m e n t was no longer frictional or cyclical but structural, W e ste rn recession pu sh ed th e em igrants back home.
C o n c l u s io n
T h e last Yugoslav policy toward labor appeared in the supplementary doc um en ts o f the long-term stabilization program adopted in 1983. It re flected what Claus Offe labeled the “realist position” em erg ing in the 1980s on the E u ro p e a n ideological left as well as in the cen ter. Although he was discussing G erm any , his description o f the policy goal also applied to Yugoslavia: “State policy should cease aspiring to the impossible, such as political guarantees o f (the restoration of) full e m p lo y m e n t.” Arguing not only that Keynesian instrum ents had “b eco m e b lu nt” but also that “th e re are no alternative ways o f achieving this goal, ” the realists, accord ing to Offe, abandon the orthodox goal o f integrating the unem ployed into th e “stable army o f em p loy ed ” and think “m ore in term s o f excluding labour from the m a rk e t.” F irst immigrants, then wom en, older workers, and young people should b e encouraged to drop out o f the labor force by policy m easures such as a “flexible reduction” o f paid working time, more “freed om of action” in self-help, “redundancy paym ents” through family policy and th e “sym bolic cu rrency o f ‘social recognition’, ” and a redefini tion o f work so as to maintain fa m ilies.111 In Yugoslavia, this policy was in effect an open admission— the first since the e m p lo y m e n t bureaus w ere reestablished in 1952— that the so cialist co m m itm e n t to full em p loy m ent could no longer be met. Yet there was nothing new for Yugoslavia about the solutions proposed by this “real ist” position in W e ste rn E u ro p e. This had b ee n the Yugoslav policy to p ro te ct individuals’ subsistence in periods o f unem ploym en t since 1952, and it had shaped the structure o f Yugoslav society, its moral economy regarding sub sistence and the right to work, and political attitudes about u n em p lo y m en t and the unem ployed. As the next chapter discusses, the social, cultural, and political conseq u ences o f the policy toward unem109 Su ch data w ere not collected for 1 9 4 8 - 5 3 , but indirect calculations from the census yield very rough estimates. T h e largest contingent after 1955 w ere ethnic Turks, while the earlier exodus also appears to have b een national in motivation. G erm ans, Italians, Turks, and Je w s left, largely as a result o f W orld W ar I I (Macura, Stanovništvo kao činilac privred
nog razvoja Jugoslavije, 69), 110 Gapinski, Skegro, and Zuelilke, Modeling, 135, 111 Offe, “T h r e e Perspectives on the Problem o f U n em plo ym en t,” 9 0 - 9 1 . l i e goes on to dem o n strate the lack o f relation betw een th ese proposals and the characteristics o f unem ploym ent, and thus that this approach is no solution (9 2 -9 5 ).
SLOVENIA AND FOČA
305
ploym ent in turn b e ca m e obstacles to political action that m ight have dem anded or proposed alternative solutions. T h e realism b eca m e self fulfilling, in that u n em p lo ym en t rem ained hidden. T h a t did not, how ever, p re v e n t its effects from having m ajor political co n se q u e n ce , as will be d iscussed in th e final chapter.
306
CHAPTER 8
A p p e n d ix “G a l e n i k a T a c k l e s t h e P r o b l e m o f R e d u n d a n t W o r k e r s ”
At the beginning o f this year, the planned task having b ee n completed, the w o rk ers’ council ordered the services in the m anagem ent to make a new systematization o f jo b s (a schem e indicating precisely the jobs ne ed e d in the factory, the n u m b e r o f workers and em ployees, and the qualifications they must have) and services need ed in the new enterprise. After a m onth, having c om p leted the systematization, the services concluded that the factory would have a surplus o f 160 workers and em ployees. T h e workers council informed the factory trade union com m ittee, the P e o p le ’s Youth c o m m ittee and o ther organizations about this, and asked th em to give their views on the proposed systematization, i.e ., the reor ganization o f the enterp rise. After close discussions at their sessions, the leaderships o f these organizations accepted the changes suggested. But they again pointed out the seriousness of the problem , and asked that it should b e systematically and carefully tackled. In the view of the political activists o f the factory, including the factory trade union com m ittee, the w o rk ers’ council should pay attention to certain principles when transfer ring workers to o th er econom ic organizations or institutions, and stick to them when deciding which man should go to another collective. T h e first o f these principles was to avoid transferring workers who had b e e n working in these factories for many years. T h e second principle was to transfer inferior workers, i.e ., those who had b ee n negligent in their duty. Suggestions w ere also made that when transferring people attention should b e paid to w h eth er he or she was the only e arner in the family, and if so, to transfer primarily those whose husband or wife worked. Among the workers there w ere som e who had retired and had pensions but, b e n efiting by the legal regulations, they continued to work. T h e standpoint of th e political activists was that such workers should b e the first to be trans ferred, and that those with the right to a pension should retire in any case. O f course th e re w ere other suggestions too, one of the most significant am ong them b eing that the transfer o f workers must be discussed by their com rad es in their e con om ic units. T h e w orkers’ council adopted these suggestions and worked out a list of workers that w ere supposed to go to o ther enterprises. T h e list was sub m itted to th e factory trade union co m m ittee with a requ est for remarks, if any. In o rd er to have a clea re r picture o f every worker proposed for trans fer, the trade union im m ediately organized the distribution of a question naire to all these workers and employees. Thus these trade union R ep rin ted from Yugoslav Trade Unions, no. 10, (S ep te m b e r 1963): 4 2 - 4 4
S LO V EN IA A N D FO ČA
307
members had to say what their vocational qualifications w ere, what kind of jo b th e y had done and for how long, w h eth er they w ere married, whether th e wife (or husband) worked, how many children they had, what the family incom e was, w h eth er they had received awards in the factory, or had b e e n punished for lack o f discipline, and if so why, and whether they had b e e n e le c te d to the workers’ council. Having received these data, the trade union organized m eetings of workers in the e con om ic units, at which they gave their opinion of this or that worker who was proposed for transfer. According to the original plan o f the m anagem ent, P . B . , a worker in the sales unit, was to b e transferred. M eanw hile, the econom ic unit held a different view, saying that he was a very good worker and that th ere were inferior workers in this service, and it proposed such a worker to the workers’ council for transfer. This view was supported by the political activists o f the factory, and o f course it was adopted by th e com mission o f the w orkers’ council in charge o f transfers. In an oth er e con om ic unit R . K . , an office em ployee, was also on the list for transfer. B u t at the m e e tin g of the econom ic unit it was said that she was pregnant and th erefore pro tected by the law. T h e change was made. O .M . was also to leave the factory. H e r e conom ic unit said that she really did not work satisfactorily, but added that she had b e e n a good worker at h e r previous jo b , and that she might b e sent back there. How ever, it was stated that h e r previous post was already filled, and so she was e n te re d on the list for transfer. T h e w orker D .S . was also on the list for transfer, but his e con om ic unit stressed that he was very conscientious and industrious and that he should rem ain in the factory. This view was adopted by the commission. It should b e added that in normal conditions the opinion o f the e c o nomic unit on dismissal or transfer, as well as on admission of workers, is valid and final. As the situation was exceptional in these cases, the e c o nomic units could only make suggestions, while the final decision was taken by the w orkers’ council through its commission. N evertheless, the views and suggestions o f the econom ic units considerably influenced the final decision o f the commission. According to the original plan, 160 workers w e re redundant. After discussion in the econom ic units this n u m b e r was red u ced to 148, b ecau se work was found in the factory itself for som e workers and em ployees who had b ee n proposed for transfer. Although th e action for transfer had b een extensively exam ined and carried out, fifty-four workers and em ployees who had to leave the factory appealed to the m anagem ent board o f the factory. To d ecide on these grievances as fairly as possible, the m anagem ent board subm itted them all to the trade union, with a requ est for its opinion. T h e trade union con v e n ed new m eetings in the econom ic units, and the workers reconsid
308
CHAPTER 8
e red each case. T h e trade union then submitted the workers’ views to the m an ag e m e n t board, which had b ee n authorized by the workers’ council to make the final decision. After a detailed study o f the complaints, the m a n a g e m e n t board allowed thirteen, so that finally the n u m b e r of those who had to go to o th er collectives was 135. B u t this com p leted only one part o f the business. T h e o ther part was to find work in o th e r collectives for the workers who had to leave the factory owing to redundancy. T h e w orkers’ council therefore ordered the expert services o f the e nterprise to contact im m ediately the neighboring facto ries and institutions to find jo b s for these workers and employees. Two m onths later this task was com pleted successfully. H e re are a few exam ples [of] how it was carried out. After the reorganization o f the new enterprise, the factory was left with som e em p ty business premises. T h e Prokupac enterprise for the sale of spirits was inte reste d in these p rem ises— it wanted to use them for the bottling o f wine. E vidently Prokupac was expanding its business. The G alenik a expert services learnt of this and agreed to hand over these p rem ises to Prokupac on condition that it should employ a number of G a len ik a ’s workers. Prokupac agreed and took over twenty workers. T h e institute for the training o f workers in Zemun was another partner with whom an a g re em en t was reached on the em ploym ent o f redundant workers. A sideline o f this institute was packing, and it did this for Gal enika. S in ce Galenika increased its production after the integration, it n e e d e d g re a te r quantities o f packing material, and this m eant in practice g re a te r production in the institute, i.e ., em ploy m ent of a g reater number o f workers. Thu s an arran g em ent was made with the institute for the e m p lo y m e n t o f a group o f redundant workers from Galenika. Sim ilar arrangem ents w ere made with the M etalac enterprise and some o th er collectives, so that all 135 workers and em ployees got new jo bs with th e help o f th e ir factory. After three months of intensive work on the p ro blem o f redundant manpower, the question was finally solved. M eanw hile the w orkers’ council was interested in what the workers in th e factory thought o f its action. At its request, the factory psychologist made a form o f inquiry in the collective: he talked with sixty workers and asked th e m th ree questions: why a n u m b e r o f workers had to leave the factory; what they thought o f the transfer procedure; and what, in their view, was the role o f the trade union in this action. T h e answ er to the first question was that the transfer o f workers had b e e n d em and ed by integration, i.e ., the e conom ic interests o f the enter prise. T h e answer to the second was that the procedure was democratic, that every bo dy in the factory could say what he or she thought of the red und an t workers. How ever, some w ere o f the opinion that the weak nesses o f th e individuals who w ere proposed for transfer should not have
S LO V E N I A A N D F O Ć A
309
been spoken o f in public, b u t com m unicated to them personally. As for the trade union role, the reply was that it was a good thing that the trade union had b e e n constantly consulted in this whole m atter; that it played its part successfully; and that its authority in the factory had risen since then.
Chapter 9 DIVISIONS O F LABOR
of socialist governm ents with full em ploym ent begins in th e n in etee n th century, when workers vulnerable to unemployment saw that it was in their econom ic interest to demand governmental re dress and eventually em p loy m e n t promotion. By the second half of the tw en tie th century, governm ents of all political persuasions were watching th e un em p lo y m en t figures b ecau se o f the potential for political conse q u e n ce s: strikes, civil unrest, or at least protest votes. In an analogy to the eco n o m ists’ co n cep t o f a natural rate of unem ploym ent, according to which a m arket econom y must expect b etw ee n 4 and 7 percent of the labor force to be “frictionally” unem ployed at any time, there is an un spoken assumption that th e re is also a natural level o f social tolerance for
T h e a s s o c ia t io n
un em p lo y m en t, above which such tolerance evaporates rapidly. Although C o m m u n is t parties ruling socialist states w ere not vulnerable to electoral defeat, this did not pre v e n t them from b eing con c ern e d as well about possible d iscontent and maintaining their authority as working-class par ties. T h e party’s power and the re g im e ’s political stability, it was gener ally argued, rested ultimately on the political legitimacy that came from full em p loy m e n t: on the basis o f a tacit social contract b etw een govern m e n t and wage or salary earners, citizens rem ained politically passive in exchange for jo b security. I f socialist parties originated in the struggle against un em p lo y m en t in capitalist societies, surely unem ploym ent in so cialist societies would lead to political opposition and demands for a change in policy. T h e failure o f socialist g o v ernm ent in Yugoslavia to prevent unemploy m e n t from rising above frictional rates or to alter policies that led to not only cyclical b u t even structural un em ploym en t by the mid-1960s can be explained by the lead ers’ continuing b e lie f in their strategy (reinforced by foreign creditors), the vested interest o f influential producers and repub lican g ov ernm ents in their particular international niche, and the vicious circles o f policy and politics d escribed at the end o f chapter 7. But these cannot explain the virtual silence about un em p lo y m en t1 and the absence 1 W ritin g in 1982, Iwo years after Yugoslavia luid achieved the highest level o f unemploy m en t in E u ro p e, Tijanie and Andjelie reported, “T h e re are economists who think we were late by a quarter o f a century in putting em ploym ent into midterm [economic] plans, hut it was still pushed to the bottom of the list of goals and tasks" (“Obieno nezaposleni mladi”).
DI V IS I O N S OK LABOR
311
of political protest by the unem ployed or by persons vulnerable to u n e m ployment who recognized their interest in com m on cause. W h y did groups that w e re system atic losers econom ically in Yugoslav society— such as w om en, youth, unskilled urban labor, the rural reserve, poorer com munities, and the less-developed regions and repu blics— not choose to improve their e co n o m ic position through, following the model o f labor parties, political organization and mutual alliances to press for change in central policies? This paradox arises from the final e le m e n t o f the leaders approach to labor. Although their strategy failed to prevent un em ploym en t, it suc ceeded in its goal o f elim inating capitalist unem ploym ent. T h e re were certainly obstacles to political organization in the constitutional privileges of the C o m m u n ist party and the limits on ind epend en t political associa tions, but far m ore significant in explaining the a b sence o f a politics of unem ploym ent w ere the characteristics of socialist un em ploym en t and the a cce p ta n ce in Yugoslav society o f the official attitude toward it. By aiming to avoid mass layoffs and to prevent proletarianization with a public guarantee o f subsistence, the regim e transformed the p u b lic’s view of un em ploy m en t. In place o f the oppositional logic of private property and class solidarity o f labor against capital, moreover, the system o f em ploy ment, reward, and reassignm ent created a logic o f individual com petition and status achieved according to regulated criteria for m em b ership and exclusion. Conflict occu rred over those criteria and over com petition to improve individual “capital” as a means to em p loy m e n t— w h eth er through schooling, personal or political contacts and loyalties, or migration. T h e division o f society into public and private sectors, to pro te ct the strategy’s co m m itm e n t to a lean public sector and rising labor productivity, also elim inated the reciprocal relation b etw ee n econom ic and political power that is found in m arket econom ies with private ownership and that formed the basis o f a com m on interest b etw ee n the em ployed and the unem ployed. T h e dual face o f capitalist un em plo y m en t discussed in ch a p ter 1, which lim ited w orkers’ power but also provided the political incentives to organize societywide against u n em ploym ent, was thereby elim inated as well. B eca u se labor markets w ere primarily local or re p u b li can, the countryw ide level o f u n em plo y m en t had little influence on labor’s strength in bargaining with managers or governm ents over jo b s and wages, and th e level of un em plo y m en t had little influence on the political strength of a party whose power dep end ed not on electoral support but on in terna tional lev erage (and, in local and republican com m ittees, on control over econ om ic resources). T h e reason labor governm ents pursue full e m p loym ent in m arket e co n o m ie s— that it serves both the econom ic in te re st o f th e ir constituents and the political interest o f their political organizations— did not hold.
312
CHAPTER 9
T h e socialist com m unities o f K a rd e lj’s vision, ironically, did not create societywide solidarity but instead segm ented society into separate uni verses o f decision making on em ploy m ent and in co m e — by the division of p roperty rights b e tw e e n the two sectors, the separate labor and capital m arkets of the republics, and the long-term em ploym ent contracts and autonom ous bargaining over wages and benefits within self-managed workplaces. E x ten s iv e decentralization and the absence o f a formal mar k e t for labor (so as to maintain direct incentives to productivity) were substantial barriers to the perception o f a com mon interest in reducing u n em p lo y m en t and to the construction o f societywide social alliances nec essary for effective pressure. As some intellectuals complained in the 1960s, this was a society com posed of many distinct “reservations.”2 In sum, social identities, moral econom y, and political organization w ere shaped by the lead ers’ strategy toward labor— and in turn sustained that strategy.
S o c ia l I n v is ib il it y o f Un e m p l o y m e n t
T h e official c o n c ep t o f un em ploym en t in socialist Yugoslavia was to be without means o f subsistence; as Bakarić said in 1982, the unemployed w ere “p eople with now here to go. ”3 H e n ce the political importance of the m echanism s that aim ed to prevent this: the guaranteed minimum wage for p e o p le in pu blic-sector jo b s and protected smallholdings in privatesector agriculture and services. Popular opinion reflected this official con ception. T h e most com m on response of both citizens and specialists when confronted with the facts o f un em ploym en t was that it was “not the E n glish k in d .” In this view, un em ploym en t did not mean the penury or proletarianization o f classic industrialization; anyone who wished could always return to the land and survive. This attitude was reinforced by the official solution to unemployment: to move truly surplus labor from agriculture into industry and, when eco nom ic rationalization created surplus labor in industry, to fire those who had sources o f subsistence such as land or a family— thus making dis missal decisions a family affair involving the farm household or workers’ organizations within the socialist-sector work community. Although the goal o f these transfers was to incorporate an ever-larger proportion of the population into the income relations o f industrial organization and princi ples o f socialist accumulation (direct incentives to increase individual and collective productivity), the effect was to build society around social rela 2 S e e M . M irić, Rezervati. ;i Bakarić, who was speaking with a delegation from Titograd University (Montenegro), i.s q uo ted in T ijauie and An djelić, “O b ično nezaposleni mladi.” Tijan ić and An djelić add that Bakarić must have been “thinking th ey ’re a m inority,”
313
DI V IS IO N S O F LABOR
tions and concepts o f welfare m ore closely resem bling those o f the p re in dustrial household. K a rd e lj’s m odel o f socialist com m unities harks back to an earlier age o f agrarian moral econom y, particularly in the ideal type associated with the theories o f A. V. Chayanov, author o f the classic study of Russian smallholding and peasant econom y, or with the populist glori fication o f th e zadruga in the Balkans.4 T h e socialist com m unity was like wise c e n te re d on production, guaranteed subsistence to its m e m b ers, and— only after the basic survival o f individuals and the collectivity was assured, and on the basis o f d em ocratic consultation among adults— distributed ne t earnings to m e m b ers according to their seniority, m ana gerial authority, and contributions to output. In socialist Yugoslavia, the public-sector e n te rp rise (divided into basic organizations o f associated la bor), th e farm household, the urban family, and the migrant keeping close ties to family at hom e all practiced collective solidarity to provide subsis ten ce.5 O nly “when a work collective cannot guarantee the constitutional right to work’ 6 from its reserve fund and the c o m m u n e ’s standing soli darity fund would the larger social com m unity e n te r to provide temporary relief for people made un em ployed as a result of industrial restructuring. U n em p loym en t was a social, not an econom ic, problem o f redistribution after a production cycle. It was as if the populist e le m e n ts o f th e 1940 alliance and the private, small-property sector defined the model for so cial relations in the urban socialized sector, rather than the o th er way around.7 According to this con cep t o f u n em ploym ent, people differed not in tlieir vulnerability to u n em p lo y m en t (except for the few m onths’ waiting time that was consid ered normal for a first jo b or for reassignment), but in their disposable incomes. T h e problem o f jo blessness was supplanted by that o f living standards, so that u n em plo y m en t itself did not arouse much sympathy. Although families differed substantially in the vulnerability of their m e m b e r s to u n em plo y m en t, its co n se q u e n ces w ere seen only as part o f th e m ore g eneral personal struggle to improve living standards and as part o f the continu um of incom e inequality, which d ep end ed on many factors. T h e discrimination against women and youth in hiring and firing 1
On this moral econom y, see J Scott, The Moral Economy o f the Peasant; on the role oi
Chayanov’s views in Soviet debates, see Cox, Peasants, Class, and Capitalism; and on the
zadruga, see Byrn es, Communal Families in the Balkans. 5 T h e mixed farm er-w orker households o f Slovenia, w here an extensive netw ork of good roads and diversified local industries and services made it possible for households to engage in a variety o f e co n o m ic activities while rem aining settled, may have b e e n th e unconscious model instead. T h e Law on Labor Relations o f 1967, cited in Yugoslav Survey 8 ,
110.
3 (August 1967):
21.
7 In this and many oth er situations, Yugoslavs familiar with th e programs o f th e Croat Peasant party in the interwar period have seen many parallels.
314
CHAPTER 9
was a cc e p tc d b ecause the “family” (the cash earnings of the employed m e m b e r ) would take care of them, redistributing what it had to ensure th e survival o f all m e m b ers. U nem ployed urban youth remained in pa rental hom es while they waited for public-sector jobs. Urban and rural families relied on networks o f kin and ritual kin for private exchange of agricultural produce and connections with urban schooling and jo bs. Mi grant w orkers— w h e th e r C roat eng ineers in Germ any, Bosnian factory workers in Slovenia, S e rb villagers in Austrian and G erm an construction, or Albanian confcctioners in the northern Yugoslav republics— sent m oney hom e to sustain their families and contribute to their means of d om estic subsistence: the house, farmland, and bank account for durable goods. T h e underlying solidarity on subsistence and incom e— not on em ploy m e n t and its associated rights in the socialized sector— even led to unions’ willingness to fire persons who could earn second incomes in the private sector, as well as to a widespread but largely incorrect view that m u ch h ig h er incom es could b e earned in the private sector. T h e c o n s e q u e n c e o f this approach was to make the truly unemployed invisible. T h e relative a b se n ce o f sociological and psychological studies on the un em ployed helped to nurture the prevailing view. Popular opinion m irrored th e n in etee n th -cen tu ry idea in the official presentation of un e m p lo y m e n t data— that un em ploym en t was voluntary or short-lived, a ch oice for leisure instead o f work made according to household stan dards o f consum ption. O pen un em ploym en t was equ ated with foreign m igration— citiz e n s’ choosing to work temporarily abroad for the higher incom es they could earn in the more industrialized north of Europe.8 Official jo b s eek ers at hom e w ere dismissed as persons who registered with e m p lo y m e n t bureaus in order to get health insurance and still be at leisu re— a view that was a poorly disguised preju d ice against “women who d o n ’t really want to work” and who bloated the unem ploym ent fig ures. T h e m ore prevalent image was o f the “un em ploym ent of the em p lo y e d ”9 in pu blic-secto r offices, an image based on the milling throngs on urban streets during working hours— people who ought to be at their desk b u t w e re enjo y ing a coffee or a stroll instead. T h e physiocrats’ “le e c h e s ” w ere alive and well in popular culture. In th e search for higher incom e, unskilled and semiskilled blue-collar HW h ile som e economists in the 1970s and 1980s began to include this foreign migration in m easu res o f “tru e” unem ploym ent at h om e (see Primorae and Babic, "System ic Changes and
U nem ploym en t
G row th ”;
and
M encinger,
“U tjeeaj
privredne
aktivnosti
na
zaposlenost”), official views pointed to the large n um ber o f migrants abroad who had been em ployed as professionals and skilled workers before they left. T h e fact o f joblessness (the pro b lem o f “filling em pty b ellies”) was, in these views, separated from the motivation to m igrate outside the country for higher incom es or to solve the migrant s “housing problem” at h o m e (which, according to opinion surveys, was a more frequent reason for migration). See. “S o m e Basic F eatu res o f Yugoslav External M igration.” 9 M en cin ger, “Privredna re forma i ne zaposlenost.''
D I V IS I O N S O F LABOR
315
workers did resort to work stoppages and strikes. B u t skilled production workers, who had w h atev er m arket leverage th ere might have b ee n over wages b ec au se th e y w e re m ore often in shortage and w ere politically re p resented, w e re m ore inclined to improve their prospects in the unofficial economy, w h ere opportunities for moonlighters (electricians, repair workers, and those in th e building trades) could b e lucrative. T h e stratum of “fluctuators” so harshly criticized by Boris Kidric in 1949 stretched from peasant-w orkers to th e c ore o f the industrial class. Skilled industrial workers did th e opposite o f what Kardelj planned for the kulaks: to end their control o v er rural m ark ets— without destroying th e ir productive capacity— b y gradually incorporating them into the socialist sector and its industrial m entality and thus w eakening their foot in the private sector. Instead, skilled workers k ept one foot in the secure and benefit-granting public sector and stepped with the o th er into a second, private jo b to su pp lem ent their in com e and pro tect them selv es against u n em ploym ent. Middle strata in cities and tourist areas, too, e n te re d the world o f private profits by renting to subtenants or foreigners, dealing in foreign cu rrency, or taking on work in private-sector tourism, retailing, or a g ricu ltu re.10 T h e diluted principles o f th e socialist sector w ere not replaced, how ever, by those o f th e m arket, for the markets in which these people par ticipated w e re local, specialized, and unregulated. As with the reversion to a m o re traditional institution in the co n c ep t o f the work com m unity, a halfway house b e tw e e n agrarian and socialist society see m e d to em e rg e in which personal conn ections, early advantages in urban housing and socialist-sector em p loy m e n t, and nonm arket allocation o f goods replaced K idric’s idea o f th e rational calculation o f econom ic incentives to in creased productivity and production for m arket dem and. W h e n villagers sent th e ir child ren to live with urban cousins for education b eyond e l e m entary school and in exchange provided their relatives with food, the urban hou seh old ’s consum ption o f agricultural produce expanded, divert ing that produ ce from th e m arket; the effectiveness o f m onetary in c e n tives to b oth farm ers and their urban relatives was diluted; and local bal ances b e tw e e n labor supply and dem and w ere disrupted by outsiders seek ing access to socialist-sector jo b s through th e ir relatives. Migrants without family in th e cities form ed urban clubs o f people from th e ir own region or republic, creating a network o f mutual assistance for housing and jo b s along regional and eth n ic lines; or they relied on political a venu es— party m e m b ersh ip and political activism— to improve their access to housing and a jo b . T h o se without rural ties and d irect access to food, such as the d escendants o f the core o f th e prew ar industrial work ing class, felt m o re intensely th e fall in the value o f their incomes. T h e principles o f selection for deciding whom to fire first in a rational111 S e e I Bicanic, “T h e Inequality Im pact of the Unofficial Eco n o m y in Yugoslavia.
316
CHAPTER 9
ization also p erp etu ated the social attitudes and habits that originally shaped those principles. T h e assumption that women or rural residents would not lack for housing and material support (despite the large num b e r o f single or divorced women and the many villagers without land) reinforced traditional attitudes toward w o m e n ’s em p loy m ent and family roles. Rural households held onto land as insurance, leaving aged women to cultivate it alone and thus reinforcing the low productivity o f the land and th e p reju d ices against peasant-w orkers— that their mentality re m ained that o f small property ow ners “tied to their land.”11 W o m e n were m ore likely to accep t downward reassignm ent and retraining and to re fuse nomination to e lective positions (such as in the workers’ council or parliament) so that they would have more time for the additional house hold duties— above all child c a re — imposed by the traditional division of household labor and the inadequate d evelopm ent of public services.12 T h e result was to dim inish further their political influence on spending priorities and e m p loy m e n t and to rein force preju dices about their productivity. Rules designed to pro tect workers— such as the obligation of manage m e n t to inform the union when dismissing five or m ore workers at once, the assignm ent o f jo b s com m ensu rate with skills, and the prohibition against layoff o f workers who w ere on leave for military service or voca tional training, w ere pregnant, or had infants up to age o n e — became reasons not to em ploy certain persons in the first place: youth who had not co m p le te d their military service, women who might b eco m e preg nant, and the disabled, the unskilled, and others o f presum ed lower pro ductivity (especially re ce n t migrants from the countryside), all of whom filled th e u n em p lo y m en t rolls in such high proportions. E n te rp rise direc tors insisted that th ere w ere no restrictions on dismissing a worker, as long as they followed the rules on prior warning and kept good records; but the long and involved process may have encouraged caution in hiring. F a c e d with high rates o f female un em ploym ent, local authorities and e m p loy m ent bureaus also reinforced occupational divisions o f labor by chan neling w om en into jo b s for which they were “suited”— textiles, food processing, health care, education, and office work. B u t these w ere lowwage sectors more vulnerable to fluctuation in world market price and d em and and to labor cuts for rationalization in g overnm ent and enterprise b u d g e t s . 13 11 Like so m uch else in this social portrait, this was a widespread characteristic in socialist Eastern Europe. S e e H. Scott, "W h y the Revolution D oesu t Solve Everything. 12 M ihovilovié et al , Žena izmedju rada i porodice. 1:1 T his strategv was particularly explicit in Macedonia (Tripo Mulina, interview with author, O c to b e r 1982) In 1978, women made up 78 percent o f the labor force in the produc tion o f finished textiles and til percent in linen and textiles (Woodward, W o m e n ," 246)
The Rights of
DI VI SI ON S O F LABOR
317
The con cep t o( e m p loy m e n t as a bundle oi rights attached to a social relation o f work" (radni odnos) in the public sector also created a world of social distinctions and com petition within that sector that w ere based on status. E m p lo y m e n t was regulated by statutory rules in the constitution, legislation, and negotiated ag reem ents on eligibility, incomes, and reas signment. It defined a status in society, o n e ’s relative prestige and share in incom e and benefits, based on the assumptions about productivity built into these rules. Most important, it defined a status legally separate trom that ol the un em ployed person or person employed in the private sector. Protests against threats to em p loy m ent took the form, as the official sys tem expected , ol individualized appeals— to fellow workers on the inju s tice oi a dismissal or unwanted reassignment, or to law courts, lawyers, and paralegal bodies on its legality. D esp ite the political rhetoric praising the worth of production workers, the statutory rules on incom e distribution and jo b -rela te d perquisites (in cluding rules formulated in bargained “c o m p a c ts ’ among governm ent, business, and labor) actually reinforced earlier values as well. T h e e m phasis on formation of human capital and on parity b etw ee n jo b classifica tion and formal skill qualification gave those with higher education a higher social status, wage rate, and priority lor benefits such as housing, and it maintained the im portance that formal education was accorded in the prewar c u l t u r e . 14 Those who achieved the appropriate educational qualifications cam e to expect em ploym ent, often viewing their school di plomas as a right to a job ol a particular category. Anecdotal evidence is rich with instances of unem ployed youth who refused jo b offers b ecause the position was b eneath the status ol the occupation for which they had trained. Education was particularly important to parents in the private sector, who saw investm ent in their ch ild re n ’s education as the avenue to public-seetor jo b s , upward social mobility, and a family’s inheritance. At the same time, it was com m onp lace to explain un em ploym en t in poorer regions as the “overproduction o f intellectuals” trained in liberal profes sions (a phrase also used by the king to justify closing rural gimnazije during the depression of the 1920s and 1930s) and to attack as irrational the investm ent in proliferating universities in provincial and regional towns (such as Pristina, Rijeka, and Nis) in the 1970s. But at an individual level, this strategy for upward mobility was rational. T h e Slovene model of Kardelj and Kidric envisioned the state as a body of rule-m aking experts that needed no authority with independ ent pro ducers o ther than that afforded by expertise and professional c o m p e tence. But the lead ers’ need to build authority rapidly after 1950 led them to draw heavily on the symbols of status in the culture of the 1940s. T h e fourth plenum of the central co m m ittee in Ju n e 1951 devoted most of its ' 1 S e e Trim ton, Peasant Renaissance in Yugoslavia
318
CHAPTER 9
agenda on the design o f the new state to the authority o f the law courts and ju d g es (“one o f the strongest weapons we had and that a state can have in its own h a n d s ,” Kardelj explained). T h e y would gain the public’s re sp ect, Tito and Kardelj insisted, if professional standards w ere raised and prew ar qualifications revived, and if their social status were improved with h ig her salaries, b e tte r housing, and a return to the offices in their prew ar buildings, w h ere p o ss ib le .15 Liberal campaigns in the 1950s, 1960s, and 1980s that aimed to replace an “older, poorly schooled Partisan g e n era tio n ” holding down positions o f authority on the basis of war ser vice (and by implication, all those in the army and police apparatus) with th e younger generation on the basis o f formal skill qualifications also im puted g re a te r authority to formal criteria o f expertise. T h e ir language of productivity and m odernity rein forced the perception o f a privileged sta tus for human capital and education and the lower social worth ascribed to the realm o f the “political. ” This began early, as can be seen in the skepti cal receptio n given R ankovic’s proposal at the second party plenum in Ja nu ary 1949 for improving the authority o f party cadres by upgrading their perquisites (and thus status). This conflict in values was exacerbated in those cases in which jo b com petition did o cc u r— when youth waiting for e ver-scarcer openings com p e te d with th e administrators, security police, and military personnel sent into the econom y with the successive waves o f demobilization and d ecentralization, and when educated youth who chose not to join the party co m p e te d with their peers who did. A national survey in 1971 of the Partisan e lite (the “first fighters,” who had jo in e d the Partisans in 1941) found that m ore than half had b ee n retired before pension age, that 27 p e rce n t had incom es below the legal minimum, and that they “com plained most o f social isolation, inactivity, and lack o f prestige. ” In 1972, o f 4 3 7 , 7 0 9 veterans in Serbia, only 3 2 pe rce n t w ere e m p lo y e d .16 This p ercep tion o f com petition and relative worth was nurtured by the regula tions on e m p lo y m e n t and reward, b ecause they specified differentials among legally defined groups to which individuals belonged according to th e ir jo b qualifications. Qualitative im provem ents or upward mobility cam e not with increased effort but by moving up through categories of relative status. T h e re w ere generally two legitimate means: educational advance (through special courses, training abroad, or night school)17 or 13 Pc-tranovic, Koncar, and Radonjic, Sednice Ccntralnap, kumitetu KPj (1948-1952), 565; see also Kankovic’s report, p. 534. This was the same reason Rankovic gave, in his report on the party to th e second plenum o f the central co m m ittee in January 1949, for improving what h e called th e miserable living conditions o f party cadres; this argum ent was reversed in 1952 (ibid , 2 0 2 - 6 , 251), ,(i D e a n , “Civil-M ilitary Relations in Yugoslavia, 1 9 7 1 - 7 5 , ” 54 n 34, 5 0 17 O n e especially com m on path was to take a m aster’s d egree in middle age so that the category o f o n e ’s position, and th erefore one s pension, was raised
D I V IS I O N S O F LABOK
319
political activism. Although many com bined the two routes, th e growing unem ployment o f educated youth after 1972, the greater d irect party in volvement in decisions on managerial and professional appointm ents d ur ing the 1970s, and th e further ’’’socialization” o f political cadres in the party, security forces, and army rein forced the b e l ie f that th e re was a contest b e tw e e n educational a ch iev em en t and the political reliability of party m em b ersh ip . Moral-ideological com missions created to review ap pointments in education and the mass media after 1974, although they rarely o v ertu rn ed the recom m end ations o f p eer-review personnel c o m missions ju d g in g professional qualifications, gave new life to this belief. When youth did not secu re the jo b their schooling had ordained, the language o f e m p lo y m e n t regulations and political campaigns made it nat ural to assum e (and difficult to refute) that the rules had not b e e n applied, that th e re was discrimination. Rival candidates had won, they assumed, only b eca u se o f party m e m b ersh ip or political con n ection s— or, in areas of mixed nationality, b ecau se o f national quotas (the ključ) or eth n ic p re ju dice and p r o te c tio n .18 At the same tim e, the dem and for production workers o f all kinds in the 1970s often w ent unfilled. Heavy physical labor in low-paying jo b s , such as mining, was perennially short o f takers. Unskilled and sem iskilled in dustrial workers had no prospect o f anything m ore than marginal im provem ents in pay. T h e ir wage gains from work stoppages and strikes did not co m p en sa te for th e depressive effect o f stabilization policies, incom es compacts, and growing inflation (especially after the m id-1970s) on their real incom es; and th e system o f individualized layoff and reallocation m ar ginalized them politically. Training in industrial skills was unpopular. As the Se rb ian labor secretary M arija Todorović com plained in 1982, the “greatest p ro blem o f harm onizing personal and collective in terests” in the Yugoslav system lay “in the contradictions expressed in the field o f e m ploym ent and reassignm ent to m ore-com p lex tasks”; its most fre q u e n t manifestation was the “many who argue for the education of youth in productive tasks and highly skilled [technical] education b u t who send their child ren into occupations for which th ere are already tens o f th o u sands o f u n e m p lo y e d .” Stipe Suvar, the Croat sociologist-politician most closely identified with the reform o f secondary education, warned the same y ear that the country was “in for difficult tim es in this d eca d e ” b e cause o f the conflict b e tw e e n a slowing econom y and the “expectations” o f 1N T h e presiden t o f the Serbian League o f Youth complained in 1982 that a “greater p roblem than un em ploym en t itse lf is th e com petition, myth, corruption, familiarity, co n nections, e t c ., in finding a j o b . ” R eflecting on the additional role o f social status, h e contin ued, “A youth will wait patiently for four to five years, knowing the eco n o m ic situation and low dem and for his profession, but his p atience is lost if som eone who graduated after him with poorer grades but from a b e t te r social position gets a jo b first” (quoted in T ija n ić and Andjelić, “O b ičn o nezaposleni mladi”).
320
CHAPTER 9
youth, which had led to a “hyperproduction o f ‘nonproductive’ intel ligentsia in the towns” and an “explosion o f higher education to a patho logical e x te n t.” H e com plained that “peasant children and workers’ child ren will do anything to avoid their p a rents’ fate and want to leave d irect production, w hereas those in the middle classes are striving to maintain or improve their position. Any petty office work is to he chosen over factory w o rk .”19 T h e official rheto ric prom oting increases in capital, including human capital, was im bu ed with the idea of achieved, not ascribed, status. But access to e m p lo y m e n t b eca m e ev e r less an issue of the expansion of the p u blic sector to incorporate a primarily peasant population and ever more a m atter o f in ternal turnover within the socialized sector and of the per sonal or political influence that an urban younger generation had with individuals already employed. W h ile parents in the private sector viewed education expend itures as their ch ild re n ’s patrimony, fathers in the pub lic sector w e re reported to see their legacy to their children as having a jo b waiting for them. In a comparison of the unemployed in Split, Croatia, in 1968 and 1981, sociologists Josip Zupanov and Mladen Zuvela found the sam e groups represented : youth, women, the unskilled or dis abled, migrants, and poorer strata. B ut their social origins had changed significantly. P eo ple o f peasant stock w ere less well represented, because th e ir nu m bers had dropped in the population at large. Children o f profes sionals or white-collar workers w ere no b e tte r represented in 1981 than in 1 968, reflecting their continued good position and political power in soci ety. Similarly, w orkers’ children had opportunities for work abroad if they did not already have access to public-sector enterprises. B u t two groups suffered particularly for their lack of influence in the public sector of the econom y. T h e children o f private artisans depended for their oppor tunities on continuing their schooling, but they could not com pete with w o rk ers’ or professionals’ children after graduation because their parents had no conn ections with a public-sector jo b that they could pass on or use as an e n tre e to another. T h e children o f parents in the defense establish m ent, in which th e re was no m ore dem and for personnel, fared worst; their p a re n ts ’ influence was outside econom ic enterprises in the socialist s e c t o r .20 P o l it ic a l E x c l u sio n
A seco nd c o n se q u e n ce o f the system created by the leaders’ strategy and its approach to u n em p lo y m en t was to segregate the political world of the 19 Suvar, “Plave i b e le kragn e.” 20 Zupanov and Zuvela, “K riteriji inferioniosti nezaposlenih.” T h e mothers ol children in the la tter category had lived with a double disadvantage in access to jo b s — on top ol their
DI VI SI ON S O F LABOR
321
em ployed from that o f th e unem ployed. In addition to social invisibility, there d eveloped a form o f political invisibility as a result o f the end to unem ploym en t in its mass, involuntary form and as a result o f the dual sector approach to u n em plo y m en t, with its distinction in political rights that arose from a political system structured around the econ om ic system. T h e level o f un em p lo y m en t significantly affected bargaining power in the econom y— b u t in bargaining over m oney and credit b etw ee n collective units o f property owners (republics, enterprises, and banks), not b etw ee n workers and em ployers, or among workers in ways that could lead to the political solidarity o f workers with the unem ployed. T h e threat o f u n em p lo y m en t in the socialized sector was individu alized, and e m p lo y m e n t and wages w ere regulated according to measures of individual capital (econom ic, political, and social). W h e th e r the loss o f a jo b in th e socialist sector led to retraining, reassignment, or expulsion into the private sector, it was executed by w orkers’ organizations (the workers’ council, its disciplinary c om m ittee, the union, or the self m anag em ent courts), not by managers or political authorities. Social ow n ership bound em ployed persons’ interests in higher wages and secure jo b s to th e e c o n o m ic results of their employers, even if those results w ere not sufficient to guarantee their continued em ploym ent. In the political system , as d escribed in chapter 5, “e con om ic in te re s t” was a constitutional concept, granting political rights to participate in e c o nom ic decisions and policy in proportion to e con om ic value produced in the pu blic sector. T h o se who did not produce value (the unem ployed) did not have such official rights, while those who did had no need to organize. In te re s t was not an unstructured political incentive defined by labor m arket com petition or w orkers’ organizational resources. To b e u n em ployed m ean t above all to b e politically excluded from the full citizenship accorded to the status o f em p loy m e n t in the socialized sector o f the e c o n omy. P eo ple em ployed in the private sector could b e re p re sen ted politi cally only in local and neighborhood assem blies o f voters and could organize according to e con om ic interests only through contractual rela tions with a socialist-sector enterprise. C entral policy was formulated by a host o f councils, assem blies, par liaments, and corporatist negotiations, all of which rep resented only social-sector producers (though variously called workers, organizations of associated labor, or enterprises). Alliances to influence policy occurred gend er, they w ere often outsiders in their com m unities because they moved frequently to accom pany th eir husbands. In a survey o f attitudes in M acedonia in 1981, respondents ranked unequal em ploym ent opportunities as th e first and most painful source of social inequality,” far m ore important than housing, education, wages, and o th e r material goods (Kimov, “Da li se povecavaju socijalne razlike?”).
322
CHAITl'H 9
am ong managers o f e n terprises, along industrial-hranch lines within the e con om ic ch am b e rs (privredne komore), and am ong e le cte d delegates in the halls of parliaments. Such alliances w ere highly influential— above all those o f the exporters, on whom the cou ntry’s capacity to import (and increasingly to produce) d epended. But if such virtual representation did not m e e t the interests o f workers or o f the unem ployed waiting for openings, then the institutional assignm ent o f jurisdiction over labor and e m p lo y m e n t to republics, localities, and firms and the vertical, terri torial organization o f the political system m eant that the independent in terests ol labor or the unem ployed could b e represented only by the single voice o f their e n te rp rise or republic. T h e institutional avenues of political influence and bargaining gave no way to assess the economic costs o f u n em p lo y m en t in the country at large, or to formulate political trade-offs b etw ee n wages and jo bs. In all these ways, the dual face of capitalist un em ploym en t had been su n d e re d — by the system o f econom ic dem ocracy that linked political representatio n to pro d u ce r-ce n te re d econom ic organization and by the property division b etw ee n public and private sectors (instead of between labor and capital). T h e two organizations explicitly representing the inter ests o f labor— the C o m m u n ist party and the union organization— are usu ally dismissed in the literature as having failed this task because they also b e c a m e official organizations, guaranteed political power constitutionally instead o f having to co m p e te with o th er parties and unions for it. But this view is insufficient to understand the roles they did play, which (as with com p etitive parties in a m arket economy) were defined by the particular organization o f the econom y and the state that resulted from the leaders’ ideology. T h e idea of social ow nership means that the party should represent the collective interests o f all working p eople— o f society as a w hole— above th e ir particular interests (served by the many other official forms o f repre sentation, such as firms, localities, industries, and professional groups). In Kardelj s model o f progressive socialization and decentralization to evis ce rate federal (state) power and to cut social expenditures on “nonproduc tiv e ” labor, the C o m m u n ist party’s importance and its p resen ce in social life w e re supposed to grow in proportion as the state (the bureaucracy, army, and police) was dismantled and its functions integrated into firms and co m m u n e s. But b ecause the party did not have a separate administra tive b ureaucracy or the formal system of nomenklatura found in countries o f “b u re au cra tic socialism ,” it increasingly d ep end ed for its power on the ability to influence who held authoritative positions within society. B e c a u s e the e conom ic criteria o f professional co m p eten ce and productivity-related skills could not be ignored, the party’s solution was to recruit managers and professionals into its m em bership. Industrial workers ne v e r composed more than 36 pe rce n t of L C Y m em b ership, a
D I VI S IO NS O F LABOIi
323
figure from the height o f the recru itm en t campaign o f 1 9 6 0 - 6 4 to favor skilled workers; two years later, rising un em ploym en t sent that propor tion plum m eting, the most frequent cause for expulsion being nonpay ment o f d u e s .21 Peasants had com posed half the party’s m e m b ersh ip after the war, but their num bers declined with the campaign o f the fifth party congress to recru it workers in 1948 and then dropped drastically after 1952, from 2 2 p e rc e n t in 1954 to less than 5 p e rce n t by 19 7 6 .22 By 1964, the party had b eco m e an organization of administrators and professionals. A Yugoslav c ontrib u tor to a study of “w orkers’ m an ag em en t” for the I n te r national L a b o r Office gave this explanation: “T h e proportion of League m em b ers is generally higher in managerial organs and in delegations than among the workers who e le c t them . M e m b ersh ip in the League is, in fact, a criterion for election to such bodies in some cases, since L eague m em bers are d e e m e d to b e motivated to defend and develop the m anage ment rights o f w o rk e rs.”23 Managers w ere e le cte d by em ployees in a firm (though approved by the local party com m ittee and governm ent), unless the firm was under tem porary local governance in a prebankruptcy re structuring; a firm ’s representatives in the assem bly were also chosen by employees. But to prevent conflicts o f interest in the decisions they took, those perform ing e le cte d functions w ere granted job security. T h e law prohibited their involuntary dismissal, and it protected the jo bs to which they would return if they w ere voted out or when their tenure ex p ire d .24 Labor regulations also required firms to hold open the jo b s and continue the salaries o f e m p loy ees on leave for official business or military service. Managers with d em onstrated loyalty to the local party c o m m ittee would, if temporarily unem ployed, receive a salary from party coffers until a new position could b e found. T h e s e protections for party-approved managers were the source of widespread criticism , from the accusation that the party had created a privileged “new class” (Milovan D jila s ’s thesis in his revival o f a classic socialist th e m e in the 1950s) to the charge that it had reproduced an infor mal nom enklatura indistinguishable from that of state-socialist regim es of the Soviet type. M e m b e r s o f this stratum of managers who owed their positions to party m e m b ersh ip or approval defended these protections, however, as the basis of in d e p e n d en ce from popular pressures within a firm when hard econ om ic decisions had to b e made (along the lines of theories of insulated b u rea u cra cies).2'’ No mention was made from e ith er 21 S e e S e r o k a , C h a n g e a n il R e f o r m o f th e L e a g u e oj C o m m u n i s t s in Y u g o s la v ia , 2 9 - 3 3 . 22 Y u g o s l a v S u r v e y 17,
110
s
1.2 ( F e b r u a r y , M a y 1976).
23 I n t e r n a t i o n a l L a b o r Office, E m p lo y m e n t., G r o w t h , a n d B as ic N e e d s . K it 21
T e n u r e w as l i m i t e d a fte r 1963 to tw o t e r m s , b u t t h e lim ita tio n w as o lte n i g n o r e d in
p r a c tic e 25 S e e t h e S ta r t i n t e r v i e w w ith T o m is la v R ado vi nac , th e m a n s e n t in to o v e r s e e th e r e s t r u c t u r i n g ot t h e i n d e b t e d F.coiioinic Bank ol Z a g r e b (t he r e p u b l i c a n b a n k ot Croa tia).
324
CHAPTER 9
cam p o f tlie fact that e le cte d representatives in parliamentary bodies were im m u ne from un em plo y m en t and therefore any personal econom ic inter est in solidarity with the fate of the unemployed. M o re ov e r, the effect of growing unem ploym ent, as well as the party’s rationalizing response to it, was not to create a political opportunity to revive its identity as a labor party or its collective interests in the potential threat to social order from the unem ployed, but to further narrow its power. T h e party’s d ep en d e n ce on managerial loyalty grew over time as it gave up o th e r instrum ents o f control and as the expansion of educational opportunity increased the n u m b e r o f people capable of holding such posts. Party m em b ership was only an additional qualification and not al ways necessary for positions o f authority, but it b eca m e an increasingly im portant distinguishing device after the early 1970s, when unem ploy m e n t rose am ong the university-educated. Although m em b ership was once m eant to b e a mark o f a ch iev em en t and honor, its selectivity forming the primary basis o f the party’s claim to authority from the civic virtue of its m e m b e r s ,26 it m ore and more b eca m e an instrum ent of exclusivity to limit entry to political and managerial posts and to raise their value by creating an artificial scarcity. T h e factors prom oting this d ev elopm en t cam e into play only shortly after the political campaign surrounding the econom ic reform of 1 9 5 8 -6 5 . B eca u se the very public display surrounding the purge ol Ranković and the central cadre commission in 1 9 6 6 - 6 7 seem ed to promise greater op enness, the disappointed expectations bred resen tm e n t in those ex cluded. As the n u m b e r o f new jobs narrowed, rules w ere introduced to cheek power within this managerial network through limited tenure within specific posts and obligatory rotation among those already e m ployed. At the same time, the m arket-oriented econom ic reform, which rewarded managers for turning a com mercial profit, had undercut the vertical lines o f party accountability and led to a purge of managers most conspicuous for creating trade-based em pires and expanding outside their repu blic o f property registration (through horizontal rather than vertical organization).27 T h e result was that in fact an ev e r more closed, narrow
2fi Piisic argues that th e party still represented “virtue* in the early 1980s as the dominant criterion in choosing representatives; th ere were election slogans of “Klect the best!” and co m m ittees to assess “moral-political suitability" of individuals For positions of responsibility in political, managerial, and social functions (“Uloga kolektivnog odlučivanja u realizaciji radničkih in te r e sa ,” 223), 27 Inform al explanations attribute this purge to nationalism, on the argum ent that firms crossing republican lines te nded to be export-im port based conglom erates originating in the adm inistrative period in Belgrade (such as G en ex) that expanded toward profitable oppor tunities in th e 1960s, such as tourism on the Dalmatian coast. In this case, the Croatian go v ern m en t and Dalmatian towns (such as Dubrovnik) opposed th eir intrusion on the
D I V IS I O N S O F LABOR
325
group circulated among directorships in the econom y and governm ent. The effect o f growing u n em p lo y m en t on the L C Y , in sum, was its m e ta morphosis into a craft union o f managers and politicians and a further decline in its governing role apart from its managerial function. The u n io n’s success in preventing mass u n em plo y m en t also had the paradoxical c o n s e q u e n c e o f weakening, not strengthening, its political r e sources. This was because its success narrowed the basis for solidarity on economic in te rest and for political action and included the loss o f labor s traditionally powerful weapon, the general strike. T h e political alliance between peasants and workers that was critical to the party’s revolution ary strategy did not survive the institutional separation o f the private and public sectors that originated in the policy against rapid socialization of agriculture. D e s p ite the protections in labor regulations against co m p e ti tion from this private-sector “reserve o f the u n em p lo y ed ,” the unions tended to see th e sub sistence guarantee o f property ow nership in the private sector as reason to give p re fe re n ce to their m e m b ersh ip — urban dwellers, usually m en assumed to b e heads o f household, with industrial or administrative skills and work habits appropriate to public-sector jo bs, and with no source o f incom e or housing should they b ec o m e u n e m ployed. Unions had little sympathy for those who could earn m oney in the private sector, for wealth earned through m arket advantage or what they considered specidation, or for workers absent from work, on the assum p tion that they w ere off working on their own land or at second jo b s and therefore in no need o f a jo b when others w ere truly unem ployed. L a bo r-m a rk et com petition largely took the form o f migration to places with labor shortages or h ig her incomes and benefits, such as Slovenia and the D alm atian coast. T hu s it was governm ents (local and republican) rather than unions that acted to protect social-sector wages and jo b s by erecting formal or informal barriers b etw ee n residents and immigrants, or by im porting “foreign” labor (from outside the area) on lim ited contract for specific p r o je c ts .28 Confined to tem porary work and dorm itory hous ing, classified as new com ers on local rolls, and su b je c te d to informal p re s sures w h ere th e re w e re differences in language and culture, immigrants
grounds that th ey w ere Serbian. No system atic study has tested this hypothesis against the one offered h ere . S e e also D jodan , The Evolution o f the Economic System o f Yugoslavia; and Sosić, 7 a čiste račune. 28
Through out th e socialist period, local and republican governm ents acted to prevent
com petition for th eir industries and populations with myriad limits on entry o f labor, indus tries, or goods (such as th e Serbian boycott o f goods trom o th er republics, especially Slo venia, in 1990), in ways analyzed by Stigler for capitalist societies— except that in the Yugoslav case th e re was no n eed for separate pressure from industries for governm ental regulations b ecau se o f social ownership and the fiscal system . S e e Stigler, “T h e T h eo ry o f E c o n o m ic R egu lation,"
326
CHAPTER 9
without familial conn ections often found it difficult to overcom e initial disadvantages in resid ence and schooling.29 W h e n the system o f w orkers’ councils replaced collective union bar gaining affecting the trade-off b etw een higher wages on the one hand and in v e stm e n t and jo b s on the other with debate and review of managerial proposals within the firm, the unions' new task confined them to the public sector o f the econom y. Like the L C Y , they were to represent so cial interest (in overall growth and its derivative, rising employment); their role was to participate in the discussions about central rules 011 productivity-based wages and wage increases and then to implement those rules. At the same tim e, they w ere to rep resen t the interests of workers against managers in reviewing and im plem enting managerial de cisions within firms on rationalizations and dismissals. Contrary to the concep tion o f unions as “transmission b elts” for central policy that domi nates the literature on C om m u nist-governed states, this dilemma be tw een their official and representative roles led, according to Ellen Comisso, to alternating pressure b etw ee n “plan” (central regulations) and “m a rk e t” (enterprise autonom y).30 In fact, the unions resolved the di le m m a in a way that distanced them even more from any societal role regarding u n em plo y m en t. On the one hand, they fought to protect their authority to im p lem e n t central regulations through their legal right to nom inate candidates to e nterprise decision-making councils, therefore fighting for the authority o f workers’ councils in general against man agerial e n croa ch m en t. At the same time, they fought to increase the e c o n o m ic resources available for the firm’s wage bill, working in col laboration with m an ag e m e n t and against central authority in support of g re a te r e n te rp rise autonom y over disposition o f its income and of taxation for the c o m m u n e ’s solidarity fund (which provided firms with insurance to pay the guaranteed wage). As a result, how ever, the authority of the union organization at the firm d ep en d e d on im p lem en tin g central labor regulations and policy, making it difficult to support a w orker’s appeal against regulations. Workers who appealed dismissal com plained frequently that they received
110
union
29 A uthor’s interviews with Josip Županov on I he fate o f migrants to Split from villages in its h interland, with Slovene sociologists and Silva Mežmirić on the restrictions Slovenia im posed on labor from o th er republics; with Ivo Banac and Olga Supek on the activities of local authorities in Dubrovnik to protect local labor against the influx o f employers from o th e r republics who would bring labor with them ; and with Radoslav Stojanovič on local reactions against the expansion o f Serbian foreign-trade firms, such as C en ex, into domestic m arkets in th e 1950s
(0 1 1
the same conflict in th e 1960s, see also Šošić, Za čiste račune). On
the introduction o f a distinction in som e municipal statutes after the 1963 constitution be tw een long-term residents and recent settlers, see Hondius, The Yugoslav Community of
Nations, 3 0 8 -1 0 * 30 C om isso, Workers' Control under Plan and Market,
DI V IS I O N S O F LABOR
327
support and w e re inclined as a result to take their complaints individually to self-m anag em en t courts, w here town lawyers outside the firm were more likely to co m e to their d e fe n s e .31 T h e unions’ influence, on the other hand, grew out o f the social bonds o f relatively stable m em b ership and personal relations with the director, m anagem ent board, and te c h n i cal staff within th e firm, making it difficult to contest a managerial d ec i sion. Instead o f organized militancy, the unions chose vagueness and dissembling so as to pro tect the personal relations underlying their influ ence. In place o f collective bargaining in the interest o f workers against managers or gov ernm ent, they fought to increase econ om ic resources within th e firm. T h e union-led “Battle for In c o m e s ” in 1 9 5 7 - 5 8 , as it was called at the tim e ,32 for example, was not a battle for higher wages (al though it had that c o n s e q u e n c e in some firms), but a jo in t battle with liberals to re d u ce e n te rp rise taxation, increase the portion o f earnings retained, free firms to make decisions on profit allocation that affected jobs and incom es (decisions regarding personal incom es, investm ent in new e q u ip m e n t and plant, funds for collective consumption goods, and expansion o f em ploym ent), and transfer authority over hiring and firing from th e m a n a g e m e n t board to the w orkers’ council. T hat alliance fell apart in 1968, how ever, when liberals took the next step and sought to transfer th e unions’ authority over hiring, firing, and incom e distribution by way o f the w ork ers’ council to the director and appointed council of technical advisers. Although the conflict cost V ukm anovic-Tem po his leadership o f the union, the union won restoration o f its authority (in the constitutional am e n d m e n ts o f 1971 and 1974) when central policy shifted after 1969.
T h e D iv is io n s o f S e l f -M a n a g e m e n t
A third c o n s e q u e n c e o f th e lead ers’ strategy and the resulting structure of econom ic and political organization was to make solidarity and alliances across social divisions on issues o f governm ental policy that influenced e m p lo y m e n t and u n em p lo y m en t extrem ely unlikely. In the classic case of social d em ocracy, the Keynesian political revolution had two elem ents: a new consciousness about the need for a m acroeconom ic conception of e con om ic activity and for active governm ental policy to cou nteract the 31 H ayden, “L abor Courts and W o rk ers’ Rights in Yugoslavia,” Hayden writes that in an analysis o f the self-m anagem ent courts (courts of associated labor) in 1977 and 1978 by the federal c ab in et in preparation for a proposed reform o f these courts, “the passive role ol the trade unions was castigated, particularly insofar as the unions do not protect individual workers (and, by extension, organizations) from im proper activities by managem ent and m anagem ent organs” (254). 32 S e e Rusinow, The Yugoslav Experiment, 1 16
328
CHAPTER 9
aggregate paradoxes of autonomous, m icroecon om ic decision making and laissez-faire; and the formation o f broad electoral alliances— among po litical parties rep resen tin g industrial labor, and other wage-earning, salaried, or small-property groups— in opposition to the unemploymentcausing policies o f orthodox stabilization and business protectionism. Col lective opposition to such policies in Yugoslavia was difficult to forge be cause both e le m e n ts were lacking: a societywide conception of collective interest in m acroeconom ic policy to counteract the powerful forces for decentralization and segm entation, and a social alliance across groups and eco n o m ic interests sufficient to exert pressure from below for policy change. T h e exam ple of social dem ocracy is usually considered irrelevant to the socialist states b ecau se their single-party systems did not operate by the com p etitiv e logic o f elections. T h e defining characteristic of social democ racy, after all, was its historic com prom ise with capitalism in accepting a parliam entary road to power and social change. Are not the privileged position of the ruling party and police harassment of dissident and opposi tion groups sufficient to explain the failure of effective political demand for chang e in socialist regim es? B u t they p revented n either the broad horizontal alliance against the party leadership in the case of the Soli darity m o vem en t in Poland after 1 9 7 9 — which jo in e d trade unions, intel lectu als’ clubs, farm ers’ associations, the Catholic church, and local party officials (the “horizontalists”)— nor the grand alliances, however, m om en tary, o f revolutionary protest against Com m u nist regim es in E astern E u rope in 1989. At first glance, a Keynesian political alliance (which Adam Przeworski calls a com prom ise with capitalism to nationalize consumption rather than production)33 would seem to have b ee n possible in the Yugoslav case, w h ere, as was argued at the beginning of this chapter, the concept of e m p lo y m e n t as subsistence and “incom e relations” had replaced political solidarity on em p loy m ent with solidarity on income. Since social owner ship m eant that few held wealth-producing assets and that everyone in th e public sector of the econom y was a wage or salary earner, and since private ow nership was limited to smallholdings, one might expect that a broad political alliance could have b e e n formed among consumers against the dem and-cutting restrictions imposed by m acroeconom ic policy on their purchasin g power, in opposition to those who might support an antiinflationary policy to restore external liquidity (such as the strongest firms or the political elite in the m o re-developed regions). H ow ever, despite the principles of political and econom ic unity on wh ich the Com m u nist party built the state and social orderjp-a single 33 Pr/.cworski, Capitalism and Social Democracy, 3 6 - 3 8 .
D IV ISI ON S O F LABOR
329
party and union, a popular front with allied social strata, social ownership, a single accounting and m onetary system, a com m on market, and uniform central ru les— the lea d ers’ methods o f gaining flexibility through foreign capital, a private sector, and extensive operational decentralization c r e ated a society riven by divisions and factional conflict. T h e re was no ab sence of social conflict or political protest over e conom ic policies in this society. Alliances could b e formed and reformed among enterprises and even gov ernm ents on policies concerning monies and credit, and govern ments w ere able to mobilize social protest in support of their demands. But no alliances e m e rg ed across social groups to pose, in Claus O ffe’s words, a cou nteracting logic to defend labor in opposition to this logic of capital54— or, to put it in Yugoslav term s, to reverse the localization or privatization o f questions of em p loy m e n t and make un em ploym en t an issue o f e co n o m ic policy. The massive e vid en ce about wage formation and investm ent decisions showing how little say workers had over their incomes and jo b creation argues against the thesis that un em ploym en t in Yugoslavia was a result of workers’ power over wages in labor-managed firms. T h e system o f self management did contrib ute substantially to u n em ploym ent, on the other hand, as a political obstacle to a change in m acroeconom ic policy b ecause it was the means to shift the locus o f bargaining over wages and jo bs to the level of the firm or lower, even though its system o f wage discipline was phrased in term s o f rights and political power. T h e political conseq u ences of self-m anagem ent had far less to do with the nature of decisions that could b e made within self-managed units than with the character o f soci ety com posed ol such units and the nature o f the links connecting them. The ostensible freedom o f self-managed firms with respect to labor, re v e nues, and individual incom es focused political energies on the firm rather than the state— in the same way that in Poland the central setting of prices and wages helped to focus political energies instead against the g overnm ent and to foster organization across social groups, in opposition to the rising price of food and the negative c on seq u en ces for labor norms and wages in export industries.35 T h e p re s e n ce ol a retail m arket and free prices for consu m er goods also was not sufficient to create a basis for political action among consum ers (as it was in the successful alliances b etw ee n workers and farmers in the ease of the Swedish Social D em ocrats in 1 9 3 2 - 3 4 and in the case of Solidarity in Poland) b ecau se that market was only one among multiple, unlinked 31 OHe, 'T w o Logi cs o f C o lle c t iv e A ction. 35 S e e W o o d a l l, T h e Socialis t C o r p o r a t i o n a n d T e c h n o c r a t i c P ow e r, on s im il a ri ti es w ith the Y ugos la v c a s e in E d w a r d G i e r e k ’s “im p o r t - l e d ’ g r o w t h s t r a te g y in t h e 1970s a n d th e origin of b o t h c c o n o m i o r e f o r m o r i e n t e d in d u s tria l po li cy a n d re o rg a n iz a tio n a n d w o r k e r p ro te s ts in e x p o r t s e c to rs , s u c h as s te e l, textiles, s h ip b u ild in g , coal, a n d c h em ic a ls .
330
CHAPTER 9
inodes of exchange. C o n su m e r goods might b e obtained through family reciprocity or with cash purchase— in nonconvertible dom estic currency, in foreign cu rre n cie s earned working abroad or bought e ith er legally or illegally, or in c red it or goods in kind from a place o f em ploy m ent in the socialist sector. E c o n o m ic solidarity on falling standards o f living did not lead to political solidarity w h ere people operated in separate distributive and exchange networks. W h at political organization could bridge the dif fere n ce s b e tw e e n those who had a hedge against inflation in foreigncu rre n cy holdings from foreign emigration or in private links to Western markets and those who did not? b etw ee n those who had access to food from private farmers through family ties and those who had no source of food outside what their m oney wage could buy? b etw ee n those who re ceiv ed benefits (such as housing credits, health and accident insurance, vacation stays, meal coupons, and winter food staples) from a social-sector jo b and those who had to purchase everything on the open market? and b etw ee n those for whom the effect o f monetary and exchange-rate policy was to increase their purchasing power and those for whom it meant a sharp decline in what they could buy? T h e end o f the “wage struggle” with the introduction of self-man ag e m e n t, which replaced unions’ rights and attempts at collective bar gaining with the rights o f w orkers’ councils to debate, be consulted, and discipline workers, did not end bargaining over wages. It only pushed that bargaining into the workplace, creating conflicts rather than soli darity am ong workers in their “socialist com m u n ities.” T h e most conten tious decision within firms was the adoption o f the rule book on wage and incom e scales. Not only did actual personal incomes vary as a result of changes in production costs, profits, and taxes, but they also depended on the rate assigned a p e rso n ’s jo b classification. This created divisions be tw een b lue-collar and white-collar wage earners and across strata defined by skill certification. T h at conflicts over purchasing power erupted within the Yugoslav firm is d em onstrated by the dismissals and rising wages of skilled workers in 1 9 5 0 - 5 3 , by the wage-push inflation in the 1960s when regulations w ere eased substantially and un em ploym ent skyrocketed, and by the fre q u e n t work stoppages against the union leadership and manage m e n t within a plant to protest wage cuts or forced job-saving mergers with unprofitable local firm s.® In contrast to Hungary, w here managers o f autonomous enterprises could choose, for example, to alter internal salaries as long as they kept within the limits o f the assigned wage bill (such as by hiring more lowcost, unskilled labor in order to increase wage payments to skilled labor), ,(i Snell work stoppages grew more frequent alter 1958. In A u gust-Septem b er 1985, a strike in M acedonia by workers from a profitable plant protesting such a decision lasted forty-five davs.
DI V IS IO N S O F LABOR
331
in the Yugoslav system rank-and-file discontent over visible inequalities within the workplace alternated with the inflationary pressures o f the ag gregate wage bill on the money supply or price levels. T h e gov ernm ent responded to wage and price inflation by alternately regulating and d e regulating wages and contributions for social benefits. W ork stoppages usually had managers ru nning to the factory floor and g overnm ents c o n ceding to wage dem ands in order to protect the myth o f self-m anagem ent (as worker control) and to prevent strikes from spreading beyond the c o n fines o f the firm. B u t these im m ediate solutions p reem p ted broader polit ical mobilization (as they w ere intended to do) while feeding inflation and eventually requ iring a new round of anti-inflationary restrictions and la bor rationalization. T h e a u thorities’ solution to the wage dem ands o f professionals and civil servants, who w ere so contentious in 1 9 4 7 - 4 9 (for example, in the attack on the M inistry o f F in a n ce under S reten Zujovic), was administrative decentralization and socialization o f g overnm ent services (and thus em ployees)— transferring the activity to the budgets o f firms or to inde pendent agencies financed by en te rp rise taxation. In the 1970s, salaries for those in administrative positions and the “nonproductive” sphere of social services (referred to as people on “guaranteed salaries”) w ere in dexed to the wage rates and gains o f production workers. 37 Politically, this indexation crea ted a silent alliance, in no need o f organization, among public-sector em ployees; but it also made wage restraint difficult to im plem ent when administrators responsible for discipline b enefited directly from wage increases, and it transposed the trade-off b etw ee n econom ic and social in vestm en t and jo b s into escalating tax rebellion. Both m e c h a nisms o f wage control in the public sector refueled inflationary pressures as well as rounds o f intensification and stabilization restrictions that in creased u n em ploym ent. But there was no political m echanism for b a r gaining over the trade-off excep t to lobby for tax concessions that had the effect o f shifting taxation onto the private sector. E cono m ic-p olicy shifts created other conflicts among incom e earners that also inhibited political alliances. In addition to the divisions a ccord ing to skill categories m entioned above, tensions b etw ee n the separate decision-making hierarchies o f production workers on the one hand and technical and administrative staff on the o th er intensified w h en e v e r new labor regulations shifted favor from one to the other. B ecau se the a c counting rules requ ired that taxes to finance public services be paid be17 T h e categories o f federal expenditure were also indexed as a percentage o f gross do mestic product (a category excluding services), which put additional p ressure on th e capacity to collect federal tax revenues to m eet the legislated percentage. T his is why the military increasingly com plained in th e 1980s about the instability und unpredictability o f its actual budget
332
CHAPTER 9
fore w orkers’ ne t-in co m e shares, the jo bs of civil servants and employees in social services w ere in direct conflict with workers’ incomes. Conflicts arose b e tw e e n e conom ic enterprises and nonprofit cultural and social ser vices when e n terprises responded to the austerities of stabilization policy with an attack on the cost o f financing public services and lobbied for their taxes to be cut by adopting user fees, relying more on market purchase, or cu ttin g the d efense budget and the nu m ber o f parastatal agencies (the self-managing com m unities o f interest). A fundam ental role of political organizations is to create the perception o f com m on in te rest that is necessary to collective action even in the pres e n c e o f seem ingly insurmountable conflicts of interest. In theory, the unions had the organizational basis to play this role— to fashion broad alliances within and across industrial branches or to propose policy change on the occasion o f writing labor and wage regulations or negotiat ing incom es-policy agreem ents. Alliances b etw een industrial-branch unions and those in the social services were difficult to form, however, becau se th e re was no role for union bargaining in workplaces whose bud gets w ere the result o f grants (as witli social services) instead of being “earned. ” In fact, th e powerful professional and civil-service unions of the 1940s w ere no longer unions as a result of this transformation, and they p erfo rm ed functions with little relation to those of unions in the enter prises. T h e y served as welfare organizations for visiting sick colleagues, sending birthday greetings, or organizing festivities within the workplace (such as for International W o m e n ’s Day), and they jo ined local, republi can, and federal associations to promote professional developm ent and define policies for reskilling and benefits. T h e incentives discussed above for union officials to focus on increasing their firm’s total revenues and collaborate with m anag em ent made alliances betw een the unions and en terprise directors or e conom ic liberals possible— until these allies turned against union authority and workers’ decision-making rights within the firm. Although the cou ntry ’s international position and its stop-and-go mac ro eco nom ic policy created an unpredictability o f conditions that made it difficult to act strategically, the conflicts over trade liberalization in the 1960s did dem onstrate the possibilities o f broader alliances on matters of federal e con om ic policy. F o r example, at the end o f 1967, students and workers in som e republics organized marches in sympathy with miners’ strikes protesting gov ernm ent neglect of their industry. An open fight at the sixth union congress in Ju n e 1968 over the damage to the textile and m ining industries caused by the decade-long trade liberalization and re pe a te d recessions produced a full union resolution of solidarity. w The «* O n t h e c o n g r e s s a n d floor fight, s e e C a r t e r , D e m o c r a t i c R e f o r m in Y ugos la v ia , 165.
DI VI S IO NS O F LABOR
333
party’s ch oice to replace Vukm anović-Tem po, Dušan P etro v ić-S a n e — who was an oth er Partisan “first fighter,” was not known for his liberal views, and was from Bosnia, w here the strikes b eg a n — suggests that union opposition was com pounding on several fronts. N onetheless, more important than this change to m ore loyal leadership in p reventing the d evelopm en t o f a b road er social alliance was the unions’ ambiguity on em ploym ent. In response to rising youth un em ploym en t and the massive social protest in the universities only weeks before, the union congress gave only a tepid nod to the stud ents’ own plight. In its Resolution on E m p loy m en t, it chose to “con d em n . . . work organizations closing in on themselves . . . conserving the existing qualification structure . . , [in] opposition to th e e m p lo y m e n t o f all categories of schooled cadre. . . . T h e unions must b e engaged in the co rrect application o f the law 011 obligatory admission o f trainees and [must] fight for im plem entation o f the rulebook on tr a in e e s .”39 T h e unions and the youth wing o f the party had b een the C o m m u n ists’ most radical and com m itted activists in the days o f revolution, b u t as em ploy m ent q uestions w ere funneled into the self-managed workplace and union authority outside the firm into setting the principles of labor regulations, the two w ere driven into separate “reservations’ with no sta ble grounds for political alliance. In the period after 1968, when u n e m ploym ent b e c a m e increasingly the plight of youth who could not get a first jo b , th e primary d em and o f the L eague of Youth (Savez Omladina) was that high-school youth and university students be given the constitutional classification o f “w orker” and thus rights to representation and participa tion in e co n o m ic decisions in their schools and localities. T h e attem pt failed, and th e league b ec a m e known for its inaction at the grass roots; it was used instead as an avenue o f individual ad vancem ent for political careers in the party leadership. D e p e n d e n t on funding from the party’s front organization, the Socialist Alliance o f W orking People, and assured of e m p lo y m e n t as long as they rem ained loyal activists, youth leaders continu ed to perform their assigned task o f organizing youth labor b ri gades and, when u n em p lo y m en t b eca m e severe in the 1980s, of making strident p ro n ou n cem en ts in youth journals and at congresses. To the e x tent th e y w e re heard at all outside these forums, these protests w ere relegated to the category o f “problem s o f youth. ” Nor did they lead to the mobilization o f “troops” among youth or to sustained pressure, b ecau se of quarrels among the youth leag u e’s separate republican b ranches over the priority o f th e ir different dem ands and concerns. Perhaps the most significant effect of the system of workplace decision making called self-m anagem en t was to end the party’s identity with the '19
Yugoslav Survey , 1968, p. 63 8
334
CHAPTER 9
working class and its interest separate from those o f enterprises or gov e rn m e n ts. Although informed observers within the country insisted that th e party never lost the loyalty of industrial workers and emphasized the im portance to its ruling power o f the web o f personal and political connec tions among party politicians throughout the country, n either this infor mal network nor workers’ silent loyalty was the same as creating political alliances across the various divisions within society in support of labor. W h e re a s th e progressive socialization of the state and o f econom ic func tions was intended to give the party a more important role in governance by resolving differences and “harm onizing” conflicts, the party itself was not im m u ne to the divisive effects o f decentralization and socialization. T h e “socialization” o f the party m eant that m em bers belonged to units at their workplace (which paid their salary) and w ere active there. T h e rankand-file party m e m b ers thus identified with and owed their first loyalty to their work collective (em ployer).40 Party m em b ership offered no spe cial privileges and requ ired paym ent o f dues (at 12 p ercent o f salary); and, unlike the tim e spent in self-m anagem ent meetings, time spent on party m eeting s and duties did not receive compensation as time worked. S tudies o f dissent within party organizations found far m ore criticism in the villages— w h ere private-sector em ploy m ent dominated and party organizations w ere territorial, rather than e nterp rise-b ased — than in pu blic-secto r firms and institutions, where party m em b ership did not p ro tect individuals from b eing fired.41 Party m em b ers were no different than non-party m e m b ers in their conflicts o f econom ic interest with p eople em ployed in offices and services supported by enterprise taxes. T h e primary means o f enforcing party policy was by influencing appoint m ents to managerial positions, but the appointm ent and accountability of e n te rp rise directors was an additional source o f conflict betw een the com m u ne and e n te rp rise party com m ittees. Conflicts b etw ee n com m une and e n te rp rise party organizations over tax revenues and retained earnings might b e resolved by com m on cause against the private sector, but the shift o f taxes and fees was guided not by the prejudices o f socialist ideol ogy (as it was usually alleged) but by econom ic interest. Divisions within 10 C o m i s s o w rite s , “T h e ro ots o f t h e LC Y 's r e c r u i t m e n t d i l e m m a s e e m s [.sic] to lie in a la ck o f i n c e n t i v e s for b lu e - c o lla r w o r k e r s to p ay t h e costs o f political act ion p a rty m e m b e r s h i p e n ta ils for t h e m . W h e n w o r k e r s as a g r o u p d e r i v e b e n e f its fr om p a r ly actions, the b e n e f its t a k e t h e fo r m o f ‘p u b l i c g o o d s ’ w h ic h a c c r u e (o t h e w o i k c o ll e ctiv e as a w hole , o r to w o r k e r s in g e n e r a l , r e g a r d l e s s o f p a r t y affiliation o r t h e lack of it. T h i s e n c o u r a g e d free r i d i n g an ti m a d e t h e p a r ty r e s p o n s i v e to tile w o r k e r s n e e d s w h e n
his i n t e r e s t s co incided
w i t h t h o s e o f socie ty o r w it h th o s e ol t h e e n t e r p r i s e , ” b u t " s h o u ld t h e y conflict, h e could h a r d l y t u r n to t h e p a r ty o f t h e w o r k i n g class for s u p p o r t ” (“C a n a P a rty of t h e W o r k i n g Class B e a W o r k i n g - C l a s s P a r t y ? ” 72, 86) 11 S e e C a r t e r , D e m o c r a t i c R e f o r m in Y u g o s la v ia , 71
D I V IS I O N S O F LABOR
335
the party thus occu rred in line with the budgetary divisions of the e c o n omy w h ere e m p lo y m e n t and wage decisions w ere made Behind the frequent criticism that delegates e le cte d to political office were primarily party cadres was the presum ption of party unity, disci pline, and com m on purpose that in fact did not exist 011 questions of money and e m p lo y m e n t capacity, unless the productivity of the firm rose or an infusion of capital from outside provided resources to redistribute. The politics o f producivity in a redistributive regim e, as C harles M aier has argued for the United States, depends on prior econom ic growth to circumvent conflicts, 12 Party leaders in the various republics and prov inces co m p eted for resources; after 1969, their own em p loy m ent and power d ep en d e d on the proportion of resources they could control and keep at hom e. W ith rare exceptions, the basis of political representation in units of autonom ous (“self-m anaged”) budgets had little relation to pol icy positions and factions on federal policy toward foreign trade, defense, and investm ent. Instead, the fo rm er cam e to define the latter: conflicts over substantive policy w ere redefined as conflicts over the distribution of money— over budgetary revenues and tax policy, transfers and subsidies, and the locus of control over monetary policy, foreign-exchange alloca tion, and banking. Studies o f effective political organization in o ther socialist states e m phasize the critical role that intellectuals play in forging broad social alli ances, by explaining the links b etw een particular and general interest and providing a language and symbols for political action.'13 In the Yugoslav leaders’ vision o f the state, professional experts had substantial authority. They wrote the rules for the legislative and executive branches o f govern ment, perform ed the analyses in research institutions to propose or justify investm ent projects, and wielded substantial critical influence in journals, universities, and party forums. In their criticism of public policies, the economists, sociologists, and party leaders with social science b a ck grounds who p resen ted professional studies to party forums or spoke at public gatherings did, over time, identify and make public many im m e d i ate causes of u n em ploym ent. T h e y pointed out, for example, that g ov ern ment policy and en te rp rise demand did not correspond to the traits of the labor supply; that the preoccupation with small-property firms as a pan acea to u n em p lo y m en t assumed a category of resident skills and resources that w ere in deficit, not surplus; that allowing earlier re tirem en t with full 12 M aier, ‘‘T h e Politics of Productivity." 1:1 T his th em e runs through the literature on econom ic reform in socialist countries and why it failed politically in Czechoslovakia hut brought revolution in Poland, for example A gocxl representative o f this literature from I ho more recent period is Staniszkis, Poland’s Self-Limiting Revolution- F o r a critical view o f the thesis, set? Laba, The Roots o f Solidarity
336
CHAPTER 9
pension in the 1970s and 1980s would only worsen the shortage of workers with industrial skills; that e nterprise demands for several years prior work e x p e rien c e w ere unrealistic, and certainly would do little to red uce u n em p lo y m en t among youth; and that labor regulations for reas sig nm en t discrim inated against new entrants to the labor force. Y et the republican ju risdiction o v ered u c a tio n , research institutes, and d ev elo p m en t planning, made effective by budgetary autonomy, centered such analyses within republics, whose very real differences in labor markets led to separate worlds and perceptions. A planner from fullernploym ent Slovenia and a planner from Kosovo or M acedonia facing open un em p lo y m en t o f 15 to 3 0 p e rce n t had little in com mon. W ith rare exceptions, the com m on ground across republics of the various proposals for rem ed y in g policy mistakes was no different from previous policy: fo cusing on alternative methods o f adjusting and allocating the supply of labor or finding new avenues for em ploy m ent in the private sector. Lik e the unions, professionals proposed nothing that would challenge the basis o f their own authority, focusing largely on qualifications and productivity. In the early 1980s, as in the early 1960s, they criticized barriers to the e m p loy m e n t o f “young, schooled cad res” and the monop oly over existing jobs by workers with less skill, work effort, and creativity than un em ployed youth, which kept productivity suboptimal; and they argued for “d ifferentiation” in favor ol “those who work and against those who do n o t .”4 * B u t in cases w h ere their proposals extended to societywide e co n o m ic policy, the differences in approach among expert communities in the republics prevailed. F o r example, one proposal originating in S er bia in the late 1970s, for long-term social planning ( 1 9 8 5 - 2 0 0 0 ) for the en tire Yugoslav space, was resisted by Slovenia because the Serbs insis ted on using their m ethod of planning and the Belgrade Institute of E c o nom ics, while the Croats insisted on their method and the Zagreb Institute o f E co n o m ics; the Slovenes preferred a third m etho d — one com binin g social, econom ic, and dem ographic aspects. Slovene econo mists argued that the S e rb proposals for devoting greater attention to dev elopm en tal planning, setting proportions among key sectors, recog nizing the links among phases and sectors o f production in final output, introducing a federal investm ent fund, and strengthening the revenue base of federal functions w ere a return to the system o f the 1950s and that im proved m acroeconom ic m anagem ent could not make up for micro e co n o m ic defects in the efficiency o f capital when investors w ere not free to manage and earn a return on capital.45 " S e rb sociologist Silvano Bolčie, in Razvoj i kriza jugoslavenskog društva u sociološkoj perspektivi, 192. T h e ''basic condition for overall progress' in Yugoslav society, Boleić con tinues, is an ''affirmation of lab o r.” 15 Review o f econom ic proposals fioni Ljub o m ir Madžar and his group at the Yugoslav
DI V IS I O N S OK LABOR
337
Experts and intellectuals w ere not defined by their republican origin. Schools o f thought crossed republican lines, and both formal and informal professional contacts maintained the frequent exchange o f ideas. B u t the progressive transfer of federal funds and com p eten cie s to the republics gradually d eprived experts of a base independ en t o f the republics w here they were em ploy ed, and resid ences and spheres o f political action had to he chosen. By the 1980s, social scientists’ proposals for change in labor market institutions varied largely with their rep u blic’s m ilie u .46 In S e r bia, for exam ple, Silvano Bolcic proposed greater gov ernm ent involve ment in the problem s of em ploy m ent, blit within the local context: E f f e c t i v e s o c ia l a c tio n to c o n q u e r u n e m p l o y m e n t r e q u i r e s e a c h c o m m u n e to c o m p l e t e a c o n c r e t e a n a ly s is o f t h e p o s s i b i l i t i e s fo r e m p l o y m e n t in e v e r y w o rk o r g a n i z a t io n in its t e r r i t o r y . . . a n d w o r k o u t a p r e c i s e a n n u a l p la n o f e m p l o y m e n t . . - w ith s p e c i f i c s c h e d u l e s o f w h o w ill b e e m p l o y e d in th a t p e r io d
. . . C o m m u n e o r g a n i z a t io n s o f t h e L e a g u e o f Y o u th c o u l d fo rm
'‘c o m m i t t e e s
fo r e m p l o y m e n t ” in
w h ich
re p re se n ta tiv e s
o f u n em p lo y e d
y o u th w o u ld a c t i v e ly p a r t i c i p a t e . W i t h t h e c o l l e c t i o n o f id e a s fo r e m p l o y m e n t a n d c o n s t a n t s o c ia l p r e s s u r e o n all in s t i t u t i o n s a n d o r g a n i z a t io n s th a t c a n c o n t r i b u t e to o p e n i n g n e w p o s itio n s , m o r e f a v o r a b le p o s s i b i l i t i e s w o u ld b e c r e a t e d . 47
In the northw estern republics, in contrast, econom ists and sociologists spoke increasingly o f the de facto existence of a labor market and the need to recognize not only its existen ce but its superiority as a method of allocating labor and resolving the irrationalities that produced u n e m p loy m ent.48 In full-em ploym ent Slovenia and in Croatia, w here u n e m ployment had fallen below 5 p e rce n t by the first half o f the 1980s, the con se q u e n ce o f tighter labor supply and even shortages had b ee n the creation of marketlike conditions; surveys on labor turnover by the Yugoslav Institu te on Productivity dem onstrated that for many years, professionals in these republics had b een moving frequently among Institute of Economic; Research in Belgrade (bv then a section o f the Institute for Social Sciences) by Jo/.e M en cin g e r (first m inister of the economy for Slovenia after the multiparty elections o f 1990) in Ekonomska Politika (1987), No republic o r province in Yugoslavia can b e treated as a “unitary a c to r,’’ for economists and politicians within republics divided among schools o f thought and economic-policy advice. Bu t at any m om ent th ere w ere also différences am ong republics, and th e two positions cited h ere from Slovenia and Se rb ia best represent the main alternatives o f influential opinion in 1 9 8 7 -9 1 . V erd ery analyzes a Romanian version o f intellectual competition with a nationalist com ponent in National Ideology under Socialism. 47 Bolcic, Razvoj i kriza, 2 1 6 - 1 7 48 T h e Slovene sociological association held a co nference in Ljubljana on th e “labor m ar ket” in O c to b e r 1982. Am ong those most prom inent on the subject in Croatia w ere Bran ko Horvat, Slaven L etica, and Josip Zupanov.
338
CHAPTER 9
firms in search of higher incom es and b etter conditions. By 1990, ex perts in these republics had equ ated their b e lie f in the rem edy o f real labor markets with abolition o f the system o f worker consultation in firms (self-m anagem ent) and had dem anded full privatization o f the pub lic sector. I f managers w ere not free to hire and fire, they argued, and il foreign investors w ere not assured o f these rights, the econom ic crisis of the 1980s would not end. T h e difficulties o f forging cross-republican political alliances on ques tions o f e m p lo y m e n t w ere most apparent in the group in which conditions for collective action w ere best and that was most prone to political protest: university students. W ithin two years o f the decline in absolute numbers o f persons em ployed, the universities exploded in Priština (in 1967 and repeated ly thereafter), in Belgrad e and Sarajevo (in 1968), and in Zagreb (by 1971). B u t b eca u se university education and em ploym ent conditions w ere un der republican ju risdiction, students differed in their perception o f the cause o f their potential unem ploym ent. As a result, they pursued q uite different dem ands and political tactics, despite many personal and professional conn ections among student leaders and the professors and critical intellectuals who inspired them. In B elg rad e and Priština, the capitals o f S erbia and its province Kosovo, surplus labor ca m e largely from the rural exodus as youth attempted to e n te r the public sector by way o f the universities, and protests were led by poorer students from village backgrounds whose excellent grades were not sufficient to win them e ith er party m em b ership or good prospects of e m p lo y m e n t.49 T h e ir attack on the state c e n te red on the L C Y as a sys tem o f spoils in em p loy m ent, whose monopoly on access to jo b s conflicted with the open and egalitarian ideals of the system. T h e ir slogan, “down with the Red B o u rg eo isie!” d em anded a change in who controlled access to jo b s , not an alternative program for unem ploym ent. Nonetheless, de spite th e se com m on interests and political programs within the same re public, the two groups could not ally b ecause of the budgetary system and the ethnonational legitimation o f its division. In Kosovo, for example, the students defined the struggle as one against Belgrade for greater control over both local education and g overnm ent budgets; the primary cause of u n em p lo y m en t was seen as the ab sence of such local control, which made possible national discrimination favoring Serbs over ethnic Albanians in education and in jo b s in the socialized sector o f the econom y and govern m ent. F e w discussed who actually benefited from the policy of invest m e n t in raw-material extraction and capital-intensive heavy industry in the province that generated so few jo bs. In Croatia, as rural surplus labor emigrated for work in Europe and as 19 Tomanović, Omladina i socijalizam, 7 3 - J0 0 .
DI V IS IO N S O F LABOR
339
the e co n o m ic reform for greater integration with W e ste rn markets fa vored many areas o f the republic, students in Zagreb in fact agreed with their republican party leadership that un em ploym en t was the result of “B elg ra d e ’s” taxation o f Croat resources (above all foreign-exchange r e ceipts from tourism, transport, and guest-w orker remittances). T h e y took to the streets to add force to their lea d ers’ dem ands for greater autonomy over resources that they claimed b elonged to Croatia. Although their r e volt beg an with a university reform in 1 9 7 0 - 7 1 , by the time they w ere in the streets, they w ere focusing their dem ands on higher retention of foreign-exchange receipts than allowed by the quotas set by the National Bank, a decentralization o f the banking system to give local producers greater access to bank c r e d it,50 and an end to the capital tax for d ev elop m ent aid for o th er republics. In full-em ploym ent Slovenia, similarly, stu dents allied with party leaders and unions who saw the drain o f “S lo v e n e ” resources to B elg rad e and the poorer republics as reducing their potential for h ig her wages and social w elfare.51 T h e s e differences also held for alliances that students in one republic might c re a te with others: students in Belgrade and Sarajevo could orga nize support for workers in coal mines and textile factories, but they w ere unable to extend this alliance to republics that b enefited from W e stern market liberalization.
T h e O r ig in s o f P o l it ic a l C h a n g e
W h e re p ressu re for political change in socialist Yugoslavia did occu r and originated at least partially in econom ic interest, social forces, and popu lar dem and, it ca m e from the cou ntry ’s two outliers on unem ploym ent. Full e m p lo y m e n t in Slovenia and nearly full un em ploym ent in Kosovo were the two exceptions that prove the rule o f this c h a p te r’s arguments about the relation b etw ee n political dem and and the society created by governm ental e con om ic policy. In Slovenia, w h ere nearly full em p loy m ent and spot shortages o f skilled 50 G ed eon identifies th e differences in the hanking proposals o f the ('m a t, Serb, and Slovene econom ic schools in “Monetary Disequilibrium and Bank Reform Proposals in Yugoslavia." 31
T h e first governm ent to resign in postwar Yugoslavia was the Slovene governm ent ol
Janko Sm ole in D e c e m b e r 1966, when the cham b er on health and welfare o f the Slovene parliament re jec te d its program for cutting enterprise contributions for social insurance and shifting th e tax onto workers' wages (the vote was later reversed, however, and th e govern m ent withdrew its resignation). In 1985, the "catalyst for nationwide abandonment ol wage austerity under the I M F program was the rapid midyear rise ol wages in Slovenia; the "Slov en e governm ent claim ed that wage compression had reached the limits of social tolera tion, although its wages had fallen least and were the highest above average" (H enderson, “T h e International M onetary Fu nd and Eastern Europe").
B Kosovo S Slovenia E Bosnia-Herzegovina
F ig u r e 9-1. P e rc e n ta g e R ate o f U n e m p lo y m e n t: Kosovo, Slovenia, and BosniaH e rz e g o v in a . Source: M e n c in g e r, “P riv r e d n a re fo rm a i n e z a p o s le n o s t,” tab le 1.
1965
1970
1975
I
K os ovo
1980
0
S lo v e n ia
1983
198«
1985
EEB o s n ia -H e rz e g o v i n a
F ig u r e 9-2. P e r c e n ta g e R ate o f Y outh U n e m p lo y m e n t: Kosovo, Slovenia, and B o sn ia -H e rz e g o v in a . Source: P rim o ra c a n d C h a re tte , “R egional A spects o f Youth U n e m p lo y m e n t in Y ugoslavia,” 218. Note: “Y o u th ” re fers to p e rso n s a g ed 27 years o r y o u n g e r.
341
D I VI S IO NS O F LABOR
1960
1965
1970
1975
I960
1966
1990
H Kosovo 0 S lo v e n i a Q] B o s n ia -H e rz e g o v i n a
F ig u re 9-3. P e r c e n ta g e R a te o f E m p lo y m e n t: Kosovo, Slovenia, a n d BosniaH e rz e g o v in a . Source: Statistički Godišnjak Jugoslavije, various years. F o r th e n u m b e rs , se e ta b le 6-1. Note: T h e ra te o f e m p lo y m e n t is d e fin e d as th e re la tio n b e tw e e n th e n u m b e r o f e m p lo y e d p e rso n s in th e social a n d p riv a te se c to rs a n d th e w o rk in g -a g e p o p u la tio n (m en ages 1 5 -6 4 a n d w o m e n ages 1 5-59 ).
workers and professionals prevailed throughout the postwar period, a so ciety had b e e n crea ted in which labor had real bargaining power over incom es, benefits, and jo b s . D esp ite arguments that such power cam e from th e institution o f “w orkers’ control’’ and “labor m an ag e m e n t” of firms, labor did not have such power in the o ther republics, w h ere self m anag em ent also prevailed. T h e exercise of that power at the level of en terprises and in republic-level politics had led in time to a pluralist politics as w ell— a burgeoning “civil society .” (It is necessary to note, how ever, that the financing for most o f these activities cam e from the party-affiliated Socialist Alliance o f W orking People). Full em ploy m ent had created de facto labor-m arket conditions within the republic, leading to the d ev elop m en t of the social and political relations that accompany labor markets. S lovene political activity increasingly resem bled that found in m arket econom ies: parliamentary responsiveness to popular pressure, gov ernm ental concessions to loosen federal restrictions on wages and social welfare, multicandidate elections, and, when d em ocratic elections occu rred in 1990, com petitive party politics in which th e sp e c trum o f political tend encies resem bled central European traditions. P ete r
342
CHAPTER 9
K a tz e n s te in ’s argu m ent for Austria and Switzerland applied equally well for Slovenia: the very fact o f econom ic success “continuously re leg itim iz ed ” the political institutions necessary to governmental policy and s tre n g th e n e d the “com patibility o f views” betw een the bargaining parties, w h e th e r labor and g overnm ent or labor and m an ag e m e n t.52 This situation d ep end ed , however, on protecting the conditions for full em p loy m e n t, which w ere republican ju risdiction over labor and control over the e con om ic resources necessary to Slovenia’s choice o f develop m e n t policy. D uring the 1980s, as will be discussed in the final chapter, the Slovene g o v ernm ent was able to strengthen its ability to act as a sov ereig n unit by giving political activities within the republic freer reign and by d irecting Slovene society ’s capacity for collective action against the outside. T h e goal was to protect these conditions— by adopting protec tionist labor policies, organizing a successful rebellion against the federal g ov ern m e n t when Slovene control over capital and em ploy m ent and the internal political system appeared threatened, and in the end pressing for total national independ en ce. T h e o th er outlier was Kosovo. It also dem onstrates the reciprocal relation b e tw e e n em p loy m e n t conditions and political action. H ere un e m p lo y m e n t was so high and the opportunities for socialist-sector em ploy m ent so few that nearly 8 0 pe rce n t o f the rep u blic’s population, and an even larger proportion of ethnic Albanians, was confined to the private s ecto r— working in agriculture, trades, household labor, and family busi nesses (particularly in o ther republics or abroad in temporary economic migration), or registered as unem ployed. W hile this lack o f opportunity for pu blic-secto r em p loy m e n t excluded them from the full enjoym ent of political rights, it provided the econom ic basis for an alternative com mu nity c e n te re d in family-based social organization and ethnically based po litical identities. E x ten d e d families lasted longer than in o ther parts of the cou ntry and am ong o th er national groups, serving in part as a vehicle for strategies of e co n o m ic diversification.53 Migrant workers and entrepre neurs sent earnings hom e, and families used the incom e to buy up land. Eventu ally , th e ir e con om ic and therefore political exclusion produced a political network in families and villages— an entire parallel society alongside the formal econom y o f the Serbs, M ontenegrins, and a few Albanians— which gave the leaders an impressive capacity for mobilizing collective action. 52 Katzenstein, Corporatism and Change, 29, 53 According to research on the zadruga in several areas of the country in the late 1960s by th e anthropologist Zagorka Golubovic and h e r students at the University o f Belgrade, households o f a hundred m em b ers w ere not rare in Kosovo (G olubovic, personal communi cation). In contrast to th e rest o f the country, where the zadruga had died out, it appeared to b e alive and well in the early 1970s among Albanian families in Kosovo. This basis for
DIVIS IO NS O F LABOR
343
Although this political network was not in a position to ignore federal rules on wages and benefits in the socialist sector (as full em p loy m ent allowed the Slovenes to do), its political capacity to mount lasting sedition and to threaten a m ajor rebellion b eca m e clear after 1981 when Albanian nationalists began another round in their efforts for political in d e p e n dence (at the time, for a separate republic). Although the response of Serbian and federal authorities to the internal war was to intensify politi cal and police rep ression— arresting suspected troublem akers, closing schools, purging Albanian leaders from the party, and eventually im pos ing martial law in the province with federal troops— the provincial au thorities’ political capacity also enabled them to extract ever-larger compensatory grants and credits from the federal governm ent. This b rib e (or blackmail), when no one in the country was willing to accede to their political dem ands, reflected the redistributive foundations of Yugoslav politics, which would grant money rather than change the d ev elopm en t strategy and the investm ent, foreign-trade, and price policies that w ere the cause o f the u n em ploym ent. In addition, while politically cou n terp ro ductive for S e rb ia and the country as a whole and in c om p lete violation of both d om estic and international declarations o f human rights, this gov ernm ental response streng thened the internal political unity o f Albanian nationalists that had originated in their e conom ic condition outside the public sector of em ploym ent. T h e Albanian uprising helped create popular support for nationalist in tellectuals in Serbia, providing the glue of anti-Albanian sen tim ent for a social m o v e m e n t in Se rb ia o f the East E uro pean type. W h e n a similar alliance among C o m m u n ist party leaders, parliamentary delegates, na tionalist intellectuals, and popular sen tim ent in Slovenia made the choice for full in d e p e n d en c e, the crucial political m o m en t cam e in a m o m e n tary alliance b etw ee n Slovenia and Kosovo against Serbia. In F ebru a ry 1989, th ree m onths after the Slovene gov ernm ent had refused to partici pate in an all-Yugoslav referendu m on a new federal constitution, argu ing that this was a m a tter o f republican and parliamentary authority and that it intended to institute a multiparty system instead, the Slovene C o m m u n ist party leader Milan Kucan told a mass m e e tin g — which took place in L ju b lja n a in support of striking Albanian miners at Stari Trg, Kosovo— that the strike was a defense o f “AV N O J Yugoslavia.’ T h e p re vious O cto b e r , Slovenia had bargained for federal concessions on the c o n stitutional a m e n d m e n ts in exchange for approving the retraction of Kosovo’s autonom y in S e rb ia ’s republican constitution. B u t by throwing down the gauntlet to Serbian nationalists, for whom the 1943 com m itdiversified econ om ic strategies across many econom ic environm ents and countries becam e important in the 1970s and 1980s,
344
CHAPTER 9
m e n t to a postwar federal state o f six republics rep resented the disempow ering o f Se rb ia through the federal division of its nation, Kučan was able to consolidate his support with the Slovene public, defend Albanian political rights with the constitutional principles of territorial sovereignty and the re p u b lics’ and p rovinces’ right o f secession, and identify Serbia and its leader, Slobodan Miloševič, as the en em ie s o f Slovene democracy and o f Yugoslavia. W h ile this did not prevent Slovenia from voting in the federal presid ency to im pose em e rg en c y rule over Kosovo in M arch 1989, it did help push increasing nu m bers o f S e rb citizens into open support for M iloševič and Serbian nationalism. O p e n nationalist confrontation b etw ee n intellectuals and then govern m ents in Slovenia and Serbia broke the rules of Kard elj’s political system and sev ered irreparably the alliances o f conv enience betw een Slovenes and S e rb s that had kept the country together under similar economic conditions in the interwar period. N onetheless, this political dynamic was a result o f g overnm ental policies o f international ad ju stm ent to those con ditions, with the aim o f restoring growth and preventing capitalist unem ploym ent. I t was a return to policies of global market integration and W estern iz ation , and the requisite changes in em ploy m ent and in social and governm ental organization, that led to this confrontation and to the system ic breakdown discussed in the final chapter of this book.
Chapter 10 BREAKDOWN
o f the 1980s began with a shift in governm ental policy, a return to an explicit program o f marketizing, “efficiency-oriented ” e c o nom ic re form — the pure version o f the Slovene model. It closed in 1989 with legislation end ing the property rights o f the socialist system and with a declaration by Slovenia’s gov ernm en t o f its intention to “dissociate” the republic from Yugoslavia. E c o n o m ic crisis had led to political crisis, then to a siege o f th e federal governm ent, and by 1991 to implosion and m ulti ple civil wars. T h e r e w ere com p etin g explanations. Presid ent T ito ’s death in May 1980— which, fortuitously, occurred within months o f this return to the I M F and e co n o m ic reform — retrospectively confirmed the popular view that th e system had b e e n held to g ether by his charismatic leadership and could not survive it. H e h im s elf had b e e n inclined to tell foreigners, in Louis X V fashion, “after m e, th e re will be c h a o s .”1 A second line saw an anticom m unist revolution paralleling events throughout the region: a popular revolt from below dem anding free e nterprise and dem ocracy and reflecting an ideological crisis— a loss o f faith in com m unism and in the legitimacy o f the ruling party. A third explanation repeated the political rhetoric that accom panied all “liberal” econom ic reform within the c o u n try, citing opposition to reform from Com m u nist conservatives and c e n tralist S erbian nationalists. Instead, th e period and its outcom e are b e tt e r understood as politics as usual in unusual tim es. T h e gov ernm ent attem pted to adjust to changing international conditions in the same way it always had, b u t both the in te r national and th e d om estic conditions on which the lead ers’ strategy had b e e n based until th e n no longer held. T h e international system underly ing their Faustian bargain of national com m unism was breaking down, and th e society that had to respond with the em p loy m ent adju stments
The decade
had b e e n transformed by their strategy o f econom ic d ev elop m en t since 1946 and by previous governm ental policies o f international adju stment. 1
Personal com m unication from Pamela Harriman (1993), to whom Tito said this when
she was staying as a guest at his villa near Split in 1979 after attending th e funeral for Edvard Kardelj with h e r husband, Ambassador Averell Harriman, as official U S representatives. Lenard C oh en gives the political scientist’s explanation: “T ito ’s death not only removed the principal symbol o f the re g im e’s legitimacy, but also the only public figure able to forge— or if necessary force— a working consensus among the increasingly divided political elite’ (The
Socialist Pyramid , 441).
346
C H A P T E R 10
W ith means used for decades to buy time ev e r less available, the politi cal re q u ir e m e n t of a new round of stabilization, structural adjustment, and sy stem ic reorganization was not charismatic leadership. It now mat tered crucially that the political institutions of the lead ers’ strategy could not, as was argued in chapter 7, perform their intended tasks of enforcing financial discipline, reg en erating growth, and managing political conflicts over e co n o m ic resources. In contrast to the thesis that th ere arose out of this e co n o m ic crisis an ideological crisis and a popular, anticommunist m o v e m e n t for political change, the existing political system — for reasons discussed in chap ter 9 — could not generate such collective action coun trywide, let alone an alternative policy more appropriate to the changed conditions. W h e re a s the ou tcom e had e lem ents of conservative reaction by C o m m u n ist party leaders and e lem ents o f Serbian nationalism, the m o v e m e n t for system ic change was initiated by party leaders in the north western republics, primarily Slovenia, who were reacting to the threat to th e ir pow er over capital that was posed by the institutional reforms being d em and ed by international creditors and by a policy of macroeconomic stabilization. T h e y ju stified their opposition, moreover, with the system’s ruling ideology. B u t in contrast to the liberal Marxist vision o f the state critical to that ideology, the withering away o f the Yugoslav state did not b ring harm ony. U n em p lo y m en t rem ained far down the list o f public concerns in this period o f e co n o m ic and political crisis, politically invisible to the en d — as it had b ee n in the previous three decades. But the collapse of the Yugoslav socialist system cannot b e understood without reference to it. As the Salais group found in the case o f F ra n c e at the same time, the institu tions set up to deal with un em ploym en t in the 1920s and 1930s retained their force into the 1980s, but they could no longer do the j o b . 2 The severity o f the ad ju stm en t program had finally brought the threat of so cialist u n em p lo y m en t— which m eant a fall in social status and political rights— to the core o f the most privileged in the public sector: the admin istrative stratum and its children. T h e ir response was to attack the institu tions o f e m p lo y m e n t allocation for such positions— the party’s influence o ver managerial positions, the affirmative action o f national quotas, and the educational reforms. Republican governm ents assailed the govern m ental functions financed by the federal b u d g et— the army, federal of fices, military pensions, and welfare subsidies to local g overnm ents— so as to red uce the h e ig h ten e d burden on their incomes. Y et another shift in labor policy for international reorientation disproportionately affected p o orer localities in the interior, w h ere populations w ere m ore ethnically mixed and d efense industries concentrated , and the result of the sectoral 2 S e e Piore, "Historical Perspectives and the Interpretation ol Unem ploym ent
BREAKDOWN
347
and geographical biases com m on to such market reorientation (as dis cussed in chap ter 8) had a pronounced territorial (and thus governmental) dim ension. Finally, the approach to labor rationalization— to cut labor costs in th e public sector and raise productivity by excluding “less pro du c tive” persons who had alternative, private sources o f su b siste n ce — introduced a new category of differentiation b etw ee n public and private em ploym ent: a p e rso n ’s national identity. F o r all these reasons, the leaders’ strategy toward u n em plo y m en t led to nationalism and the d e struction, rather than transformation, o f the Yugoslav state.
In t e r n a t io n a l A d ju s t m e n t
T h e pressure for change in Yugoslav econom ic policy and for political reform in the 1980s cam e as it had in the past— not from d om estic politi cal fo rces b u t from the international system. T h e re w ere th ree crucial m om ents: in 1979, 1985, and 1989. T o review the situation as discussed in previous chapters, problem s began in 1979 when the trade deficit and skyrocketing foreign d eb t forced the g overnm ent to draw em e rg en c y cred it from the I M F . W h e n the Croatian delegate Milka Planinc b ecam e prim e m inister in 1982, her mandate was to restore the confid ence of foreign creditors. By 1982, negotiations with the I M F had also brought a three -y e a r standby loan that was conditional on econom ic reform. A long term stabilization program aimed not only to cut dom estic dem and suffi ciently to red uce the foreign d eb t and trade deficit to manageable levels, but also to make the: institutional changes necessary for more effective financial discipline and greater exports to W e stern markets in the long run. T hat is, external stabilization was once again aimed at lowering labor costs; in order to reduce inflation, improve the com petitiveness o f m anu factured exports, increase production efficiency and invest the savings in technological modernization, and cut the drain o f state expenditures (ad m inistrative e m ployees, defense, and federal subsidies and transfers for local welfare and d ev elop m en t credits) on productive investment. E c o n o m ic reform cut short the expansion in em ploy m ent that occurred during the 1970s; after 1979, em p loy m ent stagnated and public rhetoric em phasized the problem o f ’ov erem p lo y m en t." Unlike in the early 1960s, when the previous such econom ic reform took off and registered u n em p lo y m en t was around 6 p ercent, the official un em ploym en t rate was now close to 14 p ercent. C oncealed within this n u m b e r w ere the stru c tural ch a ra cter of u n em ploym ent, its unequal regional distribution, and the fact that more than hall of the jo bless w ere under the age o f 25 and had en g in e e rin g or university diplomas. M o reover, while the problem of u n em p lo y m en t had most affected the peasantry and unskilled workers in the 1950s, the pensioned officers and security police and the university
348
C H A P T E R 10
students from poor (usually rural) origins in the 1960s, and rural migrants to the cities (especially Belgrad e and Skopje) and the children of private artisans and military personnel in the 1970s, by the 1980s unemployment was th reaten in g industrial workers and especially the children of the ur ban middle class. T h e prospect o f additional un em ploym ent thus faced the b eneficiaries of socialism— industrial workers and budget-financed administrators, professionals, and office workers. Unlike in 1 9 47 or 1950, m oreover, the proportion o f the population working in agriculture had dropped dramatically, from 78 to 19 .9 percent by the 1981 census. T h e pace of urbanization had been particularly rapid in the 1970s as individuals left rural areas and poorer towns in search of e co n o m ic opportunity. T h e realism o f the g o v ern m e n t’s domestic solution for surplus labor— to send an increasingly urban strata of unemployed back to the villages and private-sector agriculture and trades— had thus b ee n red uced substantially. T h e foreign demand for labor, the primary outlet for the rural labor surplus and children o f private-sector parents, had b ee n on the decline since 1975 (cutting the contribution o f workers’ rem ittances from one-half to only one-fourth o f the trade deficit by 1979, for e x a m p le ).3 As in the previous periods when foreign-trade conditions required such e co n o m ic reform (in 1 9 4 9 - 5 2 and 1 9 5 8 -6 4 ) , adju stm ent again began with substantial cuts in public investm ent, the leaders relying on internal sav ings and d om estic sacrifices for recovery b ecause a global recession was hind ering export trade, W e ste rn protectionism was again on the rise, and Yugoslavia’s terms of trade had deteriorated. F re s h capital was available only to refinance debt. B ut while there was a short-term econom ic recov e ry in 1 9 8 5 - 8 6 and a resumption of lending to E a stern E u ro p e by foreign banks, both of which allowed the g overnm ent to abandon the I M F pro gram in favor of m ore moderate sacrifice and some growth stimulus, for eign trade and dom estic growth did not recover, unlike in the earlier periods. And instead o f a reduction in international tensions or a military threat fio m the W arsaw Pact (which would favor conventional-war doc trine and decentralization to the territorial defense forces)— either of which would have b een com patible with the ongoing cuts in the federal d efense b u d g et— the threat from N ATO continued to mount, requiring a ttention to the air and naval defense o f the seaeoast and cities against a possible blitzkrieg attack and stimulating a new arms race in sophisticated w e ap o n s.4 W h ile a coalition o f econom ic liberals and international crediD e b a te s ill the federal assembly in 1 9 7 5 - 7 6 gave vent to anger at the workers who were re lu m in g . S e e Politika, O c to b er 10, 1975, 7; and April 11, 1976, 8 (cited in Resemeres,
Socialist Population Politics) 1
Military expenditures in developed countries, particularly NATO m em bers, peaked in
1987; in Yugoslavia (as in oth er developing countries, including G reec e and Turkey), the high point was 19<S3 (Isakovic, "The Ralkan Arm ies,” 2).
BREAKDOWN
349
tors worked throughout the decade to restore value to the cu rrency and the authority o f financial indicators and monetary regulation, by 1985 a spiral toward hyperinflation had begun with double-digit inflation. T h e dinar was replaced in d om estic transactions by foreign hard currencies, and by the end of 1989, a new prim e minister had initiated a “shocktherapy” program aimed toward im m ediate stabilization and cu rrency convertibility within the year. T he g ov ern m e n t did succeed, as it had in the 1960s, in negotiating a debt-refinancing package during 1 9 8 3 - 8 5 , which was coordinated by the U.S . State D e p a rtm e n t to support P rim e M inister Planinc and the e c o nomic reform. B u t this help was prem ised on the c o ld -w a r assumptions of Yugoslavia’ special status— on its Faustian bargain. By 1985, these as sumptions w ere seriously challenged as a result o f changes in E urope. The moves toward greater E uro pean integration after 1 9 85 — in the W e s t with th e program for E C m onetary unification in 1992, and in the East with G o r b a c h e v ’s e con om ic reform in the U S S R , the resumption o f n e g o tiations b e tw e e n the C M E A and the E C , and the move in C M E A trade away from long-term bilateral trade agreem ents toward world market pricing— suggested that the division o f the world econom y into separate markets, which had given Yugoslav manufacturers some flexibility, might end. W h ile foreign econ om ic opportunities e m erg ed for Slovenia and Croatia in tourist and trade associations with neighboring countries, the perception o f a rising military threat due to N A T O ’s posture in th e east ern M ed ite rra n ea n prolonged the arm y’s concerns for defensive self reliance. Throughout the country, but particularly in the northwest, the debates that originally shaped the lea d ers’ strategy during the 1920s and 1930s, as discussed in chap ter 2, w ere b eing revived. T h e issues o f identity and boundaries, including international econom ic and military alliances, once again revolved around the question, “W h o are we in E u r o p e ? ’’ And b e cause all regions and social groups w ere experien cing declining standards of living and rising un em plo y m en t as a result o f the d ebt and trade crisis— even though differences w ere also b eing e x a ce rb ated — the q u e s tions of what com m on econom ic program and constitutional form would fit their he te rog e n e ou s conditions w ere also raised again. T h e answers given to the second question by the long-term stabilization program of 1983 and the party com m ission ’s report on constitutional reform (made public in 1985) still reflected the com prom ises that had characterized the political-econom ic mix of the Slovene and F o c a models. B u t the pressure from the international system for homogenization and a choice for the Slovene model was intensifying. By 1989, the collapse of the Warsaw Pact, the political revolution in E a stern E u ro p e , and the term ination of Yugoslavia’s special relationship with the U n ite d States had rem oved the rationale for the country’s neu-
350
C H A P T E R 10
trality and defensive strength in the Balkans. Although negotiations with the E C and the E u ro p e a n F r e e Trad e Association had not b een as expan sive as the Yugoslavs had hoped, and although their neutrality had left them as outsiders in the E a s t-W e s t rapprochem ent in security and eco nom ic relations, th e re was a consensus within the federal government (including the army) in favor o f westernization and liberalization. There no longer see m e d to b e any purpose to the roles played in the past by the Yugoslav P e o p le ’s Army, the nonalignment m ovem ent, and domestic pro duction to support military independ ence. E v e n had Tito lived, the global era in which h e had created his primary function as a leader— his international role in balancing among foreign blocs and his domestic role in balancing b etw ee n the institutions and political factions o f the Slovene and F o c a m odels— was com ing to an end. T h e real question facing the g overnm ent was how to manage politically this task of im p lem en tin g e con om ic reform and policies for debt repay m ent. W h a t d om estic political resources would com pensate for the loss of the custom ary sources o f te m porary flexibility and maneuverability in the strategy for e con om ic growth— access to foreign capital and export mar kets and expulsion o f labor into the private sector and agriculture? T h e federal g o v ernm ent proceed ed to im p lem ent macroeconom ic sta bilization in the usual manner, introducing institutional reforms of the public sector that would increase financial discipline and labor productiv ity by improving pro d u cers’ e conom ic incentives to use resources more efficiently (to b e profitable) and by strengthening the vertical links of con trol through m onetary institutions and uniform (central) rules appropriate to a single market. According to Yugoslav econom ic liberals, I M F econo mists, and foreign creditors, the extrem e decentralization and segmenta tion o f the econom y in the 1974 constitution and subsequent legislation on foreign borrowing and d eb t obligations had b eco m e counterproduc tive, causing constant delays, financial indiscipline, and an immobilized g ov ernm ent. F o cu sin g first on the need to create a renewed capacity for e ffective m onetary policy in the hands of an independ ent central bank, by 1985 the I M F in particular began to insist on a strengthened federal ad ministration as w e ll.5 B y 1987, the I M F and W orld Bank placed priority in negotiations for new loans on this political capacity for macroeconomic policy, referring to “radical surgery’’ to rem ove the remaining socialist e le m e n ts inhibiting m arket allocation o f capital and labor. T h e constitu5
It is difficult to assess th e influence o f the I M F and oth er foreign creditors (such as the
Bank o f International Settlem en ts) in the political quarrels o f the time, although the IM F ’s credits and im prim atur w ere more critical than e v e r before. But it is perhaps ironic that, after a hall century o f urging “decentralization” as a precondition for niarketization (and even using it as a code word for the same), the I M F and oth er W estern advisers would now be the proponents o f a strong federal administration and a renewed econom ic center.
BREAKDOWN
351
tional a m e n d m e n ts em bodying the resulting federal program called these institutions o f a neoliberal m arket econom y “functional integ ratio n.” T h e goal o f m onetary discipline and reduced inflation not only gave authority back to th e National Bank (evident in, for example, its refusal to bail out in d e b ted republican banks); it also requ ired greater diligence with re s p ec t to the constitutional obligation to balance g o v ernm ent b ud gets. B e ca u s e federal tax revenues w ere declining as a result o f trade liberalization and m acro eco nom ic stabilization policies, the outflow o f taxes from republican coffers increased. At the same tim e, the rep u blics’ revenues from b usinesses w ere b eing reduced by the supply-side in c e n tives to e n te rp rises (which cut their taxes and shifted financing o f services to u ser fees and retail markets). A federal fiscal crisis necessarily implied a local fiscal crisis in all com m u n e s below the average in per capita G D P , and the q uestion o f w h eth er republican g overnm ents would have to as sum e th e ir welfare role was left open. Finally, structural a d ju stm ent to W e ste rn markets was b eing facilitated by wage restrictions and new labor legislation giving managers a freer hand to hire and fire in th e pursuit o f com m ercial profits and lower labor costs. Industrial policy guiding cred it policy and labor regulations r e e m phasized both dem and for manufactured com m odities in W e ste rn m ar kets and technological modernization to co m p ete with international standards o f productivity. T h e e m p loy m e n t program within th e long-term stabilization policy brought the dual labor-sector strategy into the public sector, proposing to divide the country territorially into a high-wage, technologically advanced, export-oriented North and a low-wage, labor intensive South. T h e search for foreign investm ent in a m ore com petitive international e n v iron m en t soon began to drive labor legislation as well— to encou rage foreign investm ent by removing the last limits on foreign ow nership and all self-m anagem ent curbs on managerial authority over labor. B y 1988, legislation for privatization— private-property rights for foreign capital, th e end o f workers’ rights to consultation, and the end of the division o f firms into basic organizations o f associated labor— was b e ing e nacted. W orld Bank recom m end ations w ere formulated into bank ruptcy legislation. T h e effect o f new banking regulations was a political crisis in Croatia and S e rb ia when the debts o f the largest depositors in their republican banks (particularly the oil pro du cer IN A and the steel industry at S m e d ere v o ) could b e reduced only by spreading the d eb t among o ther depositors, thus socializing it across smaller firms within the republic. By 1987, the limits on new federal cred it had spread th e banking crisis to Bosnia-H erzegovina, w h ere the largest cong lom erate— A grokom erc— a tte m p ted to recou p its losses with unsupported promissory notes bought by banks throughout the country, most heavily by th e still-solvent, sue-
352
C H A P T E R 10
cessful republican bank of Slovenia. A real-interest-rate policy (the last holdout o f th e federal authorities against the I M F stabilization program) made borrowing too costly for the small businesses that w ere the primary hope of the g o v e r n m e n t’s em p loy m ent policy. Tax rebellions by republi can parliam ents, which simply refused to pay the federal governm ent, led the latter to make up the shortfall in minimum legislated funds for the army and o th er federal obligations by ignoring limits on the money supply and accepting seig niorag e.6 D eclinin g subsidies to local governm ents un able to pay th e ir welfare com m itm ents led to rising taxes on the alreadysqu eezed private sector. Plant closures in declining industries (often in one-ind ustry towns) brought the first real appearance of unem ploym ent resulting from mass layoffs. By 1990, estimates of econom ic redundancies for the year (u nem ploy m ent due to bankruptcies and closures, not includ ing technological redundancies due to the introduction of new equipm ent or labor-saving procedures) nu m bered 4 4 5 ,0 0 0 in a labor force o f 10 mil lion (6 .6 million in the public sector) and w ere expected to b e even higher in 1 9 9 1 .”
T h e Po litic a l C onsequences
of
Unem ploym ent
T h e e co n o m ic success of this program, according to the governm ent’s strategy, d ep end ed on the renew ed gains in productivity and profit from the rationalizing and com m ercially oriented reforms of the public sector of th e econom y and on the en fo rcem en t power o f econom ic interest. The strategy, how ever, like all those based on classical or neoclassical models of e co n o m ic growth, had always presum ed not only a closed economy but full em ploy m ent. In the pre sen ce o f high unem ploym ent, its consequence was to u n d erm in e the political bases o f the system. Ju st as the political assumptions of the strategy intended, there was no politically mediated relation such as a political m o vem ent to protest the threat, and then the reality, of even higher unem ploym en t or to propose alternative policies; the effect was direct. T h e first effect of u n em plo y m en t was on the capacity to enforce policy goals. T h e vertical links of monetary control and econom ic interest in K a rd e lj’s political system ran on two tracks: the Com m unist party, and the parliamentary and eonciliar representation of econom ic interests. The two e n fo rce m e n t mechanism s w ere the hierarchical discipline o f the LCY and its affiliated organizations and their powers of persuasion with non 6 T h e relation betw een th e federal budget and the money supply in such a hybrid eco n om ic system is a complex and technical sub ject. S e e Mates, “Inflation in Yugoslavia” and “M easu rem en t of G o v ern m en t Budget D eficit”; and C om m ander, “Inflation and the Transi tion to a M arket E c o n o m y .” 7 Crosslin, “Labor Related Program s in Yugoslavia/’ 8.
353
BR E A K D O W N
m em b ers to accep t the rules established by experts and by social consul tation as b ein g in their collective, long-run interests; and the natural cooperation and “harmonization o f in terests” in deliberative councils and elected assem blies by delegates from self-governing, public-sector pro ducers (republican governm ents, and enterprises) whose econom ic in te r est lay in rational choices on econom ic policy. Both m echanisms b ec a m e ineffective as a result of unem ploym ent. As access to pu blic-secto r em p loy m ent b eca m e ev e r more restricted and u n em p lo y m en t grew particularly among those aspiring to administra tive positions (the category o f “guaranteed salaries”) because of their e d u cation, the authority o f the party was increasingly underm ined by its transformation into a g a te k ee p e r for such positions— a form of craft union for managers and politicians. T h e reality o f declining em p loy m ent and increasing individual com petition reinforced individual strategies to im prove personal capital— skills and years o f education, party activism, and networks o f recip rocal personal obligations. Those who failed to obtain e m p loy m e n t co m m e n su ra te with their formal qualifications, as the princi ple of parity requ ired , perceived an increasing com petition b etw een po litical and educational criteria. R e se n tm e n t over the party’s influence (or p erceiv ed influence) over high-status jo bs intensified, while the ever more fre q u e n t resort to personal and political connections further co r rupted application o f the ru les.8 W ithin enterprises, w h ere conflicts over incomes intensified with declining incomes and federal restrictions (the n u m b e r o f work stoppages and strikes rose 8 0 p e rce n t betw een 1982 and 1983; by 1987, 1 ,5 7 0 work stoppages involving 3 6 5 ,0 0 0 workers w ere re ported officially),9 relations b etw ee n industrial workers and the party were also strained b ecau se the party’s role in supervising wage r e strictions placed it increasingly in the role o f strik e b re a k e r .10 Since the program for marketization once again made professionals— no longer co n tractual e m p loy ees of e n te rp rises— respond to consu m er dem and for their services, they b e ca m e an ind ep end en t source o f support, separate from the party hierarchy, for workers challenging a firing or wage regula tions (as discussed earlier in regard to Slovene accountants and lawyers in the c o m m u n e s ’ labor courts). T h e ad ju stm ent to changing international conditions and for econ om ic stabilization over the years by altering re g u lations on m oney, labor, and constitutional ju risd ictions— and when the requ ired a d ju stm ent could not occur fast enough, by further altering the rules and convoking new a g re em en ts — had begun to un derm ine the le H An especially popular proverb after the late J9 6 0 s was “A law exists so as to have a loophole” (Zakon postoji da ima nipu). 9 R am et, “Apocalypse C u lture and Social Change “Yugoslavia.”
in Yugoslavia,” 9;
Rem ington,
10 S e e Jovanov, “P ledoaje za dijalog o drzavi u socijali/.mu,” for this assessm ent.
354
C H A P T E R 10
gitimacy of those rules. D ep riv ed of their essential attributes of stability and predictability, the rules lost authority; this could not help translating into degrading; the authority o f the party that was supposed to supervise th e ir im plem entation . Citizens did not enjoy the security of enforceable rules applied regardless o f station. T h e p arty ’s c o m m itm e n t to the general interest— a c om m itm ent e m bodied in federal rules— was also strained by the party’s “socialization” in an e con om y without full em p loy m ent b ecause its m em b ers depended for their livelihood on their w o rk p laces.11 T h e leaders’ discipline over the party rank-and-file that was essential to the en forcem en t aspect o f d em o cratic centralism was so weakened as to appear nonexistent. In a period of sharply declining resources, the national com m ittees (republican party organizations) that com posed the L C Y w ere in com petition for the e co nom ic resources necessary to their patronage on jo b s and credits within their republic. T h e second means o f enforcing policy goals— the c om m itm ent o f re p re sentatives o f republican governm ents and organizations to the ag ree m ents they had participated in m aking— thus began to unravel as well, b eca u se their responsibility for the e conom ic d ev elopm en t o f their terri tory and its capacity for em ploy m ent and rising standards o f living d e p end ed on th e resources they could keep from being taxed away or could capture from federal funds. T h e idea o f a contractual state based on mu tual interests, cooperation, and “harm onization” o f differences (rather than the electoral choice o f winners and losers) was in conflict with the e co n o m ic reality. T h e role o f parliaments was to decide issues over which the gov ernm ents that w ere re p re sen ted had fundamental differences of e co n o m ic in te re s t— budgets, taxes and transfers, and reform legislation. U n able to agree, plagued by delays in decision making and growing in stances o f vote trading, logrolling, and deadlock resolved only by tem por ary d e cr e e s o f the federal cabinet, the federal g overnm ent exhausted the p a tien ce and lost the confidence of an ever-growing n u m b e r o f Yugoslav citizens and foreign creditors. B u t the problem was not, as many ob servers insisted, that th ere was no consensus among political leaders. The p ro b lem was that political consensus was the only m echanism available for resolving these conflicts and making hard choices. F orced to com e to som e a g re em en t by the risk o f losing foreign credits or by the constitu 11 Although criticized by self-management advocates as well as W estern economists, the party’s practice of “sanitization”— the procedure for restructuring a firm to forestall bankruptcy— made some sense. The local government and party committee appointed a tem porary outside manager who was, of course, part of the circulating stratum of the party’s managerial cadres. Asked about the basis of his virtues in attempting to restructure the Economic Bank of Zagreb in 1982, Tomislav Badovinac emphasized his “independence” and therefore his freedom to make necessary but unpopular decisions (Start interview).
BREAKDOWN
355
tional tim e ta b le according to which executive d ecree s would b eco m e law unless overridden by the assembly, the m e m b ers tend ed to achieve “pa per u n ity ,’ as it was called — b u t it was ag re em en t that could not be im plem ented . A second effect o f the lead ers’ strategy in a situation o f high un em plo y m ent was to u n d erm in e the delicate balance in constitutional jurisdictions of the federal system b ecau se of the intensified com petition among prop erty ow ners to pro te ct their capital assets from declining further. In this system o f socialist property rights, those owners w ere the republican gov ern m e n ts. Conflicts in fe deral-republican relations over im plem enting federal policy occu rred in all th ree aspects of the reform that affected control over capital and e m p lo y m e n t— the recentralization of control over m onetary policy, the banking system, and foreign exchange; the r e strictions to cut excess dem and, em bodied in control on wages, salaries, and cred it and in the rising taxation of republics to reduce the federal deficit; and the proposals to improve federal administrative capacity for effective m a cro eco n om ic policy. All three would deprive the republics and provinces o f the sovereignty over econom ic resources that they had gained b e tw e e n 1968 and 1978. Although most republics opposed this dim inution o f sovereignty, b ecau se o f the con se q u e n ces for their r e sources for local investm ent and em p loy m ent expansion (and therefore political power), their bargaining strength in this contest varied according to their level o f un em ploym en t and their flexibility in international ad ju s tm e n t to p reven t un em plo y m en t from rising. W h ile the decline o f the federal party’s international bargaining position gave the republican par ties the illusion o f m ore freedom to go their own way, that freedom would also d ep end on international leverage. It was not the republics in the south with un em ploym en t o f 20 p e rc e n t or m ore that took the political lead, b u t Slovenia— with full em ploy m ent, labor shortages in industry, and only re c e n t threats to living standards. Full e m p lo y m e n t in Slovenia m eant that the costs o f liberalization and technological modernization w ere much lower. T h e re p u b lic’s extensive export orientation (in both W e s te r n and E a stern markets) and share of military industries also made it able to adapt more readily to changes in foreign econ om ic policy, even when it opposed a particular policy as less favorable to Slovene interests. In a context o f fre q u e n t labor shortages, g o v ernm ent econom ists w ere m ore inclined toward com prehensive plan ning over S lovene space, taking into account social and cultural as well as e con om ic factors in d ev elop m en t policy; and Slovene unions and firms consistently o b je cte d to the maxim ums placed on wages. W h e n stabiliza tion policies requ ired cuts in wages and social expenditures, the repu bli can g ov ern m e n t tended to respond to workers’ and managers’ protests by ignoring the controls.
356
C H A P T E R 10
Although an export-oriented, marketizing reform would seem to have b e e n most advantageous to the republics earning the largest export reve nues in W e ste rn markets, the S lovene g overnm ent ob je cte d strongly to its loss o f rights to retain those revenues in Slovenia implied by the new re q u irem en ts for depositing foreign exchange with the National Bank. W ith ou t that foreign exchange, Slovenia’s program to raise worker pro ductivity back to E uro pean standards and to resolve labor shortages in industry with imports o f more-advanced equ ip m en t and technology was in danger. In view o f declining standards o f living in the republic and wage com petition with foreign countries for professional labor, its enter prises began to campaign against the rules on redistribution o f a portion of m ark et earnings from “above-average” to “below -average” firms and lo calities to replenish solidarity funds for guaranteed wages and the federal fund for credits to less-developed republics. In their view, this redistribu tion was weakenin g the incentives to higher productivity in Slovene firm s .12 O b je c tin g to federal taxation on similar grounds— that resources w ere b eing wasted on the less efficient or unproductive— the republican g ov ern m e n t began to protest against the visible beneficiaries o f the fed eral budget: the federal army, the less-developed republics, and the fed eral ad m in istra tio n .13 (Firm s receiving selective credits and subsidies, such as for export promotion, escaped criticism.) In a campaign directly co u n te r to the reform proposals to restrengthen the federal administra tion, S lovene authorities began to press for erasure of the last vestiges of federal pow er— the YPA, the federal fund, the federal constitutional court, and all federal legislation that was in conflict with its republican legislation. An early step in this p ro ject was to prevent a political coalition from m obilizing against it; the Slovenes proposed transforming the fed eral L eag u e of Com m u nists into a confederation along the lines of the conciliar federal governm ent, with multiple-candidacy elections for the party’s presidium and a shift in voting rules from majority principles to 12 T h e r e s e a r c h b y V o d o p iv e c to d e m o n s t r a t e this p o in t o rig i n a te d in this political cli m a te , m o s t p r o n o u n c e d in S lo v e n ia (“ P r o d u c ti v ity Effects o f R e d i s tr ib u tio n in a Socialist E co n o m y ”). 13 In th e first stages oí th e return to econom ic reform and emphasis on overemployment, in 1982, th e press in Croatia and Slovenia paid much attention to the rapid growth of em ploym en t in the federal administration. According to an article in the Zagreb daily Vjesnik on S e p te m b e r 8, 1982, the average annual increase in th e previous “few years” was 16 p erce n t, in contrast to the 2 . 5 to 4 , 5 p ercent for the country as a whole, and the party organization within federal offices held meetings (presided over by Slovene party leader Marjan Rožič) to reverse the growth, the “special con cern ” over the rising proportion of em plo yees with low qualifications,” th e hiring according to “personal interest” instead of by com petition, th e rising proportion o f administrative categories in which “income is deter m ined exclusively by established coefficients” regardless ol “work contribution and results of la b o r,” and the rising n u m b er o f persons em ployed part-tim e, on contract, and after retire ment (p. 5).
BREAKDOWN
357
parity by rep u blic and consensus (a system they called asym m etric fe d e r alism). B y 1985, Slovenia was proposing that the country itself b eco m e a confederation o f sovereign republics. T h e turning point in Slovene demands cam e after 1985, when e c o nom ic d ev elop m en ts in E u ro p e suggested new opportunities— in d e p e n d en t o f the federal g ov ern m e n t— for foreign capital, W e ste rn trade, and eventually, it was hoped, integration with central E uro pe. T h e r e sumption o f com m ercial-b ank lending to E a stern E u ro p e gave profitable exporters a way to get around federal restrictions on foreign exchange; foreign in vestm en t began to flow into Slovenia and Croatia; and both Italy and Austria expanded e con om ic ties eastward, including the opening of affiliates o f four Austrian banks in Ljubljana. F o r the same external rea sons that caused a decline in the bases o f federal authority— the party’s bargaining power in a cold-war e n vironm ent that had given the govern m e n t and firms access to W e stern capital markets, fuels, and multiple export m ark ets— the Slovene party and g overnm ent saw its options m u lti ply. At th e same time, the Slovene econom y benefited less than in the past from federal g ov ern m e n t policies. T h e advantages to Slovene firms ol fed eral price regulations that favored manufacturers had dim inished substan tially with d om estic price liberalization, while the global decline in prices of primary com m od ities after their rise during the 1970s now made foreign raw materials ch e a p e r than d om estic p ro d u c ts .14 This, to g ether with the decline in the strategic threat on Slovenia’s own borders and its policy of keeping them populated with settled farm ers, made it even easier to ar gue against th e federal d efense budget and federal protection of dom estic producers o f those raw and interm ediate materials that w ere integral to the c o u n try ’s strategic policy of self-reliance. M oreover, even the Slovene un em p lo y m en t rate had risen to 5 pe rce n t by 1985, although the gov ern m ent continu ed to focus on the problem o f labor shortages. T h e S lovene gov ernm ent was not alone in opposing the reforms in property rights to e con om ic resources earned by producers on a re p u b lic’s territory. T h e Croatian assem bly was more vocal in refusing to sup port the d efense bud get with its tax monies. Vojvodina and M acedonia were as often leading the opposition to recentralization o f the “planning sy stem ’’ (control over investm ent funds and industrial policy) and to the idea that the federal gov ernm en t should have some key e con om ic func tions necessary to a m acroeconom ic policy, even though their econom ies w ere d ep e n d e n t on d om estic markets for both supplies and s a le s .15 C o n ditions in the labor markets of all the republics and provinces excep t Slo '** On th e greate r integration o f the Slovene econom y with international markets than with th e dom estic econom y in th e 1980s, see Bookman, "T h e E con om ic Basis oi Regional Autarchy in Yugoslavia/” 15 Bookman contrasts th e situation in Vojvodina with that in Slovenia (ibid.)
358
C H A P T E R 10
venia (and Kosovo, whose case was discussed in the previous chapter) at a tim e when un em p lo y m en t could clim b fu rther gave them even m ore in ce n tiv e to maxim ize the funds under republican control (including federal grants and bud g et subventions). N onetheless, b ecause their lack o f inde p e n d e n t resources in international capital and goods markets (in contrast to Slovenia) kept them d ep en d e n t on the federal g ov ern m e n t’s good rela tions with foreign creditors and its access to foreign capital and trade, the o th e r republics and provinces could obstruct the changes but not initiate a lte r n a tiv e s.16 T h e only exception was Serbia. W h ile Slovenia was locked in a struggle with the federal g overnm ent, the political econom y of S erbia was in the opposite position. W h e re a s Slovenia had never had to take federal aid and its citizens felt penalized for their econom ic success, S erbia was also ineli gible for aid, consid ered a m ore-developed republic. But its economic indicators in the 1980s told a different story. It had fallen below the aver age on all m easures, but it was still paying federal taxes at rates assessed on those classified as m ore-developed; its G D P was declining, its un em ploym ent rising, and a rural exodus continuing. T h e 1974 constitution had given its provinces control over their econom ies, including the federal grants-in-aid to Kosovo. Along the same lines as the federal proposals for increasing federal e co n o m ic capacity, liberals in Belgrade w ere attem pt ing to reverse the autonom ies granted by the 1974 constitution and regain constitutional powers over the whole o f the Serbian econom y — in oppo sition to those in Vojvodina dem anding continuing autonomy and an increasingly d eterm in e d Albanian population dem anding a separate re public for Kosovo. W ith u n em plo y m en t in Belgrade above 25 percent, a large portion o f it due to the rapid influx from rural areas and other repub lics after the late 1970s, proposals for a restreng thened federal administra tion w ere also clearly in S e rb ia ’s interest; Slovene proposals to end it entirely would, if enacted, add substantially to local un em ploym en t rolls.
,(i This position was confirmed hv the actions o f Yugoslavia’s foreign creditors in 1 990-91 when the country's breakup seem ed ev er more likely. As late as May 1991, hankers urged support for the econoinic-reform program o f the federal governm ent (under Prime Minister Ante Markovic) and therefore its capacity to service its foreign d e b t— the primary purpose ol the reform. T hey insisted that the country should be held together because only with the export-earnings capacity o f Slovenia and Croatia were the other four republics able to get reasonable credit terms in international capital markets; and without those two republics, banks had little prospect o f having their outstanding loans to the oth er four republics paid, (p ersonal comm unication from Charles Meissner, U .S. m em b er of the debt-refinancing teams o f th e 1980s and early 1990s). But as early as 1982, when the I M F adopted a far more rigid policy toward conditionality than with previous programs, a m e m b er of the I M F ’s team in Yugoslavia proposed talking directly to republican leaderships because it was clear to him that th e power ol im plem entation lay with them. He was told that this was not possible b ecause the I M F could negotiate only with sovereign authorities; he resigned trom the mission (author s interview with that mem ber).
BREAKDOWN
359
In all the republics except Slovenia, however, the reform policies di vided party leaderships, enterprises, and populations. T h e r e was no id en tifiable, single republican interest or party faction w h ere econom ics com bined socialist and private sectors; export and dom estic-m arket o rie n tation; links with W e ste rn , E a stern , and nonaligned markets; com m ercial and productive activities; and distinct areas o f manufacturing and prim ary-com m odity production. B ecau se of the strong localization and territorial patterns ol econom ic activity, party com m ittees and leaders were directly affected by these differences. T h e most striking example was the “great sile n c e ” said to reign during the 1980s in Croatia. T h e party leadership had b een elected after the 1972 political purge o f party leaders accused of nurturing mass nationalism (th e so-called mass m o ve ment, or maspok) in order to win Croatian interests at the time o f the previous marketizing, W estern -o rie n te d reform in the 1960s. T h e y w ere said as a group to fear the co n se q u e n ces o f a repeat of the social turmoil and, in the ease o f some individuals, to rep resen t areas o f ethnically mixed (mainly S e rb and Croat) population in the poor interior and the D alm atian hinterland. But these areas w ere objectively suffering from the shift in policy and deindustrialization, with particularly hard-hit local industries— railroads, construction, tim ber, and mining. It was of some c o n s e q u e n ce politically that the areas with b e tte r prospects from the e c o nom ic reform in central Croatia and Dalm atia had a more purely Croatian population, while the areas with declining prospects and severe u n em ploym ent had mixed populations. T h e same was true in Macedonia, al though h e re as in Bosnia-IIerzegovin a, there was little difference among towns and areas of the republic in their exposure to serious econom ic hardship as a result of declining demand for their products, both at home and in export markets near collapse in the Middle East and in C M E A countries. W h ile Slovenia and, to a certain extent, Croatia were in the anomalous position from the point of view of econom ic reform of benefiting from m arket principles while refusing to abandon their rights o f “econom ic sov e reig nty to allow the free, countrywide, flow o f labor, capital, and for eign exchange that a market econom y implies, so the other republics and provinces sought com pensatory federal expenditures and foreign credits for d evelopm ental infrastructure, capital industries, and welfare transfers to local budgets at the same time that they w ere resisting any loss o f their constitutional authority over capital resources to the federal governm ent. T h e result was constitutional deadlock and no sign of a com prom ise position. A third political co n s e q u e n ce ol un em ploym ent was its effect on the system s capacity to adapt politically to the requ irem ents of new econom ic and social conditions. W h e re a s the Slovene rebellion against the constitu tional aspects of the e conom ic rclorm remained within the vertical hier-
360
C H A P T E R 10
arehv o f K a rd e lj’s institutional system — taking the path o f territorial decentralization and republican sovereignty that the Slovene Communist party had b e e n pursuing since 1934 to its final conclusion— the conse q u e n ce s of g overnm ental policy w ere beginning to break down the rigid divisions of republican borders, ju s t as they had during the liberal reforms in the 1960s until the constitutional am endm ents of 1 9 6 7 - 7 1 interfered. F o r exam ple, as early as 1982, the econom ic e m erg en cy led Planinc to insist that she be allowed to ignore the rule on ethnonational parity in c ab in e t appointm ents; Slovenia traded concessions on the reform in 1985 for an exception to the constitutional order of rotation for prime minister, giving the post to Branko Mikulic from Bosnia; and by 1986 the I M F had successfully pressured the gov ernm ent to adopt a majority-decision rule in place of consensus for the board of governors of the National Bank. As part o f a m ajor reform o f defense policy, M inister o f D efen se Branko Ma mula red rew the borders o f military districts in 1985 to cut across republi can lines, and the federal army stepped up a campaign to reintegrate the m ajor infrastructural systems o f the country (transportation, com m unica tions, and energy). T h e r e were discussions in the mid-1980s (in which all republics e x ce p t Slovenia participated) about establishing a countrywide c ore cu rricu lum , with selections from all national literatures, for primary and second education, in order to break down educational barriers to labor mobility and to improve awareness and appreciation o f cultural plu ralism. Regional d ev elopm en t groups to regen erate areas devastated by industrial decline or shifts in investm ent priorities began to form, such as the one made up o f local planning authorities and econom ic experts in the krajina (an area shared by Croatia and Bosnia-Herzegovina). By 1988, workers from large industries in Croatia, S erbia proper, and Vojvodina had taken their wage protests out o f their factories and republics to the doors o f the federal a s s e m b ly .17 M o re ov e r, while full em p loy m ent in Slovenia had created marketlike conditions and the beginnings o f pluralist politics, elsew here the extent of rising un em p lo y m en t and falling wages, savings, and household incomes, as well as the e ver-h a rsh er prospects o f international adju stment, was such that o n e could imagine the fall o f political barriers as well in a coun te rfo rce of Jacksonian character against the Madisonianism of the smaller, ric h e r states of Slovenia and Croatia. Throughout the country, economic hardship, a ceiling on upward social mobility, stricter criteria for employ m e n t in the public sector, rising internal econom ic migration, and cul tural shifts to ju stify keeping women and youth at hom e were bringing a
17
C arter discusses the attempts by party organizations to obstruct workers’ efforts to
create cross-republican alliances in the 1960s (Democratic Reform in Yugoslavia, 164-67, 204-7).
BREAKDOWN
361
profound social upheaval. T h e r e was a kind o f Brownian motion o f e x cluded groups— e ith e r discarded politically in some previous purge or never given entry into the public sector— though th e re w ere no obvious signs o f how they might coalesce. T h e deaths o f Kardelj in 1979 and Tito in 19 8 0 rem oved the last taboos on political speech and reactivated voices calling for a reassessm ent o f the war and o f those purged after the war— from Archbishop S tep inac in Croatia to the many Serbs and M o n tenegrins charged as Cominformists in 1 9 4 8 - 5 0 or forced into re tirem en t as generals in 1 9 5 8 - 6 4 and m e m b ers o f the security apparatus in 1966. U nem ployed youth in many regions gave support to millenarian and fun damentalist religious m o vem ents and to right-wing ideas (such as revivals of C h etn ik , U s ta s h a ,18 and Nazi memorabilia and loyalties). C h u rches b e came m ore politically active. U n em p lo y m en t pushed many urban dwellers into “gray’’ or even criminal activities, and it increased tensions b etw ee n long-tim e residents (favored by K ard e lj’s policy o f settled c o m munities) and new com ers (such tensions dated back to the population resettle m e n ts on the northern plains in 1947, but they had shifted to the cities through individual migrations since then). Signs o f social disloca tion, “strains o f pessimism, gloom, resignation, escapism o f various kinds,” and “critical réévaluation . . . o f the central underlying myths and heroes o f the state" appeared e v e r y w h e r e .19 N onetheless, such a political revolution from this social upheaval would have to ov ercom e the segm entation by status, the republican divisions, and the personalistic, familistic, and informal channels for coping that resulted from the system o f em ploym ent. Any new arran g em ent required new political forms. B u t political response to econom ic difficulty was still institutionalized around the sy stem ’s two forms o f political action: redis tributing people among existing jo b s or b etw een property sectors, and redefining rights to assets and incomes in the direction o f greater auton omy (with the obligation o f balancing accounts and in the hope that there would b e a resulting initiative in increasing those assets). This was what Yugoslavs had learned to do. B u t this system also favored the republics, e n terprises, or individuals that had higher initial capital assets. T hose who organized the political path after 1985 w ere not the unem ployed but the em p loy ed who feared u n em ploym ent. In the society described in this book, this fear was the fear o f property owners that they would lose value and status. T h e ir fight was organized around a language o f rights. T h e first o f the two arenas o f this political fight, against redistribution of 18 The Chetniks were the armed bands formed around Serbian royal army units during W orld W ar II; the Ustashe were the elite paratroopers of the Croat fascist state. Both fought against the Partisans. 19 Rainet, “Apocalypse Culture and Social Change in Yugoslavia,” 3, 15; for a good sam ple of political and cultural manifestations, see 3-26, passim.
362
C H A P T E R 10
labor in response to international conditions, was ce n te re d in the core of the public secto r— the core o f privilege. E v e n nnore than in the 1960s, the e co n o m ic reform in the 1980s was an attack on “nonproductive” ex pe nd itu res, budgetary financing, and administration o f any kind outside the e n te rp ris e s — for defense, local subsidies, social services. Efforts to rationalize and regulate through governmental policy in the 1970s had led the party to assert influence over managerial and professional appoint m ents, to the growing re s e n tm e n t of those whose education did not guar an tee them em p loy m e n t o f the status they expected, as was discusscd above. Su ch efforts also had led to educational reform, which by the 1980s (as in th e 1960s) had moved from elem entary and secondary education to the universities. This reform struck at the heart o f the middle class and its capital— its individual bases in formal education and its ability to pass on this in h erita n ce (its cultural capital) to its c h ild re n .20 T h e major reform of secondary education after the late 1970s was, in effect, an attem pt at so cial revolution from above at a tim e of declining opportunity. T h e abol ished gimnazije had b ee n a preserve of social privilege and exclusive access to university enrollm ent. T h e extension of general education to youth in vocational schools, giving them the equal right to enroll in uni versities and putting all youth on the same track o f universal and voca tional training, b ec a m e a lightning rod for the discontents of urban middle-class parents (although the com petition over enrollm ents in pre ferred specializations still b enefited those with cultural capital and cre ated a new hierarchy of elite and less-privileged schools and students).21 B y the early 1980s, limits w ere placed on university enrollm ents in liberal-arts and medical faculties because such professionals were already in surplus. Professional parents saw these limits as political discrimination against th e hum anistic intelligentsia; similarly, they viewed the expanded opportunities for university education in new regional universities as the party’s atte m p t to dilute standards and their status.22 This urban middle-class d iscontent was also manifest in an increasingly open conflict b etw ee n the civilian and military halves o f public-sector “n on prod u ctiv e” em ploym ent. T h e largest com ponent o f the remaining federal b u d g et after 1 9 5 8 - 6 4 , the federal army and defense industry were obvious ob je cts o f criticism, while the army was also facing the need to 20 T his was a widespread phenom enon, not limited to Yugoslavia. Hirsch identified it for W e ste rn E u ro p e in th e 1970s, in Social Limits to Growth; D a hren do rf returned to it in the 1980s in Life Chances. 21 In Slovenia, however, the bureau of education soon quietly reversed th e reform be cause o f parents’ protest and exp erts’ evaluations, 22 On the oth er hand, students from rural areas who failed th eir course exams (held all at on ce at th e en d o f the year, in Eu ro pean tradition), assumed they w ere victims o f an explicit policy to cut unem ploym ent by returning them to th eir farms (even if they owned no land, as parents complained to me in Vojvodina).
BREAKDOWN
363
rationalize resources without endangering d efense preparedness. Army leaders sought several reforms in th e ir concern about the declining q ual ity and availability o f military re c ru its ,23 about the difficulty of attracting Slovenes and C roats to th e officer corps b ecau se pay was higher in civilian jo b s in th e ir econom ies, and about the econom ic costs o f conscription. In the early 1980s, young m e n w ere requ ired to c o m p le te their military s e r vice b efo re attend in g university. By 1985, th ere was a shift to th e idea o f a professional arm y (as in many o th er countries at the time). W ithin the army, th e re was a growing threat o f rebellion among the middle ranks of officers, whose salaries and benefits w ere declining; a majority o f them w ere o f S e r b nationality, and they began to resent the limits on their prospects o f prom otion and higher salaries set by th e rules on national quotas and proportions for senior officers. O utside the army, a primary focus o f youth political activity in Slovenia (and to a certain e x te n t Croatia) was a campaign against th e army and conscription— to cu t the defense b u d g et on pacifist grounds,to gain th e right to conscientious objection, and to realize rights to use o n e ’s own language in the army and b e posted at hom e. T h e second arena o f political response to the threat o f e con om ic d e cline, th e struggle for autonom y over capital, was dominated by the r e publics in response to th e institutional reforms conc erning money and cred it and th e constitutional reform that followed. This struggle was led by Slovenia, which had the most to lose and the greatest organizational and e co n o m ic resources for the fight. T h e language used by its party lead ership, as well as by e n te rp rises resisting taxation o f m arket profits and by most republican assem blies, was one o f rights and restoration o f what they consid ered rights to fight recentralization and redistribution. F e d e ra l tax ation was seen as gov ernm ental in terferen ce with the constitutional rights o f e n te rp ris es and republics to “self-m anagem en t” and “sovereignty”— an in te rfe re n ce , it was insisted, with the “fre e d om ” o f e n terprises and of “w o rk e rs .” T h e Slovene g o v ernm ent even re je cte d the d efense m in ister’s proposal to resolve their mutual financial conflict with autonomy by e x tend ing self-m anag em en t to defense, creating a separate, autonomously m anaged d efense bud get with a legislated portion o f the incom e tax .24 23 The concern over foreign emigration and loss of a large cohort of youth was particularly manifest in the defense establishment for this reason, although the support of Croat guest workers in Germ any for Croat nationalism in the 1960s and the ability of rebels from the Croat comm unity in Australia to p enetrate into Bosnia and attem pt to spur an armed upris ing in 1972 also influenced the military’s perception of national security. Emigrés played a similar role in 1990-91 funding the election of a nationalist to the Croatian presidency in 1990 and providing arms, mercenaries, and financing for the war that began in 1991. 24 T he compromise established in 1985 was to divide the federal budget into three parts: one for the army, one for export incentives and material reserves, and one for all other beneficiaries. In Novem ber 1986, however, the government agreed to finance the federal budget from federal revenues alone, breaking all remaining links to the republican budgets.
.364
C H A P T E R 10
Thu s, this political fight, contrary to the claims that it was a dem ocratic revolution against the Com m u nist system and the result of the party’s loss o f ideological legitimacy, was in fact led by Communists to justify the claim s o f property owners on econ om ic resources in terms clearly reflect ing the ideological hegem ony achieved by the parties in the more indus trialized northwest in the 1930s. T h e language of the conflict reveals how firmly the ideology underlying the party’s original strategy (as was argued in ch a p ter 9) had b e e n implanted. Using the language o f productivity, it was claim ed that monies transferred through the federal fund w ere e m ployed less productively in the southern republics than they w ere in the north or when northern enterprises invested d irectly .25 Such transfers should b e assessed in term s o f the “differential contribution o f each re p u blic” to gross dom estic product and the extent to which the “survival” of each rep u blic was aided or endangered (ugrožen). T h e proliferating autonom ous public services and utilities w ere “bloated b ureaucracies,” and military salaries w ere an “unproductive” drain on the econom y. Even the program o f the C o m m u nist party leadership in S erbia during the re new ed process of constitutional reform after 1985— which aimed to re unify S e rb ia by ending the near-republican status of its two provinces and to increase its influence on federal policy, by means of mass dem onstra tions that brought political allies to the party leaderships in its provinces and in M o n te n e g r o — was called by M ilosevic an “antibureaucratie revolu t io n ,” as T ito and Kidrič had called the firings in ministries aimed at stabi lization in 1950. And although this attem pted Jacksonian revolution stayed within the Madisonian rules and used methods similar to those of C roatian nationalists in the 1960s, Slovenia and Croatia declared it to be against th e constitution. T h e final political co n se q u e n ce of un em ploym ent was its effect on the c o u n try ’s ability to continue to manage un em ploym ent itself. T h e consti tutional assignm ent o f labor questions to the republics in 1946 survived all s u b seq u e n t changes in policy and institutional reform. As discussed in chap ter 8, the territorial decentralization of the econom y and vertical lines of the formal political system, property rights, and capital flows had c re a te d and maintained separate labor markets within each republic. I n dividuals em igrated to cities or different republics to improve their pros p ects, b ec a u se those prospects d ep end ed on the budgets that financed particular em ploym ents. T h e politics o f em ploy m ent and unemployment revolved within the republics and localities. As in the lead ers’ strategy for econom ic growth, protecting achieved status requ ired more than autonomy over capital; it was also necessary to 2r> On th e inaccuracy of’ this charge, sec Con nock, “A Note on Industrial Efficiency in Yugoslav Regions ”
BR E A K D O W N
365
adjust tlie supply of labor to declining dem and with reorganization and downsizing o f the public sector and with expulsion o f the less productive back to the land, to the family, or into emigration, even if only te m porarily. T h e “realism ’’ (to use Claus O lie ’s term) o f the last federal resolution on em p loy m ent, in 1 98 3 — which, as part of the long-term sta bilization program, deferred until the twenty-first century any a ttem p t to employ those now un em plo y ed — was up to the republics and localities to im plem ent, for labor fell within their ju risdiction. T h e political methods these authorities chose for im plem enting a “realistic” approach dealt the final blow in the process o f system ic breakdow n— an exclnsivist national ism that destroyed the country. In the early 1980s, even before the Slovene campaign to reduce the YPA to “national a r m ie s ,” Slovenia’s g overnm ent sought to send hom e Bosnian and eth n ic Albanian workers and to restrict entry by new mi grants. T h e planning bureau argued, on the basis of research studies, that their n u m b e r had reached the maximum o f social tolerance for nonS lovenes and that the econom ic costs o f additional infrastructure and social benefits for any new com ers would lower standards of living in S lo venia.2*’ B u t S lovene authorities ju stified this decision on the grounds that their “national distinctiveness’’ and cultural identity were “th r e a te n e d .”27 In S erbia, the political rebellion in the province of Kosovo that began again in 1981 expelled many S erbs and M o ntenegrins, who left b ecause o f fear or pressure. C o m b in e d with the growing immigration o f Serbs from o th er republics (particularly from smaller towns with declining in dustry in Bosnia-Herzegovina), who sought econom ic opportunities in B elg rad e or claim ed refuge from jo b discrimination as Serbs, these waves of migration threa te n e d to bring lower living standards and even higher un em p lo y m en t in S erbia proper. It was not long before such immigration b ec a m e a focus of the discontents o f middle-class professionals and intel lectuals who attributed S e rb ia ’s declining econom y and status to the (con)federal T itoist system, which had, in their view, followed a policy of “divide and c o n q u e r” against the Serbian people since the A V N O J princi ples for a federal constitution declared in 1 9 4 3 .28 T h e com plex struggle over the autonom y o f the provinces and over Albanian rights in Kosovo 2 Non-Slovene labor made up about 25 percent ol the republic’s laboi force at the lime This m easure o f “social tolerance’’ was also popular at the time in France, where it was said that the proportion ol North African immigrants in a town should not exceed 20 percent 2/ Author s conversations with oliicials and social scientists in Ljubljana Such language also pervaded the journals, press, and politicians' sp eeches by 1 9 8 6 - 8 7 ; lor a typical exam ple, see Foreign Bromlcu-'it Information Service, Eastern Europe, for April 17, 1987, 14. 2M A c om m ittee ol th e Serbian Academy of Sciences and Arts wrote a Serbian “national program ” in 1986, though it was not published until 1993 (except for excerpts from a draft, on which much speculation about a political program was based; see “Memorandum SA N U ”). Slovene opposition intellectuals issued theirs in 1987.
366
C H A P T E R 10
could not b e separated from the tend ency to reconstruct republican inter ests as “national i n te r e s t,” any more than this tend ency could b e avoided in Slovenia. T h e Albanians’ dem and for a separate republic was a demand for their “national rights to self-determ ination,” and in S erbia proper th e re w e re rising calls to defend the “hon or” and restore the “longaggrieved rights” o f the S e rb nation. In Croatia, the assem bly openly jo in e d Slovenia in the fight against the federal g o v ernm ent and the army, casting it as a struggle for Croatian national rights. T h e arm y ’s pressures for the reintegration of basic infra structure and for a restre n g th e n e d Com m u nist party, and the proposals from th e federal gov ernm ent and the I M F to strengthen macroeconomic administration, w e re identified with what were called the historical “cen tralism ” and “unitarism ” o f Serbs. S erbs in Croatia w ere said to have been privileged in governm ental em p loy m ent in the police, army, and local administration, so that cuts in g overnm ent bureaucracies and a shift of resources away from the ethnically mixed interior to central Croatia and D alm atia began to b e justified with an anti-Serb campaign in the same way that the purge o f party leaders had b een in 1 9 4 9 - 5 0 . E v e n in B o s nia-flerzeg o vin a, dem ographic shifts in the ethnic compo sition o f local com m unities as individuals left economically declining vil lages and towns for work abroad (a pattern m ore characteristic of Bosnian Croats) or for schooling and possibly work in o ther republics (more char a cteristic o f Bosnian S erbs, who tended to go to Serbia) had also changed the e th n ic composition o f those who held local political and administrative positions, resulting in growing eth n ic tensions. And ju st as in the 1960s, the h ig her birth rate o f Muslims in Kosovo, Macedonia, and BosniaIle rz e g o v in a provided an excuse for the prejudice and scapegoating that arose from re sen tm e n ts over jo b com petition and declining status and incom e. T h e regulation o f statuses for the productive use o f labor and the poli tics o f exclusion from the public sector to protect the rights of those who rem a in ed th ere culm inated with the alteration of citizenship itself in 1989. O bliged to bring their republican constitutions into harmony with the intended 1988 eeonom ic-reform am end m ents to the federal constitu tion, republican assem blies in Slovenia, Croatia, and Macedonia re defined their republics as states o f their majority nation. T h e rights of national self-determ ination and equality that adhered to individuals’ m e m b e r sh ip in any constituent nation within the country, regardless of re sid e n c e, and the re q u irem en t for national quotas in governmental posi tions w e re de facto abolished. To confirm this final step toward full “na tional sovereignty” o f the republics, Slovenia and Croatia held democratic elections in April 1990, and those who campaigned on nationalist plat forms gained pluralities. Particularly blatant about this goal was the na
BREAKDOWN
367
tionalist campaign o f F ra n jo Tu djm an, a retired general o f the federal army and fo rm e r C o m m u nist, who won th e Croatian presidency by c o m bining an anticom m unist platform with a n ti-S erb rhetoric. E q u a tin g “decom m unization” with “d e-S erb ianization” o f gov ernm ent em ploy m ent, he rallied political support behind the b an n er o f jo b dismissal, to purge e v ery one associated with the C o m m u nist re g im e — including not only party m e m b ers but any S e rb s as well. T h e nationalist exclusion o f people relegated by the constitutions to minority political status b e ca m e the goal o f rewritten citizenship rights in all the republics, in som e m ore openly than in others. Instead o f the liberal political goal o f transforming the d elegate sy stem — replacing the system o f representation o f producers with a state o f “equal citizens and w orkers” and the principle o f one person, one vote, which many proposed in 1 9 8 7 —8 9 — “national p re fe re n c e ” in jo b s and housing won out. As each rep u blic’s e c o n o m ic capacity to guarantee subsistence to all its citizens d eclined , the group receiving full citizenship rights dim inished further.
C o n c l u s io n
As with the capitalist system it aimed to replace, the underlying con tra dictions o f th e Yugoslav reform -com m unist system and its main lines o f sociopolitical conflict cannot b e understood apart from un em plo y m en t and the particular manifestation o f its threat. This book does not argue that socialist un em p lo y m en t played the same e con om ic or political role as does capitalist un em ploy m en t. B u t its causes and characteristics do reveal the prim ary m echanism s and dynamic by which socialist Yugoslavia fu nctioned — and declined. T h e politics o f socialist systems, and o f their postcom m u nist transition, mirrored their e con om ic system. U n d e r social ow nership o f productive capital, individuals’ em p loy m e n t defined their personal identities, e co n o m ic interests, and social statuses; social and po litical conflict, com petition, and collective action w ere organized a ccord ing to th e criteria for individuals’ access to em ploy m ent and the criteria for financing those jo bs. T h e social and political system that Kardelj constructed (and repeatedly reconstructed ) according to a particular ideology o f econ om ic growth and its approach to the use o f human labor— called in this book the S lovene m o d e l— p re su m ed full em ploy m ent. It could not function as intended un der u n em plo ym en t. As real and threatened u n em p lo y m en t increased during the 1960s and especially after the mid-1970s, the key e le m e n ts o f the system began to cru m b le from within. T h e vertical lines o f authority— th e L C Y , federal rules and regulations, and the banking sy stem — w e re ineffective in enforcing policy decisions; in the p re s en ce o f u n em p lo y m en t or its threat, loyalty to an em ploy er or potential
368
C H A P T E R 10
e m p lo y e r— workplace, locality, or repu blic— took p reced en ce. When th e re was a threat o f un em ploym ent, with its immediate loss of status and all that that entailed, a state based on the cooperation and discipline of mutual in te rest among political representatives of autonomous producers and property owners (in econom y and governm ent) was not conducive to— indeed, was likely to b e in conflict with— the “financial discipline” of “e co n o m ic in te rest" o f the system of self-managed budgets. T h e legit imacy of the L C Y as the representative o f the com m on interest suffered irreparably from its transformation into a craft union for managers, as well as from com petition b etw ee n political and educational routes for manage rial and professional (“middle-class ”) em ploym ents in the public sector. And th e delicate constitutional balance o f the federal system and the rights of national equality could not survive the effect that financial re forms and the sustained fiscal crisis surrounding d ebt repaym ent had on the capacity of republican governm ents to employ and to negotiate wages. B y the early 1980s, the official solution to un em ploym ent itself was reaching its lim it— the institutions o f family, farm, schooling, and foreign migration could not absorb the level of un em ploym ent generated, and the society to which this approach was adapted had b ee n irrevocably changed by the program o f e con om ic growth. Yugoslavia was no longer an agrar ian, industrializing country. People could still talk about “going back to the fa rm ,” but this psychological reassurance (if it was applied to oneself) or com placency (if it was applied to others) had little basis in reality. Kard e lj’s model o f stable socialist com m unities com bining the productive in centives and distributive solidarity of industrial wage earners and small property ow ners (the alliance of workers, peasants, and free professionals) applied to an ever-dim inishing n u m b e r of people, and the social protec tions o f that model (u nem ploym ent was still defined as a social question, not an e co n o m ic one) no longer served a society characterized by rapid urbanization and internal econom ic migration. T h e re w ere instead a growing urban underclass of unskilled workers and rural migrants; an ever-larger stratum o f managerial and professionally trained people seek ing public-sector, nonindustrial em ploym ent; and deindustrialization in p o orer regions. Although no political organization of the unemployed oc cu rred, nor was th ere any such organization around the problem of unem ploym ent, th e result was an escalating social upheaval of revolutionary proportions by the late 1980s. D e clin in g prospects, lower relative incomes, and increased competi tion for em p loy m ent com m ensu rate with educational achievem ent and status expectations all led to open and growing re sen tm e n t within the established managerial, professional, and urban white-color stratum against the system ’s policies o f redistribution. Manifest in many groups, across social layers and regions, this unorganized discontent at public,
BREAKDOWN
369
in ten d ed ( namenjeni ) redistribution was focused on several fronts: th e e d ucational reform , which appeared to th reaten privileged social position; the privileges o f party m e m b ersh ip , the L C Y ’s presu m ed control over high-status jo b s , and its network o f informal conn ections and aid; the taxes and contributions from earnings that w ent to local solidarity funds for guaranteed wages and to the federal bud get for the army and for cred its and subsidies to poorer localities and less-developed republics; and th e national quotas for g o v ernm ent em ploym ent. D em og ra p h ic shifts, particularly th e rising b irthrate o f M uslims in Kosovo and BosniaH erzegovina, evoked fears and p reju d ice from many sides. In place o f K a rd e lj’s settled com m unities with their sense o f proprietorship, latent conflicts rekindled into op en tension b etw ee n longtime residents and m igrants— r e c e n t migrants in urban areas and earlier migrants in towns and villages. And in the private sector o f rural, unskilled, and u n e m ployed persons, th e re was re s en tm e n t at their second-class status and sen se o f inferiority— a re s e n tm e n t waiting to b e exploited. D e s p ite the exhaustion o f the approach to u n em p lo y m en t and this growing social d iscontent, th ere was not yet pressure for the system to adapt politically. T h o se with the greatest e con om ic and organizational r e sources could still b en efit from dem ands for change along the lines d e fined by th e existing e con om ic system and its ideology, further autonomy over incom e, justified as the right o f those who earn (and who have a d irect in te res t in financial accountability) to d ecide on the allocation of incom e; and fu rther rationalization o f “nonproductive” labor by cutting gov ernm ental expend itures (personnel) and expelling less-productive workers into the private sector. O thers continued to pursue individual and familial strategies for gaining em ploy m ent, with its status and b e n e fits. No political cou nterforce was b eing g enerated to dem and changes th at m ight b ring action on u n em ploym ent. Instead, th e stabilization p ro gram to repay d e b t took the final step o f abolishing the entire system of protections against u n em p lo y m en t— the rules against mass layoffs and dismissal for reasons o f econ om ic rationalization; the limits on the free sale o f land and hiring o f labor that w ere intended to provide guaranteed smallholdings for farmers and artisans; and the guaranteed minimum wage. And despite th e e co n o m ic failure with regard to full e m p lo y m e n t and g uaranteed subsistence, the political system o f K ard e lj’s Slovene model had survived intact: dem ands for change and reform aimed to strengthen th e hierarchical organization o f political and econom ic power, th e vertical lines o f com m unication and conflict b etw ee n federal and republican polit ical authorities, and the states’ rights and property rights o f territorially organized g ov ernm ents and firms and their contractual relations. This p erp e tu a ted the dom inance o f relations b etw ee n international creditors
370
C H A P T E R 10
and th e federal gov ernm en t, b etw ee n federal and republican govern m ents, and b e tw e e n republican and local authorities, as against the hori zontal, cross-republican, and nonofficial associations and lines of com m unication that are m ore com m on to a m arket econom y (and socalled civil society). C o m p etitio n rem ained focused on rights to income and e co n o m ic assets. Although th e prevailing e con om ic ideology was an tagonistic to the state, periodic rounds o f liberalization led not to a m ark et-based political system but to e ver-g reater decentralization, re gionalism, and disintegration. T h e logical conclusion o f this process was the dissolution o f the country itself.
E P IL O G U E
I n 1 9 8 9 - 9 0 , th e cold war ended. T h e conditions supporting socialist Yugoslavia’s Faustian bargain w ent with it. It was historically appropriate that the bargain, contracted in the events surrounding G e rm a n y ’s divi sion in 1 9 4 8 - 4 9 and Stalin’s retreat from the reform option, should lose its raison d ’ê tre at the tim e o f G e rm a n y ’s reunification and G o rb a ch e v ’s
reforms. W ithin Yugoslavia, the d eb ate on econom ic and political reform b e tw een 1 98 2 and 1990 had, ominously, retu rned to the original bases o f political unity in the Partisans’ wartim e alliance— the struggles for na tional in d e p e n d en c e and against foreign econ om ic exploitation. “Nations” w ere “th r e a te n e d ” with cultural extinction and linguistic contamin ation; and they w ere “suffering” from the econom ic “exploitation” o f others. But this time, the nation was a republic or constituent people. T h e Slovenes suggested replacing the slogan “brotherhood and unity” with “to g eth e r ness” and “asym m etric fed era tio n .” T h e rhetoric of mutual accusations prepared people m entally for civil war, instead of a war o f resistance against the outside. Nationalism— this time o f independ en t states— turned inward, as if in an attem pt to destroy all that had b e e n a cc o m plished in forty-five years. A war did indeed follow, o f vicious proportions. Contrary to the c o m m entary by foreign journalists and politicians, which guided external pol icy and public opinion on the wars in the form er Yugoslavia, the historical m em ory o f antagonisms am ong its separate nations was at b est a tertiary factor— and it dated only to W orld W a r II. Although the argum ent in this book did not foresee a violent outcom e of the path it analyzed— everg reater disintegration for reasons o f econom ic ideology and international a d ju stm e n t— it does portray the real nature o f the conflict. E v e n in the cou n try ’s dissolution, the Slovene and F o ca models defined the p a ra m e ters. O n the one hand was the internationally negotiated retreat o f the federal army from Slovenia and the recognition o f its secession from the federation (taking “d ecentralizatio n,” autonomy over capital, and sover eignty over e con om ic assets to their logical conclusion). O n the other hand was a bloody civil war, unleashed by politicians and persons e m ployed by pu blic budgets and feeding off the d isconnected b u t mounting re sen tm e n ts (d escribed in chapter 10) that raged among secessionists, sections o f th e army, groups claiming national pre fe re n ce , and old and new settlers in the farm ing villages o f Croatia w here Partisans from “pas sive regions” had b e e n resettled after W orld W a r II, as well as in the
372
EPILOGUE
poor, deindustrializing interior o f Croatia and Bosnia-Herzegovina (which had b ee n d ep en d e n t on the production o f primary commodities, infra structure, and d efense industries). In place of the uneasy symbiosis o f the Slovene and Foča models that had lasted nearly half a century, international conditions finally forced a choice. T h e re q u irem en ts o f econom ic reorientation westward to repay foreign d e b t and then the loss o f Yugoslavia’s strategic role betw een the superpowers to g ether forced a process of homogenization. But except in Slovenia, the internal political econom ies o f the federal units were not hom ogeneous. M oreover, until a new European (or international) defense and e c o n o m ic order evolved to define the cou ntry ’s new options and pro vide th e basis for a lasting, stable ou tcom e in the region, domestic politi cians, regardless o f political camp, w ere continuin g to take the initiative along the lines o f strategic behavior in the socialist period: demanding political autonom y over e con om ic assets and redistributing persons a m ong jo b s and sectors. W ith the socialist constitutional and welfare systems removed from the reform -co m m u nist system , however, the national layer o f the wartime alliance was free to op erate unfettered. Political action cen tered on the dem and for national control over territory and the physical expulsion or reduction in status o f persons o f o th er nationalities. In the wars over land and local com m unity that resulted, it was predictable, according to the analysis in this book, that the latent conflict o f the underlying division of socialist Yugoslavia— b etw ee n the public and private sectors of e m p lo y m e n t— would explode into class war. It is com m only said that the end o f the cold war in eastern and central E u ro p e , including the disintegration o f Yugoslavia, was the result of an ideological crisis o f disillusionment. In fact, the econom ic ideology of re form com m unism was triumphant. In the midst o f war and mutual accusa tions o f g enocide, aggression, and destruction o f a country, governments in Slovenia, Croatia, the federal republic o f Yugoslavia (consisting of Ser bia and M ontenegro), and M acedonia w ere all im p lem enting an identical m a cro eco n om ic program — a business-oriented, orthodox stabilization policy to cut d om estic dem and (incomes, jo b s , and public expenditures). T h e ir primary problem s rem ained foreign d ebt and effective foreigntrade and exchange-rate policy. T h e leaders elected in 1990 were still in pow er in every state in 1994. T h e same could be said o f postcommunist econom ic policy throughout E a s te r n E u ro p e . D esp ite the introduction o f com petitive elections, the alternation in power betw een renam ed com munists and liberals, with th e ir respectiv e approaches to econom ic growth and to labor, was remark ably rem iniscent o f the alternations in Yugoslavia in response to changing international conditions chronicled in this book. T h e breakup of Czeeho-
EPILOGUE
373
Slovakia and th e Sov iet U nion follow ed paths nearly identical to the Yugoslav one o f the constitutional conflict, dem ands for national sover eignty o v er e c o n o m ic assets, and conflict over m acroeconom ic policy that accom pany socialist econom ic reform. M o re o v e r, th e successful exit o f Slovenia (in contrast to the rest o f the country) and its pluralistic politics made possible by full em p loy m e n t and a favorable trading position was not a com p lete victory for the Slovene model. T h e conditions that made th e F o č a model a constant factor in Yugoslavia began to confront Slovenia as an independ en t state. W h e re a s un em p lo y m en t had b e e n below 2 p e rce n t in 1988, it increased fivefold b e tw e e n 1989 and 1991 and stood at 14 p e rc e n t by m id -1 9 9 3 .1 This r e flected th e loss o f much o f Slovenia’s form er internal (Yugoslav) m arket for goods, an uncertain international position econom ically, and substantial gov ernm ental d efense expend itures to build a new army and appeal polit ically to local nationalists. In response to the influx o f fifty thousand dis placed persons and refugees from B osnia-H erzegovina2 (though this was a small n u m b e r com pared to the m ore than half a million refugees in both Croatia and Serbia), th e re was a rise in antiforeigner activities; and a farright, x enophobic, nationalist party won 10 pe rce n t o f the vote in the elections o f N o v e m b e r 1992, which also saw a loss by the anticom m unist coalition to th e fo rm er C o m m u n ists.3 In S e p te m b e r 1992, the Slovene g ov ern m e n t closed its borders to further refugees. T o an even g reater e x te n t in Croatia and Serbia, the co n s e q u e n ces o f insistence on “states’ (national) rights” inclu ded the e co n o m ic drain o f substantial d efense budgets and the growing power domestically o f the police and army. In Croatia, un em ploym en t was b eing kept at bay by the fact that m obilized soldiers w ere not seeking work. B u t it was only a m a t te r o f tim e b efo re dem obilization would confront the g o v ern m ent with the ch oice b e tw e e n dealing with a serious social crisis and formulating a real policy toward un em ploy m en t. T h e war pro tected the g o v ern m e n t’s co n v e n ie n t segregation b e tw e e n the ministries o f e con om ic technocrats negotiating with international creditors and the ministries and lobbies o f the d efen se establishm ent. B u t eventually th ere would b e e ith e r confron tation or accom m odation b e tw e e n these local versions o f the S lovene and 1 Milan Andrejevich, RFE/RL Daily Report, no 166, August 31, 1993, citing a study by the respected Economics Institute in Ljubljana (renamed the Bajt Institute after its founder, Aleksandar Bajt). 2 Zerdin, "Tokens of Slovene Sovereignty," 4, citing data from UN High Commissioner for Refugees’ Office of the Special Envoy for former Yugoslavia, External Relations Unit, Zagreb. 3 The recipient of this 10 percent (well above the 5 percent minimum for parliamentary representation), Zmago Jelinčič, included in his campaign speeches the accusation that Bos nian refugees were fleeing economic deprivation rather than war (Financial Times, D ecem ber 8, 1992, 2).
374
EPILOGUE
Foča models. Yet, in contrast to other areas o f the former Yugoslavia, Slovenia and Croatia were being offered relatively favorable international conditions. In the m eantim e, as war continued in Bosnia-Herzegovina, threatened to resum e in Croatia, and had not yet been avoided in Macedonia and Serbia, the autonomist impulse was still alive. As nationalist governments centralized power and economic control in the new capitals, they were countered by regionalist movements. In n eith er econom ic ideology nor political response had there been much change as a result of the end o f socialist Yugoslavia. Despite the terrible tragedy o f war in the name o f nations, there was only a holding action until a different approach to labor and employment could b e found.
Appendix STATISTICAL DATA
r a w d a t a used to create the figures in this book are presented here. E ach table o f data corresponds to the figure(s) o f the same num ber (for example, table 6-1 corresponds to figure 6-1). All the data were gathered by the Fed eral Bureau o f Statistics, which was created by Ante Novak at the request o f Boris Kidrič in June 1948 and which maintained a consis tently high standard o f professional expertise. Unemployment series were hampered, however, by changes in m easurement and definition, and the analysis o f rates of change is hindered by the absence of household sur veys on unemployment and by the fact that data on the population and on the actively employed are available only for census years. Statisticalyearbook data and the data o f the O E C D and the IL O (International L a bor Organization) are not consistent, but the differences are not substan tial enough to affect interpretation; I chose to stay with the longer series and more com prehensive data of the Federal Bureau of Statistics. In some cases, I have taken advantage of the hard work o f gathering and analyzing the bureau’s raw data that was done so carefully by economists Jože M en cinger, Miloš Macura, and Em il Primorac; and I am grateful for their generous assistance at several stages in this work. Dan Turner did the tedious work o f putting my many piles o f confusing data into computer files and performed what remain to me miracles in transforming them into graphs and tables.
The
A p p e n d i x T a b l e 6-1 a n d 9-3 Employment and Unemployment, 1962-1975
Social Sector, Economic A ctivity
1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975
(1)
Social Sector, Noneconomic A ctivity (2)
Subtotal A (1 + 2 )
Private Sector, Home and A broad (3)
Subtotal B (1 + 2 + 3 )
Registered U nemployed (4)
Subtotal C (1 + 2 + 3 + 4 )
Independent Farmers (5)
Subtotal D (1 + 2 + 3 + 4 + 5 )
2775 2862 3064 3070 2942 2908 2898 3043 3140 3299 3424 3497 3658 3854
549 549 571 595 588 588 599 626 650 683 713 742 779 818
3324 3411 3635 3665 3530 3496 3497 3669 3790 3982 4137 4239 4437 4672
114 144 161 186 252 256 269 463 737 872 882 958 935 890
3438 3555 3796 3851 3782 3752 3766 4132 4527 4854 5019 5197 5372 5562
202 187 172 206 230 238 280 295 294 264 289 354 418 502
3640 3742 3968 4057 4012 3990 4046 4427 4821 5118 5308 5551 5790 6064
4292 4265 4160 4173 4164 4122 4111 4060 3950 3842 3741 3663
7932 8007 8128 8230 8176 8112 8157 8487 8771 8960 9049 9214
Source: M en cin g er, "U tje c a j privred ne aktivnosti na zaposlen ost.”
377
S T A T IS T I C A L DATA
A p p e n d i x T a b l e 6 -2
A p p e n d i x T a b l e 6 -3
Unemployment, 1952-1988
Unemployment Rate, 1959-1988
U nem ployed (in thousands)
1.952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988
44.7 81.6 76.2 67.2 99.3 115.9 132.0 161.0 159.0 191.0 236.0 240.0 212.0 236.0 257.0 269.0 310.0 330.0 319.0 291.0 315.0 381.0 448.0 540.0 635.0 700.0 734.0 762.0 785.0 808.0 862.0 910.0 974.0 1039.0 1086.0 1080.0 1128.0
Source: F o r 1 9 5 2 - 5 8 : Macura, “E m ploym ent P roblem s under Declining Pop ulation
Growth
Rates
and
Change, 4 96 ; for 1 9 5 9 - 8 8 :
Structural M encinger,
“Privredna reform a i nezaposlenost,” 36.
Percentage U nem ployed
1959 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988
5.8 5.5 6.0 7.3 7.2 6.0 6.6 7.4 7.8 8.9 9.1 8.5 7.4 7.7 9.1 10.1 11.6 13.1 13.9 13.9 13.9 13.8 13.8 14.4 14.9 15.7 16.3 16.6 16.1 16.8
Source: M encinger, “Privredna reform a i nezaposlenost,” 37.
378
APPENDIX A p p e n d i x T a b l e 6 -4
Unemployment: Cross and Net Rates (percentages) 1964
1965
1966
1967
1968
1969
1970
1971
1972
Net unemployment Percentage change
5.6
6.3 12.5
6.4 1.6
7.0 9.4
8.0 14.3
7.8 - 2 .5
7.7 - 1 .3
6.7 -1 3 .0
7.3 9.0
Gross unemployment Percentage change
6.7
7.9 17.9
8.4 6.3
9.6 14.3
12.1 26.0
18.4 52.1
18.3 - 0 .5
19.3 5.5
19.3 0.0
Source: Babić and Primorac, “Analiza koristi i troškova privremenog zapošljavanja u inozemstvu,” tu lile 2 Note: The net rates include only the domestically employed; gross rates include those registered n working abroad as well.
A p p e n d ix T a b l e 6 -5
J o b S e e k e r s a n d M i g r a n t W o r k e r s ( th o u s a n d s )
Registered job seekers Percentage change
1952
1953
1954
1955
1956
1957
1958
1959
1960
1961
1962
1963
1964
1965
71.4
68.0
69.2
81.7
126.3
123.7
174.2
164.8
185.4
232.6
274.0
229.0
228.0
266.9
- 4 .8
1.8
18.1
54.6
- 2 .1
40.8
- 5 .4
12.5
25.5
17.8
- 1 6 .4
- 0 .4
17.1
18.0
28.0
42.0
80.0
105.0
130.0
203.4
260.6
316.0
309.0
333.0
396.9
Migrant workers Job seekers plus migrant workers 1966
1967
1968
1969
1970
1971
1972
1973
1974
1975
1976
1977
Registered job seekers Percentage change
265.3
291.5
326.8
315.6
289.7
289.5
333.5
398.7
478.5
583.8
665.2
716.7
- 0 .6
9.9
12.1
- 3 .4
- 8 .2
- 0 .1
15.2
19.6
20.0
22.0
13.9
7.7
Migrant workers
190.0
220.0
260.0
430.0
600.0
680.0
770.0
860.0
810.0
770.0
725.0
705.0
Job seekers plus migrant workers
455.3
511.5
586.8
745.6
889.7
969.5
1103.5
1258.7
1288.5
1353.8
1390.2
1421.7
1978
1979
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
Registered job seekers Percentage change
737.9
775.0
789.2
833.2
887.8
916.3
1012.9
1063.9
1084.5
1087.1
1173.0
1244.9
3.0
5.0
1.8
5.6
6.6
3.2
10.5
5.0
1.9
0.2
7.9
6.1
Migrant workers Job seekers plus migrant workers
695.0 1432.9
690.0 1465.0
693.0 1482.2
675.0 1508.2
675.0 1562.8
650.0 1566.3
625.0 1637.9
Source: For job seekers: Statistički Godišnjak Jugoslavije, various years; for migrant workers, 1960-64: Zimmerman, Open Borders, Nonalignment, and the Political Evolution o f Yugoslavia, table 4.4; for migrant workers, 1965-84: Primorac and Babić, “Systemic Changes and Unemployment Growth in Yugoslavia, 1965-1985,” table 3.
A p p e n d i x T a b l e 6-6 a n d 6-7 Unemployment by Length of Time Waiting on the Employment Service Register (thousands)
1957 1958 1959 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970
T otal
Less T han 6 M onths
Less Than 6 M onths (% Total)
6 -9 M onths
6 -9 M on ths (% Total)
9 -1 2 M onths
9 -1 2 M onths (% Total)
1 -3 Years
1 -3 Years (% Total)
123.7 173.7 164.5 184.9 232.6 274.0 229.0 228.0 266.9 265.3 291.5 326.8 315.6 289.7
92.9 134.2 119.2 133.5 157.0 173.9 150.8 148.1 159.8 151.2 163.6 181.2 166.2 145.8
75.1 77.3 72.5 72.2 67.5 63.5 65.9 65.0 59.9 57.0 56.1 55.4 52.7 50.3
9.5 13.9 14.6 17.8 23.6 29.4 22.5 23.4 30.7 29.9 33.4 40.7 38.2 35.6
7.7 8.0 8.9 9.6 10.1 10.7 9.8 10.3 11.5 11.3 11.5 12.5 12.1 12.3
7.9 11.8 13.6 15.2 25.4 29.4 22.6 23.6 32.3 29.3 34.8 39.1 38.2 38.8
6.4 6.8 8.3 8.2 10.9 10.7 9.9 10.4 12.1 11.0 11.9 12.0 12.1 13.4
11.2 11.2 13.8 14.7 20.3 34.8 25.9 25.1 32.7 41.9 44.5 48.3 50.5 46.7
9.1 6.4 8.4 8.0 8.7 12.7 11.3 11.0 12.3 15.8 15.3 14.8 16.0 16.1
L onger T han 3 Years
2.2 2.6 3.3 3.7 6.3 6.5 7.2 7.8 11.4 13.0 15.2 17.5 22.5 22.8
1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989
289.5 333.5 398.7 478.5 583.8 665.2 716.7 737.9 775.0 789.2 833.2 887.8 916.3 1012.9 1063.9 1084.5 1087.1 1173.0 1244.9
153.6 167.9 198.3 224.9 255.3 258.3 257.8 259.0 272.8 267.5 293.1 305.5 292.4 303.4 301.0 290.3 279.4 273.0 235.8
53.1 50.3 49.7 47.0 43.7 38.8 36.0 35.1 35.2 33.9 35.2 34.4 31.9 30.0 28.3 26.8 25.7 23.3 18.9
32.8 40.0 46.6 57.6 68.5 75.4 75.2 68.6 68.4 64.0 66.4 74.7 77.7 84.0 86.6 82.9 83.8 85.3 96.5
Source: Statistički Godišnjak Jugoslavije, various years.
11.3 12.0 11.7 12.0 11.7 11.3 10.5 9.3 8.8 8.1 8.0 8.4 8.5 8.3 8.1 7.6 7.7 7.3 7.8
34.3 42.1 48.1 56.8 67.7 78.9 74.9 72.8 69.4 69.4 65.2 72.8 75.3 83.4 88.1 86.2 82.7 87.6 82.4
11.8 12.6 12.1 11.9 11.6 11.9 10.5 9.9 9.0 8.8 7.8 8.2 8.2 8.2 8.3 7.9 7.6 7.5 6.6
45.5 57.0 77.3 103.5 143.2 183.7 216.0 210.0 234.5 251.7 264.0 270.3 291.7 331.7 337.0 349.1 349.5 381.2 417.4
15.7 17.1 19.4 21.6 24.5 27.6 30.1 28.5 30.3 31.9 31.7 30.4 31.8 32.7 31.7 32.2 32.1 32.5 33.5
23.3 26.5 28.4 35.7 49.1 68.9 92.9 127.5 129.9 136.6 144.5 164.5 179.2 210.5 251.2 276.0 291.7 345.9 412.8
8.0 7.9 7.1 7.5 8.4 10.4 13.0 17.3 16.8 17.3 17.3 18.5 19.6 20.8 23.6 25.4 26.8 29.5 33.2
382
A P P E N D IX A p p e n d i x T a b l e 6 -8
Unemployment— Women
1957 1958 1959 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989
R egistered Job Seekers (thousands)
Percentage Change
62.1 84.2 86.5 97.9 108.9 124.2 123.9 126.0 125.2 121.2 127.7 142.1 143.0 141.9 144.8 166.6 203.8 248.1 299.0 337.0 370.8 396.4 425.2 445.0 478.0 512.0 520.0 568.0 596.0 611.0 606.0 641.0 675.0
35.6 2.7 13.2 11.2 14.0 - 0 .2 1.7 - 0 .6 - 3 .2 5.4 11.3 0.6 - 0 .8 2.0 15.1 22.3 21.7 20.5 12.7 10.0 6.9 7.3 4.7 7.4 7.1 1.6 9.2 4.9 2.5 - 0 .8 5.8 5.3
Source: Statistički Godišnjak Jugoslavije, vari ous years.
A p p e n d i x T a b l e 6-9, 6-10, a n d 9-1 Unemployment Rate by Republic or Province (percentages)
Yugoslavia Less-developed regions Bosnia-Herzegovina Macedonia Montenegro Kosovo Developed regions Slovenia Croatia Serbia Serbia proper Vojvodina
1959
1960
1961
1962
1963
1964
1965
1966
1967
1968
1969
1970
1971
1972
1973
1974
5.8
5.5
6.0
7.3
7.2
6.0
6.6
7.4
7.8
8.9
9.1
8.5
7.4
7.7
9.1
10.1
5.5 10.5 8.5 17.9
4.2 11.5 6.1 15.4
4.5 15.0 5.9 19.3
6.3 15.5 6.3 22.7
5.8 12.0 6.5 31.6
4.8 10.0 5.8 14.6
5.2 15.6 5.7 18.0
5.7 19.3 6.9 26.6
6.5 19.9 8.0 25.4
8.1 22.8 9.2 26.9
8.5 22.5 8.8 28.4
7.4 21.9 8.3 32.3
6.0 21.2 6.5 23.9
6.7 20.8 7.2 22.8
8.5 23.0 11.3 26.6
10.9 25.0 15.0 27.0
2.4 5.1 7.0 7.3 4.2
2.0 5.6 6.1 6.2 4.0
1.7 5.8 6.9 6.9 4.3
2.0 6.7 8.6 8.5 6.1
1.8 6.2 9.8 9.4 6.2
1.4 5.6 7.8 8.4 5.2
1.8 6.1 7.8 8.2 4.9
2.4 6.4 8.4 7.9 5.4
3.1 6.6 8.6 7.9 6.2
3.8 7.2 9.8 8.9 7.6
3.5 6.2 10.9 10.2 8.4
3.1 4.9 10.7 9.9 7.6
2.7 4.3 9.2 8.7 6.7
2.2 4.6 9.6 9.1 7.4
1.8 5.2 11.7 11.1 9.2
1.5 5.1 13.2 12.9 10.0
('c o n tin u ed )
Ap p e n d i x T a b l e
6-9, 6-10,
and
9-1
(C ontinued)
1975
1976
1977
1978
1979
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990*
Yugoslavia
11.6
13.1
13.9
13.9
13.9
13,8
13.8
14.4
14.9
15.7
16.3
16.6
16.1
16.8
14.9
15.9
L ess-developed regions Bosnia-Herzegovina Macedonia M ontenegro Kosovo
12.9 26.8 17.3 30.7
14.8 28.2 17.8 34.1
15.2 26.8 17.3 35.7
15.8 27.2 19.0 36.8
16.5 27.5 19.3 37.8
16.6 27.9 17.5 39.0
16.7 29.0 18.1 39.1
17.9 28.1 19.3 41.0
20.3 26.4 21.6 44.5
23.0 26.7 23.5 49.9
24.4 27.6 24.6 54.2
24.3 27.7 24.6 57.1
23.1 27.3 23.6 57.0
24.1 27.1 26.3 57.8
20.3 21.9 21.6 36.3
20.6 22.9 21.6 38.4
D eveloped regions Slovenia Croatia Serbia Serbia p ro p e r Vojvodina
1.5 6.0 15.1 14.6 12.0
1.8 7.1 17.3 16.5 14.4
1.7 7.1 19.4 19,0 15.8
1.5 6.5 19.6 19.9 13.9
1.3 5.8 19.5 19.5 13.8
1.4 5.7 19.4 18.9 14.4
1.6 6.1 18.7 17.7 14.6
1.7 6.9 19.1 17.9 15.1
2.0 7.4 19.1 17.3 15.6
1.9 7.7 19.5 17.0 15.7
1.8 7.9 20.2 17.4 15.7
1.7 7.9 20.8 17.9 15.6
1.8 7.8 20.3 17.8 13.9
2.5 8.5 20.8 18.1 14.3
3.2 8.0 17.6 15.6 13.6
4.8 8.6 19.1 16.4 16.6
Source: F o r 1959—88: M en cin ger, “Privredna reforma i nezaposlenost,” table 1; for 1 9 8 9 - 9 0 : Statistički Godišnjak Jugoslavije (1990), 16. Note: T h e rate o f unem ploym ent is defined as th e relation betw een the n um b er o f unemployed (registered jo b seekers) and th e total n u m b er o f employed and unem ployed persons. * Estim ate
A p p e n d i x T a b l e 6 -1 1
Socioeconomic Structure of the Population by Republic or Province (percentages of total population) Agricultural Population
Economically A ctive Population
Urban Population
1953
1961
1966
1971
1979
1981
1953
1961
1966
1971
1979
1981
1953
1961
1971
1981
Yugoslavia
46.3
45.0
44.1
43.3
43.3
44.0
60.9
49.6
44.9
38.2
29.3
19.9
21.7
28.3
38.6
46.5
Less-developed regions Bosnia-Herzegovina Macedonia Montenegro Kosovo
42.5 40.8 36.4 33.2
39.2 39.4 34.3 34.8
37.8 38.8 33.1 30.1
36.7 38.3 32.7 26.0
36.7 38.2 32.7 25.9
38.7 41.8 34.3 23.8
62.2 62.7 61.5 72.4
50.2 41.3 47.0 64.2
45.1 45.8 41.0 58.4
40.0 39.9 35.0 51.5
28.9 28.9 26.0 42.2
17.3 21.7 13.5 24.6
15.0 26.1 14.2 14.6
19.5 34.9 21.1 19.5
27.9 48.1 34.2 26.9
36.2 53.9 50.7 32.5
Developed regions Slovenia Croatia Serbia Serbia proper Vojvodina
40.8 47.7 48.4 52.4 45.4
48.3 47.0 47.3 51.1 44.0
48.3 46.4 51.4 n.a. 43.6
48.4 45.5 45.7 51.5 42.7
48.4 45.5 51.5 n.a. 42.7
50.3 45.6 45.4 51.8 44.3
41.1 56.4 66.7 67.2 62.9
31.1 43.9 56.1 56.2 51.8
26.0 37.7 50.2 n.a. 40.6
20.4 32.3 44.0 44.1 39.0
12.5 24.1 34.5 n.a. 32.0
9.4 15.2 25.4 27.6 19.9
22.0 24.3 22.5 21.2 29.5
28.9 30.8 29.8 28.6 38.3
37.7 41.0 40.6 40.8 48.7
48.9 50.8 46.6 47.8 54.1
Source: Statistički Godišnjak Jugoslavije, various years.
386
APPENDIX A p p e n d ix T a b le
6-12
and
6-13
U n e m p l o y m e n t b y A g e S tr u c tu r e (tho u san d s)
123.7 173.7 164.5 184.9 232.6 274.0 229.0 228.0 266.9 265.3 291.5 326.8 315.6 289.7 289.5 333.5 398.7 478.5 583.8 665.2 716.7 737.9 775.0 789.2 883.2 887.8 916.3 1012.9 1063.9 1084.5 1087.1 1173.0 1244.9
21.7 19.8 24.1 20.3 24.2 24.6 29.7 36.0 31.7 29.4 31.6 30.7 27.4 29.3 31.1 34.1 40.4 38.6 50.3 45.9 48.8 49.7 54.5 55.5 60.2 68.1 75.7 83.1 81.9 79.0 80.4 77.6
9» 00
1957 1958 1959 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989
Total
Below 18 Years
Below 18 Years
19 to 24 Years
Below
(%
25
Total)
19 to 24 Years
Total)
Years
7.1 12.5 12.0 13.0 8.7 8.8 10.7 13.0 13.5 11.9 10.1 9.7 9.7 9.5 10.1 9.3 8.6 8.4 6.6 7.6 6.4 6.6 6.4 6.9 6.7 6.8 8.6 7.5 7.8 7.6 7.3 6.9 6.2
37.5 52.1 52.3 56.1 63.3 76.8 60.6 62.1 75.9 85.8 93.6 110.6 112.6 108.2 111.2 139.0 180.1 222.1 279.1 305.3 346.8 356.0 375.1 383.9 410.2 450.5 476.0 532.0 551.1 558.3 550.7 584.9 602.7
30.3 30.0 31.8 30.3 27.2 28.0 26.5 27.2 28.4 32.3 32.1 33.8 35.7 37.3 38.4 41.7 45.2 46.4 47.8 45.9 48.4 48.2 48.4 48.6 49.2 50.7 51.9 52.5 51.8 51.5 50.7 49.9 48.4
46.3 73.8 72.1 80.2 83.6 101.0 85.2 91.8 111.9 117.5 123.0 142.2 143.3 135.6 140.5 170.1 180.1 262.5 317.7 355.6 392.7 404.8 424,8 438.4 465.7 510.7 544.1 607.7 634.2 640.2 629.7 665.3 680.3
(%
Source: Statistički Godišnjak Jugoslavije, various years.
387
S T A T IS T I C A L DATA
Below 25 Years (% Total)
37.4 42.5 43.8 43.4 35.9 36.9 37.2 40.3 41.9 44.3 42.2 43.5 45.4 46.8 48.5 51.0 45.2 54.9 54.4 53.5 54.8 54.9 54.8 55.5 55.9 57.5 59.4 60.0 59.6 59.0 57.9 56.7 54.6
25 to 39 25 to 39 Years
Years (% Total)
48.0 64.9 61.5 70.8 94.1 121.8 97.5 94.2 105.2 101.4 119.0 142.9 128.4 113.0 102.5 114.9 130.0 158.9 194.2 219.1 236.5 245.0 259.0 261.9 277.5 288.4 290.0 322.3 344.7 361.1 374.3 416.9 258.9
38.8 37.4 37.4 38.3 40.5 44.5 42.6 41.3 39.4 38.2 40.8 43.7 40.7 39.0 35.4 34.5 32.6 33.2 33.3 32.9 33.0 33.2 33.4 33.2 33.3 32.5 31.6 31.8 32.4 33.3 34.4 35.5 20.8
40 to 49 Years
40 to 49 Years (% Total)
A b ove 50 Years
A bo ve 50 Years (% Total)
19.4 25.1 22.1 23.9 37.9 34.7 30.7 28.9 33.7 32.4 34.8 31.9 31.7 29.3 32.6 34.7 39.1 41.2 52.2 58.1 63.6 63.0 64.8 62.4 62.3 61.2 56.8 56.2 55.8 55.2 55.0 60.3 249.0
15.7 14.5 13.4 12.9 16.3 12.7 13.4 12.7 12.6 12.2 11.9 9.8 10.0 10.1 11.3 10.4 9.8 8.6 8.9 8.7 8.9 8.5 8.4 7.9 7.5 6.9 6.2 5.5 5.2 5.1 5.1 5.1 20.0
10.0 9.9 8.8 10.0 17.0 16.5 15.6 13.1 16.1 14.0 14.7 9.8 12.2 11.8 13.9 13.8 15.4 15.9 19.7 32.4 23.9 25.1 26.4 26.5 27.7 27.5 25.4 26.7 29.2 28.0 28.1 30.4 56.7
8.1 5.7 5.3 5.4 7.3 6.0 6.8 5.7 6.0 5.3 5.0 3.0 3.9 4.1 4.8 4.1 3.9 3.3 3.4 4.9 3.3 3.4 3.4 3.4 3.3 3.1 2.8 2.6 2.7 2.6 2.6 2.6 4.6
388
A PPENDIX A p p e n d i x T a b l e 6-14 a n d 6-15 Unemployment, 1952-1989 (thousands)
1952 Total registered jo b
7 1 .4
1953
1954
1955
1956
1957
1958
1959
1960
1961
68.0
69 .2
8 1 ,7
126.3
123.7
174.2
164.8
185.4
232.6
-4 8
1.8
18,1
5 4 .6
-2 .1
4 0 .8
-5 .4
12.5
25.5
n. a.
n.a
62.1
8 4 .2
8 6 .5
9 7.9
108.9
3 5.6
2 .7
13.2
11.2
5 0 .2
4 8 .3
5 2 .5
52.8
46.8
5 2 .7
61.8
66.6
seekers P erc en ta g e change Registered jo b
n a.
n.a.
n.a.
see kers— W o m en P erc en ta g e change P erc en tag e o f total P ersons seeking a jo b
157
16.9
18.4
19.7
29.8
3 2 .6
5 0 .2
7 .6
P ercen tage o f total
22.0
2 4 .9
8 .9
7.1
5 4 .0
5 .0
17.3
7.8
2 4.1
5 1.3 2 3 .6
9 .4
2 6 .6
2 6 .4
2 8 .8
3 2 .0
3 3.3
28.6
Job seekers with univ.,
n.a.
n.a.
n.a.
n.a.
n a.
7 ,5
8.3
8.2
5.3
for th e first time P ercen tage change
n.a.
college, intermedi ate, or secondary education* P ercen tage change P ercen tage o f total Migrant workers
4.3 n.a.
n.a.
n.a.
n.a.
n.a.
n.a.
n.a.
10.7
-1 .2
-3 5 .4
5 .0
4,4
2.3
18.0 203.4
260.6
n.a.
Jo b seekers plus
28,0
m igrant workers Jo b seekers receiving
n a.
n.a.
n.a.
n.a.
n.a.
21.2
23.1
22.8
20.5
29.1
9 .0
-1 .3
-1 0 .1
42.0
17.1
13.3
13.8
11.1
12.5
unem ploym ent compensation P ercen tage change P ercen tage o f total
Sources: Statistički Godišnjak Jugoslavije , various years; Yugoslav Survey , various years; for migrant workers, 1 9 6 0 - 6 4 : Zim m erm an, Open Borders, Nonalignment, and the Political Evolution o f Yugoslavia, tab le 4 .4 ; for migrant workers, 1 9 6 5 - 8 4 : P rimorac and Babić, “System ic Changes and Unemployment Grow th in Yugoslavia, 1 9 6 5 - 1 9 8 5 / ’ table 3. * Annual averages
389
S T A T IS T I C A L DATA
1'XU
J965
1966
1967
2 2 9 .0
2 2 8 .0
2 6 6 .9
2 6 5 .3
2 9 1 .5
17.8
-1 6 .4
-0 .4
17.1
-0 .6
124.2
123 .9
126.0
125.2
121.2
1962
/.96.3
274.0
1968
1969
1970
1971
1972
1973
3 2 6 .8
3 1 5 .6
2 8 9 .7
2 8 9 .5
3 3 3 .5
3 9 8 .7
9 .9
12.1
-3 .4
-8 .2
-0 .1
1 5 .2
19.6
127.7
142.1
143.0
141.9
144.8
1 66.6
2 0 3 .8
14.0
-0 .2
1.7
-0 .6
-3 .2
5 .4
11.3
0.6
-0 .8
2.0
15.1
2 2 .3
45.3
5 4 .1
5 5 .3
4 6 .9
4 5 .7
4 3.8
4 3 .5
4 5 .3
4 9 .0
5 0 .0
5 0.0
5 1 .1
83.8
8 2.6
9 1 .9
8 8 .3
8 7.4
9 2 .8
129.8
145.6
148.2
145.7
179.8
22 0 .4
25.8
-1 .4 36 .1
11.3
-3 .9
-1 .0
6.2
3 9 .9
12.2
1.8
-1 .7
2 3 .4
22.6
30.6
40 .3
3 3.1
3 2 .9
3 1 .8
3 9 .7
46.1
51 .2
5 0 .3
5 3 .9
55.3
5 .0
8.3
8 .7
10.7
17.2
2 6 .3
4 3 .0
4 3 .2
42 .3
41 .8
4 7 .7
6 3 .5
-5 .7
3 3 .1 15.9
66.0
4 .8
2 3 .0
6 0 .7
5 2 .9
63 .5
0 .5
-2 .1
-1 .2
14.1
1.8
3.6
3 .8
4 .0
6.5
9 .0
13.2
13.7
14.6
14.4
14.3
4 2.0
8 0 .0 3 0 9 .0
105.0 3 3 3 .0
1 30.0 3 9 6 .9
19 0.0
220.0
2 6 0 .0
4 3 0 .0
7 7 0 .0
8 6 0 .0
45 5 .3
5 1 1 .5
5 8 6 .8
7 4 5 .6
6 0 0 .0 8 8 9 .7
6 8 0 .0
316.0
9 6 9 .5
11 0 3 .5
1 2 58.7
3 4 .6
2 3 .8
21.8
3 2 .7
3 1 .5
3 2 .8
2 7 .5
16.8
10.6
10.5
10.2
11.5
18.9
-3 1 .2 10.4
-8 .4
5 0 .0
-3 .7
4.1
-3 6 .9
-0 .9
-2 .9
1 2.7
12.3
11.9
11.3
-1 6 .2 8 .4
-3 8 .9
9 .6
5 .3
3 .7
3 .6
3.1
2 .9
12.6
('c o n tin u e d )
390
APPENDIX A p p e n d ix T a b l e
6-14
and
6-15
(Continued)
1974
1975
1976
1977
1978
1979
mo
Total registered job seekers Percentage change
478.5
583.8
665.2
716.7
737.9
775.0
789.2
20.0
22.0
13.9
7.7
3.0
5.0
1.8
Registered job seekers— Women Percentage change Percentage of total
248.1
299.0
337.0
370.8
396.4
425.2
445.0
21.7 51.8
20.5 51.2
12.7 50.7
10.0 51.7
6.9 53.7
7.3 54.9
56.4
Persons seeking a job for the first time Percentage change Percentage of total
284.4
349.1
401.7
449.5
486.9
528.5
537 7
29.0 59.4
22.7 59.8
15.1 60.4
11.9 62.7
8.3 66.0
8.5 68.2
1.7 68.1
Job seekers with univ., college, intermedi ate, or secondary education* Percentage change Percentage of total
79.4
93.4
110.3
134.2
155.0
174.8
204 7
25.0 16.6
17.6 16.0
18.1 16.6
21.7 18.7
15.5 21.0
12.8 22.6
17.1 25.9
810.0 1288.5
770.0 1353.8
725.0 1390.2
705.0 1421.7
695.0 1432.9
690.0 1465.0
693.0 U82.2
11.3
17.1
18.7
17.2
18.4
21.1
19.7
- 1 .7 2.4
51.3 2.9
9.4 2.8
- 8 .0 2.4
7.0 2.5
14.7 2.7
-6 .6 2.5
Migrant workers Job seekers plus migrant workers Job seekers receiving unemployment compensation Percentage change Percentage of total
4.7
391
S T A T IS T I C A L DATA
m i
/982
1983
1984
¡985
833.2
887.8
916.3
1012.9
1063.9
1084.5
1087.1
1173.0
1244.9
5.6
6.6
3.2
10.5
5.0
1.9
0.2
7.9
6.1
478.0
512.0
520.0
568.0
596.0
611.0
606.0
641.0
7.4 57.4
7.1 57.7
1.6 56.7
9.2 56.1
4.9 56.0
2.5 56.3
- 0 .8 55.7
5.8 54.6
5.3 54.2
569.2
607.3
635.1
714.3
759.7
776.4
764.7
806.2
846.5
5.9 68.3
6.7 68.4
4.6 69.3
12.5 70.5
6.4 71.4
2.2 71.6
- 1 .5 703
5.4 68.7
5.0 68.0
236.6
280.0
315.6
357.7
384.6
401.0
400.5
420.0
446.3
15.6 28.4
18.3 31.5
12.7 34.4
13.3 35.3
7.5 36.2
4.3 37.0
- 0 .1 36.8
4.9 35.8
6.3 35.9
675.0 1508.2
675.0 1562.8
650.0 1566.3
625.0 1637.9
28
27.4
50.5
28.3
27.6
29.4
31.9
44.6
41.4
42.1 3.4
- 2 .1 3.1
84.3 5.5
- 4 4 .0 2.8
- 2 .5 2.6
6.5 2.7
18.7 3.2
27.8 3.8
- 7 .2 3.3
ii. a.
№
6
n.a.
1987
n.a.
im
n.a.
1989
675
n.a.
392
A P P E N D IX A p p e n d i x T a b l e 6-16, 6-17, a n d 9-2 Youth U nem p loy m ent Rates by R epublic or Province (percentages)
1965
1970
1975
1980
1983
1984
1985
Yugoslavia
20.6
15.3
22.2
27.7
33.0
35.1
37.3
L ess-developed regions Bosnia-Herzegovina Macedonia M ontenegro Kosovo
19.8 59.2 65.4 18.3
12.2 41.3 26.4 25.0
25.4 43.3 31.9 35.5
32.6 49.8 35.6 43.5
42.2 50.6 46.0 56.6
46.9 69.8 51.7 62.8
52.7 72.2 56.4 68.6
D ev e lo p e d regions Slovenia Croatia Serbia Vojvodina
5.5 20.1 23.4 15.7
5.8 8.2 22.5 13.9
2.9 13.3 28.9 24.0
3.0 14.2 35.5 34.0
4.4 20.8 37.0 35.4
4.0 22.4 36.1 34.1
3.7 24.3 34.9 32.7
Source: P rimorac and C h arette, “Regional Aspects o f Youth Unem ploym ent in Yugo slavia,” 218. Note: “Y outh” refers to persons aged 27 years or younger.
A p p e n d i x T a b l e 8-1 Social Sector E m p loy m ent by R epublic or Province (percentages of total em ploym ent)
1965
1975
Yugoslavia
18.4
21.9
L ess-developed regions Bosnia-Herzegovina M acedonia M ontenegro Kosovo
13.7 15.6 14.1 8.1
16.8 19.0 17.7 9.6
D ev elo p ed regions Slovenia Croatia Serbia Serbia p ro p e r Vojvodina
30.8 21.8 16.8 16.8 22.0
37.3 25.1 20.2 21.7 23.7
Source: Statistički Bilten Jugoslavije (1977), cited in Pleskovič and D olenc, “Regional D evelop m ent in a Socialist, Developing, and Multinational C o u n try,” 12.
BIBLIOGRAPH Y
Adam, Jan. Employment and "Wage Policies in Poland, Czechoslovakia, and H un gary since 1950. N ew York: Macmillan, 1984. ---------- , ed. Employment Policies in the Soviet Union and Eastern Europe. New York: St. M artin ’s Press, 1982. Adamic, Louis. The Eagle and the Roots. G arden City, N.Y.: D oubleday, 1952. Adizes, Ichak. Industrial Democracy, Yugoslav Style: A n Organizational Study o f Decision-Making. N ew York: C olum bia U niversity Press, 1971. Adler-Karlsson, G unnar. Western Economic Warfare, 1947-1967: A Case Study in Foreign Economic Policy. Stockholm: Almquist and Wicksell, 1968. Allcock, John. ‘“ T h e Socialist Transformation of th e Village’: Yugoslav Agricultural Policy since 1945.” In Ronald A. Francisco and Betty A. Laird, eds., A gri cultural Policies in the USSR and Eastern Europe. Boulder, Colo.: W estview Press, 1980. Alt, Jam es. “Political Parties, W orld D em and, and U nem ploym ent: D om estic and In ternatio n al Sources of Econom ic Activity.” American Political Science Review 79, no. 4 (1985): 1016-40. A nderson, Benedict. Imagined Communities: Reflections on the Origins and Spread o f Nationalism. London: Verso, 1983. Antal, Laszlo. "Conflicts of Financial Planning and Regulation. ” Acta Oeconomica 30 (1983): 341-65. Antifašističko Veće N arodnog O slobodjenja Jugoslavije (AVNOJ). Z akonodavni
rad Predsedništva AVNOJa i Predsedništva Privremene narodne skupštine DFJa (N o vem b er 19, 1 9 4 4 -O c to b er 27, 1945). Belgrade, 1945. A ppleby, Joyce O ldham , Economic Thought and Ideology in SeventeenthCentury England. P rinceton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1978. Arsov, Ljubčo. “Rešavanje pitanja radne snage.” Partiska Izgradnja 2, no. 6 (J u n e -J u ly 1950): 17-33. ' ----------. “Mobilizacija nove radn e snage za izvršenje privrednog pla na.” Narodna Država 2, no. 6 (Jun e 1948): 3 -1 1 . Auty, Phyllis. “Yugoslavia and the Cominform: Realignm ent of F oreign Policy.” In W ayne S. Vucinich, ed ., A t the Brink o f W ar and Peace: The Tito-Stalin Split in a Historic Perspective. N ew York: Brooklyn College Press, 1982. Avakumović, Ivan. History o f the Communist Party o f Yugoslavia Vol. 1. A ber deen : A b erd e en U niversity Press, 1964. Avramović, Dragoslav. O dnos izm edju spoljnih i unutrašnjih finansija soci jalističke p riv re d e .” Finansije 6, nos. 1 1 -12 (N o v e m b e r-D e c e m b e r 1950): 30. Babić, M ate, and Em il Primorac. “Some Causes o f the G row th of the Yugoslav E xternal D e b t.” Soviet Studies 38, no. 1 (January 1986): 69-88. ----------. “Analiza koristi i troškova privrem enog zapošljavanja u ino z em stv u.” Ekonomski Pregled 26, nos. 1 1 -1 2 (N o v e m b e r-D e c e m b e r 1975): 667-86,
394
BIB L IOGRAPHY
Badovinac, Tomislav. Interview . Start, O ctober 23, 1982. Bahry, D onna. “P erestroika and the D e b a te over Territorial Econom ic D ecen tral ization.” Ilarriman Institute Forum 2, no. 5 (May 1989): 1-8. Bajt, Aleksandar. “Lessons from the L abor-M anagem ent L aboratory.” Unpub. ms. 1987. ----------. “In v estm en t Cycles in E uropean Socialist Economies: A Review A rticle.” Journal o f Economic Literature 9, no. 1 (1971): 53-63. Bakarić, Vladimir. Interview . Start, January 2, 1982, 11-18. ----------. “P roblem i zem ljišne ren te u prolaznoj e tap i.” In O poljoprivredi i prob lemima sela: Govori i članci. Belgrade: Kultura, 1960. ----------. “O radu narodnog fronta na se lu .” In O poljoprivredi. ----------. “Vezana trgovina poljoprivrednih i industrijskih proizvoda i njeno ograničavanje porasta kapitalističkih elem enata na selu: Stanje zadrugarstva.” In
O poljoprivredi. Bakić, Ljubom ir. “Politika bržeg razvoja privredno nedovoljno razvijenih re p u b lika i autonom nih pokrajina.” Sociologija 19, nos. 2 - 3 (1977): 397-411. Baletić, Zvonim ir, and Božo M arendić. “Politika razvoja privredno nedovoljno razvijenih područja S. R. H rvatske.” Ekonomski Pregled 32, nos. 7 - 8 (1981): 355-67. Baletić, Zvonko, and I. Baučić. Population, Labour Force, and Employment in Yugoslavia, 1950—1990. Vienna: V erein W ie n e r Institut, 1979. Balog, Nikola. “U red b e vlade FNRJ u 1948 godini.” Narodna Država 3, no. 1 (January 1950): 97. Banac, Ivo. “T he Fearful A sym m etry of War: T he C auses and C onsequences of Yugoslavia’s D e m ise .” Daedalus 121, no. 2 (Spring 1992): 141-74. ----------. W ith Stalin against Tito: The Cominformist Splits in Yugoslav Commu nism. Ithaca, N.Y.: C ornell U niversity Press, 1988. ----------. The National Question in Yugoslavia: Origins, History, Politics. Ithaca, N.Y.: C ornell U niversity Press, 1984. ----------. “Yugoslav C om inform ist Organizations and Insurgen t Activity: 1948 1954. ” In W ayne S. Vucinich, e d., A t the Brink o f W ar and Peace: The TitoStalin Split in a Historic Perspective. N ew York: Brooklyn College Press, 1982. B artlett, William J. “O n the D ynam ic Instability of Induced-M igration U nem p lo y m en t in a D ual Econom y . ’Journal o f Development Economics 13, (1983): 85-96. ----------. “E conom ic D evelopm ent and Institutional Reform: T he Introduction of W orkers’ Self-M anagem ent in Yugoslavia.” Economic Analysis and Workers’ Management 14, no. 4 (1980): 429-43. ----------. “A Structural M odel of U nem ploym ent in Yugoslavia— An A lternative to the Institutional H ypothesis.” U npub. ms. University of Southam pton, 1980. Basom, K enneth E. “Socialism as National Liberation: E dw ard K ardelj’s Classic W ork on the National Q u estio n .” U npub. ms. N .d. B eard, C harles, and G eorge Radin. The Balkan Pivot: Yugoslavia. A Study in Government and Administration. New York: Macmillan, 1929. B ebler, Anton. “D ev elo p m en t of Sociology of Militaria in Yugoslavia.” Armed Forces and Society 3 (N ovem ber 1976): 59-68.
B I BL IOGRAP HY
395
----------. “O n Civil-M ilitary Relations in the E uropean Socialist S tates.” U npub. ms. N.d. ----------. “Yugoslavia’s National D efense S ystem .” U npub. ms. N .d. Begović, N ada.“Z aposlenost.’’ In Privreda FNR] u periodu od 1947-1956 godine Belgrade: Ekonom ski Institut FNRJ, 1957. Begović, Vlajko. “Naša poljoprivreda i pitanje njenog socijalističkog p reobražaja.” Komunist 3, no. I (January 1949): 76-102. ----------. “P roblem obezbjedjenja radne snage i stručnih kadrova u petogodišnjem p la n u .” Narodna Država 1, no. 6 (S eptem ber 1947): 18-32. B eren d , Ivan T ., and Gyijrgy Ranki. The European Periphery and Industrializa tion 1780-1914. T ranslated by Eva Palmai. Budapest: Akademiai Kiadć, 1982. Bergson, A bram . “E n tre p re n e u rsh ip u n d e r Labor Participation: T h e Yugoslav C a se .” In Joshua Ronen, e d ., Entrepreneurship. Lexington, Mass.: Lexington Books, 1982. B esem eres, John F. Socialist Population Politics: The Political Implications o f Demographic Trends in the USSR and Eastern Europe. W hite Plains, N.Y.: M. E. Sharpe, 1980. Bićanić, Ivo. “T he Inequality Im pact of the Unofficial E conom y in Yugoslavia. ” In Sergio A lessandrini and Bruno Dallago, eds., The Unofficial Economy: Conse quences and Perspectives in Different Economic Systems. Brookfield, Vt.: G ow er, 1987. Bićanić, Rudolf. Kako živi narod (1935). Reissued posthum ously as How the People Live. E d ited by Sonia Bićanić and Joel H alpern. D e p artm e n t of A nthro pology, U niversity of M assachusetts. Amherst: University of M assachusetts Press, 1981. ----------. “Agrarna kriza od 1873-1895 i njezin utjecaj na ekonom sku i socijalnu stru k tu ru H rv atsk e.” Parts 1 -3. Ekonomist, nos. 3 - 5 (1937): 97-108, 151-59, 199-204. Bideleux, Robert. Communism and Development. London and N ew York: M e th u e n , 1985. B itterm an, H enry J. The Refunding o f International Debt. D u rham , N .C .: D uke U niversity Press, 1973. Bjeladinović, Andro. “O privrednim p red u zećim a.” Finansije, yr. 2, vol. 4, no. 6 (Ju n e 1947): 373. Blaug, Mark. Economic Theory in Retrospect. 3d ed. C am bridge: C am bridge U niversity Press, 1978. Block, F red. “P ostindustrial D evelopm ent and the O bsolescence of Econom ic C a teg o ries.” Politics and Society 14, no. 1 (1985): 71-104. Bolčić, Silvano. Razvoj i kriza Jugoslavenskog društva u sociološkoj perspektivi. Belgrade: Radionica SIC, 1983. Boltho, A ndrea, ed. The European Economy: Growth and Crisis. N ew York: Ox ford U niversity Press, 1982. Bom belles, Joseph T. Economic Development o f Communist Yugoslavia, 1947 1964. Stanford, Calif.: H oover Institution, 1968. Bonacich, E dna. “T he Past, Present, and F u tu re of Split L abor M arket T h e o ry .” In C ora Bagley M arrett and C heryl Leggon, eds., Research in Race and Ethnic Relations. Vol. 1, G reenw ich, C onn.: JAI Press, 1979.
396
BIBL IO GR AP HY
Bonnell, Victoria E. Roots o f Rebellion: Workers’ Politics and Organizations in St. Petersburg and Moscow, 1900-1914. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press, 1983. B ookman, Milica Zarković. “T he Econom ic Basis of Regional Autarchy in Yugoslavia.” Soviet Studies 42, no. 1 (January 1990): 93-109. Bo.šnjović, Ilijas. Razvoj i zaposlenost (Razvoj i politika zaposlenosti u Bosni i Hercegovini). Sarajevo: Svjetlost, 1980. Brajić, Vlajko. Problemi zapošljavanja u uslovima tehnološkog progresa. M ono graph no. 64. Belgrade: In stitut za U poredno Pravo, 1972. B raun, Rudolf. “Taxation, Sociopolitical Structure, and State-Building: G reat Britain and B randenburg-P russia.” In C harles Tilly, e d., The Formation o f Na tional States in Western Europe. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1975. B rew er, Anthony. Marxist Theories o f Imperialism: A Critical Survey. London: R outledge and Kegan Paul, 1980. Burg, Steven L. "E lite Conflict in Post-Tito Yugoslavia.” Soviet Studies 58, no. 2 (April 1986): 170-93. ----------. Conflict and Cohesion in Socialist Yugoslavia: Political Decision Making since 1966. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1982. B urger, W illem , C ard K ester, and G uus d en O udem . S e lf Management and In vestment Control in Yugoslavia. T he Hague: Institute of Social Studies, 1977. B urkett, John P. “Search, Selection, and Shortage in an Industry C om posed of L abor-M anaged Firm s ."Journal o f Comparative Economics 10, no. 1 (March 1986): 2 6 -40. ----------. The Effects o f Economic Reform in Yugoslavia: Investment and Trade Policy, 1959-1976. R esearch Series no. 55. Berkeley: Institute of International Studies, U niversity of California, 1983. B yrnes, R obert F ., ed. Communal Families in the Balkans: The Zadruga. Essays by Philip E. Moseley and Essays in His Honor. N otre D am e, I n d .: University of N otre D am e Press, 1976. Čalić, D ušan. ’’Ekonom ska racionalnost, sociološki i politički zahtjevi sam ouprav nog socijalizma ” P aper p rese n te d at conference of the Serbian Academy of Sciences and Arts, Belgrade, 1982. ----------. “E konom ska problem atika na VI. kongresu Saveza kom unista.” Ekon omski Pregled 3, no. 6 (1952): 321-29. C am eron, D avid R. “T he Colors of a Rose. ” U npub. ms. 1988. ----------. “D oes G o v ern m en t C ause Inflation? Taxes, Spending, and D eficits.” In Leon L in d berg and C harles Maier, eds., The Politics o f Inflation and Economic Stagnation. W ashington, D .C .: T he Brookings Institution, 1985. ----------. “Social Dem ocracy, C orporatism , Labour Q uiescence, and th e R epre sentation o f Econom ic In tere st in Advanced Capitalist Society." In John H. G o ld th o rp e., ed., Order and Conflict in Contemporary Capitalism. Oxford: C larendon Press, 1984. C am pbell, John C. Tito’s Separate Road: America and Yugoslavia in World Poli tics. N ew York: H a rp e r and Row, 1967. Cardoso, F e rd in an d H en riq u e, and Enzo Faletto. Dependency and Development in Latin America. Berkeley and Los Angeles: U niversity of California Press, 1979. '
B I BL IOGRAP HY
397
C arlo, Antonio. “C apitalist R estoration and Social Crisis in Yugoslavia.” Telos, no. 36 (S um m er 1978): 81-110. C arr, E d w ard H allett. Socialism in One Country: 1924-26. Baltimore: Penguin, 1970. ----------. The Bolshevik Revolution, 1917-1923. Vol. 1. N ew York: Macmillan, 1951. C arr, E. H ., and R. W. Davies. Foundations o f a Planned Economy, 1926-1929. 2 vols. P art 1 o f A History o f Russia. N ew York: Macmillan, 1969. C a rter, April. D emocratic Reform in Yugoslavia: The Changing Role o f the Party. P rin ceto n , N .J.: P rinceton U niversity Press, 1982. “Č elik kao nafta.” Borba, O cto b er 29, 1982. C hepulis, Rita. “M igration Policies and R eturn M igration w ith Particular R efer en ce to Yugoslavia.” Studi Emigrazione Etudes Migrations, 18, no. 63 (S ep tem b e r 1981): 319-35. C hichilnisky, Graciela. “T erm s of T rade and D om estic D istribution: E xport-L ed G row th w ith A bundant L abor.” Journal o f Developm ent Economics 8 (1981): 163-92. C hirot, D aniel. Social Change in a Peripheral Society: The C reation o f a Balkan Colony. N ew York: Academic Press, 1976. C h ittle, C harles R. Industrialization and Manufactured Export Expansion in a W orker-M anaged Economy: The Yugoslav Experience. Tiibingen: M ohr, 1979. C h o w dhury, A bdur R., S tep h e n G. G rubaugh, and A ndrew J. Stollar. “M oney in th e Yugoslav Econom y .’’Journal o f Post-Keynesian Economics 12, no. 4 (Sum m e r 1990): 636-46. Cichock, M ark A. “R eevaluating a D ev elo p m en t Strategy: Policy Im plications for Yugoslavia.” C om parative Politics, January 1985, pp. 211-28. Clark, Cal, and Karl F. Johnson. “Variations in th e Policies of Yugoslav C o m m unes: D evelopm ental Im peratives versus Regional S tyle.” Com parative Polit ical Studies 16, no. 2 (July 1983): 235-54. Clissold, S tep h e n , ed. Yugoslavia and the Soviet Union, 1939-1973: A Documen tary Survey. London: Oxford U niversity Press for the Royal In stitu te of In te r national Affairs, 1975. č o b e ljić , Nikola. Politika i m etodi privrednog razvoja Jugoslavije, 1947-1956. Belgrade: Nolit, 1959. ---------- . “P roizvodni faktori i proizvodna orijentacija Jugoslavije.” Ekonomist 11, nos. 1 -2 (1958): 1-24. ' ' ' C o h en , L en ard J. The Socialist Pyramid: Elites and Power in Yugoslavia. O ak ville, N.Y., and London: Mosaic Press, 1989. C o h en , L en ard, and Paul Warwick. Political Cohesion in a Fragile Mosaic: The Yugoslav Experience. Boulder, Colo.: W estview Press, 1983. C o h en , S tep hen. Bukharin and the Bolshevik Revolution: A Political Biography. Oxford: Oxford U niversity Press, 1980. Čolaković, R. “R ešenje nacionalnog pitanja u Jugoslaviji.” Komunist 4, nos. 4 - 5 (J u ly -S e p te m b e r 1950): 65-67. Comisso, E llen. “Can a Party of th e W orking Class Be a W orking-Class Party?” In Jan F. T riska and C harles Gati, eds., Blue-Collar W orkers in Eastern Europe. London: Allen and U nwin, 1981.
398
BIBL IOGRAP HY
Comisso, E llen. W orkers’ Control under Plan and Market. N ew H aven, Conn.: Yale U niversity Press, 1979. C o m m an d er, Simon. “Inflation and the Transition to a M arket Economy: An O v erv iew .” W orld Bank Economic Review 6, no. 1 (1992): 3 -1 2 . C o m m u n ist Party of Yugoslavia. C entral C om m ittee. Statement o f the Central
Committee o f the Communist Party o f Yugoslavia in Regard to the Resolution of the Information Bureau o f Communist Parties on the Situation in the Commu nist Party o f Yugoslavia. B elgrade: Jugoslovenska Knjiga, 1948. C onnock, Michael. “A N ote on Industrial Efficiency in Yugoslav Regions: Some E lectrical E v id en ce.” Soviet Studies 34, no. 1 (January 1982): 86-95. C onnor, W alker. The National Question in Marxist-Leninist Theory and Strategy. P rinceto n , N .J.: Princeton U niversity Press, 1984. C oulson, A ndrew . Tanzania: A Political Economy. N ew York: Oxford University, Press, 1982. Cox, T erry. Peasants, Class, and Capitalism: The Rural Research o f L. N. Kritsman and His School. Oxford: C larendon Press, 1986. Crosslin, R o b ert L. “L abor Related Program s in Yugoslavia: Evaluation and Rec o m m e n d atio n s.” R eport for the W orld Bank, Ju n e 1990. D abčević, Savka. “N eki suvrem eni ekonomisti o ekonomskoj ulozi d ržav e.” Ekonomski Pregled 2, no. 6 (1951): 376-85. D abčević-K učar, Savka, Miladin Korać, Miloš Samardžija, Jakov Sirotković, Rikard Štajner, and T ihom ir Vlaškalić, Problemi teorije i prakse socijalističke robne proizvodnje u Jugoslaviji. Zagreb: Inform ator, 1965. D ahrendorf, Ralf. Life Chances: Approaches to Social and Political Theory. Chi cago: U niversity of Chicago Press, 1979. Dam janovič, Pero, Milovan Bosić, and D ragica Lazarevič, eds. Peta zemaljska konferencija KPJ (19-23. oktobar 1940). Izvori za Istoriju SKJ, ser. A, vol. 1. Belgrade: K om unist, 1980. D autovič, Mirko. “N agradjivanje u preduzećim a kao stim ulativ za povečanje pro duktivnosti rada. ” Ekonomski Anali 3 (1956): 131-47. D avidovič, M ilena. “N ezaposlenost i d ruštvena nejednakost u Jugoslaviji.” Gledišta 27, nos. 7 - 9 (Ju ly -S e p te m b e r 1986): 3-35. D avies, R. W. “Soviet H istory in the G orbachev R evolution.” The Socialist Regis ter, e d ite d by Ralph M iliband and John Saville, pp. 37-78. ----------. The Development o f the Soviet Budgetary System. C am bridge: Cam bridge U niversity Press, 1958. Day, Richard. “D em ocratic C ontrol and the D ignity of Politics: An Analysis of The Revolution Betrayed." Comparative Economic Studies 29, no. 3 (Fall 1987): 4 29. ---------- . ed. and trans. N. I. Bukharin: Selected Writings on the State and the Transition to Socialism. Armonk, N.Y.: M. E. Sharpe, 1982. D ean , R o b ert W. “Civil-M ilitary Relations in Yugoslavia, 19 7 1 -7 5 .” Armed Forces and Society 3 (N ovem ber 1976): 17-58. D e d ije r, Stevan. “T ito’s Bomb: T he Birth and D eath of an R & D Policy in a D eveloping C o u n try .” U npub. ms. 1972. D ed ijer, Vladimir. Novi prilozi za biografiju Josipa Broza Tita (1945-1955). 3 vols. Belgrade: Rad, 1984.
BIBL IOGRAPHY
399
----------. The Battle Stalin Lost: Memoirs o f Yugoslavia, 1948-1953. New York: Viking Press, 1971. D eleon, Ašer. “Conclusion of the C ongress o fT rad e Unions. ” Yugoslav Review 5, nos. 3 - 4 (M ay -Ju n e 1955): 18-19, 29. D en itch , Bogdan. Limits and Possibilities: The Crisis o f Yugoslav Socialism and State Socialist Systems. M inneapolis: U niversity of M innesota Press, 1990. D ereta, B. “O nekim osnovnim pokazateljim a radne snage.” Evidencija, nos. 1 -2 (1951): 8 -1 0 . Dilić, E d h em , ed. Seoska omladina danas: Rezultati istraživanja ti S.R. Hrva tskoj. Zagreb: C e n ta r D ruštvenih D jelatnosti SSOH , 1977. D irlam , Joel B., and Jam es Plum m er. An Introduction to the Yugoslav Economy. C olum bus, Ohio: C harles E. M errill, 1973. Djilas, Milovan. Rise and Fall. San Diego: H arcourt Brace Jovanovich, 1985. ----------. Tito: The Story fro m Inside. T ranslated by Vasilije Kojić and Richard Haynes. N ew York and London: H arcourt Brace Jovanovich, 1980. ----------. Wartime. T ranslated by Michael Petrovich. N ew York: H arcourt Brace Jovanovich, 1977. ----------. Memoir o f a Revolutionary. Translated by D renka W illen. N ew York: H arco u rt Brace Jovanovich, 1973. ----------. Conversations with Stalin. N ew York: H arcourt, Brace, and W orld, 1962. D jodan, Šime. The Evolution o f the Economic System o f Yugoslavia and the Eco nomic Position o f Croatia. N ew York: Casz, 1973. R eprinted from Journal o f Croatian Studies 13 (1972). Djokanović, Milovan. “Članovi partije i uključenje u radne b rig a d e .” Partiska Izgradnja 3, nos. 5 - 6 (O c to b e r-D e c e m b e r 1951): 18-22. D jordjević, A. “O socijalističkom takm ičenju.” Vjesnik Rada 4, nos. 11-12 (N o v e m b e r-D e c e in b e r 1949): 447-75. D jordjević, Jovan. “D ržavno u red jen je F ederativne N arodne R epublike Jug oslavije.” Informativni Priručnik Jugoslavije, 1949, pp. 136-47 D obb, M aurice. Theories o f Value and Distribution since Adam Smith: Ideology and Economic Theory. C am bridge: C am bridge U niversity Press, 1973. ----------. Socialist Planning: Some Problems. London: Law rence and W ishart, 1970. ----------. Welfare Economics and the Economics o f Socialism: Towards a Commonsense Critique. C am bridge: C am bridge University Press, 1969. ----------. Soviet Economic Development since 1917. 6th ed. London: R outledge and Kegan Paul, 1966. ----------. “Full E m ploym ent and C apitalism .” In On Economic Theory and Social ism: Collective Papers. N ew York: International Publishers, 1955. Originally pu b lish ed 1950. Dodevski, D obri. Problemi strukture u procesu industrijalizacije nedovoljno razvijenih područja Jugoslavije. Skopje: Ekonomski Institu t na U niverzitet “Kiril i M eto d ij,” 1975. D om ar, Evsey. “T he Soviet Collective Farm as a P roducer C ooperative. Am eri can Economic Review 56, no. 4, pt. 1 (S eptem ber 1966): 734-57. D oran, H ow ard E ., and Rozany R. D een. “The Use of L inear D ifference E q u a
400
BIB L IOGRAPHY
tions in M anpow er Planning: A Criticism. "Journal o f Development Economics 8 (1981): 193-204. D u b ey , VinocI, e t al. Yugoslavia: Development with Decentralization. Baltimore: Johns H opkins U niversity Press for the W orld Bank, 1975. D uisin, D uško. “T he Im pact of U nited States Assistance on Yugoslav Policy, 1 9 4 9 -1 9 59.” M aster’s thesis, C olum bia University, 1959. D ukanac, L jubom ir C. “Novi poreski sistem F N R J.” Finansije, yr. 2, vol. 3, nos. 1 -2 (Ja n u a ry -F e b ru a ry 1947): 4 -8 . ----------. Indeksi konjunkturnog razvoja Jugoslavije, 1919-1941. Belgrade: Bibli oteka Beogradske Trgovinske Komore, 1946. D ular, M arijan. “S truktura osoblja zaposlenog u našoj p riv red i.” Vjesnik Rada 5, no. 11 (N ovem ber 1950): 433-36. ----------. “U vodjenje izveštajno-statističke službe o uposlenom osoblju, platnom fondu i radnom v re m e n u .” Vjesnik Rada 3, no. 1 (January 1948): 16-19. D yker, D avid A. Yugoslavia: Socialism, Development, and Debt. London and N ew York: R outledge, 1990. E conom ic Com m ission for E urope. “T he Relative Perform ance of South E u ropean Exports o f M anufactures to O E C D C ountries in the 1970’s: An Analysis of D e m a n d Factors and C om petitiveness.” Economic Bulletin f o r Europe 34 (1982): 503-61. E ich en g reen , Barry, and T. J. H atton, eds. Interwar Unemployment in Interna tional Perspective. D o rdrecht, N etherlands: K luwer Academic Publishers, 1988. E ich en g reen , Barry, and M arc Uzan. “T he Marshall Plan: Econom ic Effects for E astern E u ro p e and th e form er U SSR .” Economic Policy 7, no. 14 (April 1992): 13-76. “E m p lo y m en t, 1977-1984,” Yugoslav Survey 27, no. 1 (1986). Engels, F riedrich. “T he Tactics of Social D em ocracy.” In R obert C. Tucker, ed., The Marx-Engels Reader, 2d ed. N ew York: N orton, 1978. E rlich, Alexander. The Soviet Industrialization Debate, 1924-1928. Cambridge: H arvard U niversity Press, 1960. E rlich, Vera Stein. Family in Transition: A Study o f 300 Yugoslav Villages. P rinceton, N .J.: P rinceton U niversity Press, 1966. E sping-A ndersen, Gosta. Politics against Markets: The Social Democratic Road to Power. Princeton, N.J.: P rinceton U niversity Press, 1985. E sping-A ndersen, Gosta, and W alter Korpi. “Social Policy as Class Politics in P ost-W ar Capitalism: Scandinavia, Austria, and G erm an y .” In John H. Goldthorpe, e d., O rder and Conflict in Contemporary Capitalism. Oxford: C laren don Press, 1984. E strin , Saul. Self-Management: Economic Theory and Yugoslav Practice. Cam bridge: C am bridge U niversity Press, 1983. ----------. “T h e Effects of Self-M anagem ent on Yugoslav Industrial G ro w th .” Soviet Studies 34, no. 1 (January 1982): 69-85. E strin , Saul, R obert E. M oore, and Jan Svejnar. “M arket Im perfections, Labor M anagem ent, and E arnings Differentials in a D eveloping C ountry: Theory and E vid en ce from Yugoslavia.” Quarterly Journal o f Economics 103, no. 3 (August 1988): 4 65-78.
BIBL IO GR AP HY
401
Farkaš, Vladimir. “Naša tzv. prenaseljenost i naš problem nezaposlenosti.” Soci jalna Politika 5, nos. 7 - 8 (July -A u g u st 1955): 50-59. ----------. “O dredjivanje osnovnog uzroka nezaposlenosti u F N R J.” Socijalna Poli tika 5, no. 9 (S ep tem b er 1955): 3 -1 4 . F e h er, F e ren c, Agnes H eller, and Gydrgy Markus. Dictatorship over Needs. N ew York: St. M artin’s Press, 1983. F eiw el, G eorge. “C auses and C onsequences of D isguised Indu strial U n em p lo y m e n t in a Socialist E cono m y.” Soviet Studies 26, no. 3 (July 1974): 344-62. F erg e, Zsuzsa. A Society in the Making: Hungarian Social and Societal Policy, 1945-75. W hite Plains, N.Y.: M. E. Sharpe, 1979. Filipović, Velimir, and Sulcjm an Hrnjica. “Psihološki aspekti nezapošljavanja o m lad in e .” Gledišta 8 (1967): 1693-99. F iltzer, Donald. Soviet Workers and Stalinist Industrialization: The Formation o f Modern Soviet Production Relations, 1928-1941 . Armonk, N.Y.: M. E. Sharpe, 1986. Firković, Mirko. “Tržište." In Privreda FNR] u periodu od 1947-1956 godine. Belgrade: E konom ski In stitut FNRJ, 1957. “Fiscal System and Fiscal Policy.” Yugoslav Survey 31, no. 3 (1990). Fitzgerald, E. V. K. “Stabilization and Econom ic Justice: T he Case of N icaragua.” In Debt and Development in Latin America. Kwan S. Kim and David F. Ruecio, ed s., N otre D am e, Ind.: U niversity of N otre D am e Press, 1985. F laherty, D iane. “Plan, M arket and U nequal Regional D evelo p m en t in Yugo slavia.” Soviet Studies 40, no. 1 (January 1988): 100-124 ----------. “E conom ic Reform and Foreign T rade in Yugoslavia.” Cambridge Journal o f Economics 6 (1982): 105-43. Flem ing, J. M arcus, and Viktor R. Sertić. “T he Yugoslav Econom ic S y stem .” In ternational Monetary Fund S ta ff Papers 9 (July 1962): 202-23. Foreign Relations o f the United States, 1949. Vol. 5, E astern E u ro p e, the Soviet Union. W ashington, D .C .: U.S. G o v ern m en t Printing Office, 1976. Foreign Relations o f the United States, 1948. Vol. 4, E astern E urope, th e Soviet U nion. W ashington, D .C .: U.S. G overnm ent P rinting Office, 1974. F reem an , Richard B., and Jam es L. Medoff. W hat Do Unions Do? N ew York: Basic Books, 1984. Fusfeld, D aniel R. “L abor-M anaged and Participatory Firms: A Review A rticle.” Journal o f Economic Issues 17, no. 3 (S eptem ber 1983): 769-89. Gapinski, Jam es H ., Borislav Škegro, and Thomas W. Z uehlke. Modeling the Economic Performance o f Yugoslavia . New York: Praeger, 1989. G arraty, John A. Unemployment in History: Economic Thought and Public Policy. N ew York: H a rp e r and Row, 1978. Garthoff, R aym ond L. “T he D eath of Stalin and the Birth of M utual D ete rren ce . ” Survey 25, no. 2 (Spring 1980): 10-16 G edeon, Shirley J. “M onetary D isequilibrium and Bank Reform Proposals in Yugoslavia: Paternalism and the E conom y.” Soviet Studies 39, no. 2 (April 1987): 281-91. ---------- . “T h e Post-Keynesian T heory of Money: A Sum m ary and an E astern E u ro p ean E x am p le.” Journal o f Post-Keynesian Economics 8, no. 2 (W inter 1985/86): 208-21.
402
BIB LIO GRAPHY
G ed eo n , Shirley J. “Yugoslav M onetary Theory and Its Im plication for Self M a n a g em en t.” P h .D . diss., U niversity of M assachusetts, D e p a rtm e n t of E co nomics, 1982. G ersch en k ron, Alexander. Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective: A Book o f Essays. C am bridge: H arvard University Press, Belknap Press, 1962. Ginić, Ivanka. Dinamika i struktura gradskog stanovništva Jugoslavije: Demo grafski aspekt urbanizacije. Belgrade: In stitut D ruštvenih Nauka, 1967. Gligorov, Kiro. “Factors in O u r Econom ic Stabilization.” Ekonomska Politika 1, no. 8 (xMay 1952): 143-45. ----------. “N eki problem i u vezi sa izvršenjem opštedržavnog bud žeta za 1947 g od.” Finansije, yr. 2, vol. 4, no. 9 (S eptem ber 1947): 479-88. Gligorov, Vladimir. Gledišta i sporovi o industrijalizaciji u socijalizmu. Belgrade: In stitu t D ru štv en ih Nauka, 1984. Goati, Vladimir. “Savetovanje [in honor of Naj dan Pašić]. ” Ekonomska Politika, no. 1841 (July 13, 1987): 17-18. Gogić, Janko. Razvoj i strukturne promjene regiona Jugoslavije. Belgrade: Pri vredni P regled, 1977. G orupić, Drago. “Uloga ekonom ista u našoj p riv red i.” Ekonomski Pregled 3, nos. 1 -2 (1952): 1-8. “G ovor A ndrije H e b ra n g a .” Narodna Država 1, nos. 4 - 5 (June 1947): 10-25. Gow, Jam es. Legitimacy and the Military: The Yugoslav Crisis. N ew York: St. M artin ’s Press, 1992. G radska S am oupravna In te re sn a Zajednica Zapošljavanja. Zaposlenost u Be ogradu: Tendencije, problemi i perspektive do 1985. Belgrade, 1981. Granick, David. Job Rights in the Soviet Union: Their Consequences. Cambridge: C am b rid ge U niversity Press, 1988. G reen , D onald W. “C o m m en t." In Egon N eu b e rg e r and L aura D A ndrea Tyson, ed s., The Impact o f International Economic Disturbances on the Soviet Union and Eastern Europe. New York: Pergam on Press, 1980. G regory, Mary B. “Regional Econom ic D evelopm ent in Yugoslavia.” Soviet Studies 25, no. 3 (O ctober 1973): 213-28. GrifBth-Jones, Stefany. “T he G row th of M ultinational Banking, the E u ro cu rren cy M arket, and T heir Effects on D eveloping C ountries .’’Journal o f De velopment Studies 14, no. 2 (January 1980): 204-23. Gross, Mirjana. Radnički pokret u Hrvatskoj potkraj XIX. stoljeća: Izabrani izvori. Zagreb: Školska Knjiga, 1957. Gulick, C harles A. Austria fro m Habsburg to Hitler. 2 vols. Berkeley and Los Angeles: U niversity o f California Press, 1948. G uzina, Vojin. “M edjunarodni zajmovi i socijalistička izgradnja.” Komunist 5, no. 6 (N o v em ber 1950): 21-78. H adžič, Branko. “Zašto se i dalje razvija borba za visoku produktivnost rada u ru d n ik u B rezi.” Partiska Izgradnja 3, no. 1 (February 1951): 61-63. H ahn, W e rn e r G. Postwar Soviet Politics: The Fall o f Zhdanov and the Defeat of Moderation, 1946—1953. Ithaca, N.Y.: C ornell University Press, 1982. Hall, P eter. Governing the Economy: The Politics o f State Intervention in Britain and France. London: Oxford U niversity Press, 1986. H alp ern , Nina. "Policy C om m unities, Garbage Cans, and the C hinese Economic
BIBL IO GR AP HY
403
Policy Process.” P aper delivered to the annual m eeting of the American Politi cal Science Association, 1987. H am ilton, F. E. Ian. “T he Location of Industry in E ast-C entral and Southeast E u ro p e .” In G eorge W. Hoffman, ed., Eastern Europe: Essays in Geographical Problems. N ew York: Praeger, 1970. ----------. Yugoslavia: Patterns o f Economic Activity. N ew York: Praeger, 1968. H am m el, E u g en e A. The Pink Yo-Yo: Occupational Mobility in Belgrade, ca. 1915-1965 Research Series no. 13. Berkeley: Institute of International Studies, U niversity of California, 1969. Ilankiss, E lem er. “In Search of a P aradigm .” Daedalus 119, no. 1 (W inter 1990): 183-214. H arvey, David. The Limits to Capital. Chicago: U niversity of Chicago Press, 1982. Has, Z denko. “D ruštveno-ekonom ski osvrt na problem nezaposlenosti.” Ekono mist, nos. 3 - 4 (1954): 127-62. ----------. “B orba za poštovanje ugovora o ra d u .” Vjesnik Rada 5, no. 3 (March 1950): 125-27. ----------. “P roces uključivanja radne snage i naši neposredni zadaci.” Vjesnik Rada 5, nos. 1 -2 (J a n u a ry -F e b ru a ry 1950): 26-33. ----------. “D a li su jedinstv eni sindikati državna organizacija? O dnos države i sin dikata u Jugoslaviji,” Vjesnik Rada 1, no. 7 (N ovem ber 1946): 306-9. H attam , Victoria. “E conom ic Visions and Political Strategies: American L abor and th e State, 1865-1896.” U npub. ms. 1988. H auslohner, P eter. “G orbachev’s Social C o n tra c t.” Soviet Economy 3, no. 1 (1987): 5 4 -89. Hawrylyshyn, Oli "E thnic Affinity and M igration Flows in Postwar Yugoslavia.” Economic D evelopm ent and C ultural Change 26, no. 1 (O ctober 1977): 9 3-116. ----------. “Yugoslav D evelopm ent and R ural-U rban Migration: T he E vidence of th e 1961 C e n su s.” In Alan A. Brown and Egon N euberger, eds., Internal Mi gration: A C om parative Perspective. N ew York: Academic Press, 1977. H ayden, R obert M. “L abor C ourts and W orkers’ Rights in Yugoslavia: A Case Study of the C ontradictions of Socialist Legal Theory and Practice. ” Studies in C om parative Communism 18, no. 4 (W inter 1985): 247-60. H eim an n , E duard. “L iterature on the Theory of a Socialist E conom y.” Social Research 6 (1939): 88-113. H e n d erso n , Anne. “T he International M onetary Fund and E astern E urope: T he Politics of Econom ic Stabilization and R eform .” P h.D . diss., D e p a rtm e n t of Political Science, Yale University, 1989. H ew ett, E d A. Reforming the Soviet Economy. W ashington, D .C .: T h e Brookings Institution, 1988. H ibbs, Douglas. “Political Parties and M acroeconomic Policy .’’American Political Science R eview 72, no, 4 (1977): 1467-87. H irsch, F red . Social Limits to G row th C am bridge: H arvard U niversity Press, 1976. H irschm an, A lbert O. The Passions and the Interests: Political Argutnents fo r Capitalism before Its Triumph. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton U niversity Press, 1977. ' ----------. National Power and the Structure o f Foreign Trade. Berkeley and Los Angeles: U niversity of California Press, 1945.
404
B IBL IO GR AP HY
Hoffman, G eorge W. Regional Development Strategy in Southeast Europe: A
Comparative Analysis o f Albania, Bulgaria, Greece, Romania, and Yugoslavia N ew York: Praeger, 1972. Hoffman, G eorge W ., and F re d W arner Neal. Yugoslavia and the New Commu nism. New York: T w en tieth C entury F und, 1962. Hogan, Michael. The Marshall Plan: America, Britain, and the Reconstruction of Western Europe, 1947-1952. C am bridge: C am bridge University Press, 1987. Holjevac, Vjećeslav. “P roblem radne snage: Neka iskustva i/, prvog polugodišta." Vjesnik Rada 5, no. 7 (1950): 289-91. ----------. “P roblem i radne snage." Borba, July 23, 1950. H ondius, Frits W. The Yugoslav Community o f Nations. The Hague: Mouton, 1968. H orvat, Branko. “N eke teze postavljene su naopako.” Izbor 11 (1981): 21ff. ----------. The Yugoslav Economic System. W hite Plains, N.Y.: M. E. Sharpe, 1976. ----------. “Short-R un Instability and Long-Run T rends in the Yugoslav Econom y’s D e v e lo p m e n t.” T ranslated by H elen M Kramer. Eastern European Eco nomics, Fall 1975, pp. 3 -3 1 . Originally published (in Serbo-Croatian) in Ekono mist 14, nos. 1 -2 (1974). ----------. “Yugoslav E conom ic Policy in the Post-W ar Period: Problem s, Ideas, Institutional D e v elo p m en ts.” American Economic Revieiv 61, no. 3 (June 1971): 71-169. ----------. A n Essay on Yugoslav Society. W hite Plains, N. Y.: International Arts and Sciences Press, 1969. H orvat, Branko, and J. M ichael Montias. ‘The Theory of the W orker-M anaged F irm Revisited. "Journal o f Comparative Economics 10, no. 1 (March 1986): 9 25. Special issue on participatory economics. H oston, G erm aine. Marxism and the Crisis o f Development in Prewar Japan. Princeton, N .J.: P rinceton U niversity Press, 1986. H owell, Chris. “T he D ilem m as of Post-Fordism : Socialists, Flexibility, and La b o r M arket D eregulation in F ra n c e .” Politics and Society 20, no. 1 (1992): 71 99. H roch, Miroslav. “H ow M uch D oes Nation Form ation D ep en d on Nationalism?" East European Politics and Societies 4, no. 1 (W inter 1990): 101-15. Ikonić, Branislav. “T he Yugoslav Econom y M arked by Stabilization Efforts and Structural A d ju stm en t.” Review o f International Affairs 23, no. 762 (January 1982): 3 -6 . In stitu te of Agricultural Econom ics and Rural Sociology. The Yugoslav Village. Z agreb, 1972. Internatio n al L abor Office. Employment, Growth, and Basic Needs: A One-World Problem. N ew York: P raeger, 1976. ----------. Legislative Series, 1927. Part 1, International and A D. G eneva, 1930. Irvine, Jill A. “Tito, H ebrang, and the C roat Q uestion, 1943-1944. East Eu ropean Politics and Societies 5, no. 2 (Spring 1991): 306-40 ----------. “State Building and Nationalism: T he C om m unist Party of Yugoslavia and the C ro at Q uestion, 1941 -4 5 .” P h .D . diss., D e p a rtm e n t of G overnm ent, Har vard U niversity, 1989. Isaković, Zlatko. “T he Balkan Armies at the E nd of the Cold War. Unpub. ins. Belgrade, 1993.
B I BL IOGRAP HY
405
Itoh, Makoto. “T he W orld Econom ic Crisis. '’ New Left Review 138 (M arch -A p ril 1983): 9 3 -95. Ivin, D aniel. “Analiza Pregled istorije Saveza K om unista Jugoslavije’ u vezi sa II i III p le n u m o m CK KPJ u 1949 godini.” Putevi Revolucije 2, nos. 3 - 4 (1964). Jahoda, M arie. Employment and Unemployment. C am bridge: C am bridge U n iv er sity Press, 1982. Jahoda, M arie, Paul F. Lazarsfeld, and H ans Zeisel. Marienthah The Sociography o f an Unemployed Community. Chicago and N ew York: Aldine, A therton, 1971. Jakšić, Božidar. “Jugoslovensko društvo izm edju revolucije i stabilizacije.” Praxis 8, nos. 3 - 4 (M ay-A ugust 1971). Janos, Andrew. The Politics o f Backwardness in Historical Perspective: Hungary, 1825-1945. Princeton, N .J.: P rinceton U niversity Press, 1985. Jelčić, Vera. Socijalno pravo: Prava u sistemu socijalnog osiguranja SFRJ. Zagreb: Inform ator, 1982. Jiang, Yiwei. "The T heory of an E nterprise-B ased E co n o m y .” Social Sciences in China 1 (M arch 1980): 4 8-7 0. Johnson, A. Ross. The Transformation o f Communist Ideology: The Yugoslav Case, 1945-1953. C am bridge, Mass., and London: M IT Press, 1972. Johnson, C halm ers A. “T he Nonsocialist NICs: E ast Asia.” International Organi zation 40, no. 2 (Spring 1986): 557-66. ----------. Peasant Nationalism and Communist Power: The Emergence o f Revolu tionary China, 1937-1945. Stanford: Stanford U niversity Press, 1962. Jončić, M ilorad. Ustav SFRJ sa saveznim zakonima koji se i dalje primenjuju. Belgrade: Finansijski Studio, 1971. Jovanov, Neca. “Pledoaje za dijalog o državi u socijalizm u.” Socijalizam 23, nos. 7 - 8 (1980): 79-103. ----------. Radnički štrajkovi u Socijalističkoj Federativnoj Republici Jugoslaviji od 1958. do 1969. godine. Belgrade: Zapis, 1979. Jovanović, D ragoljub. “Političke u sp o m e n e .” U npub. ms. H oover Institution A r chives, Stanford, Calif. Jowitt, K enneth. The Leninist Response to National Dependency. Berkeley: In sti tu te for International Sstudies, U niversity o f California, 1978. ----------. “Inclusion and Mobilization in E uropean L eninist R egim es.” W orld Poli tics 28, no. 1 (O ctober 1975): 69-96. ----------. “An Organizational A pproach to the Study of Political C u ltu re in M arxist L en in ist System s.” American Political Science Review 68, no. 3 (1974): 1171 91. ----------. Revolutionary Breakthroughs and National Development: The Case o f Romania, 1944-1965. Berkeley and Los Angeles: U niversity of California, 1971. Jureša-Persoglio, D jurdja. “N eke značajke socio-ekonomskog položaja n eza poslenih u SRH, te njihova sprem nost za prostornu i profesionalnu m obilnost.” Revija za Sociologiju 10, nos. 3 - 4 (1980): 145-48. K ahler, Miles. “E u ro p ean Protectionism in Theory and P ractice.” W orld Politics 37, no. 4 (July 1985): 475-502. Kalain, R. “Mao Tsc T ung’s ‘B ukharinist’ P hase.” Journal o f Contemporary Asia 14, no. 2 (1984): 147-55.
406
BIBL IO GR AP HY
K alem ber, Dragica. “Siromaštvo i pitanje besposličenja kroz istoriju i u savrem enosti. P h .D . diss., Faculty of Laws, University of Belgrade, 1981. Karcz, Jerzy F. “A gricultural Reform in E astern E u ro p e .” In M orris Bornstein, e d ., Plan and Market: Economic Reform in Eastern Europe. N ew H aven, C onn.: Yale U niversity Press, 1973. Kardelj, E dvard. Problemi naše socijalističke izgradnje. Belgrade: Kultura, 1960. ---------- . Socialism and War: A Survey o f the Chinese Policy o f Coexistence. N ew York: M cG raw -H ill, 1960. ----------. “T h e Struggle for the Fulfillm ent of the First Five Year P lan.” Speech d e liv e red in the national assembly, April 25, 1948. Mimeo. Kaser, M ichael, and E. A. Radice, eds. The Economic History o f Eastern Europe, 1919-1975. Vol. 2, Interw ar Policy, the War, and Reconstruction. Oxford: C laren d o n Press, 1986. Katz, A rnold. G row th and Regional Variations in U nem ploym en t in Yugoslavia, 1965-80. W orking P aper no. 159, D e p a rtm e n t of Economics, U niversity of P ittsburgh, 1983. K atzcnstein, P e te r J. Small States in W orld Markets: Industrial Policy in Europe. Ithaca, N.Y.: C ornell U niversity Press, 1985. ----------. Corporatism and Change: Austria, Switzerland, and the Politics o f In dustry. Ithaca, N.Y., and London: C ornell U niversity Press, 1984. K ertcsi, G abor, and Gyorgy Sziraczki. “T he Institutional System, Labour Market, and Segm entation in H u n g a ry .” In Roger Tarling, e d., Flexibility in Labour Markets. London: H arcourt Brace Jovanovich, Academic Press, 1987. Keyssar, Alexander. Out o f Work: The First Century o f Unemployment in Massa chusetts. C am bridge: C am bridge U niversity Press, 1986. Kidrič, Boris. Socijalizam i ekonomija. Zagreb: Globus, 1979. ----------. O novom finansiskom i planskom sistemu. Belgrade: Rad, 1951. ----------. “E kspoze o Predlogu opštedržavnog budžeta za 1950 g o dinu.” Finansije 5, nos. 1 -2 (J a n u a ry -F e b ru a ry 1950): 3 -1 8 . ----------. “O reorganizaciji državne uprave p riv re d o m .” Komunist 4, nos. 4 -5 (J u ly -S e p te m b e r 1950): 27-32. ----------. Ekspoze povodom pretresa prijedloga općedržavnog budžeta za 1949 (godinu). Mala Ekonom ska Biblioteka, no. 3. Zagreb: Naprijed, 1949. ----------. “E kspoze p retsednika P rivrednog saveta i Savezne planske komisije Bor isa K idriča.” Finansije 4, no. 1 (January 1949). ----------. O tekućim pitanjima naše privredne politike. Zagreb: N aprijed, 1949. ----------. “G ovor na p le n u m u Glavnog odbora Jedinstvenih sindikata” (N ovem ber 16, 1946). R ep rin ted in Privredni problemi FNRJ. Belgrade: Kultura, 1948. ----------. “G ovor na p re tre su opštedržavnog budžeta za 1948 godinu” (April 23, 1948). R ep rin ted in Privredni problemi FNRJ. Belgrade: Kultura, 1948. ----------. O brazloženje osnovnog zakona o državnim privrednim p reduzećim a.” Borba, July 21, 1946. R eprinted in Privredni problemi FNRJ. Belgrade: K ultura, 1948. ----------. “O karakteru naše p riv re d e .” Komunist, no. 1 (O ctober 1946). R eprinted in Privredni problemi FNRJ. Belgrade: Kultura, 1948. ----------. "O vezanim cen am a.” Borba, F eb ru ary 15, 1948. R eprinted in Privredni problemi FNRJ. Belgrade: Kultura, 1948.
B IBL IO GR AP HY
407
----------. “O nekim principijelnim pitanjim a naše p riv re d e .” Komunist 2, no. 2 (January 1947): 45-55. ----------. “O brazloženje nacrta osnovnog zakona o zadrugam a.” In Sabrana dela. Vol. 3. Kimov, D žordži. “Da Ii se povećavaju socijalne razlike?” NIN, N o v em b er 29 1981. Kirschen, E. S. Economic Polici/ in O ur Time. Vol. 1. Chicago: Rand iMcNally 1964. Kitaljević, B. “Istoriska G radja.” Finansije 7, nos. 1 -2 (J a n u a ry -F e b ru a ry 1952)7 6 -9 1 . K itching, Gavin. Development and Underdevelopment in Historical Perspective: Populism, Nationalism, and Industrialization. London and N ew York: iVleth u e n , 1982. Kljaković, Vojmir. “T he Legacy of the Anti-Fascist Council (AVNOJ), 1942 1945.” P aper p re se n te d at conference “W ar, Revolution, and the Early Social ist Period in Yugoslavia: A Historical R etrospective,” Yale U niversity April 1984. ----------. “T he International Significance of the Second Session of AVNOJ." Social ist Thought and Practice 23, no. 12 (1983): 63-76. K night, P eter. Financial Discipline and Structural Adjustment in Yugoslavia: Re habilitation and Bankruptcy o f Loss-making Enterprises. Staff' W orking P ap er no. 705. W ashington, D .C .: W orld Bank, 1984. “Kogod hoće da radi biće zaposlen.” 20 Oktobar, May 18, 1945, p. 4. Komisija Saveznih D ruštvenih Savjeta za P roblem e Ekonom ske Stabilizacije. Po lazne osnove dugoročnog programa ekonomske stabilizacije. 1982. K om unistička Partija Jugoslavije. C entralni Komitet. “U putstvo C.K. K .P.J. o reorganizaciji oblasti.” Komunist 4, nos. 4 - 5 (J u ly -S e p te m b e r 1950): 228-31. Kongres radničkih saveta Jugoslavije, 25-27 juna 1957. Belgrade: Rad, 1957. Kornai, Janos. The Road to a Free Economy: Shiftingfrom a Socialist System: The Example o f Hungary. N ew York: N orton, 1990. . Contradictions and Dilemmas: Studies on the Socialist Economy and So ciety. Budapest: Corvina, 1983. ----------. The Economics o f Shortage. A m sterdam : N orth-H olland, 1980. . R esource-C onstrained vs. D em and-C onstrained S ystem s.” Econometrica 47 (July 1979): 801-19. ' Korošić, M arijan Antiinflaciona politika. Belgrade: Ekonom ski In stitu t and Borba, 1980. Korpi, W alter. The Democratic Class Struggle. London: R outledge and Kegan Paul, 1983. Korpi, W alter, and Michael Shalev. “Strikes, Power, and Politics in the W estern Nations, 1 900-1976.” In M aurice Zeitlin, ed ., Political Power and Social The ory. G reenw ich, C onn.: JAI Press, 1980. Kostić, Cvetko. Seljaci-industriski radnici. Belgrade: Rad, 1955. Kostić-Marojević, Darinka. Promena društvene sredine i promene u porodici: Jedno empirijsko ispitivanje dveju grupa domaćinstava iz Crne Gore. Belgrade: In stitu t D ruštvenih Nauka, 1968. K oštunica, Vojislav, and Košta Čavoški. Party Pluralism or Monism: Social Move-
408
BI BL IOGRAP HY
merits and the Political System in Yugoslavia, 1944-1949. Boulder, C o lo .: East E u ro p ean M onographs, 1985. Kovač, Oskar. Platnobilansna politika Jugoslavije. Belgrade: Institut Ekonom skih Nauka, 1973. Kovać, Oskar, L jubom ir M adžar, Zoran Popov, and D ragoljub Stanišić. Privreda Jugoslavije do 1985. Belgrade: Ekonomika, 1982. Kovačević, Ivan. Ekonomski položaj radničke klase u Hrvatskoj i Slavoniji, 1867 1914. Zagreb: In stitut za Suvrem enu Istoriju i N IP, 1972. Kovačević, M. “P rip rem e za organizaciju oblasnih povereništava rada u NR S rbiji.” Vjesnik Rada 4, no. 4 (April 1949): 121-23. Kraigher, Sergej. “D ohodak preduzeća u našem sistem u.” Naša Stvarnost 7, no. 2 (F eb ru ary 1953): 45-64. Kranjec, Marko. “An Analysis of the Effects of Yugoslav Fiscal Policy in the Light of Som e N ew er Theoretical C o n cep ts.” Eastern European Economics 14, no. 1 (Fall 1975): 3 2-36. * Krstulović, Vicko. “Stalno podizanje proizvodnosti rada poboljšava rad n e i životne uslove radničke klase.” Vjesnik Rada 2, no. 11 (N ovem ber 1947): 699-705. K urbović, Branko. “Polugodišnji rezultati izvršenja planova za 1952.” Ekonomski Pregled 3, no. 4 (1952): 193-201. K urzer, Paulette. “U nem ploym ent in O pen Economies: T he Im pact of Trade, Finance, and E uropean In tegration.” Comparative Political Studies 24, no 1 (April 1991): 3 -3 0 . Laba, Roman. The Roots o f Solidarity: A Political Sociology o f Poland’s WorkingClass Democratization. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1991. Laković, M. “O tkaz u novim odnosim a u p riv red i.” Socijalna Politika 2, no. 7 (July 1952): 421-27. " ' L am pe, John R., Russell O. Prickett, and Ljubiša S. Adamović. YugoslavAmerican Economic Relations since W orld War II. D urham , N .C .: D uke Uni versity Press, 1990. Lam pland, M artha. “W orking through H istory.” P h .D diss. D e p a rtm en t of An thropology, U niversity o f Chicago, 1987. Lane, D avid, ed Labour and Employment in the USSR. Brighton, Sussex: W h ea tsh c af Books, H arvester Press, 1986. Lang, Nicholas R. “T he Dialectics of Decentralization: Econom ic Reform and Regional Inequality in Yugoslavia. ” World Politics 21, no. 3 (April 1975): 309 35. * ' " Lange, B. “Osnovni pokazatelji iskorišćenja fonda radne snage državnih p rivred nih p re d u z e ć a .” Teška Industrija 2, no. 4 (April 1950): 132-40. Lange, Oskar, and F red M. Taylor. O n the Economic Theory o f Socialism. M in neapolis: U niversity of M innesota Press, 1938. Lavignc, Marie. “T he C reation of M oney by the State Bank of the USSR. ” Econ omy and Society 7, no. 1 (February 1978): 29-55. Ledić, M ichele. “D e b t Analysis and D ebt-R elated Issues: T he Case of Yugoslavia.” Economic Analysis and Workers’ Management 18, no. 1 (1984): 3 5 -6 4 . Lee, Bradford A. “T he Miscarriage of Necessity and Invention: Proto Keynesianism and D em ocratic States in the 1930s.” P aper p resen ted at a Social Science R esearch Council conference, H arvard University, 1985.
BIBLIOGRAPHY
409
L eh m b ru c h , G erhard. “L iberal C orporatism and Party G o vernm en t." In P hilippe S chm itter and G erh a rd L eh m b ru ch , eds., Trends tow ard C orporatist Inter mediation. Beverly Hills and London: Sage, 1979. L enin, V ladim ir Il’ich. The Developm ent o f Capitalism in Russia. Moscow: F o r eign Languages Publishing H ouse, 1960. ----------. The State and the Revolution. Moscow: International Publishers, 1943. Les fo rce s armées de la RSFY. Belgrade, 1977. Letica, Slaven. “Pravo na rad i nacrt zakona o udruženom ra d u .” Zapošljavanje i U druženi Rad: Ogledi, Članci, i Rasprava 1, no. 1 (O ctober 1976): 5 2 -5 5 . “L e t’s O rganize th e Struggle o f the U n em ployed.” Proleter 10, no. 1 (January 1934). R eprint, 1968. Belgrade: In stitut za Izučavanje Radničkog Pokreta. Levy, M arion J., Jr. Modernization: Latecomers and Survivors. N ew York: Basic Books, 1972. Lew in, M oshe. Political U ndercurrents in Soviet Economic Debates: From Bukharin to the M odern Reformers. Princeton, N .J.: P rinceton University Press, 1974. Lewis, Paul G. “Political C onsequences of the C hanges in Party-State S tructures u n d e r G ierek .” In Jean W oodall, e d ., Policy and Politics in C ontem porary Po land: Reform, Failure, Crisis. N ew York: St. M artin’s Press, 1982. L indbeck, Assar, and D ennis J. Snower. The Insider-O utsider Theory o f E m ploy m ent and Unemployment. C am bridge: M IT Press, 1988. Livada, Svetozar, and Blažo M. Perović, eds. D ruštvene prom jene u selu. Bel grade: Biblioteka Sociologije Sela, 1974. Livingston, R obert G erald. “Yugoslavian U nem ploym ent T re n d s.” Monthly La b o r R eview (U.S. D e p a rtm e n t of Labor, B ureau of L abor Statistics) 87, no. 7 (July 1964): 756-62. Ljujić, Velibor. “P rim anje u partiji i poboljšavanje socijalnog sastava.” Partiska Izgradnja 1, no. 6 (August 1949): 31-39. L om par, D ušan. “O novom sistem u trgovine.” Narodna D ržava 2, no. 3 (M arch 1948): 10-20. L ôw enthal, Richard. “D evelopm ent vs. U topia in C om m unist Policy.” In C h alm ers Johnson, e d ., Change in Communist Systems. Stanford, Calif.: Stan ford U niversity Press, 1970. Lukač, D ušan, C onka Nikolić, Berislav Šefer, and Rafael Tabor, eds. Ljudski fa k to r u socijalističkoj robnoj privred i samoupravnog društva i problem i zapoš ljavanja. Papers p re s e n te d at conference “T he H um an F actor in a Socialist C om m odity Econom y and Self-Managing Society and the Problem of E m ploy m e n t,” F eb ru ary 11-13, 1969, at the Institute for Political Studies, U niversity o f B elgrade, at th e initiative of th e F ederal Bureau for E m p lo y m en t Affairs. Lydall, H arold. Yugoslav Socialism: Theory and Practice. Oxford: C larendon P ress, 1984. M cCain, R oger A. “T h e Economics of a L abor-M anaged E n terp rise in th e Short Run: An ‘Im plicit C ontracts’ A pproach.” In A dvances in the Economic Analysis o f P articipatory and Labor-M anaged Firms. Vol. 1. G reenw ich, C onn.: JAI Press, 1985. M acesich, G eorge. “M ajor T rends in the Postwar Econom y of Yugoslavia.” In W ayne S. Vucinich, ed., C ontem porary Yugoslavia: Twenty Years o f Socialist Experiment. B erkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press, 1969.
410
BIBL IO GR AP HY
M acesich, G eorge. Yugoslavia: The Theonj and Practice o f Development Plan ning. Charlottesville, Va.: U niversity Press of Virginia, 19G4. ----------. e d ., w ith the assistance of Rikard Lang and D ragom ir Vojnić. Essays on the Yugoslav Economic Model. N ew York: Praeger, 1989. M acura, Miloš. “E m ploym ent Problem s u n d e r D eclining Population Growth Rates and S tructural Change: Case of Yugoslavia, 1952-1958.” International Labour Review 109, nos. 5 - 6 (M ay -Ju n e 1974): 487-501. ----------. Stanovništvo kao činilac privrednog razvoja Jugoslavije. Belgrade: Nolit, 1958. M aier, C harles S. “T he Two Post-W ar Eras and the C onditions for Stability in T w e n tie th -C en tu ry W estern E u ro p e .” American Historical Review 86, no. 2 (April 1981): 327-52. ----------. “T h e Politics of Productivity: Foundations of American International Eco nomic Policy after W orld W ar I I .” In P e te r J. K atzenstein, ed ., Between Power and Plenty: Foreign Economic Policies o f Advanced Industrial States. Madison: U niversity of W isconsin Press, 1978. Malačić, Janez. “U nem ploym ent in Yugoslavia from 1952 to 1975.” Eastern Eu ropean Economics 17, no. 4 (Sum m er 1979): 85-109. ---------- . “Yugoslav Econom ists on U nem ploym ent in Yugoslavia.” Eastern Eu ropean Economics 15, no. 4 (Sum m er 1977): 60-72. Malle, Silvana. The Economic Organization o f W ar Communism, 1918-1921 C am bridge: C am bridge U niversity Press, 1985. M arendić, Božo, Ivan Turčić, and N even Mates. “M jerenje i analiza razvijenosti općina S.R. H rv atsk e.” Ekonomski Pregled 32, nos. 7 - 8 (1981): 291-311. Marić, D ušan. “O problem im a radnih odnosa posle donošenja O snovnog zakona o u p rav ljan ju.” Vjesnik Rada 5, no. 11 (N ovem ber 1950): 427-33. Maričić, Ratko. “N eki problem i organizacije i rada biroa za posredovanje rada.” Socijalna Politika 2, no. 11 (N ovem ber 1952): 662-69. M arković, Branimir. Kretanje narodna dohotka, zaposlenosti, i produktivnosti rada u privredi Jugoslavije, 1947-1967. Belgrade: Savezni Zavod za Statistiku, 1970. M arsenić, D ragutin, and Milovan Pavlović. “Teorijski sporovi o privrednom sis te m u SFRJ: Povodom savetovanja ekonom ista u O hridu [1970].” Ekonomist 24, no. 1 (1971): 76-94. M artin, A ndrew . “T he Politics of E m ploym ent and W elfare in Advanced Capital ist Societies: National Policies and International In te rd e p e n d e n c e .” In Keith Banting, e d ., The State and Economic Interests. Toronto: U niversity of Toronto Press, 1986. M artin, C h ristopher. “Public Policy and Incom e D istribution in Yugoslavia: A C ase of A rrested M arket R eform .” P h.D . diss. D ep a rtm en t of Economics, Uni versity of California at Berkeley, 1986. M arzorati, G erald. “Living and W riting the Peasant Life.” New York Timas Maga zine, N o v em b er 29, 1987, pp. 39, 46, 50, 54. M astnak, Tomaž. “Civil Society in Slovenia: From O pposition to P o w er.” Studies in Comparative Communism 23 (A u tu m n -W in te r 1990): 305-17. M ates, N even. “Inflation in Yugoslavia: Specific Form of Public Deficit Caused by Parafiscal O perations of the C entral B ank.” U npub. ins. Zagreb, 1990. ---------- . “M easu rem en t of G o v ern m en t B udget Deficit, Losses of C entral Banks,
BIB L IOGRAPHY
411
an d th e Im p act o f A ggregate Deficit of the Public Sector on Inflation.” U npub. ms. Z agreb, 1989. ----------. “R ecent T endencies in the Regulation of Incom e D istribution in E n te r p rise s.” In G. Macesich, e d ., Essays on the Yugoslav Economic Model. N ew York: P raeger, 1989. Matovič, M. “Sam ouprava u socijalnom osiguranju.” Socijalna Politika 2, no. 7 (July 1952): 428-32. M eade, Jam es E . “L abour-M anaged Firm s in C onditions of Im perfect C o m p eti tio n .” Economic Journal 84, (D ecem b er 1974): 817-24. ---------- . “T he T heory of L abour-M anaged F irm s and of Profit-sharing.” Economic Journal 82 (M arch 1972): 402-28. M eek, Ronald L. Study in the Labor Theory o f Value. 2d ed. N ew York and London: M onthly Review Press, 1956. "M e m o ran d um SANU: G ru p a akadem ika Srpske akadem ije nauka i u m etnosti o aktuelnim društvenim pitanjim a u našoj zem lji.” Duga (Belgrade), special issue, Ju n e 1989, pp. 19-47. M encinger, Jože. “P rivredna reform a i nezaposlenost.” Privredna Kretanja Jug oslavije, M arch 1989, pp. 23-39. ---------- . The Yugoslav Economy: Systemic Changes, 1945—1985. T h e Carl Beck P apers in Russian and E ast E uropean Studies, no. 707. Pittsburgh: U niversity of P ittsb u rgh, C e n te r for Russian and E ast E uropean Studies, 1989. --------- “K o m entar” [on L jubom ir M adžar proposals], Ekonomska Politika, no. 1829 (April 20, 1987): 28-29. ---------- . “O tvorena nezaposlenost i zaposleni bez posla. ” Privredna Kretanja Jug oslavije 128 (April 1983). ---------- . “Utjecaj priv red n e aktivnosti n a zaposlenost i efekti m jera za zapoš ljavanje na stabilizaciju.” Ekonomski Pregled 27, nos. 11 -1 2 (1976): 829 37. M esa-Lago, C arm elo. “U nem ploym ent in a Socialist Economy: Yugoslavia.” In dustrial Relations 10, no. 1 (F ebruary 1971): 49-69. M ežnarić, Silva. “A Neo-M arxist A pproach to the Sociology of Nationalism: A Q u est for T h eo ry .” C olloquium p ap e r p re se n ted to the W oodrow Wilson C e n ter, Sm ithsonian Institution, W ashington, D .C ., July 24, 1984. L ater pub lish ed as “A N eo-M arxist A pproach to the Sociology of Nationalism, D oom ed Nations, and D o om ed S chem es.” Praxis International 7, no. 1 (1987): 79-89. Mihailovič, Kosta. Ekonomska stvarnost Jugoslavije. 2d ed. Belgrade: Ekonomika, 1982. M ihovilović, M iro A., e t al. Zena izmedju rada i porodice: Utjecaj zaposlenosti žene na strukturu i funkciju porodice. Zagreb: In stitut za D ru štv en a Istra živanja Sveučilišta u Z agrebu, 1975. Milanovič, Branko. “T h e L abor-M anaged F irm s in the Short-Run: C o m m en ts on H o rv at’s ‘T heory of the W orker-M anaged F irm R evisited .” P ap er p re s e n te d to Yale U niversity C olloquium on Participatory Economics and Politics, May 3 -4 , 1985. ---------- . “T h e A ustrian T heory of the C ooperative F irm .” Journal o f Comparative Economics 6 (1982): 379-95. M ilenkovitch, D eb o rah Duff. Plan and Market in Yugoslav Economic Thought. N ew H aven, C onn.: Yale U niversity Press, 1971.
412
BIBL IOGRAPHY
M ilenović, M iodrag. “U nutrašnje migracije i m edjurepubličko zapošljavanje.” Socijalna Politika 33, no. 3 (M arch 1978): 25-29. Miljovski, Kiril. “N eke ekonom ske, paraekonom ske i neekonom ske pretpostavke p riv red n o g razvoja.” Scientia Yugoslavica 8, nos. 1 -2 (1982): 65-81. ----------. “Possibilities for the D evelopm ent of U nderdeveloped A reas.” In Rad mila Stojanović, e d ., Yugoslav Economists on Problems o f a Socialist Economy. N ew York: International Arts and Sciences Press, 1964, M iller, R o b ert F. “Socialism and A griculture in Yugoslavia.” P ap er p rese n te d to the 21st conference of the Australasian Political Studies Association, Australian N ational U niversity, C anberra, 1979. ----------. External Factors in Yugoslav Political Development. Occasional P aper no. 14. D e p a rtm e n t of Political Science, Research School of Social Sciences, A ustralian National U niversity, C anberra, 1977. M ilward, Alan. The Reconstruction o f Western Europe, 1945-51. Berkeley and Los Angeles: U niversity of California Press, 1984. Mirić, Jovan. Sistem i kriza. Zagreb: C ekade, 1984. Mirić, Milan. Rezervati. Zagreb: Razlog, 1970. Mirković, Nicholas, ed Jugoslav Postwar Reconstruction Papers. 3 vols. New York: Office o f R econstruction and Econom ic Affairs, G o v ern m en t of Ju g oslavia, 1943. M iroljub, Hadzic. The Wage-Push Inflation in Yugoslavia. W orking P ap er Series no. 67. T he Hague: In stitute of Social Studies, 1989. M itrany, D avid. Marx against the Peasant: A Study in Social Dogmatism. C hapel Hill: U niversity of N orth Carolina Press, 1951. M ladek, J. V., E. Šture, and M. R. Wyczalkowski. “T he C hange in the Yugoslav E conom ic S ystem .” International Monetary Fund S ta ff Papers 2, no. 3 (No v e m b e r 1952): 407-38. M ontias, John Michael. "Econom ic Reform and R etreat in Jugoslavia.” Foreign Affairs 37, no. 2 (January 1959): 293-305. M oore, John H. Groioth with Self-Management: Yugoslav Industrialization, 1952-1975. Stanford, Calif.: H oover Institution Press, 1980. M orača, Pero. lstoriia Saveza Komunista ¡ugoslavije: Kratak pregled. 2d ed. Bel grade: Rad, 1966. M orawetz, David. “E m ploym ent Im plications of Industrialization in D eveloping C ountries: A Survey. ” Economic Journal 84 (S eptem ber 1974): 491-542. Moses, Joel C. “W orker Self-M anagem ent and the Reformist A lternative in Soviet L abor Policy, 1979-1985.” Soviet Studies 39, no. 2 (April 1987): 205-28. M ucciaroni, Gary. The Political Failure o f Employment Policy , 1945-1982. Pitts burgh: U niversity of P ittsburgh Press, 1990. Mugoša, Dragiša. “O dnosi Jugoslavije i SAD-a izm edju 1945 i 1949.” M aster’s thesis, Faculty of Law, U niversity of Belgrade, 1982. M ulec, J., and M. Glišić. “P roblem radne snage u metalurgiji i ru d arstv u .” Narodna Država 1, no. 2 (N ovem ber 1946): 107-10. M ulina, Tripo. Nezaposlenost, uzroci i karakteristike u sadašnjoj fa zi razvoja pri vrede. Studije i Saopštenja no. 3, Belgrade: Ekonomski Institut, 1968. M ulina, T ., M. M acura, and M. Rašević. Stanovništvo i zaposlenost u dugoroč nom razvoju Jugoslavije. Belgrade: Ekonom ski Institut, 1981.
BIBL IOGRAPHY
413
M ustabegović, E jub, Jelisava Jankelović, and Šefik Bajramović. “U ključenje ra d n e snage u privredi u Zeničkom sre z u .” Partiska Izgradnja 1, no. 4 (April 1949): 2 8 -31. M yers, Paul F ., and A rthur A. C am pbell. The Population o f Yugoslavia. U.S. B ureau of L abor Statistics, International Population Statistics R eports, ser. P-90, no. 5. W ashington, D .C .: U.S. G o v ern m en t P rinting Office, 1954. Naljeva, Mara. “N eka pitanja partiskog rada m edju ženam a.” Partiska Izgradnja 2, no. 1 (January 1950). N arodna Skupština FNRJ. See Yugoslavia. N arodni F ro n t Jugoslavije. Drugi kongres Narodnog fron ta Jugoslavije. Belgrade, 1947. “N e postoji pravo na ra d .” Ekonomska Politika, no. 885 (March 17, 1966): 14-15. Nešović, Slobodan. Privredna politika i ekonomske mere u toku oslobodilačke borbe naroda Jugoslavije. Belgrade: Privredni Pregled, 1964. “N ew E conom ic C o u rse .” Yugoslav Review 5, nos. 8 - 9 (O cto b e r-N o v e m b e r 1955): 8 -1 2 . "N ew W ays of Yugoslav E conom y.” Yugoslav Review 5, nos. 8 - 9 (O c to b e rN o v e m b e r 1955): 3, 12-13. Nikolić, Miloje. “Politika zapošljavanja. ” Socijalna Politika, July 20, 1968, pp. 6 -9 . Nikolić, Miodrag. “Rast produktivnosti rada u Jugoslaviji.” Statistički Dokumenti 1, no. 8 (1976): 14-21. N ishim izu, Mieko, and John M. Page, Jr. “Total Factor Productivity G row th, Technological Progress, and Technical Efficiency Change: D im ensions of P ro ductivity C hange in Yugoslavia, 1965-1978. ” Economic Journal 92 (D ecem b er 1982): 920-36. Noel, Alain. “Accumulation, Regulation, and Social Change: An Essay on F ren ch Political E conom y.” International Organization 41, no. 2 (Spring 1987): 303 33. “T h e N on-A gricultural Population.” Yugoslav Survey 28, no. 3 (1987). Nove, Alec. The Economics o f Feasible Socialism. London: Allen and Unwin, 1983. ---------- . A n Economic History o f the U.S.S.R. London: Penguin, 1969. O ’D onnell, G uillerm o. Modernization and Bureaucratic-Authoritarianism: Studies in South American Politics. Berkeley: Institute of International Studies, U niversity of California, 1973. Offe, Claus. “Capitalism by D em ocratic D esign? D em ocratic T heory Facing the T riple T ransition in East C entral E u ro p e .” Social Research 58, no. 4 (W inter 1991): 865-92. ---------- . “T h ree Perspectives on the Problem of U nem ploym ent. ” In Disorganized Capitalism: Contemporary Transformations o f Work and Politics. E d ited by John K eane. C am bridge: M IT Press, 1985. ----------. “Two Logics of Collective Action.” In Disorganized Capitalism. ---------- . “T h e F u tu re of the Labor M ark et.” Telos, no. 60 (Sum m er 1984): 8 1 -9 6 . Oleszczuk, Thomas. “G roup C hallenges and Ideological D e-radicalization in Yugoslavia.” Soviet Studies 32, no. 4 (O ctober 1980): 561-79. O lson, M ancur. The Logic o f Collective Action. C am bridge: H arvard U niversity Press, 1965.
414
BIBL IO GR AP HY
Osmi kongres SKJ. Belgrade, 1965. Panić, M iodrag Lj. “R adna snaga i zaposlenost u Jugoslaviji.” P h.D . điss., Faculty of Laws, U niversity of Belgrade, 1987. P arm alee, D onna E. “M edicine u n d e r Yugoslav Self-Managing Socialism.” P h.D . diss. D e p a rtm e n t o f Sociology, U niversity of N orth Carolina, 1983 Pašić, N ajdan, and Kiro H adži Vasilev. “K omunistička partija Jugoslavije— 19454 8 .” In Pregled istorije Saveza Komunista Jugoslavije. Belgrade: In stitu t za Izučavanje Radničkog Pokreta, 1963. Pavlovič, Milenko. “E m ploym ent in the Socialized Sector, 1979-1984.” Yugoslav Survey 26, no. 3 (1985): 11. Pavlovič, Mirjana. “Boris Kidrič o principim a tržišne ekonom ije i višku radne sn ag e.” Gledišta 13, no. 9 (S eptem ber 1972): 1185-92. Pejnović, M laden. “SSO i stabilizacija.” Pitanje 11 (August 1979): 4 -5 . Perič, Aleksandar. “D ruštveni prihodi i rashodi u F N R J.” In Priručnik za ekonomiku FNRJ. Belgrade: Rad, 1958. Perišin, Ivo. “T he Banking System and M onetary Policy.” In Rikard Lang, G eorge M acesich, and D ragom ir Vojnič, eds., Essays on the Political Economy o f Yugoslavia. Zagreb: Ekonom ski Institut, 1982. Pešakovič, M ilentije. “Niško savetovanje ekonom ista Srbije, 1963 i d an as.” Ekonomska Misao 13, no. 1 (M arch 1980): 145-48. Pešič, Ratko. Radno pravo Belgrade: Naučna Knjiga, 1966. ----------. “M aterijalno obezbedjenje radnika i službenika za vrem e privrem enog p restan k a radnog odnosa.” Socijalna Politika 2, no. 5 (May 1952): 304-11. ----------. “O ugovorim a o ra d u .” Vjesnik Rada 4, nos. 1 -2 (Ja n u a ry -F e b ru a ry 1949): 14-19. ' Pešič, V. “Za p o tp u n o i blagovrem eno izvršenje plana radne snage u N.R. Srbiji.” Partiska Izgradnja 1, no. 4 (April 1949): 73-77. Peti kongres Saveza sindikata Jugoslavije. Belgrade: Rad, 1964. Petranović, Branko. Revolucija i kontrarevolucija u Jugoslaviji (1941-1945). Vol. 2. Belgrade: Rad, 1983. ----------. Politička i ekonomska osnova narodne vlasti u Jugoslaviji za vreme ob nove. Belgrade: In stitut za Savrem enu Istoriju, 1969. ----------. “N arodna vlast u periodu adm inistrativnog rukovodjenja p riv re d o m .” In Pregled posleratnog razvitka Jugoslavije. Belgrade: Zavod za Izdavanje U džbenika Socijalističke R epublike Srbije, 1966. Petranović, Branko, Ranko Končar, and Radovan Radonjič, eds. Sednice Central nog komiteta KPJ (1948-1952). Izvori za Istoriju SKJ, ser. A, vol. 2, no. 2. Belgrade: K om unist, 1985. Petranović, Branko, and Momčilo Zečević. Jugoslavija, 1918-1988: Tematska zbirka dokumenata. Belgrade: Rad, 1988. P etrin , Tea. “T he Potential of Small-Scale Industry for E m p lo y m en t in Yugoslavia. ” Economic Analysis and W orkers’ Management 12, nos. 3 - 4 (1978): 347-63. Petrovič, D. “Prelazim o od starog na novo.” Partiska Izgradnja 1, no. 4 (April 1949): 3 2 -3 5 . ’ Petrovič, Vojislav J. Razvitak privrednog sistema FNRJ posmatran kroz pravne propise. 5 vols. Belgrade: Ekonomski Institut FNRJ, 1955-57.
BIBL IOGRAPHY
415
Piore, M ichael J. “Historical P erspectives and th e Inte rp re ta tio n of U nem ploy m e n t.” Journal o f Economic Literature 25 (D e ce m b e r 1987): 1834-1850. ----------. Unemployment and Inflation: Institutionalist and Structuralist Views. W h ite Plains, N.Y.: M. E. Sharpe, 1979. Piore, M ichael J., and C harles F. Sabel. The Second Industrial Divide: Possi bilities f o r Prosperity. N ew York: Basic Books, 1984. Pjanić, Zoran. Problem stanovništva u ekonomskoj teoriji. Belgrade: Nolit, 1957. Pleskovič, Boris, and M arjan Dolenc. “Regional D evelopm ent in a Socialist, D e veloping, and M ultinational C ountry: T he Case of Yugoslavia.” International Regional Science R eview 7, no. 1 (1982): 1-24. Polanyi, Karl. The G reat Transformation. Boston: Beacon Press, 1957. Originally pu b lish ed 1944. Polovina, Svetislav. "Ciljevi i perspektive zapošljavanja.” Revija za Sociologiju 10, nos. 3 - 4 (1980): 149-51. Pop-Antoška, Hristina. “Podaci o licima koja traže zaposlenje u Jugoslaviji.” Sta tistička Revija 26, nos. 1 -2 (1976): 122-33. Portes, Richard. “C entral Planning and M onetarism : Fellow T ravelers?” In P ad m a Desai, e d ., Marxism, C en tral Planning, and the Soviet Economy: Eco nomic Essays in H onor o f Alexander Erlich. C am bridge: M IT Press, 1980. “P o treb n o je iskoristiti unutrašnje rezerve koje postoje na našim železnicam a.” Narodna D rža va 2, nos. 4 - 5 (A p ril-May 1948): 70-76. “Povodom ukidanja u re d b e o ustaljivanju radne snage.” Socijalna Politika 2, nos. 2 - 3 (F e b ru a ry -M a rc h 1952): 163-65. Prašnikar, Janes. “T he Yugoslav Self-managed Firm and Its B ehavior.” Eastern European Economics. 22, no. 2 (W inter 1983-84): 3 -4 3 . Pravda, Alex. “Poland 1980: From ‘P rem ature C o nsum erism ’ to L abor Solidarity.” Soviet Studies 34, no. 2 (April 1982): 167-99. ----------. “E ast-W est In te rd e p e n d e n c e and the Social C om pact in E astern E u ro p e .” In M orris B ornstein, Zvi G itelm an, and William Z im m erm an, eds., East-W est Relations and the Future o f Eastern Europe: Politics and Economics. London: Allen and Unwin, 1981. “P rerad a metala: Strah od neizvesnosti.” Ekonomska Politika, April 12, 1982, 13. Pribičević, Branko. Sukob Komunističke partije Jugoslavije i Kominforma. B el grade: K om unist, 1972. Prim orac, Em il, and M ate Babić. “Systemic C hanges and U nem p lo y m en t G row th in Yugoslavia, 1965-1985.” Slavic R eview 48, no. 2 (S um m er 1989): 195-213. Prim orac, Em il, and M. F. C h arette. “Regional Aspects of Youth U nem p loy m en t in Yugoslavia.” Economic Analysis and W orkers’ Management 21, no. 2 (1987): 193-220. " Prim orac, E m il, and P. A. D ella Valle. “U nem ploym ent in Yugoslavia: Some S tructural and Regional C onsiderations.” Jahrbuch d er W irtschaft Osteuropas 5, no. 2 (1974): 455-87. Privreda FNRJ, 1957. Belgrade: Ekonom ski In stitut FN R J, 1958. Privreda FNRJ u periodu 1947-1956. Belgrade: Ekonom ski In stitu t FNRJ, 1957. Przew orski, Adam. Democracy and the Market: Political and Economic Reforms in Eastern Europe and Latin America. C am bridge: C am bridge U niversity Press, 1991.
416
BIB LIO GRAPHY
Przew orski, Adam. Capitalism and Social Democracy Cam bridge: Cambridge U niversity Press, 1985. Puljiz, Vlado. Eksodus poljoprivrednika. Zagreb: Biblioteka Sociologije Sela, 1977. Pusić, Vesna. “Uloga kolektivnog odlučivanja u realizaciji radničkih interesa.” P h .D . diss., Faculty of Political Science, University of Zagreb, 1984 P u tterm a n , Louis. “S elf-M anagem ent and the Yugoslav E conom y.” Journal of Comparative Economics 10, no. 1 (March 1986). Radmilović, Jerko. “Karakter službe posredovanja rada i pitanje njene reor g anizacije.” Vjesnik Rada 3, no. 1 (January 1948): 10-13. Radonjič, Radovan. Sukob KPJ s Kominformom i društveni razvoj Jugoslavije, 1948—1950. Zagreb: C en tar za K ulturnu djelatnost S.S.O. Zagreba, 1979. Radovanovič, Miroslav. “Različita shvatanja uzroka i oblika nezaposlenosti.” Zapošljavanje i Udruženi Rad: Ogledi, Članci, i Rasprava 1, no. 1 (October 1976): 4 4 -5 5 . ----------. “O snovne karakteristike položaja nezaposlenih i shvatanje je d n e grupe n ezap o slen ih .” Gledišta 9, no. 2 (February 1968): 246-58. ----------. “Socijalno-psihološke posledice nezaposlenosti.” Gledišta 9, no. 4 (April 1968): 581-87. Radovanovič, R. “Ukidanje poreza na dohodak radnika, nam eštenika i službenika— Nov doprinos socijalističkoj privredi i pravilnom nagradjivanju ” Narodna Država 4, no. 5 (May 1950): 50 -5 2 . R am et, P edro “Apocalypse C u ltu re and Social C hange in Yugoslavia.” In Pedro R am et, e d ., Yugoslavia in the 1980s. Boulder, Colo.: W estview Press, 1985 ----------. Nationalism and Federalism in Yugoslavia, 1963-1983. Bloomington: In diana U niversity Press, 1984. Rankovič, Aleksandar. “R eferat o sindikalnom p itan ju .” In Peta zemaljska kon ferencija KPJ. Belgrade: Komunist, 1980. Rašević, M ., T. M ulina, and M. Macura. The Determinants o f Labour Force Participation in Yugoslavia. C eneva: International Labour Office, 1978. “R aspored stručnjaka treba pravilno izvršiti.” 20 Oktobar, April 20, 1945, p. 2 “Rates of E m p lo y m en t and U nem ploym ent, 1980-1987.” Yugoslav Survey 29, no 4 (1988): 27-42. Rawin, Solomon John. “M anagem ent and A utonom y in Socialist Ind u stry — The Yugoslav E x p erien ce.” Jahrbuch der Wirtscluift Osteuropas 4 (1973): 351-67. R em ington, Robin. “Yugoslavia.” In Richard F. Staar, e d., Yearbook on Interna tional Communist Affairs. Stanford, Calif. : H oover Institution Press, 1988. “Rise in E m ploym ent, 1957 -6 0 .” Yugoslav Survey 2, no. 2 (A pril-June 1961): 6 4 7 -5 9 , 793-802. Rivers, Douglas. “M icro-Econom ics and M acro-Politics.” U npub. ms., D e p a rt m e n t of Political Science, Stanford University, 1987. Robinson, Joan. “T he Soviet Collective Farm as a P roducer C ooperative: C om m e n t.” American Economic Review 57, no. 1 (March 1967): 222-23. R obinson, S herm an, and Laura D ’A ndrea Tyson. “Foreign Trade, Resource Al location, and Structural A djustm ent in Yugoslavia: 1976-1980 ” Journal of Comparative Economics 9 (1985): 46-70. R oem er, John. Free to Lose. C am bridge: H arvard U niversity Press, 1988,
B I BL IOGRAP HY
417
R oem er, Michael. “D e p en d en c e and Industrialization S trategies.” W o rld D evel opm ent 9, no. 5 (1981): 429-34. Roksandić, Drago. Srbi u H rvatskoj o d 15. stoljeća do naših dana. Zagreb: Vjesnik, 1991. R6na-Tas, Àkos. “T h e Second Econom y in H ungary: T he Social O rigins of the E n d of State Socialism.” P h .D . diss., U niversity of M ichigan, 1990. R osenblum -Č ale, K aren. “A ppropriation Politics: C onsensus-B uilding and C onflict-M anagem ent in M ostar C om m une, 1965-1969.” U npub. ms. 1977. R othschild, Joseph. East Central Europe between the Two W orld W ars. Seattle: U niversity of W ashington Press, 1974. Rucciardi, Joseph. "R ereading Marx on th e Role of M oney and F inance in E co nom ic D evelopm ent: Political Perspectives on C red it from the 1840s and 1850s.” Research in Political Economy 10 (1987): 61-81. Rusinow, D ennison. Review o f Die Kooperation zwischen den privaten Land
wirtschaftsbetrieben und den gesellschaftlichen Wirtschaftsorganisationen in der Landwirtschaft Jugoslawiens by Ivan Lončarević. Slavic R eview 36, no. 4 (S e p tem b e r 1977): 527-28. ---------- . The Yugoslav Experiment, 1948-1974. Berkeley and Los Angeles: U n i versity of California Press, 1977. Sabel, C harles, and D avid Stark. “Politics, Planning, and Shop-Floor Power: H id d en F o rm s o f Bargaining in Soviet-Im posed State-Socialist Societies.” Politics and Society 11, no. 4 (1982): 439-75. Sacks, S te p h e n R. Self-Management and Efficiency: Large C orporations in Yugoslavia. London: Allen and U nwin, 1983. ---------- . E n try o f N ew C om petitors in Yugoslav Market Socialism. Berkeley: In sti tu te o f In ternational Studies, U niversity of California, 1973. Sapir, A ndré. “E conom ic Reform and M igration in Yugoslavia: An E conom etric M o d el.” Journal o f Developm ent Economics 9 (1981): 149-87. Savez k om unista Jugoslavije. Borba komunista Jugoslavije za socijalističku demokratiju. Belgrade: Kultura, 1952. Savezni D ru štveni Savet. Dugoročni program stabilizacije. Belgrade, 1984. Savezni Zavod za Statistiku. Uputstvo za sprovodjenje izveštaja o zaposlenom oso blju. M etodološki M aterijali no. 96. Belgrade, 1958. ----------. Uputstva za polugodišnji izveštaj o zaposlenom osoblju (M etod i način sprovodjenja). M etodološki M aterijali no. 39. Belgrade, 1954. Scharpf, F ritz W. “Econom ic and Institutional C onstraints o f F u ll-E m p lo y m en t Strategies: Sw eden, Austria, and W est G erm any, 1973-1982.” In John H. G old th o rp e, e d ., O rd e r and Conflict in Contem porary Capitalism. Oxford: C laren d o n Press, 1984. S chierup, Carl. “Q uasi-Proletarians and Patriarchal Bureaucracy: A spects of Yugoslavia’s R eperipheralisation.” Soviet Studies 44, no. 1 (January 1992): 79 99. Schlozm an, Kay L ehm an, and Sidney Verba. Injury to Insult: Unemployment, Class, and Political Response. C am bridge: H arvard U niversity Press, 1979. Schrenk, M artin, C yrus Ardalan, and Nawal A. E l Tatawy. Yugoslavia: Self Management Socialism a n d the Challenges o f Development. Baltimore: Johns H opkins U niversity Press for the W orld Bank, 1979.
418
BIB LIO GRAPHY
S ch u m p e te r, Joseph A. “T he Crisis of th e T ax-State.” In Alan T. Peacock, Wolf gang F. Stolper, R alph Turvcy, and Elizabeth H enderson, eds., International Economic Papers, no. 4. L ondon and N ew York: Macmillan, 1954. S churm ann, Franz. Ideology and Organization in Communist China. Berkeley and Los Angeles: U niversity of California Press, 1966. Schw artz, H erm an. “Can O rthodox Stabilization and A djustm ent W ork? Lessons from N ew Zealand, 1 9 8 4 -9 0 .” International Organization 45, no. 2 (Spring 1991): 221-56. Scott, H ilda. “W hy the Revolution D oesn’t Solve E ve ry th in g .” W o m en s Studies International Forum 5, no. 5 (1982): 451-62. Scott, Jam es C. The M oral Economy o f the Peasant: Rebellion and Subsistence in South-East Asia. N ew H aven, C onn.: Yale U niversity Press, 1976. Scriven, John G raham . “Yugoslav Business O perations: D istribution of Incom e and Taxation.” P h .D . diss., C am bridge U niversity, 1981. Selznick, Philip. The Organizational Weapon: A Study o f Bolshevik Strategy and Tactics. N ew York: M cG raw -Hill, 1952. Sen, A m artya K. Em ployment, Technology, and Development. Study p rep ared for th e Intern atio nal L abour Office. Oxford: C larendon Press, 1975. Seroka, Jim. Change and Reform o f the League o f Communists in Yugoslavia. The C arl Beck Papers in Russian and E ast E uropean Studies, no. 704. Pittsburgh: U niversity o f P ittsburgh, C e n te r for Russian and E ast E uropean Studies, 1990. Seroka, Jim, and Radoš Smiljković. Political Organizations in Socialist Yugoslavia. D urham , N .C .: D uke University Press, 1986. Sesardić, D ražen. “Značaj reorganizacije narodnih o dbora.” Narodna D ržava 3, no. 1 (January 1949): 19-32. Šesti Kongres S.S.J. Belgrade: Radnička Štampa, 1968. Shanin, T eodor, ed. Late Marx and the Russian Road: Marx and the Peripheries o f Capitalism. London: R outledge and Kegan Paul, 1984. Shapiro, Ian, and John Kane. “Stagflation and the N ew R ight.” Telos, no. 56 (S u m m er 1983): 5 -3 9 . Shapiro, Ju d ith A. “N E P U nem ploym ent: A Failure for M arket Socialism?” U n p u b . ms. 1987. ----------. “U n em p loym ent from Tsarism to N E P. ” U npub. ms. University of Lon don, G old sm ith’s College, Birm ingham , E ngland, 1987. Shonfield, Andrew. Modern Capitalism. Oxford: Oxford U niversity Press, 1965. Shoup, Paul. Communism and the Yugoslav National Question. N ew York and London: C olum bia U niversity Press, 1968. Sicherl, Pavle. A D ynamic Analysis o f Regional Disparities in Yugoslavia. Incom e D istribution and E m ploym ent Program m e, W orking P aper no. 84. Geneva: Intern atio nal L abour Organization, 1980. ----------. “Značaj zaposlenosti u našim uslovima. ” Ekonomski Pregled 27, nos. 11 12 (1976): 897-903. ----------. “T im e-D istance as a D ynam ic M easure of Disparities in Social and Eco nom ic D e v e lo p m e n t.” Kyklos 3 (1973). Singleton, F red , and B ernard C arter. The Economy o f Yugoslavia. N ew York: St. M artin ’s Press, 1982. Sirianni, C arm en. W orkers’ C ontrol and Socialist Democracy: The Soviet Experi ence. London: Verso, 1982
BIBL IOGRAPHY
419
Škrbić, P. “M anjak— četiri m ilijarde.” Borba, O ctober 29, 1982. Slider, D arrell. “T h e Brigade System in Soviet Industry: An Effort to R estructure th e L ab o u r F o rc e .” Soviet Studies 39, no. 3 (July 1987): 388-405. Sm ith, S tep h en C. “D oes E m ploym ent M atter to the Labour-M anaged F irm ? Som e T heory and an E m pirical Illustration.” Economic Analysis and W orkers’ Management. 18, no. 4 (1984): 303-18. Solinger, D orothy. Chinese Business under Socialism: The Politics o f Domestic Commerce 1949-1980. Berkeley and Los Angeles: U niversity of California Press, 1986. “Some Basic F eatu res of Yugoslav E xternal M igration.” Yugoslav Survey 13, no. 1 (F eb ru ary 1972): 1-9. Šošic, H rvoje. Z a čiste račune: Banke, Genex, Reeksporteri. Zagreb: Matica Hrvatska, 1970. Šoškić, Branislav. “E konom ska politika zaposlenosti i zapošljavanja u Jugoslaviji.” Ekonomski Pregled 27, nos. 9 -1 0 (1976): 625-50. ---------- . “Tržišni sistem socijalističke privrede i reform a.” Ekonomska Misao 1, no. 3 (S ep te m b er 1968): 519-23. Spasojević, Nebojša. “Kako je partiska organizacija Tuzlanske oblasti izvršila zadatak uključenja radne snage u ru d a rstv u .” Partiska Izgradnja 1, nos. 9 -1 0 (S e p te m b e r-O c to b e r 1949): 53-56. Staniszkis, Jadwiga. Poland’s Self-limiting Revolution. Princeton, N .J.: Princeton U niversity Press, 1987. Stark, David. “C oexisting O rganizational Form s in H ungary’s E m erging Mixed E co n o m y .” In Victor N ee and David Stark, eds., Remaking the Economic Insti tutions o f Socialism: China and Eastern Europe. Stanford: Stanford U niversity Press, 1989. Stigler, G eorge J. “T he T heory o f Econom ic R egulation.” In The Citizen and the State: Essays on Regulation. Chicago: U niversity of Chicago Press, 1975. Stojanović, Radmila, ed. Yugoslav Economists on Problems o f a Socialist Econ omy. N ew York: International Arts and Sciences Press, 1964. Stojanović, Slavko. "Karakteristike i specifičnosti problem a zaposlenosti i zapoš ljavanja stanovništva na području Slavonije i B aranje.” Revija za Sociologiju 10, nos. 3 - 4 (1980): 139-44. Stojanovski, Jovan. Privredni sistem i nedovoljno razvijene republike i SAP Ko sovo. Skopje: Ekonom ski In stitut U niverziteta “Kiril i M etodij,” 1979. S treissler, E rich W. “W hat Kind of Econom ic Liberalism May W e Expect in ‘E a ste rn ’ E u ro p e?” East European Politics and Societies 5, no. 1 (W inter 1991): 195-201. Stupar, Mihailo. Praktikum za socijalnu politiku. Belgrade: N aučna Knjiga, 1967. Sugar, P e te r E. The Industrialization o f Bosnia-Hercegovina, 1878-1918. Seattle: U niversity of W ashington Press, 1963. Sutela, Pekka. “Ideology as a M eans of Econom ic D ebate, or the Strange Case of O bjective Econom ic Laws of Socialism. ” Jahrbuch der Wirtschaft Osteuropas 13, no. 1 (1989): 198-220. Šuvar, Stipe. “Plave i bele k ragne.” NIN, F ebruary 28, 1982, pp. 14-16. Szporluk, Roman Communism and Nationalism: Karl Marx versus Friedrich List. N ew York: Oxford U niversity Press, 1988. Tajnikar, Maks. “T he C oexistence of M arket and Plan in the D ev elo p m en t of
420
B IBL IOGRAP HY
Yugoslav E conom ic T h o u g h t.” Eastern European Economics 16, no. 1 (Fall 1977): 74-101. Tanić, Živan. “Yugoslavia.” In Ronald E. Krane, ed ., International Labor Migra tion in Europe. N ew York: Praeger, 1979. Tarschys, D aniel. “C u rbing Public E xpenditure: C u rre n t T re n d s.” Journal o f Public Policy 5, pt. 1 (February 1985): 23-68. Taševski, Bojan. “Samovoljno napuštanje posla— osnov za prestanak radnog od n osa.” Vjesnik Rada 4, nos. 1 -2 (Ja n u a ry -F e b ru a ry 1949): 4 -2 9 . T h e rb o rn , G oran. W h y Some Peoples A re More Unemployed than Others: The Strange Paradox o f G row th and Unemployment. London: Verso, 1986. T hom as, H endrik. “Personal Incom e D istribution in Yugoslavia: A H um an C api tal A pproach to the Analysis of Personal Incom e Differences in the Industry o f a L abor-M anaged M arket E conom y.” P h .D . diss., C ornell University, 1973. T hom pson, E dw ard P. The Making o f the English Working Class. N ew York: Vintage Press, 1963. Tijanić, Aleksandar, and T eodor Andjelić. “O bično nezaposleni m ladi.” NIN, F e b ruary 28, 1982, pp. 14-18. Tilly, C harles, Louise Tilly, and Richard Tilly. The Rebellious Century. C am bridge: H arvard U niversity Press, 1975. Tilton, T im othy A. “A Swedish Road to Socialism: E rnst Wigforss and the Ideolog ical F oun dations o f Swedish Social D em ocracy. ” American Political Science Re view 73, no. 2 (1979): 505-20. Tito, Josip Broz. Tito u Skupštini socijalističke Jugoslavije, 1942-1977. Belgrade: Skupština SFRJ, 1978. ----------. Selected Speeches and Articles, 1941-1961. Translated by D orian Cooke, D jura Ninčić, and Z vonim ir Petnički. Zagreb: N aprijed, 1963. ----------. “G ovor na svečanosti prilikom puštanja u saobraćaj omladinske pruge Šam ac-Sarajevo” (N ovem ber 16, 1947). In Govori i članci. Vol. 3. Zagreb: N aprijed, 1959. ----------. “T rudbeničko upravljanje p riv re d o m ,” Komunist 4, nos. 4 - 5 (Ju ly S e p te m b e r 1950). ----------. “T h e Real Reasons behind the S lander of the Cominform C ountries to w ard Yugoslavia.” N ew Year’s address to the national assembly, D e c e m b e r 27, 1948. T ypescript. ----------. “O n the National Q u e stio n .” Proleter, No. 16 (1942). Tobin, Jam es. “T h e Econom ic Pendulum : 1962 . . . 1982 . . . 1992 (?)” Interview by Richard D. Bartel. Challenge, M arch-A pril 1992, pp. 9 -1 6 . Todorović, Marija. “O snovne karakteristike izm ena i dopuna Zakona o radnim odnosima. ” In Zakon o radnim odnosima SR Srbije u praktičnoj primeni: Z bor nik radova. Belgrade: “Revije rad a,” 1981. Tomanović, Velimir. Omladina i socijalizam. Belgrade: Mladost, 1977. T om asevich, Jozo. “Yugoslavia during the Second W orld W a r.” In W ayne S. Vucinich, ed ., C ontem porary Yugoslavia: Twenty Years o f Socialist Experi ment. B erkeley and Los Angeles: U niversity of California Press, 1969. ---------- . “Collectivization o f A griculture in Yugoslavia.” In Irwin T. Sanders, ed., Collectivization o f Agriculture in Eastern Europe. Lexington: U niversity of K entucky Press, 1958.
BIBL IO CRA P H Y
421
----------. Peasants, Politics, and Economic Change in Yugoslavia. Stanford, Calif.: Stanford U niversity Press, 1955. ----------. “Postwar F oreign Econom ic R elations.” In R obert J. K erner, e d ., Yugoslavia. B erkeley and Los Angeles: U niversity of California Press, 1949. ----------. “G e rm an Econom ic P enetration and Exploitation of S outheastern E u ro p e .” Civil Affairs Information Guide: U.S. Foreign Economic Administra tion. W ar D e p a rtm e n t Pam phlet no. 31-127. W ashington, D .C ., 1944. ----------. “G erm an P enetration of C orporate Holdings in C roatia.” In Civil Affairs Information Guide: U.S. Foreign Economic Administration. W ar D e p a rtm e n t P am p h let no. 31-129. W ashington, D .C ., 1944. ----------. “G erm an Penetration of C orporate Holdings in S erbia.” In Civil Affairs Information Guide: U.S. Foreign Economic Administration. W ar D ep a rtm en t P am p h le t 31-128. W ashington, D .C ., 1944. Trninić, Milan. “Kako je partiska organizacija u rudnicim a ‘T ito’ učestvovala u organizaciji rada po novom m e to d u .” Partiska Izgradnja 1, nos. 9 -1 0 (S e p te m b e r-O c to b e r 1949): 57-61. T routon, R uth. Peasant Renaissance in Yugoslavia. London: R outledge and K egan Paul, 1952. T ucker, R obert C ., ed. The Marx-Engels Reader. 2d ed. N ew York: N orton, 1978. Turčinović, Slobodan. “Financing Socio-political Units, 1961-1967.” Yugoslav Survey 9, no. 2 (May 1968): 59-64. Tyson, L aura D ’Andrea. “In v estm en t Allocation: A C om parison of th e Reform E xperiences of H ungary and Yugoslavia.” Journal o f Comparative Economics 7 (1983): 288-303. ----------. The Yugoslav Economic System and Its Performance in the 1970s. B erke ley: In stitu te o f International Studies, U niversity o f California, 1980. ----------. “A P erm a n e n t Incom e H ypothesis for the Yugoslav F irm .” Economica, n .s., 44, no. 4 (N ovem ber 1977): 393-408. ----------. “T h e Yugoslav Inflation: Some C om peting H ypotheses. ’’Journal o f Com parative Economics 1 (1977): 113-46. Tyson, L aura D ’Andrea, and G abriel Eichler. “C ontinuity and C hange in the Yugoslav E conom y in th e 1970s and 1980s.” In East European Economic As sessment, pt. 1, country studies. W ashington, D .C .: Joint Econom ic C o m m it te e, U.S. C ongress, 1981. Tyson, L aura D ’Andrea, and Egon N euberger. “T he Transm ission o f In te rn a tional D isturbances to Yugoslavia.” In Egon N e u b erg e r and L aura D ’A ndrea Tyson, ed s., The Impact o f International Economic Disturbances on the Soviet Union and Eastern Europe. N ew York: Pergam on Press, 1980. ”U b o rb u protiv besposlice!” Proleter 2, no. 11 (F ebruary 15, 1930): 1. Ulam, Adam. Titoism and the Cominform. C am bridge: H arvard U niversity Press, 1952. U n ited S outh Slav C om m ittee. Tito Speaks. L ondon, 1944. U n ite d States D e p a rtm e n t of State. Yugoslavia: Titoism and U.S. Foreign Policy. W ashington, D .C ., 1952. Unković, Andrija. “Povodom organizacije oblasnih inspekcija rad a.” Vjesnik Rada 4, no. 4 (April 1949).
422
BIB L IOGRAPHY
Unković, Andrija. “Zaključci konferencije inspektora rada od 1 i 2 d ecem b ra 1949 održane u M inistarstvu rada F N R J.” Vjesnik Rada 4, no. 4 (N o v em b erD e c e m b e r 1949): 475-76. Unković, M ilorad. “Inostrani kapital u jugoslovenskoj p riv red i.” Ekonomska A n aliza 14, no. 1 (1980): 53-6 7. Uvalić, Radivoj. “Stanje i razvoj ekonom ske misli i prakse i njihov m edjusobni odnosi u našoj zem lji.” Ekonomist, no. 2 (1952). Uzunov, Nikola. “P roblem nezaposlenosti u uslovima stabilizacione politike Ju g oslavije.” Kadrovi i Udruženi Rad 12, no. 1 (1982): 8-13. Vanek, Jaroslav. A General Theory o f Labour-Managed Market Economies. Ithaca, N.Y.: C ornell U niversity Press, 1970. Vanek, Jaroslav, and M. Jovičič. “Uloga kapitalne oprem ljenosti rada u formiranju i raspodeli dohotka u Jugoslaviji: Teorijska i em pirijska analiza.” Economic Analysis and W orkers’ Management 6, nos. 1 -2 (1972): 50-59. V erba, Sidney, and G oldie Shabad. “W orkers’ Councils and Political Stratifica tion: T h e Yugoslav E x p erien ce.” American Political Science Review 72, no. 1 (1978): 8 0 -9 5 . V erdery, K atherine. National Ideology under Socialism: Identity and Cultural Politics in Ceau§escus Romania. Berkeley and Los Angeles: U niversity of Cali fornia Press, 1991. ----------. Transylvanian Villagers: Three Centuries o f Political, Economic, and Ethnic Change. B erkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press, 1982. “Višak nezaposlenih— i zaposlenih.” Ekonomska Politika, no. 1567 (April 12, 1982): 16-18. Vodopivec, Milan. “Productivity Effects of R edistribution in a Socialist Economy: T h e C ase of Yugoslavia.” P h.D . diss., D e p a rtm e n t of Economics, U niversity of M aryland, 1989. Von H agen, Mark. Soldiers in the Proletarian Dictatorship: The Red A rm y and the Soviet Socialist State, 1917-1930. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell U niversity Press, 1990. V ucinich, W ayne S., ed. A t the Brink o f W ar and Peace: The Tito-Stalin Split in a Historic Perspective. N ew York: Brooklyn College Press, 1982. Vujačić, Milan. “D ečija zaštita ili zaštita fondova.” Gledišta 8, no. 2 (F ebruary 1967): 217-19. Vujošević, Božo. “O nekim problem im a radne snage (Povodom donošenja U redbe o ustaljenju rad n e snage).” Narodna Država 4, nos. 1 -2 (Jan u a ry -F e b ru a ry 1950): 2 4 -31. ----------. “Za bolji m etod u našem ra d u .” Vjesnik Rada 4, nos. 11-12 (N o v em b erD e c e m b e r 1949): 446-47. ----------. “O nedostacim a službe radničkog snabdijevanja.” Vjesnik Rada 3, no. 1 (January 1948): 14-15. V ukm anović-Tem po, Svetozar. Revolucija koja teče: Memoari. 2 vols. Belgrade: Kom unist, 1971. Vukovič, Miloš. “Uticaj svetske priv red n e krize, 1929-1939, na p riv red u stare Jugoslavije.” In Srpska Akademija Nauka i U m etnosti, Svetska ekonomska kriza 1929-1934. godine i njen odraz u zemljama jugoistočne Evrope. Belgrade: Balkanološki Institut.
B I BL IOGRAP HY
423
VuSkovic, Boris. “Social Inequality in Yugoslavia.” New Left Review 95 (Ja n u a ry F e b ru a ry 1976): 2 6-41. W achtel, H ow ard. W orkers’ Management and Wages in Yugoslavia. Ithaca, N.Y.: C ornell U niversity Press, 1973. W alder, Andrew. Communist Neo-Traditionalism: W ork and A u thority in Chi nese In dustry. B erkeley and Los Angeles: U niversity of California Press, 1987. W allerstein, Michael. “C entralized Bargaining and W age R estrain t.” American Journal o f Political Science 34, no. 4 (N ovem ber 1990): 982-1004. W ard, Benjam in. “M arxism -H orvatism : A Yugoslav Theory of Socialism.” A m eri can Economic R eview 57 (1967): 509-23. ----------. “Industrial D ecentralization in Yugoslavia.” California Slavic Studies 2 (1963): 169-87. ---------- . “T h e F irm in Illyria: M arket Syndicalism in Yugoslavia.” American Eco nomic R eview 48, no. 4 (S ep tem b er 1958): 566-89. ----------. “F ro m Marx to Barone: Socialism and the Postwar Yugoslav Industrial F ir m .” P h .D . diss., D e p a rtm e n t of Economics, U niversity of California at B erkeley, 1956. W arrin er, D oreen. Revolution in Eastern Europe. London: T urnstile Press, 1950. W eiler, P. British Labour a n d the C old W ar. Stanford, Calif.: Stanford U niversity Press, 1988. W eir, M argaret, and T h ed a Skocpol. “State S tructures and th e Possibilities for ‘K eynesian’ R esponses to th e G reat D epression in Sw eden, Britain, and th e U n ite d S tates.” In P e te r E vans e t al., Bringing the State Back In. C am bridge: C am b rid g e U niversity Press, 1985. W exler, Im m anuel. The Marshall Plan Revisited: The European Program in Eco nomic Perspective. W estp ort, C onn.: G reenw ood Press, 1983. W ilson, O rm e, Jr. “T he B elgrade-B ar Railroad: An Essay in Econom ic and Politi cal G e o g rap h y .” In G eorge W. Hoffman, ed., Eastern Europe: Essays in G eo graphical Problems. N ew York: Praeger, 1970. Wolff, R o b ert Lee. The Balkans in O u r Time. N ew York: N orton, 1967. Originally p u b lish e d 1956. W oodall, Jean. The Socialist C orporation and Technocratic Power: The Polish U nited W orkers’ Party, Industrial Organization, and W orkforce C ontrol, 1958-80. C am bridge: C am bridge U niversity Press, 1982. W oodw ard, Susan L. “Soviet R ehearsal in Yugoslavia? C ontradictions of the So cialist Liberal S trategy.” The Socialist Register, Communist Regimes: the A fte r math, e d ite d by Ralph M iliband and Leo Panitch, 1991, 322-47. ---------- . “Reform ing the Socialist State: Ideology and Public F inance in Yugoslavia.” W o rld Politics 41, no. 2 (January 1989): 267-305. ----------. “O rthodoxy and Solidarity: C om peting Claims and International A djust m e n t in Yugoslavia.” International Organization 40, no. 2 (Spring 1986): SOS45. ----------. “T he Rights o f W om en: Ideology, Policy, and Social C hange in Yugoslavia.” In Sharon W olchik and Alfred M eyer, eds., W omen, State and Party in Eastern Europe. D urham , N .C .: D uke U niversity Press, 1985. W orld Bank. Yugoslavia: A djustm ent Policies and Developm ent Perspectives. W ashington, D C .: IB R D , 1983.
424
B I BL IOGRAP HY
Yugoslavia. The Constitution o f the Socialist Federal Republic o f Yugoslavia. Ljubljana: D opisna Delavska U niverza, 1974. ----------. Law on the Five Year Plan fo r the Development o f the National Economy o f the FPRY, 1947-1951. W ith speech by Josip Broz Tito. Belgrade: Jug oslovanska Knjiga, 1947. ----------. N arodna Skupština FNRJ. Drugo redovno zasedanje: Stenografske be ležke (Belgrade, D e c e m b e r 2 -2 1 , 1946). ----------. Drugo vanredno zasedanje: Stenografske beleške (Belgrade, M arch 10April 1, 1946). ----------. Prvo redovno zasedanje: Stenografske beleške (Belgrade: May 15-July 20, 1946). ----------. Savezna Skupština SFRJ. The Associated Labour Act. Ljubljana: Dopisna D elavska Univerza, 1977. Za bolju organizaciju, sadržaj i m etod ra d a.” Vjesnik Rada. 5, nos 8 - 9 (August S e p te m b e r 1950): 362-64. Zeković, Velimir. "Razvoj i karakteristike privrednog sistema F N R J.” In Priručnik za ekonomiju FNRJ. Belgrade: Rad, 1958. Z erdin, Ali. “Tokens of Slovene Sovereignty.” Yugofax, O ctober 12, 1991. Z im m erm an , William. Open Borders, Nonalignment, and the Political Evolution o f Yugoslavia. Princeton, N.J.: P rinceton U niversity Press, 1987. Zujovic, Sreten. Confession. Borba, N ovem ber 23, 1950, p. 1. Zukin, Sharon. "Practicing Socialism in a H obbesian W orld: D ev elo p m en t and P ersisten ce o f th e Yugoslav S ta te .” In Neil H arding, e d., The State in Socialist Society. Oxford: Macmillan, 1983. ----------. “T h e R epresentation of W orking-Class Interests in Socialist Society: Yugoslav L abor U nions.” Politics and Society 10, no. 3 (1981): 281-316. Ž upanov, Josip. Marginalije o društvenoj krizi. Zagreb: Globus, 1983. ----------. “A ktuelni d ruštveni zadatak.” Naše Teme 25 (1983): 1945-56. ----------. “E galitarizam i industrijalizam .” Sociologija 12, no. 1 (1970): 5 -4 4 . Zupanov, Josip, and M laden Zuvela. “K riteriji inferiornosti nezaposlenih u nas i u sv ijetu .” Kadrovi i Udruženi Rad 11, no. 4 (1981): 3-12. Zuvela, M laden. “G ru p e stanovnika pojačeno izložene nezaposlenosti i neke n je n e socijalne i psihološke posljedice.” Sociologija 10, no. 4 (1968). P e r io d ic a l s
Bulletin du Conseil Central de la Confédération des Syndicats de Yougoslavie (Belgrade), 1949
Economic Survey: Yugoslavia (Organization for Econom ic C ooperation and D e velo p m en t, Paris) Ekonomist
Ekonomska Politika (Belgrade) Ekonomski Pregled (Zagreb) Finansije (Belgrade) Informativni Bilten (Zavod za D ruštv eno Planiranje, Ljubljana), 1982 Informativni Priručnik o Jugoslaviji (Belgrade), 1950-51.
B IBL IOGRAP HY
425
Migracije (Zagreb), 1973-82 N arodna Arm ija (Belgrade), 1955-57 N arodna D ržava Partiska Izgradnja Službeni List (Belgrade), 1948-49 Socijalna Politika Statistički Godišnjak Jugoslavije (Savezni Zavod za Statistiku, Belgrade) Yearbook on Economic Statistics (Organization for Economic Cooperation and
Development, Paris) Yugoslav Federal A ssem bly (Belgrade) Yugoslav Survey (Belgrade) Yugoslav Trade Unions (Belgrade), 1963Zaposlenost i Zapošljavanje (Savezni Savet za Rad, Belgrade) Zapošljavanje i U druženi R ad (Zagreb)
INDEX
Achesnn, Dean, 144 Adam, Jan, lln .2 2 administrative period, 64, 6 6 -9 7 , 163, 168 agricultural policy: agrarian reform, 5 7 -5 8 , 60, 70, 90, 242, 266; change to gain labor for production, 117; gradualist socializa tion, 161; Green Plan, 236, 279; for pro ductivity, 286; sectoral distinctions, 285 86; with self-reliance strategy, 108-21; Slovene and Foča models’ adjustment to, 2 6 4 -6 5 agricultural production: dependence on, 1 0 5 -6 ; drought years, 160; for export, 96, 130; policy to control, 112-14; pres sure to increase, 6 0 -6 1 , 75, 90 agricultural sector: employment decline, 191, 348; exodus from, 2 86 -89 ; labor force surplus, 67, 102, 2 6 3 -6 4 ; radicalization, 100; socialist transformation, 243; voluntary labor in, 140-41. See also farmers’ (marketing) cooperatives; labor brigades; landholdings, agrarian; private sector; villages Agrokomerc affair (1987), 295 aid, foreign: dependence on, 9 5 -9 6 ; indus trialization strategy based on, 7 7 -8 0 ; from postwar Soviet Union, 8 0 -8 1 ; re quests for and receipt of, 8 1 -8 3 , 100, 121; UNRRA assistance, 83, 95, 99; U .S., 99, 1 50 -51, 249; U .S. military, 159 See also credit, foreign; military sector Albanians: land purchases, 298; national ism, 40, 343, 358, 3 6 5 -6 6 ; as political force, 3 4 2 -4 4 Alt, James, 27, 28n Antifascist Council for the Liberation of Yugoslavia (AVNOJ), 5 2 -5 4 , 57 Appleby, Joyce O , 17, 162 Arab-Israeli War (1967), 250 Arsov, Ljubčo, 123, 153 Austria, 9, 342, 357 Austrian unemployment theory, 2 1 4 -15 Austromarxism, 35, 4 8 -4 9 , 52, 155
autonomy: budgetary, 73, 167; competition to retain, 23; conflict over provincial, 365; farmers’ cooperatives, 8 9 -9 1 , 172; firms, 72; peasants, 9 1 -9 2 ; producers and production brigades, 1 4 2 -4 4 , 151, 185; republic governments, 3 3 6 -3 7 ; Slov ene model, 59, 265; Yugoslavian territo ries, 52 -5 3 . See also decentralization; self-management concept AVNOJ. See Antifascist Council for the L ib eration of Yugoslavia (AVNOJ) Bakaric, Vladimir, 137, 138, 150, 301, 312 balance of payments: commodity-trade ac count (1948), 129; current account liquid ity, 223; deficits, 95, 129, 223, 226, 244, 247, 287; effect of U .S. loans on, 145; for eign aid supports for, 228; with remit tances, 228, 246, 254, 269, 293; subdivided among republics, 235, 253. See also economic shocks; exchange-rate system; foreign policy; trade, foreign; trade deficit Balkan Pact (1954), 241 Banac, Ivo, 32, 33n, 34n, 49n, 56n, 62n banking system, 185; Austrian banks (1985), 357; autonomous producers linked through, 172; borrowing abroad, 235, 253; branches of National Bank, 123; co operative principle, 185; crisis, 3 5 1 -5 2 ; crisis (1987), 351; in liquidity crisis, 229 30; recentralization (1980s), 355; in re publics, 290, 292—93; with socialization of investment, 245; territorial organiza tion of, 230 bargaining, wage See collective bargaining barter system, 125 Bartlett, William, 212 basic organizations of associated labor (BOALs), 277 benefits: under constitution, 4 1 -4 2 ; worker acceptance of limits on, 261 Bicanic, Rudolf, 44n, 47n Blazevic, Jakov, 109, 112, 113, 115 Bolcic, Silvano, 337, 336n, 337n
428
INDEX
borrowing. See loans Bosnia-Herzegovina: abolition of district government, 270; Agrokomerc affair (1987), 295; capitalist development, 38; deindustrialization, 291; employment bu reaus, 178; large-scale agricultural pro duction, 285; low level o f development, 283; mines in, 94; as nation, 39; national ism, 366; relocation of defense-related industries in, 139, 284; separate party or ganization, 40; unemployment rates, 201, 2 0 4 -5 , 298, 3 3 9 -4 4 . See also Foca model Bretton Woods, 251 brigades. See labor brigades; Partisans; Popular Front; production brigades Broz, Josip. See Tito, Josip Broz budget deficits, 108, 131 Bukharin, Nikolai, 75, 90, 171 bureaucracy: critique, 30; differences be tween Slovene and Foca models, 161; re duction plan, 132; transfer to republics of federal, 250- See also employment bureaus cameralism, 18, 28 Cameron, David, lOn Cannon, Cavendish, 122, 129 capital: demand for foreign, 249; effect of scarce, 1 64 -65 ; focus on need for, 66; foreign aid to supplement, 77, 79 -8 0 ; formation, 225; government role in redis tribution, 186; industrialization require ments, 79, 2 2 4 -2 5 ; Marxist idea of formation, 1 8 -2 0 ; plan for accumulation of, 6 8 -6 9 , 7 5 -7 7 , 110; producers’ control of, 183—85, 229—30; redistribution through General Investment Fund, 186 87; strategy for access to foreign, 224. See also aid, foreign; credit, foreign; trade, foreign capital flows: within autonomous republics, 290; to more developed areas, 284; Slov enia and Croatia (1985), 357; territorialization, 282, 290 capitalist theory: as applied in Yugoslavia, 76; Marxist analysis, 3 capitalist unemployment, 27; elimination of, 311; rejection of, 322 capital markets: direct borrowing by banks and firms, 253; independent institutional
entrance into, 249; obstacles to, 219; separate from labor markets, 312; in separate republics, 296; unemployment without, 214 central bank (National Bank): control of en terprise finances, 152; credit policy, 123; foreign loan guarantees, 185, 225; re newed authority of, 351; socialization of debt under, 2 2 9 -3 0 . See also banking system centralization: combined with decentraliza tion, 1 3 0-4 4; of economic policy making, 119; under self-reliance policy, 130-33; in Slovene economic methods, 161-62 Chayanov, A. V., 313 class struggle, Yugoslav style, 114, 118 -1 9 Cobeljic, Nikola, 210 Cocom Accords (1947), 95 collective bargaining, 8 8 -8 9 , 1 53 -55, 261, 326 collective consumption goods, 271 collectives. See farm collectives; producers; work collectives Comisso, Ellen, 15n, 33n, 326, 334n commodity shortages: response to, 124-26, 145-4 6; U.S. food donations, 150-51. See also aid, foreign; rationing; trade, foreign Communist Party o f Yugoslavia (CPY): adoption of Slovene coalition principles, 5 9 -6 0 ; alliance with Croat Peasant party, 5 5 -5 6 ; authority shifted to, 133 -34 ; be comes League o f Communists, 64, 182; consolidation of power (1948), 126-27; fusion of party with military functions, 5 1 -5 3 ; heterogeneous ideologies in, 35 38; interwar alliances, 32; nationalism of, 56; purge (1948), 11 9 -20; strategy to en compass heterogeneity, 4 1 -4 9 . See also League of Communists of Yugoslavia (LCY) community farms, 1 0 4 -6 comparative advantage: conflict over impor tance of, 240; of regions, 292; source of, 224 competition: with declining resources, 354; labor market, 112-13, 175, 3 2 5 -2 6 , 337 38; in labor market and political system, 3 5 3 -5 4 ; among party leaders, 335; among property owners, 355; socialist, 78, 96
IN D E X Connor, Walker, 35, 41 conscription, military, 147 constitutions: amendments, 250, 274; Basic Law (1953), 164, 184; commission (1983), 255; constitution and related workers' constitution (1974), 164—65, 237, 250— 51; economic policy (1963), 270; of 1921, 4 1 - 4 2 ; principles of representation (post-1963), 184; provisional adoption (1943), 36; regulation o f employment by, 317; revised, 1 8 0-8 1. See also legislation consumption, domestic: comm mod ity scar city, 124—26, 145—46; plans for, 6 8 -6 9 ; rationing, 104; regulated by incomes and employment, 263; socially necessary, 69 cooperatives: capitalist focus of, 76; charac terization o f farmers in movement for, 8 9 -9 0 ; legal mechanism for, 90; local level, 74; requisitioning of agricultural products, 90; revised basic law (1948), 136; subdivision of, 277; trade by linked prices, 1 1 3 -1 5 ; tradition in Croatia and Slovenia, 43; village, 44, 92. See also farmers (marketing) cooperatives; labor cooperatives Council for Mutual Economic Assistance (CMEA), 29, 241, 349 Cox, Terry, 21n.42 credit: as alternative to revenues from pro duction, 302; IM F , 187, 228, 229, 245, 347; obstacle to access, 219; for public sector agriculture, 285; in regional and republican banks, 292; with socialization of investment, 2 4 5 -4 6 . See also debt, ex ternal; loans, foreign credit, foreign: dependence on, 163, 257; direct borrowing of firms and banks, 235; economic policy related to, 2 4 1 -4 2 , 265 66; Joint Export-Import Agency, Allied occupation, 144, 150; relation to current account deficit, 226; relation to domestic taxation, 232; from Soviet Union, 243; suspension of lending, 254 See also debt, external; International Monetary Fund (IM F); World Bank Croatia: decline in economy and employ ment, 359; demand for territorial con trol, 256; employment bureaus, 178-79; foreign currency flows to, 235; industrial
429
ization in, 94; investment in, 291; juris dictions granted (1939), 69; mines in, 94; nationalism, 5 5 -5 6 , 3 6 6 -6 7 ; national se curity issue, 255; organized unions and working class, 41; plans for development* 297, regional differences within, 2 8 9 -9 0 ; surplus labor emigration, 3 3 8 -3 9 ; unem ployment rates, 201, 2 0 4 -5 , 208; unrest (after 1967), 275 Croatian Communist party, 36, 43, 5 5 - 5 6 Croatian Liberation Front (ZAVNOH), 50, 55 Croatian school of rural sociology, 210 Croat Peasant party (CPP), 4 3 -4 4 ; alliance with Communist Party of Yugoslavia, 55 56; influence of economists from, 210; withdrawal of Communist party support (1947), 107 currency: devaluation, 159, 2 3 2 -3 3 , 251; reform goals (1945), 70 Cvetkovic-Macek Agreement (1939), 69 Czechoslovakia, 14, 28, 82 Dalmatia, 43, 44, 2 8 3 -8 4 , 290, 325 data, employment and unemployment, 194-208, 240, 264, 3 3 8 -4 4 , 3 7 5 -9 4 Davies, R. W., 28, 73n, 153n debt, external: federal government guaran tee for, 235; postponement, 250; recyc ling, rescheduling, and refinancing, 225, 249, 2 5 2 -5 4 , 275, 3 4 8 -4 9 ; refunding by European governments, 249; repayment, 227, 372; republics' responsibility, 295; service of, 253. See also credit, foreign; loans, foreign decentralization: combined with centraliza tion, 130—44; cost at local level, 3 0 0 -3 0 1 ; effect on labor markets, 264; effect on size of public sector, 2 7 4 -7 5 , 289; fail ure, 165, 350; in Foca model, 265; IM F campaign for, 236; with openness to for eign trade, 2 3 3 -3 6 ; in perceived wither ing away of the state, 171, 250; rationale for, 69, 331; to regional party headquar ters, 52. See also government, local; lo calization; villages defense policy: changes, 274; conscription and military training, 276; effect of, 248; effect of political strategy on, 9 8 - 9 9 ; fac tors in arms race, 3 4 8 -4 9 ; firm and local government responsibility for, 250, 276;
430
INDEX
defense policy (cont.) localization of government tasks as, 119; mobilization, 268; redrawing of military districts, 360; relation to access to foreign capital, 224-25; relation to foreign pol icy, 146-47, 241; in response to foreign trade problems, 116-17; of security zones, 139, 284; with socialization, 187-88 deficits, domestic, 108, 131 democracy: economic, 5, 322; local level, 74; with party decentralization, 135-36; technocratic, 118 developmentalist school; approach to economic policy, 245; approach to unem ployment, 210-12, 216-17; over shadowed by liberal school, 272 developmentalist state, 17-18 development theory: contradictions in, 165; developmentalists' school, 210; liberal school, 210 discrimination: against employment of women, 104; by national origin, 338, 347, 366-67; against new labor force en trants, 336; with rising unemployment, 360-61; against surplus labor, 153; against training of professionals, 302. See also ethnic criteria Djilas, Milovan, 40n, 73n, 75 Dolomite Agreement (1943), 51 Dreze, F., 221 dualism: economic/political, 127, 183, 189; of socialist/capitalist strategy, 76; of un employment/employment concept, 8 economic coercion concept, 146, 150, 151, 168, 174-75 Economic Council, Yugoslavia, 73, 122, 125 economic growth: based on foreign loans and credits, 244; Foča model, 265; gov ernment priority to promote, 222-23; Marxist ideology, 18-20; Ricardian growth path, 224-25, 233; strategy with openness to foreign trade, 224-37; Todaro and Harris-Todaro models, 212 economic interest concept, 321 economic performance: effect, 263; factors in rise and fall of, 225, 230-31 economic planning: five-year plan, 73-76, 95-96; focus of, 84; as policy goal, 170; republican government level, 282
economic policy: adjustment to strategy for, 96-97; conflict over development strategy, 74-83; correlation with unem ployment patterns, 240, 264; for develop ment, 287; differences in approach, 336 38; factors changing (1973), 251; with focus on global economy, 244-53; to in crease growth, 268-69; influence of for eign credit availability, 236, 241; to meet Tito s self-reliance policy, 108-9, 121-28; party role in coordination and control, 134; political conflict over, 237-56; re forms, 247-48, 347; reforms, response of republics, 355-59; with renewed auton omy of republics, 148. See also aid, for eign; economic planning; export promotion; investment; monetary policy; Reform (1965); self-reliance policy; trade, foreign economic shocks: external, 130, 230-33, 253-54, 257-58; oil-price shocks effect (1973, 1979), 251, 253-54; from response to international conditions, 240 economy: nonplanned socialist, 170-73; or ganized around labor-managed firms, 12, 15, 166, 208, 212-13, 215, 220, 263, 266n, 267n; post-World War II local, 60 61 economy, global: effect of Yugoslav re sponse to, 227-40, 244-53; national in dependence in, 28, 33-34, 38, 98, 146, 164, 165, 256 education: economic status with, 318; as investment, 317; reform, 276-77, 289, 362; republic policy and jurisdiction, 271, 290, 336, 338; secondary and uni versity, 289, 338; vocational, 273, 276 77 Eichengreen, Barry, 23-24 electoral laws, 184n.51 employment: adjustment by moving workers, 263; as bundle of rights, 317; demand for increased, 99; differentia tion between private and public sectors, 347; with economic reform (1980s), 347; effect of trade deficits on, 263; fac tors affecting domestic, 226-27; hid den surplus, 197; incentive proposals (1980s), 281-82; of labor surplus, 66— 67, 74, 102; lack of federal jurisdiction over, 259; narrowed definition of, 196-
IN D E X 97; national identity as criterion for pub lic, 347; private sector in villages, 334; productivity for expansion of, 174; pro jected public sector (1947), 96; ration ing criteria related to, 15 2-53; regula tion by allocation of provisions, 152-53; relation to political action, 3 3 9 -4 4 ; so cialist concept of full, 3 - 1 1 ; socialization through public sector, 262. See also over employment; socialism; unemployment; workers; workers, private sector; workers, skilled employment bureaus: functions and success of, 86, 195; registration rates, 191; re training programs, 300; self-management by, 178 -79 employment contracts: defining legally reg ulated jo b classification, 166, 174; effect of, 162; growth (1957-82), 191; legal en forcement provisions, 151-53 employment rates, 192, 3 7 5 -9 4 ; compari son of sectoral, 2 5 -2 6 ; levels in socialist and capitalist countries, 27 Estrin, Saul, 2 1 3 -1 4 , 216, 220 ethnic criteria: in jo b rationing, 301; in stu dent and employee selection, 301, 338 Europe: integration, 349; postwar relations with, 82; provision of coal for, 144 European Community (EC): monetary uni fication, 349; negotiations with (1980s), 3 4 9 -5 0 ; trade agreements with (1970, 1976), 29, 251, 253 European F ree Trade Association (EFTA), 253, 350 exchange-rate system, 159, 169; with open ness to foreign trade, 2 3 2 -3 5 ; recentral ization (1980s), 3 5 5 -56 . See also foreign exchange export production: earnings from, 146; dur ing economic crisis (1948), 122 -25 ; effect on balance of payments, 129; increased, 96—97, 9 9 -1 0 0 , 102; producer control of, 235 export promotion, 229, 246, 25 0-5 1 factors o f production: allocation in socialist societies, 2 2 -2 3 ; price regulation, 169 70; shortages, 130-31 Farkaš, Vladimir, 2 1 6-1 8, 220 farm collectives, 125 farmers, private sector: cooperative move
431
ment, 8 9 -9 0 ; policy to undercut market power, 112 -1 3 ; requirements of, 244 farmers’ (marketing) cooperatives, 4 3 - 4 4 , 8 9 -9 1 ; conceived as autonomous social ist communities, 8 9 -9 1 , 172; employ ment in, 162; monopoly position (1953, 1957), 242, 2 4 3 -4 4 ; organization of, 61; relation to standard of living, 7 3 -7 4 , 84; renewed favoritism for, 150; replace ment of free markets, 113; speculators in, 106 Federal Bureau of Employment, 269 federalism: confirmation (1924), 36, 63; eco nomic, 72; effect on states economic pol icy, 76; provisional government (1943), 3 9 -4 0 , 52 Feiwel, George, 12 -1 3 financial system: liquidity crisis, 229; pro ducer control, 1 8 3-8 5, 2 2 9 -3 0 ; Yugoslav argument for control of, 219, 2 2 2-2 4. See also banking system firms: autonomy of, 7 2 -7 3 ; borrowing abroad, 235, 253; conflicts within and b e tween, 3 3 0-3 2; defense and security sys tems as responsibility of, 250; development of private sector, 303; effect of legislation on employment policies, 2 7 8 -8 0 ; financing of social services, 262; foreign exchange retention by, 2 3 4 -3 5 ; freedom to access foreign credit, 235; privatization policy for, 280; relation to workers councils, 267; role in Slovene model, 183; subdivision of, 277; unions’ authority in, 3 2 6 -2 7 . See also produ cers; production; productivity; self management concept; state-owned en terprises; work collectives; workers’ councils firms, labor-managed, 4, 12, 15, 166, 208, 2 1 2 -1 3 , 215, 220, 263, 266n, 267n fiscal policy: federal level, 231; federal-level revenues with decentralized, 76; local government, 267. See also spending, gov ernment; tax policy Foca model, 34, 58, 60, 90; contradiction of Slovene model, 22; with country’s dis solution, 3 7 1 -7 2 ; economic methods, 1 61 -62; interference o f Slovene model with, 96; mix with Slovene model, 265— 68, 349; production, investment and la bor policies, 224, 275; property rights,
432
INDEX
Foča model (cont.) 60; reality of, 165; survival of, 163. See also developmental ist school Foča Regulations (1942), 60 food policy. See farmers’ (marketing) coop eratives; private sector; rationing; subsistence foreign exchange: control policy, 9 6 -9 7 ; firms’ retention of, 2 3 4 -3 5 foreign policy: federal government role, 2 2 3 -2 4 ; with international recognition, 146; strategy, 100-101. See also aid, for eign; foreign policy; trade, foreign free markets: postponement of, 146; re placement of, 113; under socialist com modity production concept, 169 Fund for Reconstruction of War-Dam aged Regions, 83 Gapinski, James, 2 2 5 -2 6 , 228, 231, 232, 303 Gazi, Josip, 107 Gedeon, Shirley, 185n, 229n, 339n General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT): effect on trade policy, 169, 290 91; membership, 29; trade liberalization conditions for membership, 228, 2 4 5-4 7, 2 6 8 -6 9 General Investment Fund (GIF), 186-87, 242, 245 Germany, 14; Partisan against, 80; war in demnities, 82; wartime occupation of Yugoslavia, 93 Gligorov, Kiro, 168, 232 Gomulka, Wladyslaw, 101 Gorbachev, Mikhail, 28, 245, 349 government, federal: centralization o f con trol, 1 30 -32; changing role with unem ployment, 3 5 5 -5 8 ; conditions for reduction of scope, 234; conflict with re public and local, 7 4 -7 6 ; coordination with republics, 73; economic adjustment with labor, 259; foreign policy, 223; juris diction of, 69; lack of control over em ployment, 259; loss of confidence in, 3 5 4 -5 5 ; loss o f control o f economic pol icy, 2 3 3 -3 6 ; new instruments o f coor dination and control (1950), 148; recentralization policy, 3 5 5 -6 7 ; reve nues, 185; role in revised labor policy, 110- 1 1 ; role in socialization o f the state,
187-88; sharing jurisdiction with repub lics, 248 government, local: control over coopera tives, 91; defense and security systems as responsibility of, 250; economic and po litical planning of, 7 3 -7 4 ; employmentrelated problems and policy, 282, 300 303; excise taxes of, 78; jurisdiction, 69; protection o f public-sector wages and jobs, 325; regulation and tax authority, 176; responsibility for unemployment prevention, 176; role of employment bu reaus, 300; tradition of, 52. See also lo calization; villages government, republics: administrative role with socialization, 186-8 7; autonomy over labor policy, 282, 290; coordination with federal government, 73; credit con trol by, 292; as enforcers o f self-reliance policy, 130; financial self-sufficiency, 148, 168; jurisdiction, 69, 336; management of General Investment Fund, 1 86 -87; new role in foreign affairs and defense (1966), 248; property rights’, 147-48, 355, 357; protection of commerce, 2 9 5 -9 6 ; protec tion of public-sector wages and jobs, »325, responsibility for foreign debt, 295; re turn of financial autonomy, 148; with ris ing unemployment, 3 5 5 -6 0 , 3 6 3 -6 5 ; role in revised labor policy, 111 government policy, federal level: to adjust to international environment, 263; de centralized responsibility for implemen tation of, 282; defense-oriented food policy, 285; differential effect on firms and republics, 293; labor policy, 298 303 Great Britain, 5 3 -5 4 , 80 Greece: aid to civil war rebels, 121; rela tions with guerrillas in, 82, 144 G reen Plan (1973), 236, 279 Gregoric, Pavle, 182 Gulick, Charles, 35n, 49n, 183 I larris-Todaro migration model, 212 Hatton, T. J., 2 3 -2 4 health care, 271 health insurance, 177, 195 Hebrang, Andrija, 56, 70, 7 1 -7 2 , 102, 119, 226; on increased collectivization and productivity, 75; opposition to union au-
INDEX thority, 8 3 -8 5 ; peoples government con cept, 74 Herzegovina. See Bosnia-Herzegovina Horvat, Branko, 155n, 173n, 221n, 231n, 269n housing shortage, 3 0 1 -2 human capital: formation, 282, 317, 320; status for acquisition of, 318; as substi tute for machines, 111 Hungary, 1 2 -1 3 , 14, 28, 60, 243, 330 hyperinflation (1985), 228
433
institutions: conflict among economic, 237 56; factors in definition o f Yugoslav, 65 66; factors in development, 7 4 -7 5 ; in Slovene model, 95, 165; social service, 177-80 interest groups: areas of inattention by, 3 2 9 -3 0 ; firm managers as, 3 2 1 -2 2 ; party as, 322; private sector workers as, 342 43; of students, 3 3 8 -3 9 ; veterans, 302; of workers, 327, 3 2 9 -3 0 , 341. See also po litical opposition International Monetary Fund (IM F): ambi ideology; Communist Party of Yugoslavia guity toward program of, 256; decentral (CPY), 4 3 -4 5 ; economic, 6, 1 6 -2 0 ; Marx ization advice, 171; effect o f terms of ist, 16-2 3. See also capitalist theory; agreement with (1984), 281; GATT mem Foča model; Leninism; Marxism; Slovene bership to obtain credits from, 245; as lender of last resort, 2 2 7 -2 8 ; loans from, model; socialism 228, 229, 347; membership, 82, 1 44 -45; ideology of smallness, 37 imports: capital equipment and technology, negotiations with, 122, 254; policies of, 2 2 5 -2 6 ; with decline in export income, 259; relations with, 82, 345, 348; re 1 46 -47; dependence of production on, quirements for new loans (1987), 350; 226, 249; effect of cutting, 229; payment stabilization program (1979), 280; stand for, 130—31; price effect, 228 by facilities to developing countries, 254, 347 incentives: in choosing higher wages, 260 61; to direct raising of labor productivity, investment, domestic: bias in, 295; in capi 2 2 2 -2 3 , 2 6 1 -6 2 ; in Foča model, 265; to tal projects, 291; effect o f decentraliza improve trade performance, 253; to join tion, 288; incentives against new employment, 2 6 0 -6 1 ; in less-developed public sector, 133; for joint ventures, 249; for lower taxes, 302; for property areas, 2 8 1 -8 3 ; in more-developed areas, owner, 166; in public-sector labor policy, 284; related to kinds of workers needing 2 6 1 -6 2 ; to reduce labor force mobility, jobs, 302; reliance on foreign capital, 2 2 6 -2 7 , republics’ control of, 290; for 88, 1 0 3 -4 , 14 1-43; for republics to self-reliance, 108—9; shift in priorities, invest, 234; in Slovene model, 264; 2 5 0 -5 3 ; in Slovenia, Croatia, and Serbia, to work, 102 -3. See also producers; production 297, 357; social control over, 174; social income relations system, 200 ization of, 2 4 5 -4 6 , 249; uneven distribu incomes: effect of trade deficits on, 263; en tion o f capital for, 2 9 0 -9 1 ; World Bank loans for, 236, 249 forcement policy, 2 6 1 -6 2 ; in socialized investment, foreign, 249, 251, 351 sector, 267- See also wages indexation of salaries, 277, 331 Istria, 57 Italy, 57, 357 industrialization: capital requirements for, 79, 2 2 4 -2 5 ; industrial labor force growth Itoh, Makoto, 27n.51 with, 67; postwar problems of, 66; re form o f union role with, 85—87; workers’ job security, 223, 262, 2 7 7 -7 8 , 310 and union roles, 84 Johnson, A. Ross, 118n inflation, 228, 2 7 5 -7 6 , 349; antijoint ventures, 2 5 2 -5 3 , 295 Jovanovic, Dragoljub, 49, 9 1 - 9 2 , 107 inflationary policy, 223; conditions for and response to, 331; early 1970s, 228. See also hyperinflation Kardelj, Edvard, 32, 36, 39; on agricultural informal markets: commodities, 125; labor, policy, 138; conception of new state, 117-18; concept o f farmers’ coopera315
434
INDEX
Kardelj, Edvard (cont .) tives, 172; draft constitution, 180; em ployment concept, 196; on industrializa tion, 67; model o f socialization and decentralization, 322; on national inde pendence, 146; nationalism of, 32, 36, 39, 48; on new foreign policy (1949), 146; purpose of cooperatives, 90, 92; re form of local peoples committees, 107; requirement for new liberalization (1956), 244; on role of unions, 48; Slov ene model, 1 61 -62 , 317, 3 6 7 -6 8 ; so cialist communities model, 313; on so cialist employment, 166; on trade, 116; on wages and productivity under so cialism, 141 Katz, Arnold, 212 Katzenstein, Peter J ., lOn, 238, 3 4 1 -4 2 Keynesianism, 6, 170, 217, 257, 3 2 7 -2 8 Kidrič, Boris, 68, 71, 7 6 -7 7 , 83; on agri cultural quotas, 122; anti-farmer/kulak statements, 125; class-based arguments, 115; dictatorship of the proletariat, 184; economic coercion concept, 146, 150, 168; on economic planning, 120; excess public sector employment concept, 149; fiuctuators, 149, 315; “law of value,” 76 77, 132, 158, 171, 264; peoples power, 167; Slovene model, 161-6 2, 244, 317; on social tansformation, 137 Knights of Labor, 155 Kornai, Janos, l l n , 13n, 216 Kosanovie, Sava, 144 Kosovo: demographic explosion (1962-64), 211; development o f society in, 342; in dustrial investment, 285; martial law in, 255; surplus labor, 338; unemployment rates, 201, 2 0 3 -5 , 208, 298, 3 3 9 -4 4 ; un rest (after 1967), 275, 338. See also Albanians Kraigher, Sergei, 255 Krajer, Boris, 240 Krstulovič, Vicko, 87, 103-4 Kržišnik, Anton, 72 Kucan, Milan, 3 4 3 -4 4 kulaks. See farmers, private sector; farmers (marketing) cooperatives; landholdings, agrarian labor brigades: as economic measures, 177; reallocation o f voluntary, 149-50; recruit
ment campaign (1949), 151; in reform of production, 142-44; as supplement to public-sector labor force, 7 7 -7 8 , 140; volunteer, 97, 1 11 -12, 121, 125, 243, 268, 333 labor cooperatives: local level, 115; peas ant, 90, 138-41, 242; public sector, 150 labor force: agricultural policy to gain la bor, 117; assignment of redundant, 262, 3 0 6 -9 ; distribution according to work, 273; employment of peasant-industrial workers, 192; government control of lo cal, 114; incentives for return of overseas nationals, 93, 301; with industrialization (1921-38), 67; layoffs, 201, 203; mech anisms to prevent market allocation, 2 6 1 -6 2 ; in mines, 93; mobility and lack o f mobility, 88, 1 0 3 -4 , 141 -43 , 162 63, 175, 3 0 1 -2 ; mobilization, 9 9 -1 0 0 , 1 22 -28, 139-4 1, 268; modernization of public sector, 268; nonproductive seg ment, 262, 3 6 2 -6 3 ; participation in de centralized economy, 208; politics of labor supply, 102; public sector labor books, 8 8 -8 9 ; recruitment, 104, 118 19; redistribution with rising unemploy ment, 3 6 1 -6 2 ; reduction on state farms and labor cooperatives, 266; relocation to Bosnia, 139; return of overseas na tionals, 304; role of labor brigades, 77 78; shortages, 9 2 -9 3 , 110-11, 136-37; supply scarcity, 9 3 -9 4 , 103-5; women’s participation rates, 287. See also employ ment; labor brigades; labor markets; un employment; workers; workers, private sector; workers’ councils labor force surplus: absorption of, 210; em ployment of, 6 6 -6 7 , 102; government employees as, 300; location of labor intensive industries to capture, 285; mo bilization of, 74; release to public sector, 174; right to fire, 174; rise in public sec tor, 274; Slovenia, 2 6 3 -6 4 labor inspectors, 88 labor legislation: Law on Associated Labor (1976), 278; Law on Employment (1974), 276; Law on Labor Relations (1965), 272; in 1 97 4 -7 6 period, 277 78; in 19 79-82 period, 280; revised (1968), 274 labor markets: control of employment
INDEX levels, 152; with decentralization and so cialization, 264, 2 9 5 -9 6 ; demand for production workers, 319; demand in do mestic, 287; demand in foreign (1980s), 348; differences among republics, 282 83; effect of decentralization and social ization, 264; effect of nationalization, 93; effect of separate decentralized, 3 6 4 -65 ; government intervention in local, 114; incentives as instruments to allocate, 94 95; lack of demand for new entrants, 288—89; levels of demand in domestic, 201; local supply and demand, 315; pol icy with self-reliance strategy, 110; as po litical problem, 102; preoccupation with supply, 2 1 0 -1 1 ; proposed changes, 337; quota reductions (1950), 156-60; reforms (1970s), 2 7 8 -8 0 ; relation of unemploy ment to supply, 19 4-200; with rising un employment, 3 5 2 -5 8 ; separate from capital markets, 312. See also decentral ization; employment; labor brigades; lo calization; overemployment; unemployment labor markets, informal, 315 labor offices, district, 153 labor policy: with adjustment to interna tional conditions, 9 9 -1 0 0 ; effect of politi cal strategy on, 99; federal level guidelines, 2 9 8 -9 9 ; of full employment, 261, 263; intervention in local labor mar ket, 114; as political problem, 102; within public sector, 2 6 1 -6 2 ; reforms and revisions, 182, 2 7 5 -8 0 ; response to shortages, 110—15; to structure labor market, 1 0 2 -7 landholdings, agrarian: under agrarian re form (1953), 242; with loss of tariff pro tection under GATT, 248; parcelized, 102; by peasants, 242; prohibited sale of, 114 law of value, 7 5 -7 7 , 132, 158, 171, 264 Law on Associated Labor (1976), 164, 278 Law on Employment (1974), 276 Law on Enterprises (1989), 280 Law on Labor Relations (1955, 1965), 267, 272 Law on Workers’ Social Insurance (1921), 4 1 -4 2 League of Communists of Yugoslavia (LCY), 64, 182; effect of growing unemployment
435 on, 3 2 4 -2 5 ; effect of rising unemploy ment on, 368; effect of socialization on, 334; effect of unemployment on disci pline, 3 5 2 -5 3 ; membership limitations, 189, 3 2 2 -2 3 ; fifth party congress, 126— 27, 181, 323; sixth party congress, 150, 181-82, 242; seventh party congress, 268; eighth party congress, 247, 248, 272; tenth party congress, 252. See also party leadership; party policy; Popular Front
League of Communist Youth of Yugoslavia (SKOJ), 78, 126 League of Youth, 333 legislation: abortion and contraception, 274; credit and banking (1977), 279; to encourage return of nationals overseas, 301; ending property rights, 345; free dom for managers, 351; for privatization (1988), 351; on property rights, 279; re lated to education, 2 7 6 -7 7 ; related to state-owned enterprises; 73, 85; for reor ganization oflocalities, 74; unemploymentrelated, 274; wage rates, 71, 87. See also labor legislation Lehmbruch, Gerhard, 10 n .l5 lender of last resort: IM F as, 228; National Bank as, 229 Leninism: economic growth and political radicalism, 7 4 -7 5 ; international aspects, 28; of LCY five-year plan, 65; nationalism of, 69; regimes concept, 1 5 -1 6 , 161; slo gans, 106; stages of cooperative develop ment, 90; vanguard party idea, 44 liberal school: applications of concepts of, 2 7 0 -7 2 ; approach to economic growth, 2 44 -45 ; labor, capital, and institutionalist approaches to unemployment, 210, 212
20 List, Friedrich, 38 loans, foreign, 144 -4 5, 1 50 -51 ; to banks and enterprises, 253; effect on domestic economic policy with, 2 2 4 -2 5 , 2 2 7 -2 8 ; from IM F, 249, 251, 254; to meet trade deficit, 229; from multilateral lending in stitutions, 145; World Bank loans, 232, 249, 252. See also credit, foreign localization: consequences of, 9 1 -9 4 ; of de fense, 30 0 -3 0 1 ; of financial management, 227; of government, 118-1 9; importance
436
INDEX
localization (conl.) of, 78; labor cooperatives, 90-91, 115, 150, 242; of labor recruitment, 176; of party organization, 135; self-sufficiency, 106-7; of unemployment issue, 189. See also decentralization; employment bu reaus; government, local Lowenthal, Richard, 21n,44 Macedonia: abolition of district govern ment, 270; capitalist development, 38 39; class divisions in, 39-40; demo graphic explosion (1962-64), 211; differ ences within, 289—90; employment bureaus, 178; employment in, 287; in vestment in, 291; large-scale agricultural production, 285; nationalism of, 39— 40; opposition to recentralization, 357; separate party organization, 40; SerbMacedonian disagreements, 39-40; un employment rates, 201, 203-5, 208, 298 macroeconomic policy: effect with interna tional openness, 29-30, 223, 226-37, 287; employment cuts to stabilize, 100, 146; enterprise responsibility for stabiliz ation, 235-36; federal government stabi lization plan (1985), 350; IMF and World Bank roles in, 350-51; macrosystems approach to full employment, 10; to re duce unemployment, 212; for stabi lization, 228-32, 254-56, 270, 299; state role, 222-23, 227; undermining of, 226—27* See also fiscal policy; monetary policy Maier, Charles, 98, 335 managers, firm: alliances to influence pol icy, 321-22; conflicts with unions and workers, 273, 327; election and job secu rity of, 323-24; potential conflict with workers, 167-68; protection for partyapproved, 323-24; responsibilities of, 176; wages of, 266, See also self management Marinko, Miha, 133 markets: effect of multiple unlinked, 329 30; local level, 73-74; segmentation, 233; various interpretations, 170-71 market socialism: economy under, 169-71; failure, 165; misuse of term, 169 Markovic, Ante, 5, 256, 280 Marshall Plan (1947), 98, 101, 102, 121
Marxism: focus of Communist party in Yu goslavia, 41-42; unemployment, 3, 322 mass participation concept, 118-19, 127 Meade, James, 213 Mencinger, Joze, 199 Menger, Carl, 167 Meznaric, Silva, 36, 37 migration: to foreign jobs, 198-99, 241; as labor-market competition, 325-26; as re sponse to unemployment, 303-4; un skilled labor, 191-92 Mihailovic, Draza, 50 Mihailovic, Kosta, 210 Mikulic, Branko, 360 Milanovic, Branko, 214-15 military sector: conscription, 147; defense policy related to, 276, 360; effect of World War II, 51-53; equipment and supplies, 188; foreign aid to, 79, 159; purges, 248; during wartime, 49-55. See also national independence Miljovski, Kiril, 223, 294n Milosevic, Slobodan, 344, 364 Mine, Hilary, 101 mines: before and after nationalization, 92 93; labor shortages and employment, 92 94, 192; nationalization, 57; shortages, 105; strikes, 268, 332—33, 343; voluntary labor in, 140-44 Mitrany, David, 2In.42 monetary policy: currency, 349; debt mon etizing, 223; following Slovene model, 227-37; through price regulation, 169 70; recentralization, 355; relation to pro duction requirements, 73; of Slovene Na tional Liberation Front, 59; system reform, 70-71 money supply: expansion with inflow of for eign credits, 227-28; methods to reduce circulation, 104; relation to unemploy ment, 231 Montenegro: employment bureaus in, 178; low level of development, 283; separate party organization, 40; unemployment rates, 201, 204-5, 208. See also Foca model Mutual Defense Assistance agreement, Yugoslavia/United States, 159 national communism principle, 33-34, 224, 240
INDEX
national independence, 28, 33—34, 38, 57, 65, 98, 146, 164, 165, 256 nationalism: Albanians, 342-44, 358, 365-66; Croat, 43; exclusionary, 365; focus on, 32-41, 43; party ideology, 181; republics and regions, 275, 343 44, 365-67; Serbian, 346; sources of, 346-47 nationalization: of mines, 93; during 1944 45, 57-58, 69-70; of retail trade and lo cal enterprises, 114, 117; second phase (1948), 71 nation concept, 38-40 Neuberger, Egon, 226 nonalignment movement, 241, 243, 246, 257, 350 nonproductive labor, 262, 362-63 North Atlantic Treaty Organization (NATO), 243, 349 Nuclear Test Ban Treaty (1964), 247 Offe, Claus, 23, 304, 329 Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), 241 organizations of associated labor, 4, 22, 166, 172 overemployment, 289, 347 overpopulation, 67, 216-17 parliamentary organization, 184n.51 Partisans: brigades, 52-53, 77; campaigns to replace and retire, 288, 318; interest group pressure, 302; movement, 51-54; relocation, 88 party leadership: competition over declin ing resources, 354; in factory workplaces, 268, 354; primary policy role, 126-44; shift in dominance (1924), 36 party policy: education, 362; effect of World War II, 49-51; enforcement, 130, 334 35 peoples committees, 153 people s power concept, 76-77, 167, 224 Perišin, Ivo, 187 Pet rovic-Sane, Dušan, 333 Phillips curve, 7, 219 physiocrats, 19, 22 Pijade, MoSa, 60, 180 Planine, Milka, 254, 347, 360 Poland, 9, 12 -13 , 14, 28, 82, 243, 328,
329
437
political opposition: to localization, 92; over policy, 237-56; to policy on cooperatives and agriculture, 91-94; of villages, 107. See also interest groups political system: in achievement of eco nomic objectives, 165; based on pro ducers, 166-73; constitutional changes in representation, 184; criteria for exclusion from, 320-27; factors preventing con sumer influence, 329-30; local level par ticipation, 74; people’s power concept, 76-77, 167, 224; power consolidation, 99; representation, 74, 300-301; re sponse to economic reform (1980s), 361 63; with rising unemployment, 352-55; strategy for transformation to socialist state, 31-63; village level, 334; of Yugoslavia, 22-23 Popular Front: social transformation role, 78; succeeded by Socialist Alliance of Working people, 189; volunteer labor brigades, 77-78, 97, 111-12, 121, 125, 149-51, 177, 243, 268, 333 population: explosion, 211, 263; levels of rural, 43; policy (I960), 211; by republic or province, 387; surplus agricultural, 67; unemployment as overpopulation, 216— 17 Prasnikar, James, 215 Pravda, Alex, 12-13 prices: central setting of, 329; effect of im port costs on, 228; factors of production, 169-70; under Foca model, 61; food pol icy setting of, 285; mechanism under commodity production concept, 169; reg ulation of factors of production prices, 169-70; trade by linked or interdepen dent, 113-15, 133. See also rationing; regulation Primorac, Emil, 199-200 private sector: with agrarian and currency reforms, 70; capitalism of, 174; coordina tion with local level public sector, 74, 89-92, 127, 166-67, 172; differentiation of employment from public, 347; eco nomic performance, 279; effect of gov ernment control of cooperatives, 91; employment in villages, 334; interest group development in, 342-44; as labor supply pool, 174; limitations on private sales, 114; local level coordination with
438
IN D EX
private sector (cont.) public sector, 73—74; political represen tation of employed in, 74, 321; require ments of farmers in (1957), 244; as safe haven for surplus labor, 2 6 2 -6 3 , 279, 325; subsistence for unemployed in, 261, 312, 347; surplus labor, 303; tourist ser vices, 269, See also farmers’ (marketing) cooperatives; landholdings, agrarian; workers, private sector privatization: legislation, 351; policy for public-sector firms, 279, 280 producers: adjustment to price shifts, 233; control over export policy, 235; control over finance and capital, 1 83 -84, 222 23, 2 2 9 -3 0 ; cooperative, 190; public sec tor political rights, 166, 320 -21 production: agricultural sector policy to gain labor for, 117; changes required by changed objectives, 165; commodity pro duction concept, 169; dependence on imported materials, 249; differences in Slovene and Foca approaches, 163; focus of economic policy, 137—38; incentives for farms, 113; of new products, 109; re organization under democratization, 14 2 -43; as source of income, 110 production brigades, autonomous, 142-44, 151 productive labor concept, 18 19 productivity: divisionalization to increase, 277; incentives in labor policy for, 8 6 -8 7 , 100, 166, 2 6 1 -6 2 ; as key to employment expansion, 174; Marxist definition, 174; priority over employment, 261; produc tion brigade concept, 142-4 4; projected targets for growth, 188-89; strategy to increase, 68, 8 6 -8 7 ; wages as measure of contribution to, 175 profit sharing, 175-76 proletarian brigades. See Partisans property rights: division between public and private sectors, 312, 322; Foca model, 60; for foreign investors, 5, 351; guaranteeing subsistence, 173; legislation ending, 345; opposition to reform, 357; during and post-World War II, 5 6 -5 7 , 6 9 -7 0 ; o f republican governments, 355; restoration o f republics’, 14 7 -48; under Slovene model, 59; socialist, 355; worker as owner, 166
protectionism: republics and towns, 172 73, 2 9 5 -9 6 , 325; strategy of, 2 3 2 -3 3 ; Western European, 251, 348 Przeworski, Adam, 328 Public Law 480, United States, 249 public sector: coordination with local-level private sector, 74, 8 9 -9 2 , 127, 166-67, 172; differentiation o f employment from private sector, 347; employment by re public and region in, 2 9 1 -9 2 ; factory management in, 85; growth with self reliance strategy, 111, 2 7 4 -7 5 ; guaran teed minimum wage in, 262; labor books, 8 8 -8 9 ; labor policy within, 261; local-level coordination with private sec tor, 7 3 -7 4 ; modernization of labor force in, 268; payment of guaranteed wage, 173-74; in restructuring of society (post-1944), 68; socialization through em ployment in, 262; supplements to capac ity, 77; threat of unemployment, 321; unemployment (1952), 160. See also em ployment; firms; state-owned enter prises; unemployment; workers Pucar, Djuro, 158 purges: of Albanian leaders, 343; Com intern (1928), 36; o f Communist Party of Yugoslavia, 119—20; of developmental economists, 210; party (1950-51), 180; of party members, 127; political and mili tary (1964-66), 248; Rankovic, 274, 324; related to managers’ market orientation, 324 radicalism, Yugoslav, 80 Radosavljevic, Dobrivoje, 139 Rajk, Laszlo, 145 Rankovic, Aleksandar, 4 6 -4 9 , 147, 248, 274, 324 rationing, 125, 14 5-46; with centralization of supplies, 132; control over employ ment level through, 152-53 ; of jobs ac cording to ethnic criteria, 301; for wage and salary earners, 104-5. See also com modity shortages Reform (1965), 237, 247 regions. See Kosovo; Slavonia; Vojvodina regulation: local government, 176; to pre vent unemployment, 240; prices of fac tors of production, 16 9 -70; of privatesector subsistence wage, 174; of public-
IN D EX sector wage rates, 1 75 -76, 271; o f terms of trade, 9 0 -9 1 Regulation on Settling Labor (1950), 151 52 remittances, 246, 254, 269, 293 republics: capital flows and investment within, 2 9 0 -9 8 ; differences within, 2 8 9 -9 0 ; effect o f economic autonomy, 2 9 0 -9 1 , 3 3 8-3 9. See also Bosnia; Croatia; Macedonia; Montenegro; Ser bia; Slovenia revenues, federal government, 185, 231 rights: as basis for Slovenia’s opposition (1980s), 3 6 3 -6 4 ; o f citizenship, 172, 186, 3 6 6 -6 7 ; in concept of jo b security, 262; constitutional right to work, 173; of eco nomic and political decision making, 166; to guaranteed minimum wage, 262; of private sector workers, 166; to self management o f work collectives, 261; of unemployed individuals, 4, 30 See also property rights rights, political: o f associations of produ cers (workers), 166, 320—21; of private sector, 186; o f public and private sec tor worker-producers, 166, 173, 320
21 Rivers, Douglas, 9 n .l3 Roemer, J., 19n, 19n.38 Romania, 14, 101 Rucciardi, Joseph, 20n.40 rule of law, 1 3 6 -37 Sabel, Charles, 12 Sacks, Stephen, 214 Salaj, Djuro, 154 Sarlo, Metodija Sator, 3 9 -4 0 security system: firm and local government responsibility for, 250; republics’ opin ions on issue of, 255 security zones, 139, 284 segmentation: of the economy, 350; o f mar kets, 233; obstacles to overcoming, 361; of society, 312 self-determination: o f nations within Yugoslavia, 41; strategy for, 38. See also government, local; government, repub lics; localization; villages self-management concept, 16 7 -69, 175, 1 79 -80 ; basic organizations of associ ated labor under, 277; conditions for ex
439
tension of, 2 3 3 -3 5 , 271, 277; declared end of, 5; effect of, 3 3 0 -3 4 ; for employ ment bureaus, 302; legislation ending system for, 256; by manufacturing and foreign-trade firms, 253; political conse quences of, 329; in publie-sector work places, 261; rights to, 196; in Slovene model, 2 6 4 -6 5 ; with withering away of the state, 186; for Yugoslav workers, 12, 15. See also production brigades; work collectives; workers’ councils self-managing communities of interest, 234, 302 self-reliance policy: enforcement, 130; im plementation (1948), 1 2 1 -2 8 ; of Tito, 108-11 Serbia: abolition of district government, 270; developmentalists in, 210; economic development policy and outcome, 291, 2 9 6 -9 7 ; employment bureaus, 178—79; immigration of Serbs and expulsion of non-Serbs, 365; mines in, 94; national ism, 3 4 3-4 4; plans for development, 297—98; political rebellion, 365; response to recentralization, 358; separate party organization, 40; surplus labor, 38; un employment rates, 201, 2 0 4 -5 , 298; un rest, 338 serfdom, 89 Shoup, Paul, 35 Sicherl, Pavle, 240n, 2 8 7 -8 8 Sirotanović, Alija, 143, 151 Škegro, Borislav, 226, 228, 231, 232, 303 SKOJ. See League of Communist Youth of Yugoslavia (SKOJ) Slavonia: emigration from, 283; large-scale agricultural production, 57, 285; peasant resettlement in, 93 Slovene model, 34, 58; challenge to, 83; confronts Foča conditions, 99; contradic tion of Foča model, 22; with country’s dissolution, 3 7 1 -7 2 ; economic methods, 1 61 -62; of economic role of government, 5 8 -5 9 , 2 2 2 -2 3 , 2 6 4 -6 5 , 298; full em ployment concept, 3 6 7 -6 8 ; implementa tion in Slovenia, 283; institutions of, 96, 165; investment and labor policies, 224; mix with Foča model, 2 6 5 -6 8 , 349; na tionalism, 56; populist, or agrarian social ist elements, 89; production focus, 163; requirement for closed economic system,
440
INDEX
Slovene model (cont.) 227; return to pure version (1980s), 146, 345-46, 349; vision of the state in, 182— 83, 317-18 Slovene National Liberation Front, 49, 51, 55-56, 58-59 Slovene Peoples party, 43 Slovenia: capitalist development, 38; con tested land areas, 57; demands for pro ductivity and growth standards, 283, 296-97; economic performance under government policy, 263-64; foreign cur rency flows to, 235; full employment re cord, 296, 339-41; industrialization in, 94; labor shortages and immigration, 263-64, 283, 303, 325, 339-41; national ism, 365—66; national security issue, 255; organized unions and working class, 41; population flows into, 283, 303; protec tionist labor policies, 342; response to re centralization and economic reform, 355-60, 363; secession, 371; skilled workers and professionals, 94, 296, 303; strikes, 296; unemployment rates, 201, 203-5, 208, 339-44; unrest (after 1967), 275; vote for independence, 256; wage rates, 293 Slovenian Communist party, 36 social democracy, 327-28 social insurance: centralization of funds for, 71-72; for certain unemployed, 177; de terminants of benefits, 152—53; Law on Social Insurance (1921), 41-42; self management, 169, 183; state regulation of, 86, See also benefits; health insurance socialism: commodity production concept, 169; conflict on transition methods, 158 59; differences in Yugoslavian form, 24 28; distinct from state capitalism, 167; economy without planning, 170; employ ment method of payment, 166; full em ployment concept, 3—11; at local level, 90—91; of public sector, 74-79; transfor mation to (1948), 121-44; unemployment under, 4; workplace under, 4. See also la bor brigades; market socialism Socialist Alliance of Working People, 33, 189 socialization: of agriculture, 110-15; of debt, 229-30; of defense, 300-301; effect on Communist party, 334; effect on labor
markets, 264; through employment in public sector, 262; to extend self management concept, 271; of invest ment, 245-46, 249, 271; rationalization for, 331; in Slovene and Foca models, 265; of the state, 186-89. See also public sector social policy: open unemployment as, 176— 78; unification and centralization, 71^-72 social sector. See public sector social services: financing by firms, 262; in stitutions, 180; se If-management concept in, 271; self-management for bureaus of, 274; self-management of tocal, 266 social status: of public-sector employee, 23, 317; relation of education to, 317; of un employed individuals, 3-4, 23, 30, 321; upward mobility, 317-19 social transformation: goals of, 70, 74; post-1944, 68-69; role of youth groups, 78 social unrest, 216, 255, 275, 338-39. See also strikes; work stoppages society: divided into public and private sec tors, 191, 311-12; effect of recentraliza tion policy, 360-61; with Marxist ideology basis, 21-22; perception of un employment in, 23, 311; periodic reorga nization, 262; public-sector employment as status in, 317; redistribution of assets, 68-70; regains role of the state (Slovene model), 183; response to unemployment invisibility, 312-20; segmentation, 312; structure of socialist, 312-13; with un employment in Kosovo, 342 Soviet Union: campaign against Tito, 145; economic reform, 28, 349; postwar trade agreements with, 81; post—World War II policy toward Yugoslavia, 80-81, 108; Yugoslavian conflict over Balkans policy, 107-8 spending, government: announced in creases (1947), 109; for defense (1949), 146; effect on local governments of re duced, 287; increases in local, 266-67; by self-managing communities of inter est, 234 Stalin, Joseph: postwar perceptions of Yugoslavia, 80-81; quarrels with, 100 101; wartime relations with Tito, 53 Stark, David, 12
INDEX state, the: anticentralist concept (1924), 36; disappearance of (Slovene model), 182 83; implication of socialization or wither ing away, 186; Marxist ideology, 20; new role (1948), 1 1 7 -1 8 ; Yugoslav interpreta tion of role, 219, 222, 3 3 5 -3 6 . See also government, federal; government, local; government, republics state-owned enterprises: economic link to farmers’ cooperatives, 172; expansion of United Union organization to, 87; pro tection from private sector labor de mands, 91; restructuring (1949), 151; role of, 73, 85 strikes, 86, 268, 273, 275, 296, 315, 343, 353 subsistence: in conception of economic growth, 6 6 -6 7 ; as criterion for firing workers, 3 1 2-1 6, 347; education at local level against concept of, 74; employment as, 328; guaranteed, 68, 89, 313 Suvar, Stipe, 3 1 9 -2 0 Sweden, 31, 329 Switzerland, 342 Tanic, Zivan, 301 tax policy: credits as incentives, 234, 302; to encourage employment, 281; o f in come (1980s), 281; local government, 78, 176; for private sector, 352; reform (1947), 78; relation to foreign borrowing, 232; by self-managing communities o f in terest, 234 territorial principle. See banking system; decentralization; government, local; gov ernment, republics; localization Therborn, Goran, 6n, 24, 260n Tito, Josip Broz, 32, 39; on Bosnia, 39; on distribution of labor, 174; on extension of socialism, 1 3 7 -38 ; increased personal power, 109; independence from Stalin, 3 3 -3 4 ; leadership, 33, 51, 5 3 -5 6 , 145; nonalignment policy (1958-61), 246; po sition on domestic industrialization strat egy, 96; prediction of socialism, 134; on productivity, 84; relations with Stalin, 53, 65; relations with United States, 101; on rule of law, 13 6-37; self-reliance pol icy, 108-1 1, 130-31 Todaro paradox, 212 Todorovic, Marija, 319
441
Tomasevič, Jožo, 44n, 90n, 146n, 151n, 338n trade, foreign: centralized policy manage ment, 187; Cocom export-control re gime, 9 5 -9 6 ; economic growth strategy with openness to, 2 2 4 -3 7 ; federal gov ernment policy, 2 2 3 -2 4 ; industrialization strategy based on, 79; influence on eco nomic policy, 3 4 7 -4 9 ; openness of Yugoslavian economy to, 2 8 -2 9 ; as path to increased productivity, 225; policy for mation, 116—17; searching for, 121, 129; as source of income, 9 5 -9 6 trade agreements: Joint Export-Import Agency, Allied occupation, 144, 150; with Poland and Czechoslovakia, 82; in shift to foreign trade strategy, 95; with Soviet Union, 81, 241, 243; with Western Europe, 122, 129; with Western E u ropean countries (1984), 122 trade deficit: conditions for, 231; effect of external shocks, 251, 2 5 3 -5 4 ; effect on incomes and employment, 263; financed through borrowing, 252; post-1952 pe riod, 2 2 8 -2 9 ; stabilization to reduce, 147. See also balance of payments trade policy: with change in terms o f trade, 247—48; GATT membership, 2 4 5 -4 6 ; im plementation of self-management princi ple for, 253; liberalization, 187, 2 4 5 -4 6 ; reorientation to Western trade, 159; with Western trade reorientation, 159 trade unions: functions under Regulation on Settling Labor, 1 54 -55 ; leagues in state-owned enterprises, 87; organization of socialist competition, 78; planned ef fect of workers’ councils on, 261; repre sentation on workers councils, 85; responsibility for unemployment preven tion, 176; role under socialism, 8 5 -8 8 ; unification (1944), 71 treaty of friendship, Soviet-Yugoslav, 83 Treaty of Rome (1958), 244 Trieste, 84 Trotsky, Lev, 68 Truman, Harry S, 151 Tudjman, Franjo, 367 Tyson, Laura, 213, 216, 220, 226 unemployment: analysis of postwar socialist period (Farkas), 2 1 6 -1 8 ; capitalist, 3;
442
INDEX
unemployment (cont.) consequences o f rising, 3 5 2 -6 7 ; dual face of, 8; with economic growth policy, 269; elï'ect of growing, 3 2 4 -2 5 ; effect on eth nic composition, 366; (actors causing, 165, 2 6 3 -6 4 , 2 7 8 -7 9 , 2 8 6 -8 7 ; frictional and open, 17 6-77, 195; guarantee against, 173; hidden, 6, 191-94, 198, 216—17, 271, 314, 321; immunity from, 3 2 3 -2 4 ; Marxist theory, 3 - 4 , 322; migra tion as response to, 3 0 3 -4 ; official con cept of and solution to, 3 1 2 -1 4 ; as overproduction of intellectuals, 317; po litical conséquences (1980s), 352—67; po litical exclusion with, 3 2 0 -2 7 ; prevention, 176, 240; protection against, 262, 278; relation to money supply, 231; social stigma of, 4, 23, 3 1 2 -2 0 ; societal response to invisibility of, 3 1 2 -2 0 ; stan dard explanation of Yugoslav, 218—20; structural, 194, 201, 310, 347; threat of, 3 - 4 , 321; Ward model, 165, 208, 210; Yugoslavian brand, 12. See also capitalist unemployment unemployment compensation: eligibility, 177-78, 195; funding of, 302; increase in amounts for (1980s), 281 unemployment rates: by age, 203, 2 0 6 -7 , 209, 3 8 8 -8 9 ; with cuts in labor force, 269; increase (1952-88), 191, 193 -9 4 ; in terpretation of data, 194-208, 240, 264; in Kosovo, Slovenia, and BosniaHerzegovina, 3 3 9 -4 4 ; levels and demo graphics of (1980s), 3 4 7 -4 8 ; ofpublicsector workers, 160; regional differences, 201, 2 0 3 -5 ; Todaro paradox to explain rising, 212; among women and youth, 287, 316, 333, 383 unemployment theory: Austrian school, 2 1 4 -1 5 ; capital school, 214; developmen tal is t school, 210; liberal school, 210, 2 1 2 -1 3 union leagues, 87 United Kingdom, 81 United Nations, 82 United States, 31; economic assistance (1950), 1 5 0-51; effect of containment pol icy (1947), 95, 99, loans from, 144-45, 150, 249; policy shift (1949), 121-22, 1 44 -45; postwar relations with Yugoslavia, 81, 101; relations with, 121,
144-45, 2 4 6 -4 7 , 349; revised Yugosla vian policy, 144-4 5 United Unions of Yugoslavia, 45, 71, 88 87; membership in, 18 9-90; political re sources, 325; relation to workers’ coun cils, 154, role in public-sector firms, 3 2 6 -2 7 urbanization, 348 Verba, Sidney, 9 n .l3 Verdery, Katherine, 22n.45 Veselinov, Jovan, 158 veterans' organization (SUBNOR), 51, 302 villages: agricultural labor surplus, 67, co existence with labor cooperatives, 9 0 -9 1 ; cooperatives, 44, 92; government inter vention into autonomy of, 114; guaran teed subsistence at level of, 89; labor recruitment in, 128; political system of, 107, 135-36, 334; private-sector employ ment in, 334 Vojvodina: agricultural estates, 43, 57; em igration from, 283; large-scale agri cultural production, 285; opposition to recentralization, 3 5 7 -5 8 ; peasant reset tlement in, 88, 93; unemployment rates, 201, 2 0 4 -5 voluntary labor. See labor brigades Vukmanovic-Tempo, Svetozar, 55, 124, 141-42, 273, 327, 333 wage rates: central setting of, 173 -76 , 329; differences across republics, 2 9 3 -9 4 ; across public-sector firms, 293—94; re placement oflegislated, 112; setting of, 87, 91, 103, 176 wages: components of, 176; factors reduc ing competition for, 88; as incentive to increase productivity, 8 6 -8 9 ; as measure o f contribution, 175; paid in cash and coupons, 104; public-sector guarantee of, 173-74, 312; redefined as income, 176; with rise in import prices, 228; withinfirm conflict over inequalities, 3 3 0 -3 1 ; as work defined by job classification, 166, 175; worker acceptance o f limits on, 261; worker cont ml, 267. See also collective bargaining Wagners law, 275 Ward, Benjamin, 12, 15, 208, 2 1 2 -1 3 , 215, 220, 263, 266n, 267n
IN D E X Warsaw Pact: choice against membership, 248; collapse (1989), 349; formation (1955), 243; troops invade Czechoslova kia, 250 women: discrimination in employment of, 104; employment of, 287, 316, 333; unemployment rates, 383; wages of, 123 work collectives, 111; as association of pro ducers, 166; in pnblic-sector workplaces, 261; self-management, 2 6 1 -6 2 ; under Slovene and Foca models, 265 workers: allocation in public and private sectors, 8 8 -8 9 , 157-58; conflicts among, 3 3 0 -3 2 ; effect of participation in central policy, 4—5, 321; exports of, 246; as inter est group, 327, 3 2 9 -3 0 , 341; interest of, 8 7 -8 8 ; jo b cuts and reallocation, 156-60; political rights, 166, 173, 3 2 0 -2 1 ; shift ing between public and private sectors, 263; surplus public sector, 30 0-3 01 ; un employment in public sector, 160 See also producers workers, private sector: political represen tation, 74, 321; rights, 187 workers, skilled: bargaining power, 84, 86; as brigade leaders, 14 2-43; competition for, 87; distribution of, 9 4 -9 5 ; emigra tion, 276; emphasis on, 2 6 8 -6 9 ; favored as party members, 3 2 2 -2 3 ; in informal labor market, 315; policy to increase number of, 268, 2 7 6 -7 7 ; scarcity, 102, 107, 110 -12 , 130, 141, 296; in Slovenia, 283; wages of, 266
443
workers, unskilled: day labor, 303; increase in, 368; in mines, 9 2 -9 3 ; not in public or private sectors, 191-92; problems of, 286; return from abroad, 199; wages of, 319; weak position of, 86; work stoppages and strikes by, 3 1 4 -1 5 , 319 workers’ constitution, 278 workers’ councils: in assignment of redun dant workers, 3 0 6 -9 ; effect of, 1 6 1-6 2; to end collective bargaining, 8 8 -8 9 , 153 55, 261, 326; function, 156—57, 175, 2 6 6 -6 7 ; introduction of, 64, 8 4 -8 5 , 261; rationale for, 28; relationship with unions, 155—56 work stoppages, 330, 331, 353 World Bank: development loans, 232, 236; effect of loans from, 279; loan for timber equipment (1948), 122; membership, 144; negotiations with, 122; require ments for new loans (1987), 350 Yugoslav Emergency Assistance Act (1950), United States, 151 Yugoslav People’s Army (YPA): defense pol icy, 2 5 0 -5 6 ; redundancy, 350; wages, pensions, and benefits, 188 ZAVNOH. See Croatian Liberation Front (ZAVNOH) Zimmerman, William, 200 Zuehlke, Thomas, 226, 228, 231, 232, 303 Zujovic, Sreten, 48, 76, 119 Zupanov, Josip, 320 Zuvela, Mladen, 320
About th e Author Susan L. Woodward is a Senior Fellow in th e Foreign Policy Studies Pro gram at the Brookings Institution.
Lightning Source UK Ltd Mi IIon Keynes UK 21 January 2010
1 4 8 9 17U K 0 0 0 0 1B /54/A