The international potato industry
The international potato industry JOSEPH F GUENTHNER
Cambridge England
Published ...
134 downloads
1747 Views
2MB Size
Report
This content was uploaded by our users and we assume good faith they have the permission to share this book. If you own the copyright to this book and it is wrongfully on our website, we offer a simple DMCA procedure to remove your content from our site. Start by pressing the button below!
Report copyright / DMCA form
The international potato industry
The international potato industry JOSEPH F GUENTHNER
Cambridge England
Published by Woodhead Publishing Limited, Abington Hall, Abington Cambridge CB1 6AH, England www.woodhead-publishing.com First published 2001, Woodhead Publishing Ltd © 2001, Woodhead Publishing Ltd The author has asserted his moral rights Conditions of sale This book contains information obtained from authentic and highly regarded sources. Reprinted material is quoted with permission, and sources are indicated. Reasonable efforts have been made to publish reliable data and information, but the authors and the publisher cannot assume responsibility for the validity of all materials. Neither the author nor the publisher, nor anyone else associated with this publication, shall be liable for any loss, damage or liability directly or indirectly caused or alleged to be caused by this book. Neither this book nor any part may be reproduced or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic or mechanical, including photocopying, microfilming and recording, or by any information storage or retrieval system, without permission in writing from the publisher. The consent of Woodhead Publishing Limited does not extend to copying for general distribution, for promotion, for creating new works, or for resale. Specific permission must be obtained in writing from Woodhead Publishing Limited for such copying. Trademark notice: Product or corporate names may be trademarks or registered trademarks, and are used only for identification and explanation, without intent to infringe. British Library Cataloguing in Publication Data A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library. ISBN 1 85573 465 6 Typeset by Best-set Typesetter Ltd., Hong Kong Printed by TJ International Ltd, Cornwall, England
Contents
Foreword . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
ix
Preface . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
xi
List of abbreviations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
xiii
Part I Introduction
1
2
History and background . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
3
A brief history . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
3
Cultural aspects of potatoes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
12
References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
19
Potato properties, types and use . . . . . . . . . . . .
20
Nutritional attributes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
20
Culinary aspects of potatoes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
22
Potato types and varieties . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
24
Fresh potatoes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
28
Processed potatoes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
29
v
CONTENTS
Fresh processed potatoes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
31
Seed potatoes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
31
Livestock feed and other uses . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
32
References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
33
Part II Economics of the global potato economy
3
4
5
Supply . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
37
Potato growth requirements . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
37
Production zones . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
39
Production trends . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
42
Production systems . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
56
Costs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
65
Factors that influence plantings . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
70
Potato yields . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
73
References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
74
Demand . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
76
Demand theory . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
76
Factors that influence demand for potato products . . .
79
Utilization trends by country . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
87
Consumption trends by type of final product . . . . . . .
98
Demand forecasting models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
106
References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
111
Prices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 113 Price theory . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
113
Pricing mechanisms, institutions and information . . . .
126
Price changes through time . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
135
Price forecasting . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
141
References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
143
Part III
6
The trade
Fresh potato trade . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 147 Fresh potato exports . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . vi
148
CONTENTS
7
8
9
10
Fresh potato imports . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
152
Net trade for fresh potatoes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
155
Fresh potato prices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
158
Fresh potato trade issues . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
161
References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
168
Frozen potato trade . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 169 Frozen potato exports . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
172
Frozen potato imports . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
176
Net trade for frozen potatoes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
179
Frozen potato trade prices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
181
Frozen potato trade issues . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
184
References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
189
Seed potato trade . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 191 Seed potato exports . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
194
Seed potato imports . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
196
Seed potato net trade . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
202
Seed potato prices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
206
Seed potato trade issues . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
209
References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
213
Other potato trade . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 214 Potato snack trade . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
214
Dehydrated potato trade . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
220
Starch potato trade . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
226
Miscellaneous potato trade . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
229
References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
232
The marketing chain . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 233 Quick-service restaurants . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
234
Processors . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
243
Retailers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
251
Fresh packers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
253
Growers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
254
Potato futures markets . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
255
References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
260
vii
CONTENTS
Part IV
11
12
Key issues for the future
Technology issues . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 263 GMO acceptance . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
264
Seed technology . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
268
Plant property rights . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
269
Electronic technology . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
272
References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
273
Market issues . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 274 Greater China . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
274
Trade agreements . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
278
Currency exchange . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
280
Branding by variety . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
281
International growers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
282
Reference . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
283
Bibliography . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
285
Index
288
..........................................
viii
Foreword
I
t is with great pleasure that I write a Foreword to this book. J o s e p h Guenthner, whom I have known for several years, has a quite incredible knowledge of the potato industry and he is particularly gifted at disseminating this knowledge to the many audiences who have had the privilege of listening to his lectures. For those particularly, like myself, who have been immersed in the potato industry for many years, and even to those who have only been in this industry for a few years, I am quite certain this will be found a most interesting, stimulating and very readable book. We have always known the potato is a particularly versatile commodity. Well, we now have an equally versatile handbook to this most interesting of industries. I wish you very pleasant reading. Richard Harris President of UEITP (European Association of Potato Processing Industry)
ix
I
Preface
was thrilled when Neil Wenborn asked me if I would be interested in writing a book about the global potato industry. He explained that Woodhead Publishing had a series of books about the international trade of commodities ranging from aluminium to zinc. I was pleased to accept the challenge of writing the first book to deal with the fascinating topic of the international potato industry. I am grateful to the University of Idaho for granting me a sabbatical leave that gave me the time to write this book. The book is aimed at a wide audience. People who are involved in the business part of the potato marketing chain as growers, processors, shippers, retailers, marketers, advisers or fast-food providers should find items of interest in the book. Economists, students and those entering the industry for the first time may find that this book provides background information that can make them more familiar with the potato industry. This book also provides an opportunity for those people at the end of the marketing chain, the consumers, to learn more about one of the world’s most important foods. Part I introduces readers to the impact that potatoes have had on people and their culture. From its origins in the Inca society of xi
PREFACE
South America to its role in the Irish Potato Famine to its contribution to the settlement in remote islands, the potato has a long, rich history around the globe. Potato consumption, in its many forms, has influenced economic development, wars and the fast-food society. Part II describes the global potato industry in the economic terms of supply, demand and prices. Part III looks at the trade of potatoes around the world. Since the different potato products flow in separate channels, four chapters are devoted to trade by type of product. Another chapter deals with the marketing chain from field to consumer. Part IV deals with the future outlook for the global potato industry. One chapter discusses technology issues, the other explores market issues. Three generations of women inspired me to write this book. I am grateful that my mother, Carol Dawley Guenthner taught me to love to learn. I am deeply indebted to a potato farmer’s daughter, my wife Terri, for her support in writing this book. She and my three daughters,Amanda, Megan and Hayley, were patient with me when I devoted time and energy to the book. They understood my fascination with the potato industry because it is in their blood as well as mine. They are descendants of many generations of potato growers.
xii
Abbreviations
APEC APHIS BC BPC BRR CFIA CIPC CITT CME CPB CPI EFP EU FAO GATT GI GMO GNP GPS HDP HI
Asia Pacific Economic Cooperation Animal and Plant Health Inspection Service British Columbia British Potato Council bacterial ring rot Canadian Food Inspection Agency chlorpropham Canadian International Trade Tribunal Chicago Mercantile Exchange Colorado potato beetle consumer price index exchange of futures for physicals European Union Food & Agriculture Organization General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade glycemic index genetically modified organism gross national product global positioning system high demand and production Herfindahl Index xiii
ABBREVIATIONS
IFPRI International Food Policy Research Institute IGRI Idaho grower return index IMPACT International Model for Policy Analysis of Agricultural Commodities and Trade IPC Idaho Potato Commission ITC International Trade Commission KFC Kentucky Fried Chicken LIFFE London International Futures and Options Exchange MAFF Ministry of Agriculture, Fisheries and Food (UK) MH maleic hydrazide MI McDonald’s Index NAFTA North American Free Trade Agreement NAPI Navajo Agricultural Products Industry NPPB National Potato Promotion Board (US) NYCE New York Cotton Exchange NYME New York Mercantile Exchange P&G Procter & Gamble PCCF per capita consumption of potatoes for food in kg/year PEI Prince Edward Island PGI Potato Growers of Idaho PGW Potato Growers of Washington PLRV potato leafroll virus QSR quick-service restaurants RS resistant starch SPS Sanitary & Phytosanitary Measures TPS true potato seed UEITP European Association of Potato Processing Industry USDA US Department of Agriculture USTR US Trade Representative WANA West Asia and North Africa WTO World Trade Organization ZMP Zentrale Markt- und Preisberichtstelle
xiv
PA RT
I INTRODUCTION
CHAPTER
1 History and background
A brief history
T
he humble potato has long been a vital part of societies scattered around the world. When European conquerors raided South American cities, they found the natives eating an unimpressive, odd-looking vegetable. In their quest for gold and silver, they could not have imagined the impact that this potato would have in Europe, then North America, then the rest of the world. The history of the potato is intertwined with the lives of the people who influenced its development into an important international food. Major economic and political forces of the last four centuries were tempered by the potato’s attributes but also by its vulnerability to disease. This common vegetable literally shaped societies in South America, France, Ireland, North America, China, New Zealand, remote islands in the Southern Hemisphere and in many other parts of the world.
A gift from the Incas The potato was more than a food to the Incas of South America. They believed it had the power to heal ailments such as headaches, broken bones, skin disease and rheumatism. Incas had been growing and eating potatoes 3
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
for two thousand years before the Europeans came to the New World. They domesticated the wild potatoes that grew naturally in the Andes mountains and began the development of a food that is now among the top staples worldwide. Wild potatoes are indigenous in South, Central and North America but the Incas were the only people to cultivate them in pre-Columbian times. Over the years the Incas planted and improved a wide variety of potatoes. They used the name papas for potatoes in general, but had other, colourful names to describe particular types. One with red flesh was called ‘weep blood for the Inca’. Another, tough type was known as the ‘knife breaker’. Others were called ‘human head’ and ‘red mother’.1 Potato colours seemed to span the rainbow – ranging from white and yellow to blue, red, brown and black. To say that the potato was important to the Incas is an understatement. It was their lifeblood. Although they sometimes ate fish, deer and fowl, their diet was mostly vegetarian, consisting of potatoes, beans and maize. They grew several crops in the lowlands, but mostly potatoes in the highlands where the people lived at altitudes not suitable for maize. The Incas built sophisticated terraces and irrigation systems for their potato crops and made their homes on rocks where potatoes could not grow. The Incas were not only the first potato growers but also the first potato processors. They developed a method to freeze-dry the tubers into chuño, a product that could be stored from year to year and was even used as currency. The chuño process was to drive water out of the potatoes using human power and the elements. At harvest the Incan workers spread out the potatoes to freeze during the cold nights in the mountains. During the day men, women and children stomped on the potatoes with their bare feet to squeeze out the moisture. After four or five days of this, the Incas had their chuño, a freeze-dried food that was easy to store and transport. Food production, processing and storing systems based on the potato enabled the Incan society to flourish. Food efficiency enabled many of the citizens to become involved in other pursuits such as engineering, art, law, astronomy and science. The potato helped build the Incas into the largest society in the Americas. When the Spanish invaders came, the Inca empire consisted of ten million people spread over 2000 miles along the Andes mountain range of the South American continent. Spanish conquistadors, although small in number, easily defeated the Incas and imposed colonial rule over them. How could a small force of invaders conquer such a large empire? Some say that the conquistadors strategically captured Incan food storehouses, which held chuño, to gain the upper hand. Ironically, the potato helped the Incas build their society, but it may have led to their demise because they depended so heavily on it. 4
HISTORY AND B ACKGROUND
Pedro de Cieza de Leon provided early written record of potatoes in 1553 when he described his Peruvian adventures of 1538. He told of potato production, the chuño process and how potatoes protected the Incas from famine. He also told of many Spanish citizens becoming wealthy by transporting chuño to the mines of Potosi.2 Spaniards destroyed the Inca civilization in their search for gold and silver. They shipped vast amounts of the precious metals back to the mother country, but they also left with something perhaps more important – the potato. According to one European observer in 1800, ‘. . . this useful root, for which we are indebted to America, . . . is more valuable than all the gold of Mexico, all the diamonds of Golconda or all the tea of China’.3
The potato in Europe The lifeblood of the Incas was at first merely a botanical curiosity in Europe. In time the potato became an important food crop in many parts of the continent. The potato in Europe is a story that involves myths, fear, deception, theft, exploitation and tragedy. There is no conclusive written evidence regarding how and when potatoes first came from the New World to Europe. Some scholars believe that the route was from North America to Europe via either Sir Francis Drake or Sir Walter Raleigh.4 Some writers acclaim Raleigh for the introduction of potatoes to the British Isles, but others suggest that he did not travel to the places at the times he supposedly transported potatoes. The legend regarding Drake, the first Englishman to circumnavigate the globe, is that he introduced potatoes from Virginia to England. Myth-refuters claim that Drake did indeed learn about potatoes at a 1577 stop in Chile during his first round-the-world trip, but did not return to England until 1580. On a later voyage, in 1586, Drake collected potatoes at Cartegena (in today’s Colombia), then stopped in Virginia on his way back to England. In the colony he picked up some discouraged English settlers and gave them transport back home. Many people assumed that since the passengers came from Virginia, the potatoes did as well. Potatoes arrived in Spain a bit earlier, but since the actual first event was not recorded there is not one specific name associated with it. Spain controlled trade from its American colonies, so the first potatoes may have arrived in some ship’s stores or among the personal belongings of a returning colonist or administrator. The earliest written record of a commercial European transaction involving potatoes was in 1573. The Hospital de la Sangre in Seville purchased potatoes in the fall, which suggests that they were grown domestically and not imported. For stocks to be built up to commercial levels from small amounts carried on ships, potatoes must have been planted in Spain several years before the hospital purchased them. 5
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
Myths accelerated and slowed the acceptance of potatoes in Europe, but within 150 years of introduction potatoes became ubiquitous.The potato plant was, in various places and times, regarded as a botanical curiosity, a medicine, a narcotic, a poison, a livestock feed, a food for royalty, a salvation of peasants and a harbinger of famine. Herbalists and physicians who claimed that eating potatoes could cause indigestion, flatulence, rickets and syphilis slowed acceptance of potatoes as a food. A French provincial government, convinced that potatoes caused leprosy, banned potato production. Because of its phallic shape some people claimed the potato was an aphrodisiac. Religious leaders declared potatoes evil because the Bible made no reference to them. Other societal leaders made claims about potatoes that accelerated acceptance. Carolus Clusius, a French botanist, said that eating cooked potatoes was good for the health, made for large families and increased life span. One herbalist prescribed potato broth for diarrhoea, tuberculosis, impotence and barrenness. During the 1600s potatoes were a food for aristocrats on the European continent. Perhaps through scarcity and high prices, potatoes were viewed as a luxury good and not for the likes of peasants. Royalty, however, came to realize that potatoes could play an important role in feeding the masses. Kings in Prussia and Sweden commanded peasants to grow potatoes, in some cases providing free seed and soldiers to enforce their orders. French pharmacist Antoine Parmentier used psychological deception to get farmers to grow potatoes in the eighteenth century. He developed a taste for potatoes while a prisoner in Germany during the Seven Years War (1756–63). After returning to France he planted a potato field near Paris and stationed guards around the perimeter. He left it unguarded during the night. Neighbours, wondering what crop could be so valuable, began to pilfer Parmentier’s potatoes after dark to plant on their own land. Parmentier’s deception certainly played a part in the rapid spread of potatoes in France. The plant became so popular that potato blossoms worn in women’s hair became a new fashion in Paris after Marie Antoinette adorned herself with them. The potato had several advantages that contributed to its widespread acceptance as a food in Europe. Convenience was one important attribute, as it is in modern society. Potatoes competed quite favourably with other contemporary foods such as grains that required milling to make flour and ovens to make bread. Potatoes did not need to be processed and could be made ready for consumption simply by placing them in the embers of a fire. Potatoes were also found to be much more productive than grains, especially in the climates of northern and eastern Europe. On the same amount of land potatoes could feed five times as many people as could wheat. Vig6
HISTORY AND B ACKGROUND
orous seed was another plus for potatoes. Weather conditions that wiped out other crops would only set back potatoes temporarily as the seed tubers sent out new sprouts to emerge as potato plants. The potato’s ability to adapt to poor soils allowed for production of a third of a crop or half a crop under conditions that would completely destroy small grains. Another advantage is that potatoes could be stored in the ground where planted, reducing pilferage and preventing invading armies from easily destroying or confiscating food supplies. Enemies could burn wheat fields and steal livestock, while potatoes were out of sight in the soil. Since the potato provided food security and required no processing it became an important crop of the masses.
The Irish Potato Famine The first person to plant potatoes in Ireland is unknown. The earliest plantings probably came from potato tubers found on Spanish ships that ran aground after the defeat of the Spanish Armada in 1588. Unlike on the European continent, where it was an aristocratic food, in Ireland the potato quickly became the main food for peasants. There are several reasons why potatoes spread very rapidly in Ireland. One reason was the island’s mild climate, in which potatoes thrived, especially in southern Ireland. Irish growers produced surprisingly high yields, even in terms of potato production two centuries later. During the early 1800s Irish potato yields were over ten tons per hectare, which is about the average for all developing countries in 2000. Another reason was the structure of Irish society. Over several centuries the evolving political and economic situations created powerful forces that led Ireland, more than any other country, to be associated with one crop – potatoes. One early political force goes back to the twelfth century when Pope Adrian IV, the only English pope in the history of the Catholic Church, granted control of Ireland to English King Henry II. Four centuries later in a series of harsh measures Queen Elizabeth I brutally crushed Irish rebellion. A large portion of the Irish population was killed and the devastated food supply put many on the brink of starvation. Then potatoes came to Ireland. The convenience and nutritional value of the potato rescued Irish peasants by keeping away famine and disease. Political unrest continued during the seventeenth century; warfare created uncertainty in food supplies. The English army and rival Irish factions would confiscate or destroy cattle, standing crops and stored food supplies. Potato growers could survive the chaos by leaving the tubers in the soil and only harvesting them when needed. The mild climate prevented 7
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
freezing in the ground, so potatoes were stored over winter in the soil where they grew. Any tubers left unharvested would sprout in the spring and grow into a new crop. During the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries the potato helped feed Ireland’s expanding population. Irish citizens depended very heavily, too heavily it turned out, on the potato as their main food. A fundamental part of Irish society, the land tenure system, contributed to this dependence. Much of the agricultural land was in the hands of English landlords. Many of them chose to be absentee landlords, preferring the comforts of Dublin or London to the poverty-stricken Irish countryside. The tenants produced grain and meat for their landlords, who exported the products for their income. Potatoes were typically not part of the tenancy agreement, so the Irish peasants grew them for family subsistence on the remaining poor soils. The Irish used their ingenuity to develop a yield-maximizing potato production system. They planted seed potatoes in raised beds of soil mixed with manure. One agricultural expert of the time estimated that 90% of Ireland’s manure was used in potato production. The tubers were covered with soil from the trenches between the strips of raised beds. Growers could leave some of the potatoes in the soil, which would allow them to sprout in the beds and produce a crop the following year. An entire family could be fed from one acre of potatoes. This potato production system, although quite efficient, became the main food source for more people than had ever before lived in Ireland. A 1780 report claimed that, on the average, Irish people ate three kilograms of potatoes per day. A continually increasing supply of nutritious, convenient potatoes fuelled remarkable growth in Ireland’s population, which increased from 1.5 million in 1790 to 9 million in 1845. About half made up the peasant class, but the health of the entire Irish economy depended on potatoes. From a few tubers found on a Spanish shipwreck Irish growers multiplied potato plantings into a production system that fed millions of people. Unfortunately, the Irish people depended not only on one crop for their subsistence, but also on a crop descended from a very narrow genetic base. Since potato production from seed tubers essentially makes each plant a clone of the mother plant, the potato crop became very vulnerable to disease. If one plant was susceptible to a disease, they all were. The devastating disease came in the mid-1800s. In 1845 Irish growers planted a two-million-acre potato crop, much of it cultivated by spade in plots of less than one acre. Emergence and growth of the crop was off to a fine start. The potato plants were green, vigorous and healthy. Until early July it looked to be one of Ireland’s best potato years.
8
HISTORY AND B ACKGROUND
Then the weather changed. Clouds and fog blocked the sun. The temperature dropped. Storms of wind and rain pelted the potato fields. The cold, damp weather continued. A fungus, Phytophthora infestans, thrived and reproduced rapidly under these conditions. Potato plants were ideal hosts for this microorganism that caused a terrible plant disease. First symptoms of the disease, later to be known as late blight, included brown spots spreading on the leaves of the potato plants. The gangrene spread, leaving nothing but black, withered stalks where healthy plants had flourished a few days earlier. Some early-maturing potato plants survived long enough to produce tubers, but the fungus could also cause harvested potatoes to rot quickly. The stench of decay permeated the countryside. The malady was horrifying in its rapid destruction. Families were shocked that they could go to bed with a healthy crop and wake up to blackened, stinking fields. Growers tried an assortment of treatments. They pulled the infected stalks to stop the spread. They lit fires to purify the air. They placed stones and turf over the potatoes to protect them. They sprinkled potato fields with holy water. In spite of their frantic efforts the destruction continued, with the fungus invading homes and barns, wiping out harvested potatoes. About half the 1845 crop was lost. Famine struck the Irish people the next winter. With a complete potato crop failure in 1846 starvation and death followed. Dry summer weather in 1847 provided a reprieve from late blight, but Irish potato plantings had dropped to 284,000 acres, one-eighth of the 1845 acreage, due partly to the fact that people ate their seed potatoes. Late blight struck again the following two years. The impact was devastatingly similar to that of the Black Death 500 years earlier. The peasants were without food and without money in a nearly cashless society, forcing them to sell their belongings to eat.They slept in rags and foraged for anything to eat. Typhus, cholera and other diseases ravaged the weakened people. In some towns there were not enough healthy people to bury the dead. Visitors entered homes to find nothing but corpses. One million Irish people died. Two million emigrated to other countries. Over the next half-century five and a half million people left Ireland.
From Europe to North America The Irish potato monoculture, together with late blight, created the famine that caused immigration to America. The flow of people across the Atlantic became a flood of 100,000 per year, with Irish immigrants soon making up 30% of the populations of Boston and New York. Money earned by the IrishAmericans was sent back home to pay for the departure of their relatives and friends.
9
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
In spite of hardships endured by the recent immigrants, they beckoned those still living in Ireland with letters describing their new home as a land of plenty. Compared to famine, America provided a better opportunity but the lives of most Irish immigrants were very difficult. Penniless, uneducated and weakened by hunger and disease, the only employment available to them was low-paid temporary work unwanted by others. Many lived in squalid urban hovels. Three out of five of their children died before the age of five. After a long struggle against poverty and discrimination, the Irish became a successful ethnic group that influenced US culture and politics. The Irish lobby became very strong, influencing policy toward Britain and delaying American entry into both world wars. Currently about one-sixth of the US population is of Irish descent. Part of the legacy the Irish brought to America is that the potato has long been known in the US as the Irish potato. Some Irish people moved to America long before the Potato Famine. Irish immigrants brought potatoes from Europe to the North American continent in 1719 when they came to the British colony of Londonderry, New Hampshire. Potatoes made a circuitous route from South America to Europe to North America, but potato late blight travelled in the reverse direction. The disease first hit North America in 1842, spreading from Massachusetts to Novia Scotia along the Atlantic coast. Although not recorded in history, the terrible fungus probably hitched a ride east across the Atlantic in a diseased tuber, aboard one of the fast new steamships of the time. In spite of late blight, potato production expanded in America, spreading from New England to the Mid-Atlantic region. Thomas Jefferson, who learned to love potatoes during a visit to France, was a factor in this expansion. Jefferson grew potatoes on his farm, experimented with them and served them at the White House during his term as President of the United States. As the frontier pushed westward, American pioneers brought potatoes with them. During gold rushes, when some people abandoned their farms to search for gold, potatoes became quite valuable. One Montana farmer wrote about a long, bitterly cold trip to a mining community during which he built night-time bonfires next to his wagons to prevent his potatoes from freezing, then using blankets and snow to protect them during day-time transit. He was richly rewarded with gold dust for his potatoes when they arrived in good shape. He reported that there was even a market for frozen potatoes in the community. Christian missionaries, such as Henry Spaulding in 1830s Idaho, encouraged native Americans to plant potatoes in their efforts to get them to adopt the ways of white people. It is ironic that Europeans obtained potatoes from native South Americans, then used potatoes to try to convert native North Americans to the ways of Europeans. 10
HISTORY AND B ACKGROUND
Potatoes around the globe European colonial powers, often with the help of their churches, spread potatoes around the world. Potatoes came to China with missionaries from Britain and the Dutch East Indies (Indonesia) in the seventeenth century. Some parts of China first saw potatoes brought in by Portuguese and Spanish traders. Russian potato production spread over the border into northern China. During the same period Portuguese traders and British missionaries introduced potatoes into India. Although most potato varieties do better in a cooler climate, potato production expanded in the parts of India where tropical heat and monsoon rains were not problems. From India and from China potatoes spread to Tibet where by 1900 potatoes were an important part of the Tibetans’ favourite stew. Japan’s first potatoes came from Dutch traders around 1600. Although the Japanese did not like the potato’s taste, production spread for practical agronomic reasons. Following a series of floods and famines during the seventeenth century, Japanese growers expanded potato production in higher, cooler but less fertile areas. From Japan potatoes spread to Korea, where the crop became an important food and livestock feed in mountainous regions. Meanwhile Belgian missionaries introduced potatoes to Africa. The tubers in central Africa became known as the ‘white man’s yam’ or ‘European root’.5 Natives began growing potatoes to sell to Christian missionaries, but some considered them taboo and would not eat the tubers themselves. Their attitudes gradually changed and, of course, they ate potatoes during times of famine. The pattern of adoption from European colonists to indigenous peoples was repeated in many parts of the world. In the late eighteenth century the French explorer de Surville brought potatoes to New Zealand, where Maoris widely adopted them by 1840. Also in the late eighteenth century Europeans had introduced potatoes to Persia (Iran) in the Middle East. A half-century later Syrians began to grow potatoes, then a half-century after that Turks started to grow them. Potatoes have played an important role in feeding people who settled on small, isolated islands. Salaman studied the diets of people living on Tristan da Cunha, a 45-square mile South Atlantic island midway between the Cape of Good Hope and Rio de Janeiro. After failed attempts by the British and Dutch to colonize the island William Glass, his wife, two children and two other men were successful in the early 1800s. Later, six black slave women, a few shipwrecked sailors and members of the Repertto family from Italy joined the group. In spite of problems with late blight, rats and strong winds, potato crops did well and provided the major part of the diet of the people on Tristan da Cunha. They supplemented their potato diet with fish, eggs, milk and other 11
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
foods purchased from ships that stopped infrequently at the island. A 1926 study revealed that the islanders were in remarkably good health, which was in part owing to their potato-rich diets. The good health of potato eaters has been confirmed on other islands. Potato production had expanded from South America to Europe to North America to the rest of the world in 400 years. With wheat, rice and maize, potatoes are now one of the top four crops in terms of world production. Many scientists see potatoes as the main solution to world hunger problems.The International Potato Centre in Peru was founded by the United Nations, the World Bank and other governments and foundations to develop new ways to prevent famine. The potato offers much to developing countries. It produces more calories and protein per acre than any grain crop. Although it thrives mostly in temperate climates, some varieties are well suited for warmer climates. A potato crop in hot climates can be harvested 40 to 90 days after planting, allowing growers to plant potatoes between slower-growing grain crops. The current trend is that potato production is expanding more rapidly in developing countries than in developed countries. The trend will probably persist for a long time as the potato continues its role as an important source of sustenance for a wide variety of people.
Cultural aspects of potatoes The potato is more than a plant or a crop or a food. It is an important component of the daily lives of people all over the world. In many societies the potato has been a catalyst for change in their culture. Webster’s Dictionary6 defines culture as ‘the ideas, customs, skills, arts, etc. of a people’. The potato’s productivity and adaptability have brought food security to many people, freeing up time and energy to develop their culture.
Potatoes in art The Andean cultures of South America were the first to include potatoes in their art. Archaeologists have documented the potato motif in Peruvian preIncan pottery. Burial-site pottery depicted three common threads of potatoes, man and mutilation, which was associated with the practice of cannibalism. Scholars argue that the inclusion of potatoes as one of three themes indicates the importance of potatoes in that culture. Incan pottery often depicted large and twin potato tubers, which were regarded as fertility symbols. 12
HISTORY AND B ACKGROUND
Perhaps the most profound example of the potato in European art is the work of the renowned Dutch painter Vincent van Gogh. Living among peasants at Neuen, Holland during the 1883–85 period, van Gogh gained insight into the lives of his subjects, realizing the important role of potatoes in their work, diet and culture. During his time at Neuen, van Gogh painted many pictures of Dutch peasants planting, tending and harvesting potatoes. His indoor paintings often dealt with women peeling potatoes. He created four still-life paintings devoted entirely to potatoes. In 1885 van Gogh produced his famous masterpiece ‘The Potato Eaters’. Salaman7 quotes a letter from van Gogh to his brother explaining how he felt about the picture: I have tried to make it clear how those people, eating their potatoes under the lamplight, have dug the earth with those very hands they put in the dish, and so it speaks of manual labour and how they have honestly earned their food.
Other examples of European art regarding potatoes include mundane utensils of food preparation. The Irish cauldron, used extensively by peasants for boiling potatoes, is one example. Cauldrons are pots consisting of three legs and two handles. The beauty of design and ornamentation of many of the cauldrons suggests the importance of potatoes in the everyday life of the Irish peasantry. Ireland was the source of another type of potato-related culinary art, but this one came from the middle and upper classes rather than the peasantry. During the eighteenth century, many Dublin residents of means imported mahogany furniture that could easily be damaged by hot surfaces. Traditionally in these households potatoes had been served hot in wooden bowls that were often trimmed with silver. In order to protect polished mahogany tables, people used dish rings to keep the bowls several inches above the table surface. Also known as ‘potato rings’, some of these silver dish rings are elaborately ornamented works of art that are on display in museums.
The role of potatoes in economic development The potato has played an important role in economic development in many places around the world. In developing countries the potato provides an abundant supply of cheap, nutritious food that can keep the masses fed and liberate labour for non-agricultural pursuits. In developed countries, the potato can play an important role in providing quick meals for a busy, affluent society. Walker8 describes Bennett’s model of transition from a potato economy to a potato-and-wheat economy, then to a wheat economy and finally to an 13
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
advanced economy. As a developing country’s economy grows, consumers with increased income substitute bread for potatoes, but eventually as income continues to grow they reduce consumption of both staples. The model seems appropriate for Ireland and Eastern Europe but not for other regions, such as Asia, where rice is an important staple. Walker has revised Bennett’s model into a potato ‘feed–fresh–processed’ framework. He says that people in less-developed economies use a substantial amount of potatoes for livestock feed. As the economy grows, potato use shifts from livestock feed to human consumption of fresh potatoes. When a modern economy becomes completely developed, human consumption shifts from fresh potatoes to processed potatoes. Large numbers of citizens who eat fries and chips at fast-food restaurants suggest that a country fits into the ‘developed’ category. Potatoes can be more than simply an indicator of a stage of economic development or a measure of a society’s culture. History shows that when potatoes are introduced into some regions, they became catalysts, or primary driving forces, for economic development. The potato can become such an important part of a people’s culture that it not only drives the development of their own society, but also impacts on neighbouring societies. One example is the effect of European-introduced potatoes on the Maori society of New Zealand. According to Harris and Niha,9 Captain James Cook and other explorers brought potatoes to the Maoris between 1769 and 1773. Some Maori claim that their ancestors grew potatoes long before that, but there is no scientific evidence to support that claim. What is clear, though, is that potatoes became an important part of Maori society. The Maori found the European-introduced potatoes to be quite palatable, high-yielding and easy to grow at varied locations and altitudes. They soon saw the potato as superior to the kumara that had been a food staple in Maori society. Maori communities burned and cleared forests to build potato plantations. The potato became an important trade good both within and outside Maori society. The Maori soon began to market potatoes to ship captains for provisions and to European settlers. Maori sailing vessels were used to transport potatoes to population centres. The potato transformed Maori society from a culture of subsistence agriculture to a society of commercial agriculture and traders. The Maori developed efficient potato production and storage systems to provide ample supplies of the tubers to offer to European traders for iron goods. Since potato production required less time and effort than kumara production, the Maori had more time for non-food production endeavours. Some scholars suggest that the potato provided the Maori with food security that led to warfare. With less labour needed for food production Maori warriors could more easily go to war. Belich10 suggests that the ‘Musket wars’ 14
HISTORY AND B ACKGROUND
could have been called the ‘Potato wars’ because of the crop’s importance in warfare.
Potatoes in war Warfare places high demands on a society’s ability to produce, store and transport food. Since potatoes yield more calories per acre than any other crop, it is an important source of nutrition for soldiers and civilians in a nation at war.The potato has a food-security advantage of being stored underground in the fields, offering some protection against invading armies. When armies stay in place for a long period, however, the soldiers have time to get the potatoes. That happened in eighteenth-century Europe during the Kartoffel Krieg, or the Potato War. Also called the War of the Bavarian Succession, it occurred when Prussia’s Frederick the Great invaded Austria in 1778. The two armies met on the upper Elbe and faced each other to a stand-off. Being short of supplies the invading Prussian army confiscated food from Austrian citizens in the countryside. Since the upper Elbe was primarily a potato-growing region, the soldiers subsisted on a diet heavy in potatoes. Winter cold and the strength of the Austrian army eventually led Frederick to withdraw, but not before soldiers ate enough potatoes for the war to earn its name. Armies that intentionally camp in farming regions can consume the region’s resources, including its potato crops, but armies on the move have different food supply requirements. Fresh potatoes have two disadvantages in wartime supply lines. First, they are heavy and bulky, consisting of about 80% water. Second, potatoes have a short storage life. Before the advent of modern processing methods, the potato’s main role during times of war was to feed citizens at home rather than soldiers away at war. War-time governments usually develop programmes to enhance food production and security. This was especially important to the United Kingdom during World War I. Prior to the war the UK relied on imports for a large portion of its grain and meat consumption. Enemy submarines threatened the shipping lanes and put the country in danger of hunger. The Ministry of Agriculture was granted wide powers, including price controls, to increase food production. British farmers responded by producing an abundant supply of potatoes in 1917. Potato plantings in 1917 increased nearly 20% over the pre-war period. Profitable minimum prices fixed by the government encouraged the acreage increase and were a powerful economic incentive to manage the crop for high yields. The result was a large surplus of potatoes. At the guaranteed price growers produced a larger supply than the market demanded. 15
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
The Ministry of Agriculture dealt with the surplus disposal problem by purchasing the excess potatoes. The United Kingdom situation was similar during World War II. The Ministry of Agriculture established programmes to encourage growers all over the country to produce potatoes. The government paid bonuses to growers who planted potatoes on marginal soils. Again, the growers responded to economic incentives by producing a potato surplus. Great Britain potato plantings doubled from 0.7 million acres in 1939 to 1.4 million acres in 1944. Yields increased about 7 tons per acre. The Ministry handled the surplus by diverting potatoes to livestock feed. The potatoes destined for feed were coloured to keep them from food market channels. The Ministry also established dehydrated potato factories to supply overseas soldiers with potato products. Meanwhile, North Americans also worked to solve the potato’s twin military problems of bulkiness and limited storage life. Idaho entrepreneur Jack Simplot built an onion dehydration factory in 1940 to supply military needs. During that same year Rodgers Brothers operated a small-scale factory to provide dehydrated potatoes to the US Quartermaster. Two years later Simplot built a successful large-scale factory to supply US soldiers with dehydrated potato products. The profitability of selling potato products to the war-time government led Simplot to develop frozen potato processing after the war ended. The frozen potato products tapped into a powerful consumer market driven by post-war prosperity in the United States.
The fast-food society Although the United States suffered serious casualties in World War II, its infrastructure was undamaged. Since battles were not fought on American soil, the war did not devastate its highways, factories and cities as it did in Europe and Asia. This allowed the US economy to steadily rebound from a war-time economy to peace-time prosperity. During the war many women stepped into positions that had been filled by males.The war-induced shortage of males in the workforce created opportunities for women, some of whom were reluctant to go back to pre-war customs. This led to a post-war increase in the number of women working outside the home. In subsequent decades females joined the away-fromhome workforce in ever-growing percentages. The increase in female workers and managers helped the US economy grow. Their efforts added to the gross national product of the country and increased individual family income. Families now had more money, but the person who traditionally prepared the meals, the mother, had less time for domestic chores. The increased income also led to less need for children to 16
HISTORY AND B ACKGROUND
earn an income and allowed them time and resources to pursue hobbies, sports, arts and other activities. The trend of more money and more activities but less free time created the fast-food society. People who work long hours but who have plenty of money for food and family recreation don’t want to spend much time in meal preparation and consumption. They want fast food. They are willing to pay for more service in their food products. Rather than taking time to prepare meals from scratch, they purchase foods that are partially or completely prepared. The fast-food society created a tremendous growth opportunity for the potato industry. The traditional American meal of hamburger and fries as well as the traditional British meal of fish and chips became icons of the fast-food industry. Restaurant entrepreneurs became adept at providing these meals rapidly for customers who were in a hurry. They could do it by purchasing fresh potatoes and making them into fries and chips, but some searched for more efficient methods to provide consistent, high-quality potato products for quick service. United States potato magnate Jack Simplot pioneered the development of a potato product for fast-food restaurants. His researcher Ray Dunlap experimented with different ways to turn raw potatoes into a frozen French fry product that restaurants could quickly fry in oil. He developed a system for peeling, cutting, blanching, pre-cooking and freezing potatoes that did not break down their cellular structure. Restaurants purchased the product, fried the potato strips in oil and served them to their fast-food customers. Dunlap’s frozen potato processing system was copied and improved in subsequent years, but the basic strategy of efficiently converting raw product into a frozen product for the restaurant trade remained unchanged. The rapid growth of fast-food firms, such as McDonald’s, created the opportunity for frozen potato processors to grow along with them. The driving force of the fast-food society is the trade-off between money and time. Economic development leads to higher incomes but less time for food preparation. This creates opportunities for the fast-food and frozen potato industries. First, however, must come the economic development. Following the pattern in the US, post-war economic recoveries created fastfood societies in numerous other countries. Many Third World countries, however, have not had the economic development needed for a fast-food culture.
The potato in developing countries A challenge for many developing countries is to feed a rapidly increasing population. People in some regions face not only hunger and malnutrition 17
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
but also death by starvation. Government policy in developing countries has long focused on increasing grain production. According to the Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO) of the United Nations, wheat, maize and rice production grew at annual rates of 4.3%, 3.9% and 2.9%, respectively, in developing countries from the 1960s into the 1990s. In spite of the potato crop receiving less emphasis, developing country annual growth in potato production during the same period was 4.0%. Given some inherent advantages, potatoes are receiving increasing attention as a tool to solve world hunger problems. Dr John Niederhauser, who worked extensively in developing countries on potato production problems, lists the following as the potato’s advantages as a food crop:11 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
High yield potential Excellent nutrient source High proportion of edible biomass Ease of preparation for consumption Wide acceptance as a daily food Adaptable for intensive cultivation in small areas Wide variety of cultivars Extensive production technology Security of production under stress Short crop season.
The Neiderhauser list of potato disadvantages is: 1 2 3 4 5 6
Bulkiness (in harvesting, marketing, transport, storage) Perishability and post-harvest losses Storage Cool climate crop Seed problems Disease and pest control.
Niederhauser’s lists of advantages and disadvantages are relevant for both developed countries and developing countries. Concerning developing countries, Niederhauser says that disease control (especially potato late blight), seed production and scarce economic resources are the main factors limiting potato production. Although problems are serious in some developing countries, advantages more than offset disadvantages in most locations. Potatoes are becoming quite important in many developing countries. Potato production has been increasing more rapidly in the Third World than in the rest of the world. Significant potato production in Third World countries may even go uncounted by government sources because of the abundance of subsistence farmers who produce potatoes on small plots for their own consumption. 18
HISTORY AND B ACKGROUND
Declining price is one factor that encourages potato consumption in developing countries. In places where they had been considered expensive or even a luxury good, potatoes have become relatively cheap. Noting a decline in potato prices from 1950 to 1980 in Third World markets, Niederhauser pointed out that the potato/rice price ratio declined from 3.9 to 0.8 in Bangkok, Thailand and from 2.4 to 0.7 in Dhaka, Bangladesh. With demand increasing, price declines of those magnitudes must come from an abundance of potatoes produced at low costs. Government policy influences potato production and consumption in developing countries. In Peru, the birthplace of the potato, per capita consumption had declined from 100 kg in the early 1960s to 45 kg in the mid1980s. Scott et al.12 attribute the decline to subsidized cereal production, an overvalued currency that encouraged imports of cheap cereals, price controls and market regulations. The floundering economy also contributed to a record high potato/rice price ratio. A 1990s change in government policy toward more economic freedom led to economic recovery as well as an increase in potato consumption from 45 kg to 65 kg per capita.
References 1 M Meltzer, The Amazing Potato, New York, HarperCollins, 1992. 2 C Brown, ‘Origin and history of the potato’, 76th meeting of the Potato Association of America, Past, Present and Future Uses of Potatoes Symposium, Fredericton, Canada, University of Idaho, 1992. 3 W Burton, The Potato: A Survey of its History and of Factors Influencing its Yield, Nutritive Value, Quality and Storage, Wageningen, Holland, Veenman & Zonen, 1966, p 20. 4 R Salaman, The History and Social Influence of the Potato, Cambridge, University Press, 1949. 5 D Horton, Potatoes: Production, Marketing, and Programs for Developing Countries, London, Westview Press, 1987, p 12. 6 V Neufeldt and D Guralnik, Webster’s New World College Dictionary, New York, Macmillan, 1997. 7 Salaman, History and Social Influence of the Potato. 8 T Walker, P Schmiediche and R Hijmans, ‘World trends and patterns in the potato crop: An economic and geographic survey’, Potato Research, 1999 42 241–64. 9 G Harris and P Niha, Nga ¯ Riwai Ma ¯ori – Ma ¯ori potatoes, Lower Hutt, New Zealand, Open Polytechnic, 1999. 10 J Belich, Making Peoples, Auckland, Penguin Press, 1996. 11 J C Niederhauser, ‘The role of the potato in the conquest of hunger’, 76th meeting of the Potato Association of America, Past, Present and Future Uses of Potatoes Symposium, Fredericton, Canada, University of Idaho, 1992. 12 G Scott, M Rosegrant and C Ringler, Roots and Tubers for the 21st Century, Lima, Peru, International Potato Center, 2000. 19
CHAPTER
2 Potato properties, types and use
Nutritional attributes
T
he potato provides inexpensive calories, but perhaps more importantly, it also contains nutrients vital to good health. Potatoes are rich in ascorbic acid, a water-soluble vitamin, C6H8O6, also known as Vitamin C. A diet deficient in Vitamin C causes scurvy, a common affliction among people who go long periods without fresh produce. One small potato per day can provide all the Vitamin C needed to prevent scurvy. R H Dana1 wrote a vivid description of the plight of two scurvy victims on a ship travelling from California to Boston in the 1830s: The scurvy began to show itself on board. One man had it so badly as to be disabled and off duty, and the English lad, Ben, was in a dreadful state, and was daily growing worse. His legs swelled and pained him so that he could not walk; his flesh lost its elasticity, so that if it was pressed in, it would not return to its shape; and his gums swelled until he could not open his mouth. His breath, too, became very offensive; he lost all strength and spirit; could eat nothing; grew worse every day; and, in fact, unless something was done for him, would be dead in a week.
20
POTATO PROPERTIES , TYPES AND USE
Fortunately, fresh provisions were obtained from another ship. Potatoes soon restored the ailing sailors to good health and probably saved the life of the English lad. A small amount of potatoes quickly healed the sailors because potatoes have a high nutrient density; each potato calorie carries a large amount of essential nutrients. Although the potato is 80% water, it is a nutritional jewel box. One medium-sized potato provides half the daily adult requirement of Vitamin C. It also provides significant amounts of dietary fibre, protein, thiamin, niacin, calcium, iron, Vitamin B6, folic acid, phosphorus and magnesium. People in developing countries, who face the problem of insufficient calories, are well served by potatoes. High nutrient density means that moderate consumption of potatoes, even in calorie-deficient diets, can provide valuable health-enhancing nutrients. While too few calories is a concern in developing countries, people in developed countries worry about eating too many calories. In places where obesity, rather than hunger, is a concern, potatoes compare quite favourably with other foods. Table 2.1 shows that potatoes prepared in four different ways contain fewer calories than 15 other foods. With less physical activity many people in developed countries need the same nutrition as their
Table 2.1
Calorie comparison Serving size
Potatoes, boiled Potatoes, mashed with milk Potato, baked Potato salad with dressing Spaghetti, cooked Bread Biscuit Candy, chocolate Rice, cooked Sweet potato, baked Milk, whole Peanuts, roasted Pancakes Pizza Macaroni with cheese Ground beef Steak Cake, chocolate Milk shake
1
/2 cup /2 cup 1 medium 1 /2 cup 3 /4 cup 2 slices 1 1 oz bar 3 /4 cup 1 medium 8 oz 1 oz One 3–4≤ diameter 1 slice 1 /2 cup 3 oz 4≤ ¥ 2.5≤ ¥ 0.5≤ 2≤ ¥ 1≤ 12 oz 1
Source: Meltzer
21
Calories 45 70 90 99 115 120 130 150 150 155 165 170 180 180 240 245 330 420 520
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
ancestors required, but from fewer calories. Here again, the potato’s high nutrient density is important. In the US potatoes had long been viewed as a fattening food. The first mission of the National Potato Promotion Board (NPPB), founded in the 1970s, was to dispel that notion and educate consumers about the nutritional benefits of potatoes. The industry won that battle but new diets that exclude potatoes continue to come into vogue. A fad diet at the beginning of the 2000s shuns carbohydrates for protein and fat. Advocates of high-protein, high-fat diets use the glycaemic index (GI) to identify foods that they claim are unhealthy. The GI compares foods on their ability to increase blood sugar. Foods with a high GI are linked to diabetes, heart disease and obesity. Potatoes have a moderately high GI. What may be more important than GI alone is the relationship between GI and resistant starch (RS). Some nutritionists say that a high RS may have more health benefits than low GI. Potato RS levels can be enhanced in several different ways. Cooking then cooling potatoes provides a rich source of RS. Frozen chips (fries in North America), twice-baked potatoes and left-over potato dishes are examples of high RS potato products. Another curious thing is that small tubers have higher amounts of RS. Maybe some day the enhanced health aspects of small potatoes will be a marketing hook. If more nutritionists recommend low GI foods the potato industry could respond by developing new potato products and promoting other health attributes of potatoes. One important health attribute is the potato’s high content of phytochemicals that reduce the risk of heart attacks, strokes, cancer and other chronic diseases. Diet fads will come and go, and nutrition research will point out pluses and minuses of all foods. The important thing is for the potato industry to have a finger on the pulse of consumer tastes and preferences. New attributes, such as low GI, high RS and enhanced phytochemicals, can be added to make the nutritional jewel box shine even more brightly in the eyes of consumers.
Culinary aspects of potatoes The nutritional benefits of a food may be ignored if consumers find it unpalatable. For people to eat potatoes during times of plenty the prepared dishes must be appetising. Although preferences vary between countries and through time there are a few standards for potato culinary quality. First, potato products must appeal to the senses, especially the sense of taste. The potato should send a pleasurable message from taste buds to brain. The potato’s aroma should please the sense of smell. The potato’s texture 22
POTATO PROPERTIES , TYPES AND USE
should appeal to the sense of touch. The visual presentation of a potato dish should be pleasing to the sense of sight. The remaining sense, hearing, may even be important to consumers who appreciate the sound of sizzling foods. Assuming flavour is a composite of both aroma and taste, what is it about potatoes that is appealing? Scientists say potato flavour is determined by reactions between amino acids, sugars and pectins during cooking. The difficulty is in trying to quantify or describe flavour preferences. Burton2 says that English consumers prefer maincrop potatoes with a ‘mild, but not insipid flavour’ to be served as a ‘neutral accompaniment to more strongly flavoured foods’ while early potatoes should have a ‘strong distinctive potato flavour’. Harris3 says new potatoes should have a ‘slightly sweet taste’. While fresh potatoes are often served with flavoured toppings, potato processors simply add flavoured ingredients, such as onion powder, to their processed products to get the flavours they want. Texture and flavour are interrelated. Consumer perceptions of texture influence their subjective evaluation of flavour. When a potato product is eaten, the flavour and mouth-feel are sensed at the same time. Different potato products have different preferred textures. Many consumers prefer baked potatoes with their dry, mealy texture. Others like a boiled potato with a moist or waxy texture. Potato snack foods are expected to be crisp while a popular standard for chips (fries in the US) is crisp on the outside and moist in the inside. Regarding the sense of sight, consumers prefer raw potatoes that are free from blemishes and defects such as cuts, bruises and diseases. Preferences for shape and colour vary, but darkening during storage and cooking are undesirable for varieties with light-coloured flesh. Consumers expect processed potato products to be uniform in colour, but North American consumers expect their unflavoured fries and potato snacks to be very light-coloured. Potato products are eaten in meals during the morning, mid-day and evening and as between-meal snacks. Where the potato fits on the plate for the evening meal has received attention from potato marketers. In many countries the evening meal is often seen as consisting of three segments: main course (usually meat), starch and vegetable. Although the potato has traditionally fitted into the starch category, many people consider it a vegetable. The versatility of the potato provides opportunities to design different potato products for different parts of the plate, including potatoes as part of the main course. Cooks fry, boil, steam, roast, hash and mash potatoes. They put them in soups and stews and make pancakes out of them. They top baked potatoes with foods ranging from sour cream to caviar. They use potato flour to bake breads, doughnuts and cakes. Some dairies use potato starch in ice cream. 23
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
Certain potato dishes have become identified with particular regions or nations. Fried potato strips served at North American fast-food restaurants are known there as French fries. German potato salad is a popular, spicy dish even outside its country of origin. Italians use potatoes to make gnocchi. A flat potato cake, known as roesti, is a national dish of Switzerland. In the North American market, the Idaho potato industry has marketed its russet potatoes so well that some consumers, in spite of brand protection, refer to all baked potatoes as ‘Idaho potatoes’.
Potato types and varieties Potato markets in South America include hundreds of species and varieties, with a wide assortment of sizes, shapes, flavours and colours that have been cultivated for centuries. In North America there is one dominant variety, but growers also produce about a hundred other varieties. In Europe, hundreds of varieties have been developed in both the private sector of Western Europe and the public sector of Eastern Europe. The rest of the world relies mostly on potato varieties from these three continents. Why is there such a wide assortment of potato types and varieties? One reason is the tremendous genetic diversity of potatoes. In addition to the primary commercial potato species, Solanum tuberosum, there are six other cultivated species and an additional 200 wild species. By contrast the genetic resource base for maize consists of one cultivated species and no wild ones. Rice and wheat have eight species. Another reason for the large assortment of potato varieties has to do with the way growers plant potatoes. Although potato plants produce seeds, farmers usually plant potato tubers. Potato seeds yield plants with wide genetic variations, but potato tubers produce plants that are clones of the mother plant. This clonal reproduction, also known as vegetative propagation, is subject to small variations, or mutations, between generations. The mutated plants occur frequently, but are often not noticed because they usually differ in only a single trait. When differences are discovered, growers can control the potato’s evolution by either discarding or keeping the new types. Over the centuries, before scientific breeding programmes developed, growers selected the mutated plants that produced higher yields or better quality or were resistant to pests. By planting tubers from the superior plants and sharing with other growers, new potato varieties were developed. Russet Burbank, the most popular variety in North America, was developed this way. One selected mutation from the Burbank variety in 1873 eventually became the Russet Burbank variety. Even within a specific variety 24
POTATO PROPERTIES , TYPES AND USE
classification, seed producers market mutated selections as superior strains of that variety. For example, the Dark Red Norland is a mutation of Red Norland that produces a more vivid red-coloured skin. Following the Irish Potato Famine, many commercial plant breeders focused on developing blight-resistant potato varieties. Most potato varieties until that time had been developed in Europe, but choices were limited and the genetic base was narrow. From six European varieties in 1850, breeders in the US developed 350 new varieties over the next 60 years. Breeders sought new genetic material from South America, the original source of the potato plant. One important South American selection was the Rough Purple Chili, which the Reverend C E Goodrich introduced into breeding programmes in 1851. Hundreds of modern European and American varieties trace their lineage to Rough Purple Chili. Potato markets have long been classified according to colour and shape. In the UK in the 1730s, potatoes were put into five market categories: black potatoes; round reds; yellows; round whites and the white, flat, kidney potato.4 Two of the categories involved colour only, while the other three included shape as well as colour. Modern potato markets also describe potatoes by shape and colour. Most popular North American potato varieties have traditionally fitted into four classifications: round white, long white, round red and long russet. Round yellows are a recent addition that is relatively small but growing in importance. Blue and purple varieties show some promise, especially in upscale restaurants. Maturity, or time of harvest, is another type of potato classification. A traditional British classification consisted of four maturity types: first earlies harvested in June; second earlies harvested in July and August; early maincrop harvested in September and late maincrop harvested in October and November. In North America the time-of-harvest classifications have evolved from six to four categories based on the seasons. The summer crop is considered the first of the new crop year. It is followed by the fall crop, which is sold out of storage during the harvest of the winter and spring crops. As a result of modern storage technology, the fall crop storage season now overlaps with the summer crop as well. Although different varieties are often used for early crops, global trade and modern transport have changed perceptions regarding maturity and market timing. Canadian consumers can buy newly harvested red potatoes from Florida in January when Canadian fields are under snow. During the same month consumers in Scotland can buy new potatoes grown in Egypt. The maturity-type differences must now be something other than time of availability. Potato buyers in many parts of the world can purchase both early and maincrop potatoes all year round. The distinctions between earlies and maincrop potatoes have moved toward culinary differences. Varieties considered 25
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
earlies typically have thinner skins and a higher moisture content than maincrop potatoes sold out of storage. Consumers who want to serve boiled potatoes or potato salad can choose early-variety potatoes, while those who want to prepare jacket potatoes (‘baked’ in North America) might purchase a late variety. Potato processors also choose between early and late potatoes. The earlies, or potatoes processed at harvest time, typically have less trim and peel loss than potatoes processed out of storage. Offsetting this advantage is the transport cost during the time of year when potatoes cannot be harvested near the processing facility. In North America an annual accounting of varieties planted is not conducted in the commercial potato market. Such accounting is, however, mandatory in the certified seed potato market. Using acres approved in seed certification programmes as a proxy for all plantings, we see differences between the top 10 varieties in 1982 and 1999 (Tables 2.2 and 2.3).The North American variety mix is rapidly changing. Only two of the top 10 varieties in 1982, Russet Burbank and Norland, remained in the top 10 less than two decades later. Kennebec, the second most popular variety in 1982 with 14% of the acreage, not only dropped out of the top 10, but fell to just 2% of plantings in 1999. The tables also show a trend toward wider distribution of varieties, with non-top 10 variety share increasing from 20% to 29%. In 1999, for the first time a yellow variety, Yukon Gold, entered the top 10. The dominant variety remained the Russet Burbank, with a market share that declined slightly from 30% to 28%. It is a dual-purpose variety, used in both fresh and processing market channels, but particularly well suited for the rapidly growing frozen processing segment. Potato breeders have been
Table 2.2 United States and Canada seed potato plantings, 1982 Percentage 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Russet Burbank Kennebec Superior Katahdin Norchip Chieftain Norland Green Mountain Sebago Red Pontiac Other varieties
30 14 7 6 5 5 4 4 3 3 20
Source: National Potato Council, 1982 Yearbook F = fresh, P = processing
26
Use F, P F F, P F P F F F F F
POTATO PROPERTIES , TYPES AND USE Table 2.3 United States and Canada seed potato plantings, 1999 Percentage 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Russet Burbank Russet Norkotah Shepody Atlantic Frito-Lay varieties Superior Norland Ranger Russet Yukon Gold Red Lasoda Other varieties
28 10 7 6 4 4 4 3 3 2 29
Use F, P F P P P F, P F P F F
Source: National Potato Council, 1999 Yearbook F = fresh, P = processing
Table 2.4
UK potato plantings by variety, 1989 Percentage
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Maris Piper Record Estima Wilja Pentland Squire Cara Pentland Dell Desiree Romano Maris Bard Other varieties
13 12 9 8 8 7 7 4 4 3 26
Use P F, P F, P P P F F F, P F F
Source: British Potato Marketing Board F = fresh, P = processing
trying to develop better varieties for more than a century, but with limited success. A few varieties, including Shepody for processing and Norkotah for fresh, appear to be making inroads as Russet Burbank replacements. British growers have also shifted varieties (Tables 2.4 and 2.5). During the 10-year period from 1989 to 1999 Maris Piper remained the number one variety, increasing share from 13% to 21%. Only four of the rest of the 1989 top 10 – Estima, Cara, Pentland Dell and Desiree – remained in the top 10 a 27
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY Table 2.5
UK potato plantings by variety, 1999 Percentage
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Maris Piper Estima Cara Saturna Nadine Pentland Dell Desiree Marfona Lady Rosetta Maris Peer Other varieties
21 10 6 5 4 4 4 4 3 2 36
Use P F, F, P F F, F, F P F
P P
P P
Source: British Potato Council F = fresh, P = processing
decade later. Plantings of the number two variety in 1989, Record, dropped from 12% of plantings to less than 1% in 1999. As in North America, variety plantings became more diversified, with the share of non-top 10 varieties increasing from 26% to 36%.
Fresh potatoes Fresh potatoes, also known as ware potatoes or tablestock potatoes, have been a staple in Western diets for many years. A traditional evening meal consisted of ‘meat and potatoes’ eaten at home. With the increasing popularity of fast-food restaurants, the traditional meal seems to have shifted toward ‘hamburgers and fries’ and ‘fish and chips’ eaten away from home. This shift in preferences contributed toward a decline in fresh potato per capita consumption during the 1950s, 1960s and 1970s in North America and Western Europe. In North America the decline in fresh potato consumption has bottomed out and appears to be heading back up. One reason is that microwave ovens make it more convenient to prepare jacket (baked) potatoes. Another reason is that fresh vegetables in general are seen as healthy foods. Still another factor is that some fast-food restaurants include fresh potatoes among their menu choices. Fresh market potatoes in North America can be classified as russets, reds and whites, based on skin colour. Regardless of their classification potatoes 28
POTATO PROPERTIES , TYPES AND USE
sold in North America have been almost exclusively white fleshed. Yellowfleshed potatoes have been popular in Europe for many years and are successfully entering the North American market. South American consumers have eaten blue, purple and black potatoes for centuries. Although markets for these ‘exotic’potato types are small, they are expanding around the globe. The structure of the fresh potato market varies only slightly across North America. In general, Eastern potato growers are also shippers. In the West, growers and shippers are usually separate businesses. Western shippers compete with processors in the market for potatoes at the grower level. In the East, many growers operate their own fresh pack operations. Fresh potato sales are made in a variety of containers and grade specifications. Russet potatoes are usually packed in three general size categories: consumer packs, count cartons and institutional packs. Consumer packs consist mainly of 4–8 ounce (non-size A) potatoes packed in plastic, paper or mesh bags. The most valuable potatoes are the 8–14 ounce tubers that are packed in 50-pound cardboard boxes. These are called ‘count cartons’ and each carton has a number that tells how many tubers are in a box (60, 70, 80, 90, 100, 110, 120). Retail stores and restaurants buy count carton potatoes, which are typically used for baking. Institutional buyers such as government military bases like to buy 100-pound bags of large potatoes to minimize packaging, handling and peeling costs. Although some reds and whites are sold in the same three size categories as russets, it is more common to pack them in a wider range of sizes in one container. The russet consumer packs are usually the closest competitors for the reds and whites. Only the very largest and smallest are typically sold separately. In North America the large and small potatoes have traditionally brought the lowest prices, which is the reverse of the situation in Europe. Small red-skinned potatoes now sometimes top the market in North America, indicating a possible shift toward European size preferences. Some fresh potato production areas have mandatory inspection for fresh shipments. The rules, usually administered through government entities, require all fresh shipments of potatoes to meet grade standards. Strict quality control has been an important component in some regional advertising and promotion campaigns.
Processed potatoes Other than the centuries-old chuño processing in South America, much of the growth and development of the global potato processing industry is recent. Potatoes have, however, been processed in the US since 1831 when 29
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
the first starch plant was established. Potato snack foods are also reported to have been first prepared during the mid-nineteenth century. Potato processing remained on a small commercial scale until World War II, when processors developed improved peeling and frying techniques. Growth in potato processing has been remarkable. Prior to 1960, US reports on potato utilization did not differentiate between snack foods and fresh consumption. By 1970 US processed utilization was nearly equal to that of fresh. Major processing uses of potatoes now are snacks, dehydration and freezing, which together account for about 98% of US potato processing. Canned, starch and flour processing make up the remaining 2%. Geographic dispersion of processing facilities varies according to product form. In North America frozen and dehydration factories are near supply sources in the Northeast, upper Midwest and Pacific Northwest. In contrast, factories for making potato snacks (also known as crisps in the UK and chips in the US) are in every region. Since potato snack products are fragile and their low density makes them expensive to transport, they are processed in heavily populated areas. Growers of potatoes for the snack food industry are also widely dispersed. Prior to drought and flood problems during the 1990s North Dakota was the largest US producer of raw product for potato crisps. Florida then replaced North Dakota as number one. Other major producing areas include Arizona, central California, Maine and Michigan but pockets of production are scattered across the continent. Processing markets are quite different from fresh potato markets. Frozen processor contracts with growers emphasize things that influence finished product quality. Specific gravity is of particular concern; processors pay premiums for high specific gravity and discount for low specific gravity. Other characteristics, such as tuber size and grade, also earn premiums. Contract provisions change in response to changes in technology and production practices. Processors use contracts to guarantee some portion of their raw product needs. Typically, processors contract for 50% or more of their expected requirements. The remainder of their needs is met by purchases on the open market. Contracts allow growers to concentrate on production practices that produce profitable yields and quality. Over time, contracts stabilize grower prices and to a lesser extent returns, which are also influenced by the vagaries of weather. Frozen processors make fries, hash browns and other products from the usable potatoes delivered to the plant. The dehydration industry in North America operates differently, purchasing most of its raw product as off-grade potatoes from fresh packers. Growers produce potatoes specifically for frozen and fresh markets but returns are usually too low to attract dehy-only growers. Future development of varieties designed specifically for dehydra30
POTATO PROPERTIES , TYPES AND USE
tion could change this situation. In Europe, where the government provides economic incentives to produce starch potatoes, growers plant highyielding varieties suitable only for that market. The processing industry is a growth market. While problems exist, processing benefits both producers and consumers. Grower returns from sales to processors have added some stability to an otherwise highly volatile market.
Fresh processed potatoes A chilled potato product developed in Europe is becoming increasingly important in global markets. The impact of government food safety regulations on British fish and chips businesses was a key catalyst of change. Faced with new, expensive health regulations fish and chips managers struggled with their traditional method of preparing chips from raw potatoes. The expense became prohibitive for many operations. Some clever entrepreneurs filled their need by peeling, cutting, packaging and marketing a ‘fresh processed’ product. The fish and chips businesses were thus able to purchase a less labour-intensive product that met food safety regulations. One advantage of chilled versus frozen potatoes is that refrigeration is generally cheaper than freezing. The convenience of fresh processed potatoes provides marketing opportunities in the retail food market as well. In developed countries consumers are choosing to buy more convenient foods. They increasingly buy prepared salad mixes and ready-to-cook packaged foods. Consumers have also become interested in potatoes that have been peeled and even cut into slices, wedges or other shapes they want. While this market has been growing in Europe since the early 1990s it arrived in North America nearly a decade later. Fresh processed potatoes may be regarded as a substitute for both fresh potatoes and processed potatoes. The net effect of the introduction of this important new potato product is that total demand for all potato products may expand. Fresh processed potatoes give consumers another quick-meal choice that should compete well with other starches and vegetables in the convenience food array.
Seed potatoes Seed potatoes are vital to the health of the potato industry. Since potatoes are propagated vegetatively, diseases of the mother plant are passed on to 31
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
the next generation. Seed potato certification programmes were developed in the early 1900s to reduce seed-borne disease and maintain varietal purity. These programmes, often administered by government agencies, enforce rules about production practices and inspect seed plants and tubers to determine which lots meet seed certification standards. Potato growers who specialize in seed production are usually located in cold climates where winter weather destroys pathogens. Seed potato farms are often isolated from commercial potato farms that might be sources of disease. Seed growers who are located near processing facilities or have access to fresh packing have the flexibility to market their seed potatoes in other market channels. Seed potato markets usually offer the best returns, but seed growers stuck with unpopular varieties usually sell some in other market channels. New varieties must be increased by seed growers for several years before a sufficient quantity is available for commercial sales. The ultimate source of seed is usually the laboratory in the form of tissue culture. Public and private sources of disease-free potato stocks are available to seed potato growers. Plantlets grown from tissue culture produce small tubers, known as minitubers, that seed growers plant in either greenhouses or in fields. They produce several generations of seed to spread out the front-end costs of the laboratory production.
Livestock feed and other uses Potatoes have been used for livestock feed probably for as long as they have been used for human food. The general principle is that the best potatoes go into the food market and the rest into the feed market. The principle is breached during years when potatoes are in surplus. When the market is supplied with an overabundance of potatoes, food market prices may decline to the level where even high-quality potatoes are diverted to livestock feed. Raw potatoes are sometimes chopped before feeding to cattle to reduce problems with swallowing whole potatoes. Potato waste from processing is an important source of feed nutrients for cattle feeders. Some processors are able to sell the waste by-product which, without livestock feeders, would be a disposal liability rather than a marketable product. In this way the cattle industry in Western North America has helped support potato processors who might have located facilities in other regions. Low-value potatoes have also found their way into energy and alcoholic beverage markets. Potatoes are used as raw product for vodka producers. Some facilities have been constructed to turn potatoes into ethanol fuel. Some US states require that automobile fuels contain a certain amount of 32
POTATO PROPERTIES , TYPES AND USE
ethanol for two reasons. One is to reduce air pollution and the other reason is to indirectly support prices for farm commodities.
References 1
H Dana, Two Years Before the Mast, New York, Westvaco, 1992, pp 346–8, originally published in 1840. 2 W Burton, The Potato: A Survey of its History and of Factors Influencing its Yield, Nutritive Value, Quality and Storage, Wageningen, Holland, Veenman & Zonen, 1966, p 20. 3 P Harris, The Potato Crop, London, Chapman & Hall, 1992, p 539. 4 Burton, The Potato, p 27.
33
PA RT
II ECONOMICS OF THE GLOBAL POTATO ECONOMY
CHAPTER
3 Supply
T
he gift of the Incas has spread to many different types of farming regions around the world. Before discussing potato supply it is useful to know something about the people who produce potatoes. Like potatoes themselves, potato growers are quite a diverse lot. According to Harris:1 Some of the world’s largest and smallest, richest and poorest, most progressive and most backward farmers grow potatoes. Subsistence potato growers in isolated mountain areas in Rwanda and Bolivia are among the world’s poorest farmers. Commercial growers in northern Mexico and Brazil are among the richest. Market gardeners in parts of Guatemala and the Philippines are among the most intensive and productive. Uncounted households, both rural and urban, also grow potatoes, along with other vegetables, in home or garden kitchens.
Decisions made by these diverse potato growers determine the global supply of potatoes. This chapter discusses the results of grower decision-making within the biological, climate and economic forces that influence potato supplies around the world.
Potato growth requirements Potato growers can dictate some factors of production but others are beyond their control. Location of planting is one important factor over which 37
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
growers have some influence each growing season. Those with mobility can choose to farm in regions that are favourable to potato production. Those who are not mobile should still select potato fields carefully. Since potato production is expensive, they should choose fields with suitable soil types that are free of risky weather patterns such as frost pockets. Soils suitable for potato production should be well drained, deep and friable. Soils with heavy clay content can be difficult for potato production owing to water runoff, air deprivation, tuber growth restrictions and harvest difficulty. Sandy soils, including those with low organic matter, are suitable for potato production if irrigation is available to keep the soil from becoming too dry. Both heavy and light soils can be improved by increasing organic matter, which keeps the soil loose, reduces compaction, improves water retention and enables proper root and tuber growth. Growers can plant cover crops, rotate potatoes with legume crops and apply manure to increase soil organic matter. Growers can also control variety selection, fertility, pest protection, soil moisture and the end of the growing season. Variety selection can help growers choose the type of potato most suited to their region. Fertility can be managed by rotating crops, testing soil nutrients, applying fertilizer and monitoring nutrient content in the potato plants by a practice known as petiole analysis. Pest protection may include selecting pest-resistant varieties, rotating crops, scouting for pests and applying pesticides. Growers who have irrigation systems or drainage systems can practise water management by monitoring soil moisture then adding or removing water as needed. Growers can also control the end of the growing season by deciding when to kill the top growth of the potato plants. Potato top growth, also known as vines or haulms, is usually killed in advance of harvest in order for tuber skins to toughen up, or ‘set’. This is quite important for potatoes going into long-term storage. Seed potato management is another important factor under grower control. Selecting high-quality seed potatoes that are free from seed-borne disease and variety mix can help prevent production problems. Seed potato size is also important. North American growers, many of whom plant cut seed, can control size by adjusting their seed cutters. European growers prefer whole seed potato tubers and can control seed size by purchasing a specified size range. A third area of seed potato control is plant spacing. Growers can adjust plant populations on the basis of varietal growth differences and market destination. Wider spacing generally produces larger tubers. Potato growth factors beyond grower control include air temperature, soil temperature, frost-free period, light intensity, humidity, wind and other weather patterns. Potatoes are considered a short-day, cool season crop but do well in a variety of climates. Some potato varieties have adapted to 38
SUPPLY
the longer days of the potato-producing regions in higher latitudes. The highest potato yields are obtained in high-latitude desert regions such as Washington state’s Columbia Basin, where daytime temperatures exceed 38°C (100°F) but cool substantially at night. Potato yield potential is a function of sunlight and respiration. Photosynthesis, which converts sunlight to plant tissue, is controlled by day length and light intensity. Sunny days are conducive to high potato yields. Yield is determined by the amount of photosynthate produced minus the amount used by the plant. The plant’s usage, also known as respiration, is reduced by cool night-time temperatures. Too-cool weather, such as freezing temperatures during the growing season, will kill potato top growth. Potato plants, however, have shown a remarkable ability to survive and produce a crop of tubers even after frost has blackened and apparently killed a field of potatoes. Potato fields that have suffered from early-season frosts may come back to life as the energy stored in seed tubers allows them to send up new sprouts that become new potato plants. Late-season frosts, however, usually put a premature end to the potato-growing season. Frosts that go deep into the soil can actually damage potato tubers and render them unfit for marketing.
Production zones Farmers successfully grow potatoes in a wide variety of locations, from the tropics to near the Arctic Circle. Growers in Sub-Saharan Africa and the northern Andes of South America produce potatoes along the equator. Others plant potatoes at high-latitude areas in Alaska, Scandinavia, New Zealand and Patagonia. Potato production is also spread from fields near the sea to terraced plots more than 4300 metres above sea level. Farmers in the Netherlands plant potatoes on reclaimed land that is actually below sea level, while growers in Nepal produce potatoes within sight of Mount Everest. Potato growers succeed in hot, tropical lowlands as well mountain valleys with bitterly cold winters. Given the diversity of potato production sites it is useful to consider four global production zones: (1) temperate; (2) highland; (3) lowland tropical and subtropical; (4) Mediterranean. Although many countries fit entirely into one category, some large countries such as China have land in all four zones.
Temperate zones Temperate zones are characterized by at least one month when the average temperature drops below 0°C. Day length is suitable for most varieties but 39
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
growers face the risks of severe weather such as hail, frost and drought. Although many temperate-zone growers irrigate, others depend entirely on rainfall to produce their potato crops. Developed countries in northern Europe, North America and portions of South America’s Argentina and Chile fit into the temperate-zone category. Developing countries in northern Asia, including China, North Korea and South Korea, contain farmland considered to be in the temperate zone. Farther to the west, Iran and Turkey also fit into the category of temperate-zone developing countries. Although there is some technology spillover from developing to developed regions, temperate-zone production methods are very diverse. In developed countries, most potato producers plant in the spring and harvest in the fall. Cold weather allows for potato storage through the winter and spring and in some areas until the next potato crop is harvested. Rotation with grain and forage crops is typical. In some developing countries growers double crop and inter-plant. Where the climate permits, potatoes are planted immediately after rice or maize has been harvested, allowing for both a grain crop and a potato crop to be produced from the same field in the same year. Some growers mix potato plants in with orchards or other vegetable plantings. Temperate-zone growers use draft animals and tractors, livestock manure and chemical fertilizer, hand harvest and mechanical harvest depending on the availability of inputs and the economics of production in their areas.
Highland zones The highland zones, regardless of latitude, are the mountainous regions of the world. The Andes mountains of South America are where potatoes originated so that region remains a logical potato-producing region. Similar conditions exist in the Himalayas and other mountain ranges scatted across Asia, Africa, the Americas and Oceania, all of which have highland zones where potatoes are produced. Tropical highland zones have cool, but volatile temperatures that can make potato production inconsistent from year to year and even from field to field within a year. The local climate in highland areas changes with elevation. Individual growers may have fields with much different planting and harvest dates based on climate-induced length of growing season. In the lower elevations crop rotations and alternatives may include many other agronomic and horticultural crops. At higher elevation potatoes and barley, the hardiest grain, may be the only cropping choices. Highland growers use both manure and chemical fertilizer, but in remote areas some growers produce potatoes without fertilization and move to new fields as fertility declines. Early harvest of immature tubers is common to take advantage of seasonal price spikes. 40
SUPPLY
Some highland growers plant another crop of potatoes after an early harvest. Storage consists of both special-purpose storage buildings and storing in the ground until needed.
Lowland tropical and subtropical zones Average monthly temperatures are 10°C or higher in tropical and subtropical zones. The Indo-Gangetic Plain of Pakistan, India and Bangladesh is a region that fits into this category. Other tropical and subtropical potatoproducing areas include southern China, Cuba, Egypt, the coast of Peru and Vietnam. Until recently experts regarded the climate in tropical lowlands as too hostile for potato production. Since potatoes are not indigenous to tropical lowlands, potato-farming systems in these regions have not had much time to develop, as they have in temperate and highland zones. When potato production expanded in Europe and North America, the development of new potato varieties and technology favoured temperate zones. In the latter part of the twentieth century new techniques were developed specifically for tropical lowlands. As a result the Indo-Gangetic Plain has become one of the world’s three largest potato-producing regions. The potato production pattern in tropical lowlands is to plant seed potatoes at the beginning of the cool, winter season. Since this is the dry part of the year irrigation is required in most areas. For proper potato development it is important that night-time temperatures remain below 20°C for much of the growing season. In regions where this is the case, growers enjoy a more reliable weather pattern than in highland areas. Growers, even small growers with limited resources, generally achieve high yields in tropical lowlands. A combination of suitable winter climate, the potato’s short growing season, water availability, high yields and high prices have led to rapid expansion of potato production in some tropical lowland areas. As new varieties are developed specifically for lowland production, the growth will no doubt continue.
Mediterranean zones Mediterranean zones have dry summers, cool, humid winters and moderate temperatures, with the coldest month averaging between 0°C and 10°C. The European, Middle Eastern and African lands near the Mediterranean Sea, of course, are included in this category. Other countries with Mediterranean zones include Chile, New Zealand and the United States. Potato cropping practices in Mediterranean zones are a mix of those in temperate and lowland tropical zones. Much of the Mediterranean potato 41
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
production is in developed countries. Mediterranean growers often double crop potatoes, planting both a spring crop and a fall crop in the same field. Global potato processing firms operate a few factories in Mediterranean zones, but perhaps more importantly, procure raw product from Mediterranean growers for their factories in temperate zones. Both the processing and fresh market channels rely on Mediterranean zone potato production for new potatoes in the winter and spring.
Production trends Global distribution Potato production is widely dispersed throughout the world. Walker et al.2 developed a map of global potato plantings during the mid-1990s (Fig. 3.1). The map gives a visual image of potato plantings during the latter part of the twentieth century. Although pockets of intensive potato growing are on all the continents, the heaviest concentrations are in Europe, China and India. The European potato-planting concentration is in Eastern Europe, especially in the countries that made up the former Soviet Union. The Asian plantings are heaviest in northeast India and central China. Other pockets of significant potato production include the Northwest United States, Northwest Europe and the Andes mountains of South America. Walker’s map provides a snapshot of world potato plantings during the mid-1990s, but potato production continually shifts. During the last quarter of the twentieth century the distribution of global potato plantings shifted from West to East (Fig. 3.2 and 3.3). During the 1974–76 period nearly twothirds of the global potato supply was produced in Europe, but 25 years later that share declined to about half of the global total. Production shares changed little in the other regions, but Asia’s share jumped from 17% to 31%. The pie charts suggest that potato production declines in Europe coincided with potato industry expansion in Asia. Since the Asian expansion is primarily in the developing countries of that region, potato production in general may be shifting away from developed countries. In a study on root and tuber crops in the twenty-first century Scott et al.3 confirmed that potatoes are becoming more important in developing countries. During the 1983–96 period potato production in developing countries grew at an annual rate of 4.1%, while production in developed countries actually declined 0.8% (Table 3.1). Continuation of this trend could eventually close the gap between production in developing and developed countries. Developing country production grew from 64.3 million metric tonnes in 1983 to 108.1 million metric tonnes in 1996. Developed country 42
3.1
Global potato production map (Potato Research, vol. 42, extra edition, 1999, pp 246–7).
SUPPLY
43
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY Oceania 1%
Africa 3% N & C America 9% S America 4%
Europe 52% Asia 31%
3.2 World potato production by region, 1995–97.
Oceania Africa 1% 2% N & C America 10% S America 5%
Asia 17% Europe 65%
3.3 World potato production by region, 1974–76.
production declined from 209.2 to 187.6 million metric tonnes during the same period. In percentage terms, the developing country share of global potato production increased from 24% to 37% in 13 years. Scott’s research not only confirms that potato production is shifting to developing countries, but also that much of the shift is toward Asian developing countries. Large increases in annual production growth in India (5.1%) and China (4.6%) support the regional production shifts observed in Fig. 3.2 and 3.3. The production increases are attributed only partially to area planted. In all regions except Sub-Saharan Africa actual production growth
44
SUPPLY Table 3.1 Annual growth rates in potato production and area planted, 1983–1996 actual and 1993–2020 forecasted
Country/region
Actual 1983–96 production (% per year)
Forecasted 1993–2020 production (% per year)
Actual 1983–96 area (% per year)
Forecasted 1993–2020 area (% per year)
4.6 -1.0 5.1 3.7 5.4 2.0 4.8 0.6 4.1 -0.8 0.6
1.5 1.1 3.1 2.9 2.1 1.7 2.0 3.0 2.0 0.3 1.0
3.0 -2.1 3.8 2.7 2.5 0.3 2.6 0.7 2.4 -1.4 -0.1
0.2 -0.4 1.2 0.9 0.6 0.4 0.6 1.2 0.5 -0.2 0.1
China Other East Asia India Other South Asia Southeast Asia Latin America WANA Sub-Saharan Africa Developing countries Developed countries World Source: Scott et al. WANA = West Asia and North Africa
outpaced plantings growth, indicating that yields are trending upward. For developing countries, overall annual production growth of 4.1% is nearly double the area growth of 2.4% per year. The Scott study also included a forecast for potato production and consumption for the 1993 to 2020 period. The ‘forecasted production’ column in Table 3.1 depicts the expected growth rate in world potato plantings. In Sub-Saharan Africa, developed countries and the world as a whole forecasted growth into 2020 is expected to exceed actual growth during the 1983–96 period. In all other regions production is expected to continue to grow, but at slower rates than in 1983–96. The gap between forecasted production growth and forecasted area growth in all regions shows that Scott expects yields to increase all over the globe. The global trends of potato production shifting from Europe to Asia and from developed countries to developing countries may be modified or clarified by analysing potato production in individual regions. Table 3.2 shows actual potato production for six global regions in 1967, 1977, 1987, 1997 and 2000. In all of the regions except Europe production has been steadily increasing. The figures for 2000 show that Europe’s share of production dropped to 46% and Asia’s share increased to 36%, indicating a continuation of the trend identified in Fig. 3.2 and 3.3 and in Table 3.1. The predictions that European production will continue to decline and production will increase in all other areas deserves further analysis. Discussions of the regional potato supply situation follow.
45
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY Table 3.2
World potato production by region, 1967–2000 1967
Africa Asia Europe N & C America Oceania South America World
2 184 12 254 142 772 16 549 904 7 754 308 281
1977 1987 1997 (000 metric tonnes) 4 377 60 922 114 535 19 394 990 9 321 292 938
7 028 58 761 108 420 21 929 1 304 10 500 283 849
9 275 89 972 154 346 26 794 1 592 13 429 295 407
2000
10 350 108 751 138 152 27 975 1 875 14 699 301 803
Source: FAO, United Nations
Africa Africa is a vast continent with diverse farming regions ranging from the European-influenced Mediterranean area in North Africa to subsistence farming in war-torn Sub-Saharan Africa to the productive commercial agriculture of South Africa. All four of the production zones discussed in the previous section are present in Africa. In recent decades potato production has been expanding across the entire continent. Table 3.3 shows growth patterns for the main potato-producing countries in Africa. Africa’s largest producer, Egypt, is in the north with Mediterranean ports that provide access to European markets. The Egyptian industry is a significant supplier of winter potatoes to European fresh produce and processing market channels. In spite of European Union tariffs, Egyptian growers with new potatoes successfully compete with European growers who sell fallharvested potatoes out of storage during the winter months. Although changes in trade policy could affect potato production in Egypt, the successful adaptation of European varieties and the presence of processors and traders who depend on Egyptian potatoes will probably maintain Egypt’s stature in the potato industry. In Sub-Saharan Africa, the countries in a band to the south of the Saharan desert, war and civil strife have limited potato production. For example, potato production in Cameroon grew to 172 000 metric tonnes in 1987, then fell dramatically to 35 000 metric tonnes in 1997. Following a similar pattern, potato production in Rwanda, where 90% of the population is farming, built up to 181 000 metric tonnes in 1987 then dropped to 96 000 metric tonnes in 1997. The drop is even more dramatic when one considers that Rwanda’s potato production peaked at 347 000 metric tonnes in 1992. In five years during the Rwandan civil war potato production fell 72%. In nearby Kenya potato production also declined 72%, from 730 000 to 205 000 metric tonnes, from 1987 to 1997. 46
SUPPLY Table 3.3 Potato production in African countries, 1967–2000
Algeria Burundi Cameroon Egypt Ethiopia Kenya Libya Madagascar Malawi Morocco Rwanda South Africa Tanzania Tunisia Uganda Other Africa Africa total
1967
1977 1987 1997 (000 metric tonnes)
204 95 10 278 152 195 10 100 3 205 107 520 35 79 23 168 2184
500 151 40 970 177 375 80 120 89 180 170 740 88 90 384 223 4377
905 47 172 1678 220 730 114 267 276 520 181 1022 220 188 188 300 7028
948 43 35 2743 360 205 130 280 380 1145 96 1619 240 280 360 411 9275
2000
950 24 49 1 900 340 360 209 293 1 800 1 070 175 1 680 255 330 478 437 10 350
Source: FAO, United Nations
Prior to the civil strife, potato plantings and productivity were increasing in the highland zone of Sub-Saharan Africa. In a 1980s study of potato production in the Central African countries of Burundi, Rwanda and Zaire, Scott4 found a great deal of potential for expansion. He cited an abundance of farm family labour, suitable climate in the highlands and a familiarity with the crop as reasons for untapped capacity for growth. Since Europeans introduced potatoes into Central Africa in the 1880s generations of farmers have been integrating potatoes into their cropping practices. If political stability returns to the region the potato industry may flourish. Potato production increases from 1997 to 2000 are an encouraging sign. Another encouraging sign in Sub-Saharan Africa is the potato-supply response of growers in the Zaire–Nile divide of Central and East Africa. Growers there helped feed refuges from the Rwanda civil war in the 1990s by intensifying their potato production with the planting of two crops per year and adopting new production methods. One source of improvement was a blight-resistant variety from Mexico – Cruza 148. The variety does not produce high-quality potatoes for the commercial markets in developed countries, but its high yields and disease resistance helped improve the nourishment of many refugees. As people became displaced, many of them brought seed tubers of Cruza 148 to plant near their refuge camps. 47
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
Adoption of the new variety is an example of the power that investment in agricultural research can have on potato producers and consumers in developing countries. Walker5 mentions three other important points regarding potato production in Sub-Saharan Africa. First, the lifting of the embargo on South Africa opens the door for much-needed potato crop improvement technology to the region. South African expertise could be quite valuable to its neighbours. Secondly, dramatic increases in potato productivity could be achieved if inorganic fertilizers become available. Thirdly, unreliable government statistics may mask the true growth of the importance of potatoes in the region. Apparent potato industry expansion in some countries has not been documented by official government statistics. Another leading African potato-producing country, South Africa, is at the opposite end of the continent. Like Egyptian producers in the North, South African growers have adapted potato production and marketing techniques from the most developed potato production countries. International potato processing firms such as Frito-Lay have invested in South Africa because of the growers’ ability to efficiently, and consistently, produce high-quality raw product suitable for sophisticated global market channels.
Asia Asia is a large, sprawling region that some analysts divide into sub-regions. Table 3.4 depicts potato production in the broad region of Asia including the Middle Eastern countries. Although potato production is expanding in the Middle Eastern countries of Iran, Israel, Syria and Turkey, only Iran and Turkey are among the five largest producers in Asia. Of the countries listed in Table 3.4, 2000 potato production is down from 1967 only in Japan and South Korea. Rice is the main staple food in many Asian countries. Since potatoes are a substitute good for consumers and an alternative product for growers, increased potato production comes at the expense of rice.The ratio of potato price to rice price can be a driving force in Asian potato production and consumption. In countries where the government provides price support programmes for rice production and not for potato production the potato : rice price ratio becomes distorted. The Japanese government’s policy has long been in support of higher prices for its rice growers. The resulting low potato : rice price ratio encourages Japanese farmers to shift plantings from potatoes to rice. In spite of increasing demand for potatoes in Japan its potato production has decreased. The gap in demand is met with potato imports. In countries where government policy does not favour rice growers there is more incentive to expand potato production. 48
SUPPLY Table 3.4
Potato production in Asian countries, 1967–2000 1967
Afghanistan Bangladesh China India Indonesia Iran Iraq Israel Japan Korea, North Korea, South Lebanon Nepal Pakistan Saudi Arabia Syria Turkey Vietnam Other Asia Asia total
* * * 3 522 * 213 10 110 3 638 930 566 81 255 768 * 40 1 760 2 359 12 254
1977 1987 1997 (000 metric tonnes) 228 735 41 646 7 287 133 580 47 212 3 742 1 400 650 90 269 318 * 135 2 900 18 532 60 922
350 1 069 28 046 12 731 379 2 210 168 218 3 955 1 950 450 143 395 594 34 334 4 300 498 937 58 761
235 1 508 45 534 19 240 1 100 3 200 400 260 3 200 1 550 663 320 997 964 435 315 5 000 300 2 170 89 972
2000
235 1 702 58 039 22 500 827 3 450 150 333 3 400 1 963 562 270 1 182 1 868 331 450 5 315 371 5 803 108 751
Source: FAO, United Nations * = Insufficient data
Asian farmers in the highlands tend to grow more potatoes than do growers in the lower, and usually hotter, regions where rice is the dominant crop. Although the high- and mid-elevation areas are more conducive to potato production, potato growing in Asia’s tropical regions can actually be a complement to rice growing. Since the potato is a short-season crop, rice and potatoes may be planted on the same field in the same year. During the traditional winter fallow period for rice a crop of potatoes can be grown. An additional incentive is that winter-harvested potatoes usually sell for price premiums. China is the largest potato-producing country, not only in Asia, but also in the whole world. It has held the number one position since it replaced the Russian Federation in 1994. Although the United Nation’s Food and Agriculture Organization has reported China’s potato production since 1972, the accuracy of the numbers is dubious. Historical restrictions by the Chinese government on domestic vegetable trade, unusually large year-toyear changes in production numbers and inconsistencies between different data sources contribute to uncertainly of production, especially for historic 49
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
data before the 1990s. In spite of data problems it seems clear that China holds the top spot as the world’s largest potato-producing country. According to FAO, Chinese farmers grew 15% of the world’s potato crop in the late 1990s. Scott’s potato forecasting model predicts that China will produce 63.4 million metric tonnes of potatoes in 2020, which is 17% of the predicted world total. Walker’s map (Fig. 3.1) shows that Chinese potato production is concentrated in a north–south band a bit to the right of the centre of the country, but well inland from the Pacific Coast where China is most heavily populated and consumer income is highest. The potato band is mostly highlands stretching from Burma/Myanmar in the south to the borders of Mongolia and Siberia in the north. China’s main rice production area is in the southeast, well outside the potato band. Efforts have been made to increase winter potato production in the rice fallow fields of the southeast to take advantage of higher seasonal prices as well as higher prices in a potato-deficit area. Most Chinese potato growers rely on traditional agricultural practices that use cheap labour, small fields, little or no mechanization and organic fertilizers such as human ‘nightsoil’. Although China has a large number of potato scientists for a developing country, many growers are reluctant to adopt modern potato production techniques and varieties. One global potato processor built a frozen potato processing facility in China in the 1990s but had difficulty obtaining a consistent supply of high-quality raw product. Ironically, the top potato-producing country in the world cannot meet domestic demand for frozen potatoes in its restaurant industry. The problem is not quantity; it is quality. Growers using traditional Chinese cultural practices have been unable to produce a consistent supply of potatoes that meet the quality standards required by global food service firms such as McDonald’s. The other large band of Asian potato production lies in a long east–west strip stretching from Bangladesh through northeast India along the border of Nepal and extending across the border into Pakistan. Potato production in all four countries is expanding. This entire area is considered to be a lowland tropical zone. Walker attributes the rapid expansion of potato production in the Indo-Gangetic Plain to ‘synergy between government and private sector investment’. Publicly funded irrigation projects and agricultural research coupled with private investments in such things as cold storage facilities have provided farmers with effective means to expand potato production. Turkey is another large potato-producing country in Asia. Although its pro-Western culture and proximity to Europe make it a potential candidate for membership in the European Union, many people consider Turkey a true Asian country. Potato production has steadily increased and is expected to 50
SUPPLY
continue to increase. Global potato processors such as Lamb-Weston have built factories in Turkey. The firms are contracting for potato production with native growers but have also assisted growers from other countries in setting up potato-growing operations in Turkey. The country is blessed with productive soils, a temperate climate and close market access to population centres in the Middle East and Mediterranean region.
Europe A dramatic political shift in the latter part of the twentieth century changed potato production patterns in Europe. Before the Iron Curtain came down the potato industries in Eastern Europe and Western Europe reflected the differences between communism and capitalism. In Eastern Europe collective farms, central planning and use of potatoes for livestock feed were major forces in the potato industry. Meanwhile in Western Europe rapid adoption of new technology, large commercial potato farms and development of a processed potato industry influenced the potato economy. Since the fall of communism the Eastern European potato industry has been evolving into one that looks more like that in Western Europe. The emphasis of potato production is shifting toward satisfying the needs of consumers rather than the needs of government planners. As a result the amount of potatoes grown for livestock feed is declining so much that total European potato production is also falling. Two striking examples of shrinking potato production in Eastern Europe are the Russian Federation and Poland, where in both countries the 2000 potato crop was less than half the size of the 1967 crop (Table 3.5). During the 10-year period from 1987 to 1997 potato production fell 18% in the Russian Federation and 43% in Poland. Although from much smaller bases, production declined rapidly in other formerly communist countries during that period – falling 33% in Czech Republic, 58% in Romania and 59% in Yugoslavia. In the three years following 1997 Poland increased potato production, perhaps in response to global potato-processing firms building factories there. Although its production numbers were not available for the entire 1967–2000 period (Table 3.5), Ukraine appears to be on a production rollercoaster since the fall of communism. During the 1995–97 period Ukrainian growers produced 14.7, 18.4, and 19.0 million metric tonnes, respectively. But then production declined to 13.0 million metric tonnes in 2000. This variation may reflect potato production on cotkas or small gardening plots. During difficult economic times marking the transition from a centrally planned economy to a market economy Ukrainians increasingly relied on their cotkas to feed themselves. Collective farm potato production on a 51
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY Table 3.5
Potato production in European countries, 1967–2000 1967
Austria Bel-Lux Bulgaria Czech Rep Denmark Finland France Germany, East Germany, West Germany, Total Greece Hungary Ireland Italy Netherlands Norway Poland Portugal Romania Russian Fed Spain Sweden Switzerland Ukraine United Kingdom Yugoslavia Other Europe Europe total
1977 1987 1997 (000 metric tonnes)
3 049 1 943 381 6 038 857 881 10 406 14 065 21 288 35 353 599 1 507 1 748 4 010 4 840 807 48 214 1 296 3 085 95 464 4 490 1 399 1 125
1 352 1 310 350 3 785 800 737 8 190 9 976 11 251 21 227 936 1 416 1 200 3 310 5 752 605 41 300 1 144 3 738 83 400 5 553 1 346 870
879 1 957 316 3 072 957 491 6 720 12 228 7 354 19 582 948 1 077 697 2 454 7 478 371 36 252 1 178 7 572 75 908 5 552 1 068 658
7 201 2 804 739 142 772
6 598 2 854 162 114 535
6 760 2 210 171 108 420
690 2 300 320 2 066 1 414 783 6 500 * * 12 438 1 050 1 049 700 2 032 8 081 400 20 776 1 300 3 206 62 513 3 420 1 240 700 19 000 7 154 904 2 457 154 346
2000
660 3 006 538 1 417 1 502 816 6 644 * * 11 568 900 1 200 559 2 076 8 200 398 22 270 1 250 3 650 45 037 3 100 1 210 583 13 000 6 957 810 801 138 152
Source: FAO, United Nations * = Insufficient data
massive scale is no longer done, but potatoes remain an important part of the Ukrainian diet thanks to their cotkas. Potatoes are so important to Ukrainians that they are known as ‘the second bread of Ukraine’. When commercial farms shift to other crops Ukrainians make sure they have enough potatoes to eat by growing them themselves. This phenomenon may also be occurring in other formerly communist countries, but official government statistics may be clouded by the difficulty of quantifying production in small plots. With a more unified Europe, potato production made another, perhaps more subtle, shift at the turn of the century. It is interesting to look at the shifts in European potato production in one decade, in particular the period 52
SUPPLY
from 1989, the year before the fall of the Berlin Wall, to 1999. Among the countries where potato production declined, Poland dropped 42%, Italy was down 15%, Germany down 33% and Spain fell 39%. The countries where production increased include the North Sea countries of Netherlands, where production was up 20%, France up 20%, Denmark up 20% and the United Kingdom up 14%. These numbers suggest that there has been a significant shift from east to west and from south to north. One possible reason is that growers in the North Sea region are better able to compete in modern, global markets. In addition to possible advantages in soil and climate, North Sea growers may possess the advantages of a willingness to specialize, new production/storage technology and proximity to processing facilities.
North and Central America The United States dominates potato production in North and Central America (Table 3.6). US 2000 production was more than five times the size Table 3.6 Potato production in North American, Central American, South American and Oceania countries, 1967–2000 1967
N & C America Canada Cuba Guatemala Mexico USA Other N & C America South America Argentina Bolivia Brazil Chile Colombia Ecuador Paraguay Peru Uruguay Venezuela Oceania Australia New Zealand
16 549 2 130 105 14 378 13 856 66 7 754 1 797 610 1 467 717 800 403 10 1 712 105 133 904 653 250
1977 1987 1997 (000 metric tonnes) 19 394 2 498 147 31 653 15 972 93 9 321 1 777 679 1 900 928 1 609 504 4 1 600 130 190 990 729 257
Source: FAO, United Nations
53
21 929 3 033 250 68 950 17 484 144 10 500 2 150 625 2 343 727 2 243 354 8 1 709 126 216 1 304 1 015 281
26 794 4 050 364 57 1 282 20 861 180 13 429 2 275 843 2 757 1 305 2 900 493 2 2 388 145 322 1 592 1 308 278
2000
27 975 4 204 206 58 1 592 21 700 215 14 699 3 450 882 2 588 995 2 705 543 2 3 072 110 352 1 875 1 372 500
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
of production in Canada, the second largest producer. After several decades of slow, but steady, growth Canadian potato production grew more rapidly toward the end of the twentieth century. During the decade of the 1990s, Canadian potato production set new records in seven of the 10 years. Although other factors are involved, two important forces were currency exchange rates and the location of new North American potato-processing facilities. During the 1990s the US dollar strengthened significantly. Early in the decade the exchange rate was $1.15 Canadian for $1.00 US, then gradually moved to $1.60 Canadian for $1.00 US. The strong US dollar, along with the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA), provided the Canadian potato industry with a powerful economic incentive to expand and sell in the US market. In response to this incentive several North American potato processors expanded their processing capacity in Canada by enlarging existing factories and building new factories. As in Europe during the latter part of the twentieth century, North American potato production shifted from east to west and from south to north. An analysis of the 1989 to 1999 period shows large shifts in North American potato production. The US states where production declined include Florida down 10%, Maine down 18% and California down 24%. Gainers were the Pacific Northwest states of Idaho up 35%, Oregon up 13% and Washington up 45% as well as Canada, where potato production increased 51%. The US shifts occurred because of improved storage technology and less production risk in the desert climates of the West. In the earlier part of the twentieth century North American potato production was concentrated near population centres. Modern transportation, new storage technology and potato processing changed the location economics of the potato industry. No longer is it economically efficient for a large number of producers, scattered near large cities, to be the potato suppliers. Growers became more specialized and potato production shifted toward the regions where higher yields could be produced. This gave a distinct advantage to areas such as the Columbia Basin in Washington, where potato yields are double the yields achieved by growers in many other states. One additional factor in the location of North American potato production is marketing. During the 1930s Idaho was a minor player in the North American potato market. In 1937 the Idaho State Legislature formed the Idaho Potato Commission (IPC). Through advertising, promotion and quality control the IPC changed consumer tastes and preferences. The Idaho potato soon earned a reputation as a superior product. Consumer willingness to pay a higher price for Idaho potatoes fostered an expansion of the industry in that state. Even in the latter part of the twentieth century the Idaho price premium remained strong, and Idaho’s production share con-
54
SUPPLY
tinues to grow. One-third of the 2000 US fall crop was grown in Idaho. Without the successful IPC marketing programmes Idaho’s share would not be as large.
South America and Oceania In the birthplace of the potato, South American production is scattered between many countries, without the domination of one or two countries as seen in other regions (Table 3.6). Production in 1997 for the top four countries – Argentina, Brazil, Colombia and Peru – was within a narrow band of 2.3 to 2.9 million metric tonnes, but in 2000 Argentina jumped ahead of the pack. Potato production in 2000 was higher than in 1967 in every country except Paraguay, with most countries showing a steady increase over 33 years. South American potato producers are perhaps the most diverse of any region. The advanced economies of Argentina and Chile foster the type of large, high-tech operations seen in North America and Western Europe. Global potato-processing firms have factories in both countries. Processed potato products from Argentina and Chile will not only satisfy domestic needs, they are being exported to other South American countries as well. With new trade arrangements, such as an expansion of NAFTA, South American processed potatoes could enter other international markets. At the other extreme is the South American subsistence farmer who grows potatoes only for family consumption rather than commercial markets. Growers in Bolivia and parts of Peru fit into the subsistence or semi-subsistence categories. In some South American countries, such as Brazil and Peru, both the subsistence and commercial growers co-exist. Oceania makes up the smallest of the world’s potato-producing regions. The advanced economies of Australia and New Zealand provide incentives for the development of modern potato industries. Several major food processors have established potato-processing operations in the region. Possible transport cost advantages may make this region a serious competitor in Asian processed potato markets. A discussion of potato-producing countries would not be complete without an overall list of the world’s largest producers. Table 3.7 shows the top 20. China was the largest potato-producing country in 2000, followed by Russia, India and Poland. Seven of the top 10 were in Europe, two in Asia and one in North America.
55
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY Table 3.7
Top 20 potato-producing countries, 2000
Country 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20
China Russian Fed India Poland USA Ukraine Germany Netherlands UK France Turkey Canada Romania Iran Argentina Japan Spain Peru Bel-Lux Colombia
Quantity (000 mt)
Percentage of total
58 039 45 037 22 500 22 270 21 700 13 037 11 568 8 200 6 957 6 644 5 315 4 204 3 650 3 450 3 450 3 400 3 100 3 072 3 006 2 705
19.2 14.9 7.5 7.4 7.2 4.3 3.8 2.7 2.3 2.2 1.8 1.4 1.2 1.1 1.1 1.1 1.0 1.0 1.0 0.9
Source: FAO, United Nations
Production systems Potatoes are produced by many different methods in diverse production regions around the globe. Consumer demand is the ultimate driver of potato production. A grower’s intended market influences production decisions regarding field selection, variety selection, cultural practices, harvest method and storage.
Seed potato production One important market for potato producers is other potato producers. Since potatoes are grown from tubers, about 10% of overall potato production is replanted. For other types of crops growers can simply save some of the harvest to use as seed for the next crop. It is much more difficult to do that with potatoes for two reasons. First, potato tubers are highly perishable. Unlike true seeds, potato tubers can only be saved for next year’s planting in expensive facilities where temperature and humidity can be controlled. 56
SUPPLY
Second, potatoes suffer from serious seed tuber-borne potato diseases. A few infected seed tubers can cause crop failure, especially with diseases that are also spread by equipment, insects, water and air currents. The need for healthy seed led to the development of seed potato improvement programmes, first in Europe in the late 1800s then in North America in the early 1900s. One founding principle of the programmes was to set up a system whereby seed potatoes could be ‘certified’ and approved for sale. At first the systems focused on varietal purity, but then the twin emphasis of disease purity emerged. At the time a serious potato production malady known as ‘running out’ was common. As new varieties were developed the yield of succeeding generations declined owing to seed-borne viruses. Seed certification programmes were designed to reduce the virus problem by establishing disease tolerances for seed potatoes. Seed potato certification is now in the hands of government agencies, universities or grower associations depending on the country and state. The certification agencies establish rules, set tolerances, inspect fields, detect disease and issue shipping certification. Unfortunately, some disease-causing pathogens go undetected because they remain latent, or express no symptoms. This led to limited generation regulations in most seed certification agencies. The probability of disease infection increases with each generation of seed potatoes because of the continual exposure to pathogens. To reduce this risk most agencies limit the number of generations that seed may be multiplied to five years, or up to nine years for some agencies. In the past growers or seed agencies would visually inspect seed potato fields and select the healthiest potato plants for the beginning of a new multiplication programme. New technology has replaced both the visual selection and early-generation multiplication methods. Tissue culture is the laboratory method used to provide disease-free potato stocks for seed multiplication. The technique involves growing plants under sterile conditions in artificial media. The procedure is as follows: 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
Cut a meristem, a small growing point the size of a flake of black pepper, from the stem of a potato plant. Put the meristem into a test tube with the nutrients required for it to grow into a small plantlet. Test the plantlet for the presence of disease-causing pathogens. Make nodal cuttings – consisting of a stem segment, a growing point and a leaf – from the plantlets that pass the disease tests. Place each nodal cutting into a medium that promotes root development and allows it to develop into a new plantlet. Plant the new plantlets in greenhouses or in outdoor fields. Harvest the tubers produced by the plantlets. Since they are small they are called minitubers. 57
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
8
Plant the minitubers in fields for multiplication as certified seed potatoes.
One variation of this technique is to allow the plantlets produced in step 2 to grow and produce tubers, which are very small. Known as microtubers, these can be marketed as disease-free stock or planted in greenhouses for multiplication. With this new technology the management of seed potato operations has changed. Some growers have built laboratories and greenhouses to vertically integrate backwards in the seed potato marketing chain. Others rely on public or private entities to sell them the plantlets and minitubers that they require for beginning seed stocks. Although tissue culture technology has moved part of the seed potato production system indoors, conventional outdoor field production continues to play an important role in the multiplication of high-quality seed potatoes. The economic purpose of growing several field generations of seed potatoes is to spread tissue culture costs. During the 1990s US minituber prices for some varieties were $24 per pound ($53/kg). At a planting rate of 400 pounds per acre (2178 kg/ha), seed costs alone were $9600 per acre ($23 712/ha). With additional costs of $1500 per acre ($3705/ha), total production costs for the first generation of seed potatoes were $11 100 per acre ($27 417/ha). A typical yield for the first field generation from minitubers was about 200 hundredweight per acre (22 t/ha), giving a production cost of $55.50 per cwt (45.4 kg). Assuming planting rates of 30 cwt/acre and yields of 285 cwt/acre for subsequent generations, production costs for the first six generations of seed potatoes are $55.50, $11.11, $6.43, $5.94, $5.89 and $5.88 per cwt (45.4 kg), respectively. Under this scenario the cost structure flattens out at the fourth generation. Commercial growers can plant high-quality, earlier-generation seed potatoes, but at a higher cost. New technology that reduces tissue culture costs and increases seed potato yields would shorten the field generation timetable. Potato growers who want to grow for the seed market should be located in areas that reduce the risk of field contamination. Isolation from commercial potato fields is so important that some seed potato production areas are quarantined to prohibit planting of non-seed fields. Although seed potato growers generally use the same equipment and production practices as commercial growers, they must also utilize extra sanitation methods to reduce the risk of disease. Quality control is a major challenge for seed potato growers. Some diseases, such as bacterial ring rot (BRR), have a zero tolerance with seed certification agencies. If a seed grower has one plant infected with BRR, some agencies will prohibit the whole farm’s production from being certified. Seed potato growers face marketing challenges that differ from those in 58
SUPPLY
the commercial market. First, the seed growers’ target market is other potato growers. Since their customers are in a similar business and tend to be loyal to suppliers, many seed growers focus on establishing long-term relationships with successful commercial growers. Secondly, seed growers must make production and marketing plans several years in advance. Since they multiply seed stocks for several years before selling to commercial growers, they must try to determine what varieties will be in demand several years into the future. If they are wrong, they may be in an excess supply situation for a particular variety and be forced to sell either at low prices or in commercial markets. Although commercial potato market prices are usually lower than seed potato prices, that is not always the case. For seed growers who are close to processors or fresh packers, the additional market alternatives can reduce risk and improve profitability. Seed potatoes can be sold in other markets, but it is a one-way street. Potatoes grown for commercial purposes and not entered into a seed certification programme cannot officially be sold as seed potatoes. Some states and countries prohibit planting seed that is not certified, but enforcement is difficult, especially for growers who plant tubers produced on their own farms. A common practice among growers in some areas has been to plant ‘year-out’seed or ‘eliminators’.The first term describes potatoes a commercial grower harvests from a crop planted with certified seed. Saving a portion of that crop to plant next year is the practice of using ‘year-out’ seed. The second term describes the practice of sorting small potatoes from a commercial harvest to plant next year’s crop. Potato processors usually specify in their grower contracts that certified seed must be used, but buyers in fresh markets do not have such a policy. Commercial potato growers in North America usually plant seed potatoes that have been cut into pieces. An eight-ounce seed potato might be cut into four two-ounce pieces. The seed-cutting practice increases the risk of disease infection entering via the cut surfaces, but the trade-off is that seed potato costs per acre are reduced. European growers typically plant whole seed potatoes, which reduces the risk of disease. Growers in other parts of the world follow both the North American and European seed practices. Seed potatoes make up a large portion of potato production costs for most growers but are higher in areas far from seed potato production. In tropical lowlands high aphid populations, lack of winter-time pest kill and continual threats of viral and fungal diseases make it difficult to grow seed potatoes locally. This has generated interest in true potato seed (TPS). The risk of disease transmission is lower with TPS, and tonnes of seed potatoes that require careful temperature and humidity control can be replaced with a few kilograms of easy-to-store TPS. The problem is that TPS produces a genetically diverse crop that lacks the uniformity that many markets require. 59
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
New technology that solves the uniformity problem could change the seed potato industry, especially in tropical lowlands.
Commercial potato production Commercial potato production is generally for human consumption. Although a large portion of potatoes produced in Eastern Europe were grown for livestock feed, human consumption has become more important since the fall of communism. In capitalist countries the primary market for commercial potato production is for human food, with potatoes going to livestock feed only when they fail to make the grade for food or during times of when large supplies depress prices. Commercial potatoes flow into two main food market channels: fresh and processing. Within the processing channel are several distinct sub-channels including frozen, dehydrated and snack food processing. Growers should think about marketing before planting a crop of potatoes. Variety selection may determine what market channels are open to them. Some varieties do well in fresh markets, while others are best suited for a particular type of processing. Growers with processor contracts may have the variety selection determined for them. A few varieties may be used in both fresh and processing markets. After selecting varieties some critical steps in commercial potato production include: seed potato procurement, seed bed preparation, planting, fertilizing, irrigating, pest scouting, controlling pests, harvesting, storing and marketing. Seed potatoes can be purchased from individual seed potato growers or from brokers. Some processors procure seed potatoes for their contract growers and deduct the costs from their payments. Many seed growers and commercial growers prefer developing long-term relationships with each other. Seed bed preparation consists of a variety of soil tillage methods. Some growers plough in the fall, some in the spring and some not at all. For proper soil aeration deep tillage of the soil, if not by plough then by disc or ripper, is recommended for potato production. To reduce damage during mechanical harvest, stones are either removed from the field or placed in furrows away from the potato plants. Working the soil when wet can cause soil compaction problems, creating clods that can bruise potato tubers. Clodbreaking tillage is often used to prepare seed beds. If bed-shaping equipment is not used at planting, a later ‘hilling’ operation is done to form potato beds that cover shallow tubers and facilitate harvesting. Potato growers in developed countries use mechanical potato planters that efficiently and evenly place seed in rows. The size of planters has increased from two-row to four-row to six-row to eight-row planters. In the late-1990s the 12-row planter made its debut in the United States. Some 60
SUPPLY
planters are equipped to place fertilizer and systemic insecticides near the seed. In developing countries the entire planting operation may be done with draught animals and human labour. Furrows are opened with implements pulled by horses or oxen, and seed potatoes are placed by hand before the furrows are covered. Growers usually fertilize at planting, and some apply additional fertilizer during the growing season. In developed countries, chemical fertilizers are common. In developing countries manure is often used. In China and other places, human waste, or ‘nightsoil’, is used as a fertilizer. Irrigation is done as needed during the growing season, but in very dry regions fields are irrigated before planting in order to facilitate soil preparation. Pest scouting and pest control methods vary but are a critical factor in producing a potato crop that has the yield and quality to be profitable.
Potato harvest methods Potato top growth is usually killed before harvest. The tops, known as potato haulm in the UK and potato vines in the US, are killed for several reasons. The first reason is to stop growth. Potato tubers can be too large for some markets, such as the seed potato market. Another reason to stop growth is for pest control. If the top growth is dead, potato diseases can no longer enter the tubers via the tops. In cases of serious disease outbreaks potatoes are killed prematurely to save the crop. Another reason to kill top growth is to hasten skin set, the natural process that thickens the tuber’s protective outer layer. In developed countries growers use a variety of methods to kill top growth. One method is chemical dessicants that are sprayed onto the foliage. Another method is mechanical devices that either pull out or chop the haulms. Some growers use a combination of mechanical rollers to weaken the haulms then follow with a chemical dessicant whose effectiveness is enhanced by the rolling. When energy prices are low some growers use petroleum burners to kill the tops with flames. Growers in some temperate zones rely on frost to kill potato tops. Potato harvest involves the separation of 20 to 40 tonnes of potatoes from 500 to 1500 tonnes of soil per hectare. Regardless of harvest method the goal is to separate tubers from roots and soil. The most primitive method used long ago by the Incas and still used by subsistence farmers is for some sort of spade to dig and lift the potatoes to the soil surface. Mechanical harvesting consists of the following steps: digging the bed; sieving the soil; separating tubers from plants; and transferring to a vehicle. Modern potato harvesters perform all of those steps as they move down the rows of potatoes. Recent mechanical harvest improvements emphasize 61
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
speed of harvest. To minimize turning-around time, many growers use potato harvest methods that pick up four, six or even 12 rows at one pass. Some growers use a two-stage harvesting method with smaller harvest machines, called windrowers, to dig rows of potatoes not to place in a vehicle, but to place in the rows that the main harvester will pick up. This allows a tworow harvester to pick up four rows, two of which are dug and two of which were placed on the beds by the windrower. It also allows a four-row harvester to dig only four rows, yet pick up the potatoes from eight other rows placed in its harvest beds by two four-row windrowers. One advantage of hand harvest methods is that people can handle potatoes more gently than can machines. Bruising is an ongoing concern for mechanical harvesting, especially when tuber temperatures are below 10°C. Careful adjustment and operation of potato harvesting and handling equipment is critical during cold harvest weather. Growers are advised to avoid early morning harvest and wait until temperatures warm in order to minimize bruising. Careful handling is required in transport and handling at the market or storage as well.
Storage systems Where storage is an option, growers must make important storage-related decisions that affect the profitability of their potato crops. Whether or not to store, how to store and how long to store are the main issues. Even after the tops are killed, potato tubers are still living organisms. The crop’s condition coming out of storage cannot be better than it was going into storage. The goal is to minimize losses, not eliminate them. Storage losses consist of weight loss and quality loss. Weight loss is a natural occurrence for the living, breathing potato tubers. Some water weight is lost through evaporation and some carbohydrate weight is lost through respiration. The end result is that growers have less tonnage of potatoes to sell coming out of storage than they had at harvest. Even under optimal storage conditions weight loss for potatoes stored for crisp processing can reach 10% for eight months of storage (Fig. 3.4). The other storage loss category – quality loss – can range from zero to one hundred percent when a disease problem such as late blight gets out of control. For the example in Fig. 3.4 quality loss begins at 1% in the third month of storage then increases to 5% by the eighth month. The three critical variables that affect storage loss are: (1) the condition of the potato; (2) the storage environment; and (3) the length of storage. Growers have some control over all three variables. The condition of potatoes going into storage is influenced by the production practices the grower
62
SUPPLY % 16 Quality loss 14
Weight loss
12 10 8 6 4 2 0 Nov
Dec
Jan
Feb
Mar
Apr
May
Jun
Jul
3.4 Potato storage loss ( J Gibson, personal communication).
used, such as pest control, haulm kill and bruise prevention during harvest. Problems caused by factors beyond grower control, such as excess rainfall or severe frost, can lead growers to sell at harvest rather than take on the increased risks of storage losses. Temperature control and humidity control are the main functions of a storage facility. The crudest form of storage is to leave the potatoes in the soil where they grew. If the climate during field storage provides adequate soil moisture and soil temperatures that are neither too hot nor too cold, storage weight and quality losses may be low. Storages in some regions consist of pits or trenches into which the harvested potatoes are placed, then covered with soil, straw or some built structure. Potato storage facilities in the temperate zones of developed countries are above-ground, insulated buildings made of concrete, metal and wood. The design of these modern storage buildings includes ducts for air movement to control temperature and humidity within the piles of potatoes. Some facilities include electronic sensing and control devices to automatically keep an optimal storage environment. In modern facilities potato storage consists of three periods. First is the curing period during which potato bruises and wounds are healed in a
63
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
temperature range of 10°C to 15°C. During a process called suberization potato tubers form a corky layer of cells over a cut or wounded area to prevent entry of harmful organisms that could cause rot. The curing period also allows the tuber skin to further mature and thicken. Second is the holding period during which the temperature is held in a range from 4.4°C to 10°C depending on the market channel. Potatoes stored for fresh and seed use are held at the low end of the range, those stored for frozen processing are held in the middle of the range and those held for potato snack processing are stored at the high end. The third stage is the warming phase before removal from storage. Since potatoes bruise more easily at low temperatures, potatoes in low holding temperatures are warmed before handling for removal. In arid climates moisture is added to the air to reduce evaporative weight loss in the potato tubers. Where potatoes are stored into hot months, refrigeration is added to some facilities. One potentially serious type of quality loss during storage is sprouting, which some varieties tend to do several months after harvest. As a control method growers can apply chemical sprout suppressants. During the growing season maleic hydrazide (MH) can be applied to the foliage. Potato plants move MH to the tubers where it carries over and prevents sprouting. An alternative is to use a chemical during the storage season if the potatoes are to be stored longer than two or three months. Growers can apply chlorpropham (CIPC) through the ventilation system. For long-season storage of more than six months additional CIPC applications are usually done. Of course, sprout inhibitors should not be used for seed potatoes. Since some global potato buyers, including Japanese customers, are becoming reluctant to purchase processed potato products that have traces of CIPC, potato scientists are investigating alternative sprout-control methods. Potatoes can also be stored successfully outside the temperate zones in some regions. In highland zones potato growers use in-field storage as well as in-home storage. They also use general farm buildings, especially for seed potato storage. A few highland growers have invested in special-purpose potato storage buildings. Growers in the Mediterranean zones who can harvest potatoes during the fall, winter and spring have less need for storage than do growers in other zones. Lowland tropical growers face the challenge of hot-weather storage. Since they grow their potato crops during the winter, stored potatoes must survive hot summer temperatures. On-farm storage usually consists of holding potatoes in dark, well-ventilated buildings or even under shade trees. Egyptian growers have built permanent mud huts for potato storage. The effective storage season for most lowland growers is two or three months, but refrigerated storages are being built by agribusinesses in India and Bangladesh. The extended storage season has helped expand the potato industry in the Indo-Gangetic Plain. 64
SUPPLY
Costs Growing costs Potato production is an expensive enterprise when compared to the costs of growing grain and forage crops. An example of estimated potato production costs for a temperate climate zone in a developed country is given in Table 3.8. The Idaho potato production costs are split into two categories: variable and fixed. Also known as operating costs, the variable cost category includes the direct costs of producing a crop. Fixed costs are incurred regardless of the level of production. In developed temperate zones such as Idaho fixed costs represent a large portion of total potato production costs. Since Idaho growers use expensive equipment the ownership costs – depreciation, interest, taxes and insurance – for machinery and tractors make up a large portion, 14%, of total production costs. Unlike grain drills and combines that can be shared between wheat, barley, maize and other grain crops, potato equipment is only used for potatoes. When one considers both the fixed and variable costs of equipment it is seen that mechanization expenses make up 28% of total production costs. Obviously potato production in Idaho is very capitalintensive. The same is true for most other temperate-zone potato regions in developed countries. Table 3.8
Estimated potato production costs per acre, eastern Idaho, 1999
Variable costs Seed Fertilizer Pesticides Equipment Labour Other Total variable costs Fixed costs Equipment Land Other fixed costs Total fixed costs Total costs
Cost ($/acre)
Cost ($/cwt)
Cost (£/tonne)
Percentage of total
176 130 134 175 126 102 843
0.54 0.40 0.41 0.54 0.39 0.31 2.59
7.24 5.34 5.50 7.18 5.16 4.18 34.60
14 10 10 14 10 8 66
181 220 33 434 1277
0.56 0.68 0.10 1.33 3.93
7.43 9.03 1.34 17.79 52.39
14 17 3 34
Source: University of Idaho Equipment variable costs include fuel, lubrication, maintenance, repair and custom work. Other variable costs include crop insurance, promotion tax, water assessment and interest on operating capital. The assumed currency exchange rate is $1.50 per £1.00.
65
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY Table 3.9 Distribution of expenditures on selected inputs for potato production in various area Zone & region Highland zone Benquet, Philippines Ruhengeri, Rwanda Sabana de Bogota, Colombia Lowland zone Cañete, Peru Dhaka, Bangladesh Punjab, India Temperate zone Idaho South Korea United Kingdom
Seed
Labour
Fertilizers
Pesticides
Equipment
55% 38% 24%
16% 62% 34%
17% 0% 22%
10% 0% 14%
2% 0% 6%
38% 37% 45%
20% 27% 27%
17% 20% 18%
11% 15% 6%
14% 1% 4%
19% 32% 28%
13% 38% 23%
14% 3% 9%
15% 26% 11%
39% 1% 29%
Sources: Horton; Claydon; University of Idaho
Costs of production vary between growers and production areas and even between fields on the same farm. In international markets currency exchange rates also affect relative costs of production. It is useful, however, to look at the relative distribution of costs in producing areas scattered around the globe. Horton6 and Claydon7 show how growers in different locations rely on different types of production inputs to produce potatoes (Table 3.9). Rwandan growers relied only on seed potatoes and labour; they use no fertilizer, pesticides or machinery. Seed potato expenditures are highest for growers in regions where seed potatoes are not produced. Since it is difficult for growers in the lowland regions of Cañete, Peru and Punjab, India to produce seed potatoes in their hot, tropical climates they must import them from other regions. Seed expenses are also high for growers in some highland regions such as Benquet, Philippines where suitable nearby seed production sites are very limited and imported seed potatoes are expensive. Even in the temperate-zone areas where seed potato production is common, seed costs exceed one-fifth of the total direct input costs. Labour costs range from a low in highly mechanized Idaho of 17% to a high of 62% in Rwanda. For Rwandan farmers whose families can provide the needed labour, their only out-of-pocket expenses may be for seed potatoes. Family labour can reduce direct labour expenses in other regions as well, but the opportunity to reduce total costs is less where growers depend more heavily on mechanization. Fertilizer costs range from a low of zero in Rwanda to a high of 22% in Colombia, both of which are in highland production zones. The Colombian growers use manure and chemical fertilizers, both of which they apply heavily. The Rwandan growers did not have access to chemical fertilizers. 66
SUPPLY Table 3.10
European processing potato production costs and returns
Category Returns Yield (t/ha) Price (£/t) Total revenue Variable costs (£/ha) Seed Fertilizer Pesticides Other Total variable costs Fixed costs (£/ha) Rent Machinery Contractors Labour Irrigation Levies Other Total fixed costs Total costs (£/ha) Net margin (£/ha) Net margin (£/t)
UK
Netherlands
France
45 102 4590
50 59 2950
43 72 3096
556 197 359 46 1159
504 70 278 17 869
367 138 206 53 764
261 399 96 358 151 41 69 1376 2535 2055 46
340 226 148 70 17 17 52 871 1740 1210 24
121 418 44 286 143 11 77 1100 1864 1232 29
Source: Fearne,Wye College £1 = 3.3 NFL, 9.9 FF
In general, fertilizer expense appears to represent a larger portion of the total in the highland production areas, while pesticide expenses are larger in temperate zones. In heavily mechanized Idaho and the United Kingdom equipment expenses make up 39% and 29% of the direct expenses, respectively. A study conducted by Dr Andrew Fearne of Wye College in London analysed costs and returns for processing potato growers in the UK, Netherlands and France. Based on surveys of 173 growers Fearne compiled the averages in Table 3.10. The study indicates that costs are higher in the UK, but higher prices give British growers a larger net margin.
Storage costs Except for potatoes sold off the field grower costs do not end at harvest. Some growers mistakenly consider potatoes in storage like ‘money in the bank’, which is a mistake for two reasons: storage risks and storage costs. 67
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY Table 3.11
Estimated potato storage costs
Category
Cost (£)
Potatoes (3000 tonnes ¥ 75) Facility ownership Operating expense Interest (1%/mo ¥ potato value) Shrink (6%) Total costs Cost per tonne
225 000 24 000 18 000 13 500 13 500 294 000 92
Potato storage should be managed like any business enterprise; it should be viewed as a profit centre. An example of potato storage costs is in Table 3.11. The potatoes themselves should be considered an expense and are indeed the largest expense. If the crop were not placed in storage it could have been sold at harvest. The off-the-field price multiplied by the volume of potatoes in storage determines the value of this expense category. In our example we estimate a 3000ton storage filled with potatoes worth £75 per tonne at harvest, giving a potato cost of £225 000. Growers who hire storage can allocate that expense as a storage cost, but those who own their facilities also incur the ownership costs of depreciation, repairs, taxes and insurance. In our example we assume storage ownership cost of £8 per tonne. The next item, operating expense, includes estimated costs for electricity, labour and sprout suppressants. Interest is estimated at 1% of potato value per month. Shrinkage, the loss of potato weight and quality, is estimated at 6% for the six months of storage. The 3000 tonnes of potatoes going into storage is estimated to shrink to 2820 after six months in storage. The bottom line in Table 3.11 is that the break-even price for potatoes placed in storage for six months is £92 per tonne. The storage enterprise will only be profitable if the market price rises from the £75 per tonne at harvest to at least £92 per tonne six months later. Following similar analysis growers can estimate storage costs for each month to help them decide when to sell. On the revenue side is the price offered by buyers or a futures market if one is available. Processor contracts offer storage incentives, but the open market for fresh potatoes is a volatile roller-coaster that offers opportunities and risks.
Packing costs Some growers also pack potatoes for the fresh market. Those who do not pack their own potatoes can enter the fresh market by either selling to a 68
SUPPLY Table 3.12
United States fresh potato packing costs and returns 1985 ($/cwt)
1990 ($/cwt)
1995 ($/cwt)
Average ($/cwt)
12.87
17.64
11.67
14.06
Raw product cost
8.83
13.63
7.54
10.00
Containers Depreciation Inspection Labour Maintenance Overhead Supplies Utilities Total packing costs Total costs Profit
1.27 0.05 0.06 1.67 0.25 0.39 0.13 0.06 3.88 12.71 0.16
1.72 0.12 0.06 1.31 0.24 0.37 0.01 0.03 3.86 17.49 0.15
1.65 0.17 0.07 1.16 0.15 0.73 0.01 0.03 3.97 11.51 0.16
1.55 0.11 0.06 1.38 0.21 0.50 0.05 0.04 3.90 13.90 0.16
Percentage of revenue Revenue
Average price
Costs 71 Packing costs 11 1 0 10 2 4 0 0 28 99 1
Source: Reeve
packing business or contracting with a firm to pack and sell their potatoes for a fee. A University of Idaho study by Reeve8 analysed packing costs and returns for a large multi-state packer, as shown in Table 3.12. The profit margins were quite thin (1%) and nearly identical in each of the years, even in 1990 when potato prices were comparatively high. Profits during the years not placed in the table were also within the $0.13 to $0.16 per cwt (45.4 kg) range, suggesting that this firm keeps a stable profit margin in spite of volatile potato prices. This means that growers do not shift price risk on to the packers, or at least not this packer. The largest packing cost is for raw product, which is 71% of revenue on average. Containers form the second largest cost, making up an average of 11%, slightly higher than the labour figure of 10%. The trend in labour costs is downward, moving from $1.67 to $1.16, a decline of $0.51 per cwt (45.4 kg) in a decade, despite an upward trend in wage rates. This packer made a series of investments in labour-saving equipment that increased packing volume. During the same decade, depreciation expenses increased from $0.05 to $0.17 per cwt. In spite of operating more expensive and more sophisticated equipment, maintenance expenses declined from $0.25 to $0.15 per cwt. The investment in high-volume, labour-saving equipment 69
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
added $0.12 to depreciation costs that were more than offset by labour savings of $0.51 and maintenance savings of $0.10 per cwt (45.4 kg).
Factors that influence plantings Growers consider several things when they decide what crops to plant. They look at the availability of land, labour and other inputs as well as cropping history and desired rotations. They also respond to economic signals. Perhaps the most important of the economic signals is the price of potatoes. Given the time between the decision to produce and the actual harvest of potatoes there is a lagged response to prices. Human nature is such that high potato prices during the time when growers are deciding what to plant will give them incentive to increase plantings. Even though they know that the price for the next crop may be different from the price for last year’s crop current price levels can make growers pessimistic or optimistic. Changes in prices can also cause people to enter or leave the potato business, with high prices often tempting people who never before grew potatoes. Potato growers who farm in countries where potato futures contracts are available may lock in prices before they plant, as discussed in Chapter 5. Those who don’t use potato futures may be influenced in their planting decisions by prices on the futures exchanges. More discussion on potato futures follows in Chapter 10. Of course, potato price is but one factor that influences plantings. Other factors, known as supply shifters, that can affect the supply of agricultural goods include input prices, profitability of alternatives, technology, prices of joint products, risk, government programmes, and weather and pests. Joint products are important for products such as wool and mutton, but are not relevant for potatoes. The other factors are discussed below.
Input prices Potato production input expenses are seen in Tables 3.8, 3.9 and 3.10. Economic theory tells us that changes in any of the major expenses could affect potato plantings. Equipment costs make up the largest cost category, with variable and fixed costs comprising 28% of Idaho total production costs. Statistical analysis, however, has shown an insignificant relationship between equipment costs and US potato plantings. One reason may be that once growers make an investment in potato production equipment they tend to plant potatoes regardless of changes in prices of fuel or the market for new and used potato equipment. Seed potato price is sometimes thought to be 70
SUPPLY
an important factor in potato plantings and probably is in production regions where seed potatoes represent a large portion of total production costs. For potato plantings in the US, however, no significant statistical relationship has been established for seed prices or for any other input.
Profitability of alternatives Although most farmers like to practise crop rotation, the relative profitability of the alternative crops can cause them to break rotation. Even if they stick to rotation on land they own, they might have flexibility to adjust plantings on leased land. In most potato-producing regions grain crops and forage crops are grown in rotation with potatoes. In some regions a wide variety of agronomic and horticultural crops are possible alternatives. Increased profitability of alternative crops, via higher prices or lower costs, can cause potato growers to reduce potato plantings. When profitability of alternatives declines, the economic signal is to increase potato plantings. The price of alternative crops is a statistically significant variable in United States potato plantings forecasting models.
Technology Although new technology is usually thought of in terms of its impact on yields, it can also have a positive impact on potato plantings. The introduction of a new, disease-resistant variety particularly well suited for a certain potato-producing region could well cause plantings there to increase. Improved irrigation is another type of technology that could increase potato plantings. Yet another is new planting equipment that can decrease the time and cost of planting potatoes. For people who are interested in forecasting potato plantings, the impact of new technology may be difficult to quantify.
Risk Potato growers face two types of risk: production risk and price risk. Changes in either type of risk can influence potato plantings. Converting dryland farms to irrigation is one example. The growers who no longer face the risk of drought, because they now can irrigate, are likely to increase plantings because of reduced risk. The presence of potato disease is another example. Prior to the 1990s potato late blight did not exist in some Western US states. After late blight appeared, the increased production risk put downward 71
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
pressure on potato plantings. Reducing the risk of low prices can cause potato plantings to increase. Better availability of processor contracts, futures contracts or crop insurance can reduce price risk and increase plantings.
Government programmes Government programmes can distort markets and economic signals to growers. Programmes that provide price floors reduce risk and encourage plantings of the supported crops. Even in countries, such as the United States, where potato price supports have not been provided, programmes for alternative crops can influence potato plantings. If total risk of a farming operation is reduced, the grower may be inclined to increase plantings of a potentially high-value crop like potatoes. Some government programmes restrict the amount of plantings or the amount of a commodity that can be marketed. Other government programmes provide incentives or penalties for use of certain inputs. Still others fund irrigation projects, research and trade. Any programme that distorts market signals between consumers and producers can influence plantings.
Weather and pests Unusual weather or pest pressure can cause sudden shifts in the supply of potatoes. The weather situation doesn’t even need to be during the growing season to influence the available supply of potatoes. For example, when severe weather shuts down trucking or rail transport in potato-producing regions the market supply temporarily shrinks. Outbreaks of insects or other pests or the change in availability of pesticides can also influence potato plantings. If a government agency bans the use of a pesticide that is an important input in a potato-producing region, growers there are probably going to reduce potato plantings.
Forecasting potato plantings 9
The author built a potato plantings forecasting model for 17 different potatoproducing regions in the United States. He found the following variables, all lagged one year, to be statistically significant in at least one region: previous potato plantings; potato price; monthly range of potato prices; and alternate crop prices including barley, maize, hay, sugar beet, wheat, sunflowers and vegetables. The lagged potato plantings variable captures the influence of a concept called ‘asset fixity’. That is when an investment in specialized equipment 72
SUPPLY
becomes a fixed factor of production. Since US potato production requires expensive, single-purpose equipment such as planters, harvesters and storage facilities, grower investment in that equipment becomes fixed. They are not likely to sell and buy potato equipment from one crop to the next, and the equipment is not useful for producing other crops. Therefore, the forecasting model includes a lagged plantings variable to capture the influence of asset fixity. The monthly price range variable is a measure of price risk. A large price range indicates more market volatility and more risk to the growers. The plantings-forecasting model was simple but accurate for some potato regions. The model explained at least 92% of the variation in potato plantings in six of the 17 regions. Potato market analysts employ similar models for their market newsletters or agribusinesses.
Potato yields People in the potato industry are also interested in forecasting potato yields, which may be more difficult than forecasting plantings. Although growers respond to the same economic forces when they make yield-influencing decisions, there are other factors that are difficult to quantify. Plantings models predict human behaviour, while yield models predict weather. Both are challenging. MacKerron10 wrote the seminal book on the topic of potato yield forecasting. He split 11 European countries into 64 similar production regions and investigated methods to forecast potato yields in each. The purpose of MacKerron’s work was to provide a framework of analysis for European Community agricultural policy. Others have followed up on MacKerron’s work to provide proprietary forecasts for their company’s personal business interests. A more simple type of analysis is to look at yield trends. Figure 3.5 shows the movement in potato yields in five geographic regions. Yields in Africa, Asia and South America are seen to be well below those of the other regions. The yields in all regions are progressing upward through time. Analysis of US potato yields suggests that the upward trend in yields may be accelerating in that part of the world. Figure 3.6 shows that during the 1990s the yield trend is steeper, actually increasing at the rate of 7 cwt (45.4 kg) per year, as compared to 4 cwt (45.4 kg) per year during the 1949–89 period. Scott predicts that world potato yields will increase 0.9% per year during the 1993–2020 period. His forecast for developing countries is for yields to increase 1.5% per year, while developed country yields are expected to go up 0.5% per year. Yield forecasts for the developing regions range from 1.3% per year in Latin America to 2.0% per year in Other Asia. 73
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY 40
Africa N & C America S America Asia Europe
Metric tons per hectare
35 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 1967
1972
1977
1982
1987
1992
1997
3.5 Potato yields in world regions, 1967–2000.
400 Yield
350
Trend 1 100 lbs/acre
Trend 2 300
250
200
96 19
92
88
19
84
19
19
80
72
76
19
19
19
68
60
64
19
19
19
52
56 19
19
YE
AR
150
3.6 Trends in United States potato yields.
References 1 2
P Harris, The Potato Crop, London, Chapman & Hall, 1992. T Walker, P Schmiediche, and R Hijmans, ‘World trends and patterns in the potato crop: An economic and geographic survey’, Potato Research, 1999 42 241–64. 3 G Scott, M Rosegrant, and C Ringler, Roots and Tubers for the 21st Century, Lima, Peru, International Potato Center, 2000. 74
SUPPLY 4 G Scott, Potatoes in Central Africa: A Study of Burundi, Rwanda and Zaire, Lima, Peru, International Potato Center, 1988. 5 T Walker et al., ‘World trends and patterns’. 6 D Horton, Potatoes: Production, Marketing, and Programs for Developing Countries, London, Westview Press, 1987. 7 K Claydon, The Economics of Potato Production in the United Kingdom, University of Nottingham, 1995. 8 D Reeve, ‘The farm – retail price spread for Idaho fresh russet potatoes: a case study’, MS thesis, Moscow, Idaho, University of Idaho, 1996. 9 J Guenthner, ‘Acreage response: an econometric analysis of the United States potato industry’, PhD dissertation, Pullman, Washington, Washington State University, 1987. 10 D MacKerron, Agrometeorological Aspects of Forecasting Yields of Potato within the EC, Brussels, Commission of the European Communities, 1992.
75
CHAPTER
4 Demand
Demand theory
T
he consumer is queen. The people who make everyday purchasing decisions in supermarkets, restaurants and farmer’s markets drive the entire food production and marketing chain. Although potatoes are also used for livestock feed the primary purpose for growing potatoes is to feed human beings. Potatoes must meet one or more of three human needs for people to purchase and consume them. Principles of demand At the very basic level people eat potatoes for the same reason they eat other foods – to survive. In some subsistence agricultural areas, the challenge is indeed to keep the family fed. That may involve producing or acquiring food staples such as rice, wheat, maize or potatoes, depending on the location. A second level of need is to eat to provide fuel or energy for work, recreation and other human endeavours. The more energy that is required, the more calories people need to eat. At this second level people look for variety and consume foods beyond the staples. Fruits, vegetables, livestock products and processed foods are choices for some people at the second level of demand. 76
DEMAND
People at the third level of need consume food for pleasure. With the income to open a wide variety of choices, third-level consumers are concerned about food flavour, texture and appearance. Not merely interested in calories for survival or energy for work they are willing to pay for services included in their food products. They choose to pay higher prices for foods that have been washed, peeled, sliced, canned, frozen, cooked, served or even delivered to their homes. Regardless of the level of human need, most consumers try to maximize their personal satisfaction with their food purchases. Economists use the term ‘utility’ to describe consumer satisfaction. One important economic principle is that of diminishing marginal utility. As a consumer eats additional potatoes, or apples, or any product, the satisfaction gained from the last one is less than it was for the previous one. Someone may enjoy the first serving of potatoes quite a bit, but the second serving of the day is less satisfying. By the third or fourth or fifth potato serving the consumer may get no additional satisfaction and may crave some other food. Another important economic principle is the inelasticity of the human stomach. In developed countries, whose consumers are at the third level of human need, total per capita food consumption is about 1500 pounds (680 kg) per years, consisting of 3500 calories per day.1 They are not hungry and, on the average, are not likely to eat much more. In fact, many are satiated. Their stomachs are full and inelastic. If one food, say potatoes, becomes more attractive they will give up something else, perhaps rice, to consume more potatoes. Many things can influence individual consumer demand for food products. Prices of the different products are, of course, important in consumer decision-making. Consumer income is another factor. In general demand for staples goes down as a consumer’s income goes up and moves them from first-level to second-level to third-level human needs. Demand for some other foods such as processed products increases as income goes up. The inelasticity of the human stomach dictates that changes in income lead people to change the mix of food they consume. A simple model of demand would be that a consumer’s consumption of potatoes depends on (1) potato price (2) consumer income and (3) price of potato substitutes. If we knew the values of all three variables we could predict the quantity of potatoes a consumer would buy. If we had aggregate data for all consumers in a city or a country, we could forecast total demand. Demand is not the same as consumption. The per capita consumption figures estimated by government agencies are calculated by dividing total supply by population. Price is not part of the calculation. Potato industry people are sometimes confused when a large crop follows a small crop and per capita potato consumption increases. This does not mean that demand for potatoes increased. The larger crop most likely sold at lower prices and 77
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
demand may not have changed, or it could have even decreased. The influence of changes in consumer income and prices of substitutes are not included in per capita consumption figures.
Elasticity of demand An economic concept that is often mentioned in discussions about potato markets is elasticity of demand. A potato industry mantra is that prices are volatile because the demand for potatoes is inelastic. The statement is true but may be confusing economic jargon to some. Elasticity is a measure of change. A change that is of particular interest to growers is a change in price. The most powerful force that changes potato prices is the supply of potatoes. Growers know that a larger supply drives prices down and a smaller supply boosts prices. The key question is by how much. Elasticity of demand quantifies supply–price relationships. It specifies the change in quantity sold for a change in price. Elasticity is a measure without units such as kilograms or tonnes or dollars or pounds; it can be explained in terms of percentages. Elasticity of demand is the percentage change in quantity divided by the percentage change in price. For example, consider an estimated elasticity of demand of -0.2 for fresh potatoes. This means that for each 1% change in price, the quantity sold will change by 0.2% in the opposite direction. A 5% increase in price would cause quantity to decline by 1%. That seems like a large price change for a small change in quantity. The reason is that consumers are not very sensitive to changes in potato price. They tend to purchase about the same amount of potatoes regardless of price. When potatoes are scarce, prices must be marked up a large amount for the supply to be rationed to consumers who are willing to pay. When the supply is large, consumers are willing to buy more only at much lower prices. Before moving on, notice two things about the potato elasticity of demand estimate of -0.2. First, the sign is negative. One expects an inverse relationship between quantity and price. As price increases, quantity will decrease and vice versa. The second thing to notice is that its value is between 0 and -1, which fits into the ‘inelastic’ category. For inelastic goods, the percent change in quantity is smaller than the percent change in price. A figure that is outside that range, such as -2.0, would fit into the elastic category, which is for those goods whose percent change in quantity is larger than the percentage change in price. The elasticity of demand concept is more relevant to retailers than it is to growers. Retailers would like to know how many potatoes to stock if they change the price. Growers would like to know the potato-supply impact on their price. The concept of price flexibility is more useful to growers. Price 78
DEMAND
flexibility is the percentage change in price for each 1% change in supply. For fresh potatoes a US rule of thumb figure is a price flexibility of -5. This means that for each 1% change in supply the potato price will change five percent in the opposite direction. A 5% supply reduction would be expected to cause a 25% increase in price. Both flexibility and elasticity measure the supply–price relationship. One can be estimated by calculating the inverse of the other (this is not precise for all goods). The inverse of a -0.2 price elasticity gives a price flexibility of -5 (1/-0.2 = -5). The relevant concept in both measures is a single number that can predict change. The same concept can be applied to other economic variables. For example, income elasticity is the percent change in potato quantity sold for each 1% change in consumer income. Cross-price elasticity is the change in potato quantity sold for each 1% change in the price of a substitute such as rice.
Factors that influence demand for potato products Potato demand consists of two parts. The first part is the price of potatoes. The second part is demand shifters, named to describe the situation where the basic quantity–price relationship shifts to a new level. The four main demand shifters – consumer income, other goods and services, tastes and preferences, and population – are examined below, following a discussion of price.
Price When the price of potatoes changes, the proper economics terminology is to say that the ‘quantity demanded’ also changes. A change in demand (shift) is different from a change in quantity demanded. Figure 4.1 shows the relationship. Imagine that the graph shows the demand relationship for a monthly period for one particular family. A potato price increase from £0.40 per kg to £0.60 per kg causes the consumer to decrease quantity demanded from 10 kg to 9 kg per month. This is a movement along the lower demand line from point A to point B. For the 50% increase in price the quantity demanded increased 10%. This depicts an inelastic demand relationship of -0.2. The price–quantity relationship varies according to geographic location, time period, marketing chain level and type of product. For the US retail market a study by the author and others2 estimated price elasticity for fresh potatoes at -0.14. This is in the highly inelastic range, with a 1% change in 79
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY Price (£/kg) 1.60 1.40 1.20 1.00 C
0.80 0.60 B
0.40
A
0.20 0.00 6
7
8
9 10 Kg/month
11
12
4.1 Potato demand for an example family.
quantity causing only a 0.14% change in price in the opposite direction. The price flexibility, or inverse of the elasticity, provides a measure more meaningful to producers. An elasticity of -0.14 corresponds with a flexibility of about -7.0. This means that for each 1% supply increase the retail price increases seven percent. A one percent decrease causes a seven percent price drop. Other researchers have estimated US fresh potato elasticities of demand in the range of -0.14 to -0.40. We also estimated elasticities of demand for three types of processed potato products in the retail market. The estimated elasticities for frozen, dehydrated and potato crisps were -0.55, -0.77 and -0.67, respectively. These are all in the inelastic range, but are not nearly as inelastic as the demand for fresh potatoes. For the processed potato products consumers are much more sensitive to prices. Since fresh potatoes are a substitute, when processed potato prices change, consumers adjust their fresh potato purchases. The influence of price on the quantity of potatoes demanded at awayfrom-home meals is more difficult to estimate. In many restaurants potatoes are included as parts of meals sold for a fixed price, without a specific charge for the potato portion. In fast-food restaurants potato products like McDonald’s fries are sold as separate menu items, but there are difficulties there as well. Many quick-service restaurants have gone to ‘meal deal’ pricing with a sandwich (burger), fries or crisps and beverage sold for a set price. In other away-from-home markets such as schools, military bases and hospitals there may be no direct pricing for potato products. In these cases where consumers don’t see a potato price the institutions providing the meals do. Institutional buyers must compete in the wholesale potato market alongside other buyers. At both the wholesale and farm levels, potato prices remain clearly expressed. In developing countries Horton3 reports that potato demand becomes 80
DEMAND
more elastic as the potato industry grows. Potato supply increases cause sharp price drops, but if the production is sustained, consumers respond by developing preferences for potatoes. In the very short run, such as a few weeks, consumers do not switch food preferences. If there are several consecutive crops of abundant supplies and low prices consumers come to appreciate the inexpensive food. Prices then move upward. Horton also points out that potato demand is more elastic in poor countries than in rich countries. Since poor people spend a higher portion of their income on food, they are more responsive to price changes.Whereas a high-income consumer in a developed country may buy the potatoes she wants without even looking at price, the low-income consumer in a developing country may be very price-conscious and carefully adjust all purchases based on relative prices. Another important principle is that more substitutes mean more elastic demand. For example, the demand elasticity for apples, a product for which many other fruits are substitutes, is higher than that for onions, a food with few close substitutes. The closest substitute for a food product is usually another grade or form of the same food. Therefore the demand for mediumsized, red-skinned fresh potatoes is more elastic than is the demand for all potatoes.
Demand shifters Point A on the lower demand line in Fig. 4.1 is only a temporary relationship between quantity and price. When quantity changes, price responds as depicted in moves along the line. When other things affecting consumer behaviour change the demand line shifts to a new level. The line can shift in or out, but Fig. 4.1 shows an outward shift to a higher level of demand. Any one of the four demand shifters can cause such a shift. For example, increases in consumer income, potato advertising and population could all shift out the demand for potatoes. When demand increases, or shifts out, the same amount of potatoes can be sold for a higher price, a larger amount of potatoes can be sold at the same price, or both the quantity of potatoes and the price of potatoes can increase. The move from the lower to upper line in Fig. 4.1 shows the latter. At point C, with 10.5 kg at £0.70, both the quantity and price are higher than at points A or B. Of course, demand shifters can cause the movement to go the other way as well.
Consumer income Changes in consumer income can shift the demand for potatoes in or out, depending on geographical location and type of product. Horton found 81
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY Table 4.1
Income elasticities for fresh potatoes
Developed market economies North America Oceania Europe USSR and Eastern Europe Developing market economies Latin America Near East Africa Far East China & other Asian centrally planned economies
-0.21 -0.19 -0.10 -0.19 -0.33 +0.19 +0.12 +0.11 +0.51 +0.16 +0.30
Source: Horton
income elasticities for fresh potatoes to be negative in developed countries but positive in developing countries (Table 4.1). His figures indicate that a one percent increase in income in Africa would increase the quantity of potatoes purchased by 0.51%, but a 1% increase in European income would decrease potato purchases by 0.19%. The seeming contradiction is cleared up when one considers the low-income status of most consumers in developing countries. The lower the family’s income the larger the proportion of money that is spent on food. More money will result in more food purchases. A poor family is more likely than a rich family to buy more potatoes when income goes up. This points out the importance of income distribution on potato demand. Within a country, an increase in income for poor families will result in a higher demand for fresh potatoes than will an increase in rich-family income. With negative income elasticities, an increase in rich consumer income with no corresponding increase in poor consumer income could actually decrease the total demand for fresh potatoes. High-income consumers may also prefer to eat potatoes, but in a different form. With more money to spend on food they are likely to choose processed potatoes rather than fresh potatoes. As income increases people tend to purchase more service in their foods. The service may include some type of processing for retail products or food preparation at a restaurant. Hinton4 found that in the United Kingdom the income elasticity of demand was -0.40 for fresh potatoes and +0.25 for processed potatoes. We found similar results in the United States, so this is probably a common relationship in developed countries. In the jargon of economists, goods with negative income elasticities, such as fresh potatoes in developed countries, are called ‘inferior goods’. Goods with positive elasticities are known as ‘normal’ goods. 82
DEMAND
Prices of other goods Consumers with limited income compare prices when they shop for food. Consumers who are concerned about the high price for a particular good might buy a substitute instead. Prices of similar goods help determine demand for a product. When the price of a potato substitute increases, it increases or shifts out the demand for potatoes, as in Fig. 4.1. Of course, decreases in substitute prices will cause potato demand to decrease. What are some close substitutes for potatoes? It varies among countries, but researchers have found strong substitute relationships between rice and potatoes in Asia and maize and potatoes in Mexico and other Latin American countries. In some developed countries there is little evidence of strong substitute relationships for potatoes with any other food. In those countries other potato products appear to be the closest substitute for a potato product. For example, fresh potatoes are substitutes for dehydrated and frozen potato products. Complements are another type of good that can influence demand for potatoes. In developed countries consumers often eat potatoes with some other food, especially meat or seafood. The quick-service restaurant fare of hamburger and fries and fish and chips closely ties the potato market with the beef and fish markets. The relationship between potato demand and the price of complements is an inverse one. Complement price decreases cause an increase in potato demand. Theoretically, prices of many or even all other goods and services influence the demand for a product. For this reason many analysts use a consumer price index (CPI) to deflate all prices. By dividing prices by the CPI they remove the influence of inflation or deflation. During times of price stability this is less important than during times when price levels are changing rapidly.
Tastes and preferences Consumers change their minds about foods. Individuals who become more concerned about nutrient content, for example, will change the array of foods they prefer. If many consumers become like-minded, the aggregate market changes and demand shifts. Many things can change consumer attitudes about particular foods. The news media, for one, influences opinion. Press coverage of the mad cow disease in Europe is one example that decreased demand for a food – beef. News from medical organizations that fresh fruits and vegetables enhance human health is an example of a media story that increased demand for fresh produce. Commercial interests want to change consumer perceptions about their products. They use three methods to do this: publicity, advertising and pro83
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
motion. Publicity consists of reaching the masses through the media at no expense to the product providers. Press releases about new products or some interesting anecdote can influence news outlets to write stories that have a positive influence on the demand for a product. Advertising also uses the news media but in a paid format. Companies hire marketing specialists to create persuasive advertisements for which they buy exposure in newspapers, magazines, television, radio and outdoor billboards. Promotion is another form of paid effort that involves such things as industry trade shows, in-store demonstrations and discount coupons to encourage customers to purchase the product. National organizations such as the US Potato Board, the British Potato Council and the Cyprus Potato Marketing Board are nationwide organizations that were formed to expand the demand for potatoes. Provincial or state organizations, such as the Idaho Potato Commission, were also formed for the same purpose. In addition to advertising, promotion and public relations some of these groups are also involved in research, education, market intelligence and quality control. Their fundamental purpose, however, is to increase potato demand. For some this effort goes beyond domestic markets and into global markets. Changing lifestyles influence consumer tastes and preferences. In developed countries where women work outside the home, consumers prefer food products with more service built into them. For these families the emphasis on convenient foods leads them to purchase more processed potatoes than fresh potatoes. Although food products with additional service attributes are more expensive there are two reasons that consumers prefer such goods. First, they can afford them. Second, they have less time for meal preparation. New product development can also influence consumer tastes and preferences. The advent of frozen chips for the quick-service restaurant industry provided a consistent-quality potato product that helped fuel the growth of the away-from-home market. New snack food products with flavouring, such as Walker’s prawn cocktail potato crisps, or shapes, such as United Biscuit’s Hula Hoops, changed tastes and preferences for many consumers in the United Kingdom. Some potato products are particularly attractive to youngsters, whose tastes and preferences may be more easily influenced. Others may be more attractive to people with different ethnic backgrounds or some other demographic distinction.
Population The number of people living in a market area is an important demand shifter. Total world population grew 1.4% in 1999. If nothing else changed we would 84
DEMAND
expect world demand to have grown at the same rate. Population growth rates vary around the globe, but in general growth is more rapid in developing countries. Among the countries that grew more rapidly than average were Afghanistan 5.9%, Cambodia 3.1%, Gambia 3.6%, Jordan 3.6%, Nicaragua 3.0%, Saudi Arabia 3.4%, Uganda 3.1% and Yemen 3.8%. China and India, the two countries with the largest populations, grew at rates of 1.0% and 1.8%, respectively. Developed country growth rates include Australia 1.1%, Canada 1.2%, France 0.4%, Germany 0.3%, Japan 0.2%, Netherlands 0.6%, United Kingdom 0.3% and USA 1.0%. The type of people who make up the population can also influence demand. Table 4.2 shows potato consumption in the United States for different population groups based on differences in region, urban vs rural, race/ethnicity, income, age and gender. The numbers in the table are market shares divided by population shares. Numbers greater than 100 indicate that consumption is higher than average for those population groups. The numbers for the Midwest region of the US show an above-average consumption for five of the six potato products. The Midwest is the only region that is above average for fresh potatoes. This may be partially explained by the fact that the predominant ancestry of the Midwesterners is Northern and Eastern Europe. The tastes and preferences of immigrants from England, Ireland, Germany and other countries where people ate lots of potatoes carried over into their descendants more than a century later. Regarding demographics, rural residents eat more of all types of potatoes (except dehydrated) than do urban residents. A striking difference is for fresh potatoes. Suburban residents eat only 10% of the average, while rural citizens are 24% above average. This contrasts to dehydrated potatoes and frozen fries where there is little difference between urban, suburban and rural people. Racial and ethnic figures show that Hispanics consume less than average for all types of potato products. This seems surprising since the birthplace of the potato is in Latin America, but many of the Hispanic immigrants into the US came from Mexico, a country where potato consumption is low and maize consumption is high. The ‘other’ category includes Asian people who also consume less than average for all potato products. For them the potato substitute is rice. Like Americans with European ancestry, those with Hispanic and Asian ancestry seem to carry ancestral potato preferences for at least several generations. Subsequent generations of immigrants seem to lose their language and cultural customs before they lose their forebears’ food preferences. The age and gender data also point out some differences between population groups. In general, males eat more potato products than females. Males in the 12–19 year old group eat more than double the average frozen fry 85
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY Table 4.2 Relative per capita consumption of United States potato products: market shares divided by population shares
Fresh
Chips
Dehydrated
Frozen french fries
Other frozen potatoes
Canned
Percentage Census region Northeast Midwest South West
91 118 99 90
101 125 97 77
83 145 101 66
71 108 120 86
68 93 105 127
105 101 107 84
MSA status Metropolitan Suburban Rural
85 10 124
98 94 117
102 100 96
98 98 107
103 87 125
95 67 183
Race/ethnic origin White, non-Hispanic Black, non-Hispanic Hispanic Others
110 64 90 69
101 133 68 64
107 100 65 65
97 131 89 95
106 94 85 59
99 33 77 363
Household income as a percentage of poverty 0–130% 131–350% 351% and above
87 107 98
96 101 101
113 97 96
99 101 99
99 126 72
85 98 110
117 44 59 110 132 153
126 62 127 178 147 39
109 67 76 154 116 96
127 65 111 213 144 36
128 81 216 169 131 53
123 32 62 94 141 185
84 40 50 70 90 114
75 69 112 114 80 20
91 62 91 96 103 64
75 60 107 152 73 21
73 77 142 76 72 39
78 57 54 53 77 114
Gender and age Male All 2–5 6–11 12–19 20–59 60 and older Female All 2–5 6–11 12–19 20–59 60 and older
Source: United States, Department of Agriculture, Agricultural Research Service, Continuing Survey of Food Intake by Individuals,Washington, DC, 1994–96, two-day data
consumption. People 60 and older prefer fresh potatoes (153% males, 114% females) to frozen fries (36% males, 21% females). An as yet unanswered question is whether the young people who prefer frozen fries to fresh will continue those preferences when they move into the older age groups. 86
DEMAND
Utilization trends by country Global distribution Europe is the top potato-using region for both food and feed use. Although European potato use for food grew during the 1961–98 period (Fig. 4.2), European use for livestock feed dropped by half during the same period (Fig. 4.3). Per capita potato use for food expanded in all regions, with the largest increase occurring in Oceania. South America had the smallest increase. Potato consumption for feed declined in all regions except Africa and Asia. Per capita use for both food and feed declined in developed countries, but increased in developing countries (Fig. 4.4, Fig. 4.5). China was the leading potato-consuming country in 1998 (Table 4.3). Ten of the top 20 potato-consuming countries are in Europe, five in Asia, three in South America and two in North America. The top three countries – China, the Russian Federation and Poland – made up 40% of total world
80.0
70.0 1961 1998
60.0
Kg/yr
50.0
40.0
30.0
20. 0
10.0
0.0 Africa
Asia
Europe
N & C America
Oceania
4.2 Potato per capita consumption for food by region, 1961 and 1998 (FAO, United Nations). 87
S America
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
consumption. An interesting observation is that all three built up potato consumption during periods when their economies were centrally planned. Although the Russian Federation and Poland have moved toward free market economies, their citizen’s potato preferences were built under communism and may be slow to change. The consumption trend in many developed countries is downward (Table 4.4). From 1961 to 1998 potato use per capita declined in every Western European country except the United Kingdom, which increased 13% from 97.8 kg to 110.1 kg, and Portugal, which increased 45% from 87.6 to 127.4 kg. Potato use in some countries dropped dramatically. One example is Italy, where potato utilization in 1998 was only 41% of what it was in 1961, putting it in last place among the European countries listed in the table. In Germany and France potato use dropped by nearly half during the 37-year period. Europe’s decline in potato use is, of course, directly related to a decline in potato plantings. Horton suggests that changes in the hog (pig) industry contributed to a decline in the amount of potatoes grown for feed. Small hog-potato farms that were common in Europe, including Western Europe,
45.0 40.0 35.0
1961 1998
Kg/yr
30.0 25.0 20.0 15.0 10.0 5.0 0.0 Africa
Asia
Europe
N & C America
Oceania
4.3 Potato per capita consumption for feed by region, 1961 and 1998 (FAO, United Nations). 88
S America
DEMAND Kg/year 700
600
500 1961 1998
400
300
200
100
0 World
Developed
Developing
4.4 Potato per capita consumption for food, developed and developing countries, 1961 and 1998 (FAO, United Nations).
have given way to large, specialized hog production facilities. The small farmer had the labour available to grow, harvest, transport, boil and feed potatoes to hogs, but the modern operations prefer less labour-intensive rations of barley and soybeans. The trend is less clear in Eastern Europe. Potato use declined in Poland and Hungary, but increased in Romania. Incomplete data masks what happened in Belarus and Ukraine, but 1998 potato use in those two countries was the highest in Europe. Usage in the other developed countries was mixed, with increases in Australia, New Zealand, South Africa and USA and declines in Canada and Japan. South Africa showed the sharpest change, more than doubling potato use. The potato use trend is upward in most developing countries (Table 4.5). The largest potato user, China, doubled its use from 1961 to 1998. The countries of the Indo-Gangetic Plain – Bangladesh, India and Pakistan – doubled, tripled and quadrupled their potato use, respectively. Among the 89
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY Kg/yr 30.0
25.0
20.0
1961 1998
15.0
10.0
5.0
0.0 World
Developed
Developing
4.5 Potato per capita consumption for feed, developed and developing countries, 1961 and 1998 (FAO, United Nations).
Asian developing countries North Korea is the exception to the upward trend, showing a 1998 potato use of 27% of the 1961 figure. North Korea’s communist government was reluctant to share agricultural information during the 1990s but people outside the country were well aware that many of the country’s citizens were starving. The largest per capita potato-using country in Asia was Turkey at 66.9 kg. Included at the other extreme of less than 10 kg are the tropical countries of Indonesia and Vietnam. A general observation is that developing countries in the hot tropics are at the low end of the potato use range, while those with temperate and highland production zones are at the upper end. All the African countries showed increased potato use. Malawi’s ninefold increase to well over 100 kg is remarkable, but makes one question the accuracy of the figures. The Latin American developing countries show quite a contrast. At the low extreme is Bolivia, where potato use dropped to less than half the 1961 total. At the high end is Colombia, where use more than 90
DEMAND Table 4.3
Top 20 potato-consuming countries, 1998 Quantity (000 mt)
Percentage of total
China Russian Federation Poland USA India
61 364 33 318 25 808 21 679 17 624
20 11 9 7 6
6 7 8 9 10
Ukraine Germany UK Belarus France
15 409 10 999 8 065 7 236 6 019
5 4 3 2 2
11 12 13 14 15
Turkey Spain Japan Netherlands Iran
5 298 4 634 3 751 3 681 3 362
2 2 1 1 1
16 17 18 19 20
Romania Argentina Canada Brazil Peru
3 351 3 242 3 203 2 934 2 647
1 1 1 1 1
1 2 3 4 5
Source: FAO, United Nations
doubled. Latin American per capita use in 1998 varied over a wide range, from 12.6 kg in Mexico to 76.6 kg in Argentina. The potato use figures in Tables 4.3, 4.4 and 4.5 were not for human consumption only. They include potatoes used for livestock feed, human food, seed and other uses. Figure 4.6 shows world utilization by all categories in 1998. The non-food uses of feed, seed, waste and other make up 37% of all uses. A more detailed look at potato usage by category for the regions of the world is provided in the following sections.
Africa Only a handful of African countries use potatoes for livestock feed (Table 4.6). The only developed country in the region, South Africa, feeds the highest (10%) portion of its potatoes to livestock. Five of the countries use 100% of their potatoes for human food. Those at the low end of the food use range include Burundi at 52% and Cameroon at 58%. The next column, seed 91
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY Table 4.4 Potato use per capita in developed countries, 1961 and 1998
Western Europe Belgium-Lux Denmark France Germany Ireland Italy Netherlands Portugal Spain United Kingdom Eastern Europe Belarus Hungary Poland Romania Ukraine Former USSR Others Australia Canada Japan New Zealand South Africa USA
1961
1998
1998 as percentage of 1961
133.3 121.6 115.2 139.0 139.1 95.2 97.8 87.6 125.2 97.8
102.5 75.3 67.1 76.7 129.8 39.0 80.7 127.4 87.1 110.1
77 62 58 55 93 41 83 145 70 113
na 95.2 222.8 69.4 na 132.8
168.5 67.3 134.3 79.7 137.7 123.4
na 71 60 115 na 93
36.0 67.0 27.8 61.6 11.5 48.0
62.7 56.1 24.1 79.3 28.8 64.0
174 84 87 129 250 133
Source: FAO, United Nations Use is in kg per year
usage, shows that those two countries use large portions of their potatoes for seed, with Burundi at 43% and Cameroon at 33%. Wastage ranges from 0% in several countries to 15% in Malawi, 17% in Congo and 20% in Uganda. The ‘other’ category, which includes alcohol production and industrial uses, was zero in all but Mauritius, South Africa and Zimbabwe. The lowest African potato consumption for food, at 1 kg per year, was in Angola, Burundi, Cameroon and Congo. These countries fit into a band of sub-Saharan Africa that is hot tropical lowland where potato production is difficult. Countries in which the people consume more than 20 kg per year include Algeria, Libya, Malawi, Morocco, South Africa and Tunisia. Four of the five high-consuming countries are in a tier along the Mediterranean Sea. At 17 kg/year, Egypt, the other African country on the Mediterranean, is only 92
DEMAND Table 4.5 Potato use per capita in developing countries, 1961 and 1968
1961
1998
1998 as percentage of 1961
4.8 12.6 4.0 0.5 9.4 21.5 16.9 1.7 7.6 38.1 1.0
10.0 26.4 12.8 4.1 43.4 5.7 32.7 7.4 20.2 66.9 4.2
208 210 320 820 462 27 193 435 266 176 420
31.4 7.7 8.6 12.2 6.3 13.4
33.4 21.3 12.2 113.4 32.3 22.7
106 277 142 930 513 169
81.1 93.3 8.6 64.1 20.6 16.2 47.3 6.2 80.0
76.6 39.8 14.4 48.7 44.7 27.6 30.0 12.6 66.8
94 43 167 76 217 170 63 203 84
Asia Bangladesh China India Indonesia Iran Korea, North Nepal Pakistan Syria Turkey Vietnam Africa Algeria Egypt Madagascar Malawi Morocco Rwanda C & S America Argentina Bolivia Brazil Chile Colombia Cuba Ecuador Mexico Peru Source: FAO, United Nations Use is in kg per year
slightly behind the other four. These five countries fit into the Mediterranean potato production zone described in the previous chapter.
Asia China, the world’s largest potato user, fed 22% of its potatoes to livestock in 1998 (Table 4.7). Azerbaijan, Cyprus, Georgia, Iraq, Kyrgyzstan and North 93
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY Feed 16%
Seed 11%
Processing 5%
Fresh 58%
Waste 8% Other 2%
4.6 World potato utilization, 1998 (FAO, United Nations).
Korea also used more than 10% of their potatoes for feed. Many others, including Turkey, one of the top total potato users, fed no potatoes to livestock. Food use in Asian countries ranged from 52% in Cyprus to 100% in Brunei Darsm and Maldives. Armenia, Cyprus and Kazakhstan are the top countries for seed usage, with each using more than 20% for that purpose. Given the challenges of storing large potato crops in a hot tropical climate, wastage was highest in India at 18%. Significant uses in the ‘other’ category were in Lebanon, Malaysia, Philippines and United Arab Emirates. The lowest per capita potato consumption for food, at under 5 kg/yr, was in Burma/Myanmar, Indonesia, North Korea, Laos, Philippines, Thailand and Vietnam. These countries, except for North Korea, lie mostly in the tropical production zone. The highest consumption, at more than 40 kg/year, was in Armenia, Georgia, Israel, Kyrgyzstan, Lebanon and Turkey. Four of the six high-consuming countries border the Mediterranean Sea. In both Africa and Asia the highest potato-consuming countries are in the Mediterranean region. This propensity to eat potatoes extends around to European side of the Mediterranean as well.
Europe Four of the seven European countries that have a Mediterranean coast – Spain, France, Greece and Malta – had per capita potato consumption of at least 48 kg per year in 1998 (Table 4.8). The heaviest potato consumption for food is in three Western European countries: Ireland, Portugal and the United Kingdom, all at over 100 kg per year. Although several Eastern European countries had higher total potato use per capita (Table 4.4), when non94
DEMAND Table 4.6
Potato utilization in African countries, 1998
Africa Algeria Angola Botswana Burundi Cameroon Cape Verde Congo, Rep Djibouti Egypt Eritrea Ethiopia Gambia Kenya Lesotho Libya Madagascar Malawi Mauritania Mauritius Morocco Mozambique Rwanda Senegal Seychelles South Africa Swaziland Tanzania Tunisia Uganda Zimbabwe
Feed (%)
Food (%)
Seed (%)
Waste (%)
Other (%)
PCCF
2 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 5 3 0 0 3 0 0 0 0 10 0 0 0 0 0
77 83 75 96 52 58 100 83 100 78 86 83 100 70 100 80 65 74 89 75 78 89 83 91 100 75 82 78 83 67 83
10 6 14 0 43 33 0 0 0 11 9 12 0 20 0 14 17 8 0 7 9 7 13 0 0 5 12 12 7 13 7
10 10 11 4 4 9 0 17 0 11 5 5 0 10 0 5 12 15 11 7 10 4 4 9 0 5 6 10 10 20 3
1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 11 0 0 0 0 0 5 0 0 0 0 7
8 28 1 13 1 1 18 1 3 17 9 4 2 6 4 25 8 84 3 14 25 4 19 2 12 21 12 5 25 8 2
Source: FAO, United Nations PCCF = per capita consumption of potatoes for food in kg/year
food uses are considered consumers in the British Isles and Portugal seem to be the champion potato eaters. In some European countries, a large portion of the potato crop was fed to livestock in 1998. In the Western European countries of Belgium, Luxembourg and Switzerland at least one-third of their potatoes is used for livestock feed. The same holds for the Eastern European countries of Belarus, Lithuania and Poland. Although feed use may be declining in Europe, it is still quite important in some countries. There is a marked difference in seed use between Western Europe and Eastern Europe. The portion of the 95
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY Table 4.7
Potato utilization in Asian countries, 1998
Asia Afghanistan Armenia Azerbaijan Bangladesh Brunei Darsm Burma/Myanmar China Cyprus Georgia India Indonesia Iran Iraq Israel Japan Jordan Kazakhstan Korea D P Rp Korea Rep Kuwait Kyrgyzstan Laos Lebanon Malaysia Maldives Mongolia Nepal Pakistan Philippines Saudi Arabia Sri Lanka Syria Tajikistan Thailand Turkey Turkmenistan Untd Arab Em Uzbekistan Vietnam Yemen
Feed (%)
Food (%)
Seed (%)
Waste (%)
Other (%)
PCCF
13 1 3 18 0 0 0 22 10 11 0 4 0 10 3 0 0 5 20 8 0 26 0 0 3 0 6 0 0 0 0 0 4 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
72 90 72 74 80 100 84 68 52 76 71 85 85 69 90 89 79 67 70 84 98 60 79 76 84 100 75 77 82 78 79 87 78 91 99 81 94 85 87 85 89
7 6 23 6 10 0 6 4 23 12 12 5 5 12 1 4 5 24 0 3 2 11 12 5 0 0 9 10 8 3 12 4 6 6 1 8 3 0 9 10 8
8 3 2 2 10 0 10 5 7 2 17 4 10 10 0 6 11 4 10 6 0 3 9 5 0 0 10 13 11 3 9 10 13 3 1 10 3 5 4 5 3
1 0 0 0 1 0 0 1 8 0 0 1 0 0 6 0 5 0 0 0 0 0 0 14 14 0 0 0 0 16 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 10 0 0 0
13 9 62 24 8 6 4 18 22 44 9 4 37 9 43 22 11 37 4 8 30 56 4 47 5 8 18 25 6 1 13 6 16 18 3 54 7 22 26 4 9
Source: FAO, United Nations PCCF = per capita consumption of potatoes for food in kg/year Cyprus is reported in the region assigned by the source
96
DEMAND Table 4.8
Potato utilization in European countries, 1998 Feed (%)
Food (%)
Seed (%)
Waste (%)
Other (%)
PCCF
Western Europe Austria Bel-Lux Denmark Finland France Germany Greece Iceland Ireland Italy Malta Netherlands Norway Portugal Spain Sweden Switzerland United Kingdom
4 35 16 1 6 14 8 0 9 4 0 22 10 5 9 5 33 7
74 50 69 37 72 61 71 95 79 85 79 63 77 84 75 54 34 80
1 3 7 8 6 6 11 5 8 6 5 11 10 7 5 7 3 6
2 6 7 0 10 11 8 0 3 2 5 4 3 2 5 0 7 0
20 7 0 54 6 8 2 0 1 4 10 0 0 2 7 34 23 6
44 51 52 25 48 47 50 58 102 33 64 51 61 106 65 35 14 103
Eastern Europe Albania Belarus Bosnia Herzg Bulgaria Croatia Czech Rep Estonia Hungary Latvia Lithuania Macedonia Moldova Rep Poland Romania Russian Fed Slovakia Slovenia Ukraine Yugoslavia
10 51 7 24 5 15 32 13 17 34 15 5 46 13 15 2 26 23 28
58 25 81 51 76 60 38 66 44 28 58 64 22 55 58 85 60 45 39
22 23 8 15 14 14 27 8 33 31 15 27 12 31 23 13 8 30 23
11 1 5 10 5 11 3 4 2 6 12 3 17 1 4 0 7 1 10
0 0 0 0 0 0 0 8 3 1 0 0 3 1 0 0 0 0 0
18 42 69 16 86 49 34 45 61 37 31 41 29 43 72 58 34 63 14
All Europe
23
52
16
6
3
48
Source: FAO, United Nations PCCF = per capita consumption of potatoes for food in kg/year
97
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
potatoes used for seed in Western Europe is in the 0% to 11% range, while seed use in Eastern Europe goes from 8% to 33%. Lower yields for the amount of seed planted and less successful seed certification programmes may be factors in the high seed use in Eastern Europe. In countries where much of the potato production is on small plots, growers may not be able to afford high-quality certified seed potatoes and instead replant their own potatoes. Waste appears marginally higher in Eastern Europe, but ‘other’ use is higher in Western Europe.
North America, South America and Oceania Livestock feed is an important use for potatoes in several South American countries, including Colombia, Ecuador and Uruguay, but is less important in North America and Oceania (Table 4.9). Seed use and waste are highest in Latin America. Per capita food consumption is lowest in the Central American countries, with nine countries at less than 10 kg per year. The highest consumption of potatoes for food is in Canada, USA, Argentina, Australia and New Zealand, with consumers in each country eating at least 50 kg per year. Those five countries are the most economically developed countries in their regions. The growth of the processed potato industry is a factor in the high potato consumption rates among their consumers.
Consumption trends by type of final product Processed vs fresh consumption In developed countries processed potatoes have been a growth industry. Potato consumption in the UK and the United States illustrates this trend (Fig. 4.7). Although consumers in Great Britain consume more than twice as many fresh potatoes, British and American citizens eat about the same amount of processed potatoes. British per capita consumption of processed potatoes increased by 26% from 36 kg to 45.5 kg per year during the 1989–99 period. United States processed potato consumption increased by 30% from 33.1 kg to 43 kg per year. In both countries the annual growth rate was nearly one kg per person each year. US fresh potato consumption was stable at around 22 kg per person per year while British fresh potato consumption declined from 71.5 kg to 57.8 kg per year, a loss of nearly 20%. In developing countries most potatoes are consumed in the fresh form. On the African continent, South Africa has a potato processing industry, but the United Nations Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO) statistics show 98
DEMAND Table 4.9
Potato utilization in American and Oceania countries, 1998
N & C America Antigua Barb Bahamas Barbados Belize Bermuda Canada Costa Rica Cuba Dominican Rp El Salvador Grenada Guatemala Haiti Honduras Jamaica Mexico Neth Antilles Nicaragua Panama St Lucia Trinidad Tob USA South America Argentina Bolivia Brazil Chile Colombia Ecuador Paraguay Peru Suriname Uruguay Venezuela Oceania Australia Fiji Islands Fr Polynesia New Caledonia New Zealand
Feed (%)
Food (%)
Seed (%)
Waste (%)
Other (%)
PCCF
1 0 0 0 0 0 0 4 2 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1
77 100 80 100 100 100 89 80 83 79 90 100 81 82 36 87 80 88 85 77 100 93 81
6 0 0 0 0 0 9 4 5 11 10 0 12 9 21 4 4 0 2 12 0 0 6
10 0 0 0 0 0 0 9 10 11 0 0 7 9 21 9 9 13 12 8 0 7 7
6 0 20 0 0 0 1 3 0 0 0 0 0 0 21 0 8 0 0 4 0 0 5
35 8 10 34 10 35 50 18 23 1 1 8 3 1 0 7 10 27 6 6 15 28 52
3 0 8 0 6 10 11 0 0 0 9 0
76 85 64 81 78 71 69 100 64 100 71 86
9 3 20 11 10 7 16 0 15 0 7 6
11 11 8 8 5 12 5 0 21 0 9 5
1 1 0 0 1 1 0 0 0 0 3 3
24 65 25 12 38 32 21 1 43 15 27 12
3 4 0 0 0 3
84 84 100 100 100 84
10 10 0 0 0 11
2 2 0 0 0 2
0 0 0 0 0 0
44 53 19 22 32 67
Source: FAO, United Nations PCCF = per capita consumption of potatoes for food in kg/year
99
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY 75.0
65.0
UK fresh 55.0
UK processed US fresh
Kg/yr
US processed 45.0
35.0
25.0
15.0 1988/89 1989/90 1990/91 1991/92 1992/93 1993/94 1994/95 1995/96 1996/97 1997/98 1998/99
4.7 Fresh and processed potato consumption in United Kingdom and the United States (BPC; NPC).
no potato processing in any other African country. FAO statistics depict small potato processing usage scattered around Asia and Latin America. The very low consumption of processed potatoes in developing countries is a function of price, income, facilities and lifestyle. Since processed potatoes are more expensive than fresh potatoes, low-income people in developing countries are not likely to buy them. Cooling equipment required to hold and transport frozen potato products is lacking in many developing countries. Another difference is the lack of the fast-food lifestyle that drives away-fromhome potato consumption in developing countries.
At-home vs away-from-home consumption The number of meals eaten away from home is increasing in many developed countries. Potato products are a popular part of these away-from-home meals. In the UK 44% of potato consumption occurred outside the home in 100
DEMAND Table 4.10
Consumption distribution for UK potatoes, 1998/99
Home Away from home
Raw
Crisps
Dehydrated & canned
Frozen or chilled
Total
61% 39%
84% 16%
16% 84%
41% 59%
56% 44%
Source: British Potato Council
Table 4.11
Consumption distribution for United States potatoes, 1994–96 Other frozen potatoes
Canned
Fresh
Chips
Dehydrated
Frozen fries
Home
79%
79%
89%
12%
53%
80%
Away from home Fast food Restaurant School Other
21% 6% 12% 1% 2%
21% 7% 1% 3% 9%
11% 4% 1% 2% 2%
88% 67% 13% 6% 2%
48% 23% 9% 12% 3%
20% 5% 15% 0% 1%
Source: CSFII, 1994–96, two-day data
1998/99 (Table 4.10). Frozen and chilled potato consumption away from home was much higher at 59%. A large share of this was most likely at fish and chips shops, pubs and restaurants. The UK potato crisp market was mainly an at-home market, with consumers buying 84% of their crisps to eat in their homes. Raw or fresh potato consumption was also popular in British homes, with a 61% share. For dehydrated and canned potatoes 84% of the consumption was away from home. The United States pattern is similar for all potato products except dehydrated and canned potatoes for which at least 80% are consumed at home (Table 4.11). The frozen fry market is 88% away from home, with most of that, 67%, going through fast-food restaurants and another 13% going through ‘other’ restaurants. Only 12% of frozen fries are consumed in US homes, the smallest at-home share for any potato product in the UK or the United States. The ‘other frozen’ potato category is almost evenly split between at-home and away-from-home markets, suggesting that fries are perceived as a very different product from hash browns, potato rounds and other frozen products. The smallest share for away-from-home consumption is dehydrated potato products in the US at 11%. One major fast-food chain in the US, 101
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
Kentucky Fried Chicken (KFC), serves a dehydrated potato product but most other fast-food chains stick with frozen fries. The snack food market for US chips is similar to the Great Britain market for crisps, with a large majority of the product consumed at home. The ‘other’ category for US chips includes sales through vending machines. At a 79% consumption rate the fresh market is much more heavily an at-home market in the US than in Great Britain, which suggests that British restaurants prepare a larger share of meals with fresh potatoes.
Fresh Fresh potato consumption is expanding in developing countries, but is stagnant or declining in developed countries. The consumer preference for convenience is putting a cap on fresh potato demand in high-income regions where many females work outside the home. Counteracting that trend are several factors that could stop the decline or even increase the quantity demanded for fresh potatoes. First is the microwave oven. This kitchen appliance reduces meal preparation time and indeed makes fresh potatoes more convenient. In consumer surveys regarding microwave oven use, cooking fresh potatoes is at or near the top. Second is the enhanced perception of fresh fruits and vegetables as healthy foods. Medical research results that show potatoes can reduce the risks of cancer and heart disease can help shape consumer tastes and preferences. A third factor is fast-food restaurants. Some chains such as Wendy’s have featured fresh baked potatoes. Other have tried and dropped fresh potato products. Since the trend is for consumers in developed countries to eat more meals away from home, an increase in the number of fast food-restaurants that serve fresh potatoes would certainly boost demand. In many developing countries fresh potato demand is increasing on the merits of a cheap, nutritious food. Continued growth is tied to the relative prices between fresh potatoes and substitute foods. If potato production technology improvements continue, lower costs to the grower and correspondingly lower prices to the consumer could boost demand.
Frozen Processed potato production varies by country according to domestic and export market demand. Table 4.12 shows that frozen and chilled potato production is similar at about 60% of the total in the UK, the United States and South Africa. In the Netherlands 90% of the processed production is in the frozen/chilled category, but a very large share of that is exported. An 102
DEMAND Table 4.12
Processed potato production by category in selected countries United Kingdom
United States
South Africa
Netherlands
5% 28% 6% 60%
2% 18% 20% 60%
3% 43% 0% 54%
1% 3% 6% 90%
Canned/Other Crisps (chips) Dehydrated Frozen & chilled
Sources: British Potato Council; US Potato Council; South Africa Potatoes; NIVAA
Kg/year 30.0
25.0
Frozen Snacks Dehydrated
20.0
15.0
10.0
5.0
4 199 5 199 6 199 7 199 8
199
199 3
198 9 199 0 199 1 199 2
5
4
6 198 7 198 8
198
198
198
1 198 2 198 3
198
198
0
0.0
4.8 United States processed potato consumption, 1978–98 (NPC).
increasingly international market for frozen fries is connected to the fast-food industry. Potato processors who hitched their wagons to the fast-food industry have enjoyed rapid growth during the 1980s and 1990s. Figure 4.8 shows how frozen potato consumption grew in the United States during the 1980s and 1990s. 103
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
As fast-food meals become more popular, even in developing countries, demand for frozen fries will continue to grow. When frozen processors bump against their production capacity limits they must decide where they will expand. Options are the temperate-zone countries, where most of the frozen potato production is now done, or new areas, where demand is expanding. The key will be a consistent supply of high-quality raw product. Developing countries with a large potato production base are importing frozen fries for their fast-food industries, not because domestic potatoes are scarce, but because the domestic industry has not met the high quality standards for finished product. Developing countries in the hot lowland tropics are not likely to be able to compete in the frozen potato industry, which requires yearround supplies of raw product.
Chilled Chilled potatoes, a relatively new player in the potato market, require refrigeration instead of freezers. The industry got a boost in the United Kingdom when fish and chips shops found it increasingly difficult to comply with food safety regulations regarding the preparation of raw potatoes. Rather than face the high costs of compliance and the risk of not getting it right many proprietors searched for suppliers who would sell them washed, peeled and cut potatoes. Entrepreneurs met the need and a new type of potato-processing industry emerged. Chilled potato processors now supply the restaurant trade as well as the retail trade with attractively packaged, refrigerated potato products that reduce meal preparation time. Chilled potato products have been widely available in Western Europe since the early 1990s. Acceptance in the rest of the world has been slower. Efforts to market chilled potato products in North America did not begin in earnest until the late 1990s. Given North Americans’ acceptance of peeled carrots, salad mixes and other partially prepared produce, it is likely that chilled potato products will also become accepted.
Dehydrated Of the four countries in Table 4.12 the dehydrated potato industry is most important in the United States. The US dehydrated potato industry is tied closely to two other market channels – fresh potatoes and potato crisps. In the Pacific Northwest states of Idaho, Oregon and Washington, the largest potato-producing region in North America, the most popular potato variety is Russet Burbank. This variety produces a large share of undersized and misshapen potatoes that are unfit for the fresh market. Even the best potato pro-
104
DEMAND
ducers may see half their Russet Burbank crop not meet fresh standards. A dehydrated potato industry sprang up to handle those off-grade Russet Burbanks. With an abundant supply of high-quality raw product the dehydrators built successful businesses. They marketed dehydrated potato products that were packaged and aimed mostly at retail customers. During the mid-1990s nearly 90% of the dehydrated product flowed into the at-home market (Table 4.11). Beginning in the 1990s another opportunity appeared for the dehydrated potato industry. Some snack food manufacturers introduced potato snack foods that were made via an extrusion process with dehydrated potatoes rather than raw potatoes. General Mills with its Pringle’s and Frito-Lay with its Baked Lays led the charge. The increased demand for dehydrated potatoes improved the profitability of dehydrated potato processors and the growers who sold them raw product. Per capita consumption of dehydrated potato products increased in the US from 4.5 kg in 1980 to 8.2 kg in 1998 (Fig. 4.8). The global market also grew. International demand for these snack foods led to export of dehydrated potatoes destined for European extrudedsnack factories in the late 1990s.
Snack foods Potato use for snack foods in the US has been stagnant at about 7 to 8 kg per year (Fig. 4.8). The potato crisp industry in the UK is expanding, with crisping use increasing 22% during the 1990s. Future demand around the globe depends primarily on three demand shifters – income, prices of other goods, and tastes and preferences. Since potato snacks are priced higher than fresh potatoes, growth in the low-income developing countries will continue to be limited. Economic growth that boosts consumer income in developed countries will improve demand for potato snack foods. Prices of other snack foods influence demand for potato snack foods. Products that use corn as the main raw product are close substitutes. Tastes and preferences may have put a damper on potato snack foods in some regions. Medical experts warn consumers that diets with excess fat can be detrimental to human health. Since traditional potato snack foods were fried in oil, many consumers chose to reduce consumption on health concerns. New products that use less oil, less harmful oil or no oil at all (baked products) have been developed to provide snack foods that are perceived to be healthier. Potato snack food firms have also used a new fat substitute, olestra, in the manufacture of a healthy-image snack. During the late 1990s US sales of olestra-based snack foods were disappointing, even though they commanded higher prices at retail.
105
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
Seed potatoes Demand for seed potatoes is derived from the consumer demand for potato products. Consumer tastes and preferences influence the varieties that commercial potato growers plant. The challenge for seed growers is to plan ahead and produce the varieties that will be popular several years into the future. Current seed production systems require several years of field production to multiply primary seed stocks. New technology may reduce the number of field generations needed. This creates an opportunity for seed growers to shorten their planning horizon, but reduces the total need for seed potato plantings. New developments that would make true potato seed (TPS) a viable option could in the future replace the current seed tuber system.
Other In none of the countries does the ‘canned/other’ category make up more than 5% of the processing share (Table 4.12). Use of potatoes by other food processors for soups, stews and other processed meals makes up a small part of this sector. Use of potatoes for livestock feed will probably continue to decline, but during years of large potato supplies and low prices, feed rates will go up. One stable part of the feed market is potato waste from potato processors. In western North America cattle feedlots depend on potato processing facilities for a steady supply of a potato-based feed component. Use of potatoes for alcohol for both beverages and fuel will continue to be small markets.
Demand forecasting models Several researchers have published studies about forecasting future potato demand. Private forecasting models are used for proprietary purposes and the results are not published.Two of the academic studies are discussed here.
United States In the late 1980s the Idaho Potato Commission (IPC), curious about future growth opportunities for the Idaho potato industry, funded a research project at the University of Idaho to forecast demand. The result was a study which predicted 1995 potato markets, seven years into the future.5 The 106
DEMAND Table 4.13
Factors affecting the demand for United States potato products
Factor Own-price, substitutes Price – fresh potatoes Price – dehydrated Price – potato snacks Price – frozen potatoes Complement Price – hamburger Consumer income Tastes & preferences Females in labour force Microwave ovens Meals away from home Advertising – frozen Advertising – dehydrated Advertising – potato snacks Western restaurants in Japan Yen exchange rate
Fresh Potatoes
Dehy Retail
Dehy FS
-
+ -
+
Potato Snacks
Frozen Retail
Frozen FS
+
+
Frozen Japan
+
-
+
+ +
+
+
-
-
-
+
+
+
+ -
+ +
+ + +
+
+ + + +
FS = food service market + indicates that as the factor increases demand increases - indicates that as the factor increases demand decreases
project consisted of three parts: (1) build an econometric model to determine the main forces that affect US potato demand, (2) forecast US potato demand and (3) estimate Idaho’s share of the forecasted potato demand. The econometric model included demand for seven potato markets: fresh, dehydrated-retail, dehydrated-food service (FS), chips (snacks), frozenretail, frozen-food service and frozen exports to Japan. Table 4.13 provides a summary of the model in terms of direction of impact, but not actual coefficients. The model includes the four demand shifters from economic theory (see pages 99–109). Although population does not appear in the list of explanatory factors, all quantities and consumer income were converted to per capita figures. The first group of factors includes prices for four potato products. The first column, representing the demand for fresh potatoes, has a negative sign in the fresh potato price row. This means that the mathematical model depicts a negative relationship between price and quantity, as expected. The blanks in the fresh potato column for the other three potato prices mean that the impact of substitute potato products had a statistically insignificant impact on fresh potato demand. In the next column, dehydrated retail potatoes, there is the expected negative sign for own-price and a positive sign for fresh potato price. This means that the price of fresh potatoes does have a statistically significant impact on dehydrated potato demand. As fresh 107
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
potato price increases, demand for retail dehydrated potatoes also rises. The positive signs in the fresh potato price row show that fresh potatoes are statistically significant substitutes for dehydrated-retail, dehydrated-food service, frozen-retail and frozen-food service. The only other substitute relationship is that frozen potatoes are a significant substitute for dehydrated food service potatoes. Own prices for dehydrated and frozen potatoes in the food service markets were excluded. Discussion with industry experts revealed that non-price factors were quite important, which the model verified. As we have seen, many restaurants use ‘meal deal’ pricing with a set price for a complete meal, so the consumer price for frozen-food service potatoes cannot be clearly determined. The same is true for dehydrated-food service potatoes that are served in schools, hospitals, nursing homes, prisons and military bases where clientele are not charged a direct price for potato products. A hamburger and fries is a common meal in the United States and in fast-food restaurants around the world. Foods that are frequently eaten together are considered complements. When the price of one increases consumers tend to buy less of both products. In this model the hamburger was found to be a statistically significant substitute for frozen potatoes in the retail, food service and Japanese export markets. The positive sign for hamburger price in those three columns indicates that as hamburger price increases, demand for these three potato products decreases. The next seven explanatory variables fit in the demand shifter category of consumer tastes and preferences. The first, females in the labour force, is a variable intended to capture changes in preferences for convenient foods. The negative sign in the fresh potato column says that more females working outside the home will decrease demand. The positive signs in frozen retail and frozen food service shows that working women prefer frozen potato products. The microwave oven variable is the percentage of US homes that own a microwave oven. This variable is also related to convenience. As more consumers own microwaves the demand for fresh and dehydrated retail potatoes increases. These products are well suited for this cooking method. The demand for frozen-retail and frozen-food service declined with increased microwave ownership, probably because the frozen potato industry did not have products that performed well under microwave cooking. The mealsaway-from-home variable was also related to the consumer preference for convenience and had a positive influence on fresh, snacks and frozen-food service demand. The three advertising variables had positive impacts on the products they promoted and one, frozen-potato advertising, took away demand from potato snacks. The number of Western restaurants had a positive, significant impact on
108
DEMAND Table 4.14
Actual and forecasted potato demand for the US and Idaho 1988 Actual
1995 Forecast
1995 Actual
US quantity sold (million cwt) US price ($/cwt)
309 6.02
365 6.02
409 6.32
Idaho quantity sold (million cwt) Idaho price ($/cwt)
92 5.40
120 5.40
122 5.40
the demand for US frozen potatoes in Japan. Since many of these restaurants serve burgers and fries, Japanese consumers have developed a preference for US frozen potato products. The last variable in Table 4.13, the yen : dollar exchange rate, relates to own-price rather than a demand shifter. When the value of the yen changes in relation to the dollar, the Japanese price of US frozen potato products also changes. Actual values of the explanatory variables for the 1970–88 period were used to develop the mathematical equations in the forecasting model. In order to complete the 1995 forecast, future values of the explanatory variables were forecast. Some forecasts were obtained from government sources, some from private sources and some were estimated with linear trends and logistic functions. Results of the forecast are in Table 4.14. The forecast was for US potato quantity sold to increase by 18% between 1988 to 1995 if potato prices were at the same level. Actual US potato demand increased more than that, with both quantity sold and price rising. The quantity sold actually increased 32% and went for a 5% higher price. Although the econometric model forecast an 18% growth in demand in seven years, it underestimated the rapid growth of the demand for US potatoes. The model was very accurate for the Idaho portion of the forecast, predicting a 30% growth in quantity sold compared to the actual increase of 32%, with no change in price.
World market Researchers G Scott, M Rosegrant and C Ringer at the International Potato Center in Peru developed a model to forecast world demand for four root and tuber crops – cassava, potato, sweet potato and yam.6 In order to better understand the role of roots and tubers in the early twenty-first century the research team analysed trends and factors that influence the supply and demand for these commodities. Included in the project were forecasts for potato demand in the year 2020.
109
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY Table 4.15
Projected growth rates in world potato use, 1993–2020
China Other East Asia India Other South Asia Southeast Asia Latin America WANA Sub-Saharan Africa Developing Developed World
Baseline food (%)
HDP food (%)
Baseline feed (%)
HDP feed (%)
Baseline total (%)
HDP total (%)
2.2 1.3 3.1 3.0 2.3 1.7 2.0 3.1 2.3 0.4 1.2
2.8 1.3 3.8 2.9 2.4 1.7 2.3 3.2 2.8 0.3 1.4
0.3 1.2 na na 2.6 1.6 1.6 1.8 0.4 0.2 0.3
2.7 1.3 na na 2.4 1.6 1.6 1.8 2.7 0.2 1.0
1.5 1.3 3.1 3.0 2.3 1.7 2.0 3.1 2.0 0.3 1.0
2.8 1.3 3.8 2.9 2.6 1.7 2.3 3.1 2.8 0.3 1.3
Source: Scott et al. na = not applicable WANA is West Asia and North Africa HDP is the high demand and production growth scenario
The Scott team worked with the International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI), an organization that makes global projections of food supply and demand. The foundation of the projections is the International Model for Policy Analysis of Agricultural Commodities and Trade (IMPACT). The mathematical model consists of supply, demand and trade equations for 37 countries or groups of countries and 18 commodities, including potatoes. The commodity demand equations account for prices, consumer income, population growth, livestock production, feed prices and feeding efficiency. The model’s main driving forces for estimating demand were growth rates in population and consumer income. For the largest potato-consuming country, China, the researchers assumed an annual population growth rate of 0.7% and an annual income growth rate of 5.6% for the 1993–2020 period. The assumptions for the second-largest potato country, India, were 1.3% and 5.1% for population and income growth, respectively. The researchers made two forecasts for 2020, one called a baseline forecast and the other a high demand and production (HDP) growth scenario. Since previous efforts to forecast potato demand in developing countries had underestimated actual demand, the HDP scenario was developed. Problems with underestimating include wrongly applying income elasticities from developed countries to developing countries. In the HDP scenario income elasticities for food use of potatoes were increased. Results of the Scott forecasts are in Table 4.15 and Table 4.16. The projected annual growth rates in Table 4.15 show total world use increasing 110
DEMAND Table 4.16 Projected world potato consumption per capita, 1993–2020
China Other East Asia India Other South Asia Southeast Asia Latin America WANA Sub-Saharan Africa Developing Developed World
1993 (kg/yr)
Baseline 2020 (kg/yr)
HDP 2020 (kg/yr)
14 18 13 9 3 22 28 3 13 75 27
20 21 21 11 3 24 28 3 16 77 27
23 21 25 11 3 24 31 3 18 76 28
Source: Scott et al. WANA is West Asia and North Africa HDP is the high demand and production growth scenario
at a rate of 1% per year in the baseline scenario and 1.3% in the HDP scenario. The projected growth is only 0.3% in developed countries under both scenarios, much lower than the 2.0% and 2.8% in developing countries. The most rapid growth rates are projected for India and sub-Saharan Africa. To get a perspective of the size of the potato demand in different regions, Table 4.16 shows the projections in terms of per capita use. Although the developed country category has the lowest growth rate, it has the largest per capita use by a large margin. Under the HDP scenario the developed countries per capita use is more than double the next largest user and at least triple the use of all other regions. Although potato demand has been expanding and is projected to continue to expand all over the globe, the main potato eaters will continue to be the people living in developed countries.
References 1
United States, Department of Agriculture, Food Consumption, Prices and Expenditures, 1970–98, Washington, DC, 2000. 2 J Guenthner, A Levi, and B-H Lin, ‘Factors that affect the demand for potato products in the United States’, American Potato Journal, 1991 68:9 569–79. 3 D Horton, Potatoes: Production, Marketing, and Programs for Developing Countries, London, Westview Press, 1987. 111
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY 4 5 6
L Hinton, Potatoes in Surplus, Occasional Papers no. 37, Cambridge University, Department of Land Economy, 1987. J Guenthner, A Levi, and B-H Lin, Forecasting the Demand for Idaho Potatoes, AES Bull. No. 734, Moscow, Idaho, University of Idaho, 1992. G Scott, M Rosegrant, and C Ringler, Roots and Tubers for the 21st Century, Lima, Peru, International Potato Center, 2000.
112
CHAPTER
5 Prices
P
otato supply and demand are powerful driving forces, but several other factors also influence potato prices. This chapter deals with priceinfluencing factors not covered in the previous chapters, which dealt specifically with potato supply and potato demand.
Price theory Market structure Potato prices can vary between markets that have different types of market structure. The term ‘monopoly’ gives most people an image of a firm setting prices, while the term ‘competitive’ suggests that firms have little or no power to set prices. Economists use more than just those two categories of market classification, generally putting markets into four categories: competitive, oligopolistic, monopolistic and monopolistic competition.They also use four structural characteristics to classify markets: the number of buyers and sellers; the size of buyers and sellers; the amount of product differentiation; and the barriers to industry entry and exit. The various types of market structure as related to the potato industry are discussed below. 113
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
Competitive markets The following characteristics define competitive markets: 1
sufficiently large numbers of buyers and sellers so that individuals cannot influence price; 2 products homogeneous to the degree that one producer’s product cannot be distinguished from another’s; 3 no market restrictions such as government control or collusion; 4 no barriers to entry. Since individuals cannot influence prices in competitive markets, the participants are known as ‘price takers’. As the term suggests, price takers simply take the price offered; they have no power to do anything else if they want to be in the market. In competitive markets there are no excess profits in the long run. Temporarily profitable prices attract new producers and expansion of existing producers, both of which put downward pressure on prices. When prices are at unprofitable levels some producers cut back or leave, which in turn pushes up prices. In competitive markets an individual potato grower who changes production has no impact on price. An expansion can change a grower’s cost structure, but not market structure or price. Collectively, if many growers expand during the same crop year it will, of course, affect prices. This points out the paradox of competitive markets. An individual acting out of selfinterest has no impact, but the aggregate actions of like-minded growers do change prices. A grower who expands to reduce per unit costs, or to simply increase revenue, has no price impact, but if other growers do the same the aggregate affect pushes down prices for everyone. Since small changes in potato supply can cause large changes in price, competitive markets provide growers with the risk of very low prices, but also the opportunity for very high prices.
Monopolies Monopolies are at the other end of the market classification spectrum. An absolute monopoly is a single firm with a product that is different from any others. Monopolistic markets also have barriers to entry. A monopoly sets high prices, which provide the firm with higher profits than are possible in competitive markets. Most governments have a mix of laws to regulate, promote and prohibit monopolies. Public utilities are examples of regulated monopolies, which operate with government regulation to provide citizens with consistent supplies and stable prices for such goods as telephone services. Patent law is an example where governments provide incentives for monopoly development. Patents are designed to protect the property rights 114
PRICES
of inventors and to give businesses incentives to invest in research and development. Patent laws typically allow a firm to operate as a monopoly for a fixed period, such as 17 years in the US, after which other firms may enter the market. Although patent laws protect monopolies, most countries also have laws to prohibit some other types of monopolies. Known as antitrust laws, this type of legislation is designed to prevent abusive market power, with the implicit principle that more competition is better. Two types of monopoly power relevant to the potato industry are local monopolies and producer monopolies. A local monopoly may exist in a geographic region where one firm can operate profitably, but two or more cannot. An example could be a potato processor in a small, isolated potatoproducing region where the high costs of transporting potatoes limits growers’ market alternatives. Although such a potato-processing monopoly controls price, there are limits. If the price is too favourable to the monopolist, excess profits might be an incentive for another firm to enter. Likewise, if grower profits are too slim, they may choose not to grow potatoes for the processor. Governments sometimes promote agricultural producer monopolies. Recognizing an imbalance of power in some agricultural markets, governments grant farmer exemptions to antitrust laws. Marketing orders, collective bargaining, co-operatives and marketing boards are some of the tools governments use to allow growers to collude and exercise monopoly power.
Oligopolies Oligopolies are markets in which there are a few large sellers and many buyers. Products may be homogeneous or differentiated. Barriers to entry do exist. Actions by individual firms in such markets can and do affect market prices. Price behaviour depends on the strategies of the firms. Assuming that the firms do not collude, they react to the decisions of the others. In some oligopoly markets a dominant firm sets prices and the others follow. Prices remain stable because firms that cut prices may cause a price war in which all firms lose revenue. Instead of price competition, oligopolistic firms use non-price competition such as advertising, promotion, coupons and rebates. In markets when there is collusion, such as the OPEC oil cartel, the challenge is to determine market shares for each firm. Oligopsonies are markets dominated by a few large buyers that purchase from many sellers. In some places potato processing is considered an oligopsonistic market where many growers sell to a few large processors. The market power of the processors pushes down grower potato prices to a level lower than what would prevail if the market were competitive. The amount of the price gap depends on the growers’ alternatives. In areas where 115
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
growers can choose to sell in the seed market or fresh market, especially if they grow multi-purpose varieties, the oligopsony power is weakened. If the growers have many non-potato production alternatives such as growing grains, forages and horticultural crops they gain power but not as much as if they have alternative potato markets. Since potato growing requires expensive, single-purpose equipment, asset fixity can provide market power to the processors. Potato processors hold oligopsony power in their raw product market, but may face different situations in the final product markets. In the retail market channel there have been many buyers, but in the food service market there are fewer. For dehydrated potato products, potato snacks and retail frozen potatoes, the market is dominated by a few major potato processors that operate as oligopolists. In the food service frozen-fry market, which is dominated by several firms, including McDonald’s and Burger King, the market consists of a few large processors selling to a few large buyers. This situation has led to serious price competition and forward contracting. Since the number of buyers and sellers is similar and the product is homogeneous the price results may be close to the competition norm.
Monopolistic competition The fourth category of market structure is monopolistic competition. In this type of market a large number of sellers offer a differentiated product. Although each firm’s product has many substitutes, sellers differentiate on the basis of non-price competition. They try to use service, quality, reputation and other attributes to influence buyers to prefer their products. Firms have some control over pricing, but substitutes limit that power. Demand for a firm’s product is quite elastic. Small price changes can precipitate large changes in quantity sold. Prices in monopolistic competition are higher than in purely competitive markets, but lower than prices in monopolistic and oligopolistic markets. Seed potatoes are sold in monopolistic competition. The market involves many seed potato growers who differentiate their products. One important category of difference is variety. Although commercial growers may have flexibility regarding varieties planted they have preferences and some processor contracts specify a certain variety. Another point of differentiation is quality, as objectively measured by seed certification agencies. Disease readings in field inspections, laboratory tests and winter growth samples are provided to the public. A seed grower’s lot of potatoes that was completely disease-free in all readings is a higher-quality product than a lot that contains disease readings that barely meet certification tolerances. Seed potato markets also differentiate based on field generation. Since 116
PRICES Table 5.1
North American seed potato prices, 1998–99
Variety Norkotah Norland Ranger Russet Russet Burbank Shepody Superior
Low price
High price
Midpoint
$6.00 $8.00 $8.50 $5.75 $8.50 $6.75
$14.00 $12.00 $10.00 $8.75 $15.00 $9.00
$10.00 $10.00 $9.25 $7.25 $11.75 $7.88
Source: Fraser’s Potato Newsletter
generations closer to the parent seed from the laboratory are thought to be better, they get price premiums. Services such as timely delivery, sanitation procedures, tuber size sorting and optimal storage conditions can also help seed growers differentiate their product. Finally, the reputation of seed growers can bring price premiums or discounts depending on how buyers perceive them. The result of product differentiation in the seed potato market is that prices vary over a wide range. Table 5.1 shows seed potato prices for six popular varieties in North America reported by Fraser1 during the 1998–99 marketing season. There is a wide range of midpoint prices among the different varieties, ranging from $7.25 for Russet Burbank to $11.75 for Shepody. The same-variety price range was the widest for Norkotah, which had prices ranging from $6.00 to $14.00. For each variety the price varies depending on location, time of sale, generation and the reputation of the seed grower. The large size of the price range supports the notion that seed potatoes are sold in monopolistic competition conditions where producers, although many in number, can differentiate their product.
Marketing margins As potatoes move from field to consumer, value is added by firms that store, transport, wash, sort, package and even cook the potatoes. Where ownership changes on the marketing chain different potato prices are established. For example, fresh potato prices change along the trail from grower to packer to wholesaler to retailer to consumer. The difference between two prices in a marketing chain is called a marketing margin. The margin from the farmer at the beginning of the marketing chain to the consumer at the other end of the chain receives much attention from those involved in agriculture. Fresh potato prices at the grower level have traditionally been determined under competitive conditions in most potato-producing regions. A 117
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY Table 5.2
July August September October November December January February March April May June Average
UK fresh potato marketing margins 1994/95 Grower price (p/kg)
1994/95 Consumer price (p/kg)
1994/95 Marketing margin (%)
1996/97 Grower price (p/kg)
1996/97 Consumer price (p/kg)
1996/97 Marketing margin (%)
15.7 12.0 10.9 10.1 13.2 14.6 18.6 22.2 24.0 25.7 25.4 26.1 18.2
42.8 37.6 35.8 34.3 33.5 36.2 37.4 43.5 48.1 53.4 58.3 63.7 43.7
63 68 70 71 61 60 50 49 50 52 56 59 59
8.9 7.7 6.3 6.2 5.3 5.8 6.2 6.2 7.1 7.2 7.4 na 6.8
37.6 34.8 30.6 25.3 24.1 23.7 24.8 25.9 27.3 30.5 35.3 34.5 29.5
76 78 79 75 78 76 75 76 74 76 79 na 77
Source: British Potato Council na = not available
large number of buyers and sellers and a homogeneous product make for competitive pricing; producers’ choices are limited to merely accepting or rejecting the current market price. At the other end of the retail marketing chain, fresh potatoes are sold in oligopolistic markets where restaurant managers and retailers set whatever prices they choose, with a careful eye on the competition. Table 5.2 shows marketing margins for fresh potatoes in the UK during two marketing years: 1994/95, which was a high-price year for growers, and 1996/97, which brought growers low prices. The comparative data suggests how fresh potato marketing margins behave. First, the grower and retail prices move together, with increases in grower prices corresponding to retail price increases in the same month or the following month. Another observation is that margins are higher in percentage terms during years when grower prices are low. For the high-priced 1994/95 crop marketing margins ranged from 49% in February to 71% in October and averaged 59% for the entire marketing season. Margins varied in a more narrow, but higher, range of 74% to 79% during the low-priced 1996/97 marketing season. Table 5.2 supports an economic hypothesis that fresh potato prices are ‘sticky downward’ in the retail market channel. The concept describes a situation where retail prices come down slowly. When supplier prices go down, retailers have an incentive to keep prices at about the same level and increase their profit margins. Both monthly and annual data in Table 5.2 118
PRICES Table 5.3
Year 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 Average
United States fresh potato marketing margins Shipper price ($/cwt)
Retail price ($/cwt)
Marketing margin ($/cwt)
Marketing margin (%)
10.00 10.60 6.60 5.90 7.50 7.40 7.60 7.70 5.50 7.40 7.62
34.20 37.10 33.00 30.50 34.80 37.40 37.90 38.10 35.40 37.00 35.54
24.20 26.50 26.40 24.60 27.30 30.00 30.30 30.40 29.90 29.60 27.92
71 71 80 81 78 80 80 80 84 80 79
Source: National Potato Council
support that concept. The larger margins are clearly higher for the low-price year. During the high-priced year, 1994/95, the largest margin at 71% was during October when the grower price was at its lowest. From the previous month the grower price dropped 7% while the retail price dropped only 4%. The ‘sticky downward’ phenomenon is also apparent in marketing margin data for fresh retail potatoes in the United States (Table 5.3). A large drop in potato shipper average price from $10.60 in 1990 to $6.60 in 1991 corresponded to almost no change in the marketing margin as measured in dollars, $26.50 versus $26.40. For the 38% drop in shipper price, retailers reduced their prices only 11%, from $37.10 to $33.00, keeping their profit margins about the same in dollar terms. In percentage terms the marketing margin jumped from 71% to 80%. A similar scenario unfolded during the price drop from 1996 to 1997. From a longer-term perspective, the marketing margins in Table 5.3 seem to have reached a plateau of around $30.00 during the last five years, moving in a narrow range of $29.60 to $30.40. During the 1989–92 period the marketing margin seemed to be on a lower plateau around $25.00. A change in market structure toward fewer and larger retailers with more market power could be a reason that margins reached a higher plateau. Marketing margins are larger for processed potato products. One reason is that the potatoes go through more of a physical transformation when processed. Fresh potatoes are washed, sorted and packaged for the fresh market, but their structure and appearance remain unchanged. Processed potatoes undergo fundamental changes, with the final product of crisps, dehydrated potato flakes and frozen fries bearing little resemblance to the 119
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY Table 5.4 margins
United States potato snack marketing
Year
Retail price ($/lb)
Grower price ($/cwt)
Marketing margin (%)
1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998
2.86 2.96 2.97 2.90 2.88 2.97 3.00 3.06 3.13 3.16
5.06 4.75 4.58 4.50 5.06 4.66 4.66 4.77 4.86 4.68
93 94 94 94 93 94 94 94 94 94
Source: National Potato Council Grower prices are for all processed potatoes
raw product. Potatoes lose much of their water weight during processing. The conversion rates of raw product to final product are approximately 2 : 1 for frozen, 4 : 1 for potato snacks and 7 : 1 for dehydrated potato products. Marketing margins for United States potato snacks during the 1989–98 period are shown in Table 5.4. The margins are higher than the fresh potato margins shown in Tables 5.2 and 5.3. The value of the potato supplied by growers makes up only about 6% of the retail value of potato snack food products. Notice also that prices are relatively stable at both the grower level and retail level. Although there is a general upward trend in retail prices the $0.30 increase from 1989 to 1998 is an increase of only about 1% per year, less than the US rate of inflation, which ranged from 1.6% to 5.4% during that period. The grower price was also stable, varying within a range of $4.50 to $5.06. Since processors contract for a large part of their raw product needs, the processing potato price does not show the volatility that occurs in the fresh potato market. In the food service market where consumers pay for someone to prepare, cook and serve their food one would expect high marketing margins. During the year 2000 many US fast-food restaurants were buying frozen fries in 100-pound (45.4 kg) bags. They could get about 400 servings from each bag. A common price was $1.00 per serving, giving revenue of $400 per bag of frozen fries. The restaurants paid about $40 to get the 100-pound bag of fries into their stores. About $10 went for transport and distribution and the remaining $30 to the potato processor, who passed on $10 to the grower. One hundred pounds of frozen fries requires 200 pounds 120
PRICES Grower Processor 2.5% 5.0% Other 2.5%
Restaurant 90.0%
5.1 Marketing margins for frozen fries in food service.
of potatoes, which processors purchased from growers at a typical price of $5.00 per cwt. Of the $400 that consumers spent on fast-food fries the restaurant got $360, the processor $20, the distributor $10 and the growers $10. The grower share in this example is 2.5% (Fig. 5.1).
Location Potatoes are bulky, perishable and difficult to transport. The expense of moving potatoes means that potato prices vary between locations. According to Von Thunen’s Principle, farm product prices are lower in places far distant from the market and higher in the locations closest to market. The far locations also have the disadvantage of more price volatility. Since transport costs make up a higher percentage of the consumer price, small changes in consumer demand can cause large changes in grower prices. Potato prices can vary over a wide range at different locations within a country at any particular time. Table 5.5 shows potato prices for four locations in Germany during one week at the end of March 2000. The prices vary according to type of potato, with the ‘firm cooking varieties’ getting the higher prices. For both types of potatoes, the prices progress from a low in Hanover to higher prices, progressively, in North Rhine, Bavaria and Brandenburg. The Hanover region is in north central Germany, the North Rhine is on the western edge of Germany bordering the Netherlands, Bavaria is in southern Germany and Brandenburg is in eastern Germany. The price pattern exhibits a circular, counter-clockwise progression from north to west to south to east (Fig. 5.2). If potato transport costs were lower the large differences in prices would most likely be less. 121
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY Table 5.5
Potato prices in selected German markets, March 2000 Low (E/100 kg)
High (E/100 kg)
Midpoint (E/100 kg)
Firm cooking varieties Hanover North Rhine Bavaria Brandenburg
2.56 4.09 5.11 5.62
5.62 6.14 6.65 7.16
4.09 5.12 5.88 6.39
Predominately firm cooking varieties Hanover North Rhine Bavaria Brandenburg
2.56 3.58 3.58 4.60
3.07 5.11 5.62 6.90
2.82 4.35 4.60 5.75
Type/location
Source: ZMP
Hanover 4.09
Brandenburg 6.39
North Rhine 5.12
Bavaria 5.88
5.2 Potato prices in selected German markets, March 2000.
Location and transport economics are important factors in the location of processing facilities. Dehydrators want to minimize the cost of hauling raw product. Owing to the relatively low value of dehydration-grade potatoes, most dehydration factories are located quite close to fresh packing facilities. To minimize costs of transporting off-grade potatoes from fresh packer to dehydrator some facilities are located across the road from each other or even on the same site. The economic incentive is the same for frozen potato processors in that an objective is to minimize costs of transporting raw 122
PRICES
product. Frozen processors locate their facilities in large potato-producing regions where they can procure a year-round supply of raw product from local growers. Potato snack manufacturers use a very different approach, building their factories in or near big cities, some of which are far from major potatoproducing areas. Since potato snack foods have a low density they bump against a space constraint before reaching a weight constraint in transport. A lorry full to the brim with potato crisps would carry a light load. Transport costs per unit of weight can be quite expensive for snack foods. The incentive for potato snack firms is to minimize final product transport costs. As a result, they transport raw product great distances, especially during times of the year when local potatoes are unavailable or unacceptable. In North America Canadian snack-food factories are supplied with Florida potatoes during some periods of the year. In the same manner Egyptian potatoes have supplied potato crisp factories in the United Kingdom. In the potato snack industry grower prices also vary according to location. During the week of 7 December 2000, Fraser reports the following prices for open-market raw product going to potato snack processors: Michigan $7.00/cwt, Wisconsin $6.25/cwt and the Red River Valley of Minnesota and North Dakota $5.25/cwt. All three potato-producing states are in the same region, the Upper Midwest. The highest price is in Michigan, which is closest to large population centres. The lowest price is in the Red River Valley, a sparsely populated area far from major cities and potato-snack factories. Transport economics is not the only driving force that affects regional differences in potato prices. The market for fresh russet potatoes in the United States is a case in point. According to the Federal-State Market News Service, the following prices per cwt were reported for 70-count cartons of russet potatoes during the week of 7 December 2000: Wisconsin $12.50, Colorado $14.00, Idaho $18.00, Washington $15.00 and the Klamath Basin of California and Oregon $15.50 (Fig. 5.3). Of these five areas Wisconsin is the closest to the major population centres of the Eastern US, but its shippers got the lowest price. Idaho is the greatest distance from population centres, yet its shippers received the highest price. The reason is that the Idaho industry has successfully differentiated its potatoes. Consumers perceive the Idaho product to be superior and are willing to pay a price premium that more than offsets transport cost differentials.
Quality Grade standards are established for agricultural products, often with government assistance, to make marketing more efficient. Without adequate 123
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY Washington $15.00 Wisconsin $12.50
Idaho $18.00 CA/OR $15.50
Colorado $14.00
5.3 United States russet 70-count fresh potato prices, 7 December 2000.
grade standards buyers would have to rely on personal inspection to determine quality. Proper grade standards allow for trade by electronic communication rather than by a large number of buying agents who travel to producers for face-to-face buying. One of the challenges of developing or revising grading systems is to capture the quality attributes that are important to consumers. Size, shape, firmness and appearance are important fresh potato attributes. Although size and shape preferences vary among consumers and by the type of cooking method, consumers generally want potatoes that are free from unsightly blemishes such as cuts, bruises, diseases and rot. Fresh potato industries in many regions operate with grade standards that are clearly understood by buyers. Standards for US No. 1 size A require potatoes to be of similar varietal characteristics; firm; clean; well-shaped; free from freezing, blackheart, blight, wilt, rot and damage by other causes; and not less than 17/8 inches (47.8 mm) in diameter. Tolerances allow for a total of 8% of potatoes in any lot to fail to meet standards and still make grade. Tolerances for individual types of defects include 5% for external damage, 5% for internal defects, 3% for disease defects and 1% for frozen or rotten potatoes. Some of the main differences in fresh potato grade standards are in sizing. Consumers have shown preferences for potatoes that are sold in similar size ranges. Potato packs that include large and small potatoes together sell for lower prices than those sorted by size. In the North American russet potato market fresh potato sizing is split into two groups. The smaller potatoes in the 4 to 8-ounce (113 to 227 g) range go into non-size A 124
PRICES $35
$30
70-count 100-count 10 mesh
$25
$20
$15
$10
$5
$0 Sept.
Oct. Nov. 1998
Dec. Jan.
Feb.
Mar.
Apr. May 1999
Jun.
Jul.
Aug.
5.4 Idaho fresh potato prices, 1998–99.
bags, mostly in 5-pound (2.3 kg) or 10-pound (4.6 kg) packs. These potatoes do not meet US No.1 size A grade standards, but are sold to retailers as ‘consumer packs’ for at-home consumption. The larger and most valuable potatoes are in the 8–16 ounce (227–454 g) range. They go into 50-pound (22.7 kg) cardboard boxes, known as ‘count cartons’. Each carton has a number that specifies how many tubers are in a box. An 80-count carton would contain about 80 potatoes, with an average weight of 10 ounces (284 g). Count cartons are popular in the restaurant trade where sized portions are important. Since potatoes of different size grades are substitutes for each other, their prices generally move together. Prices for three grades of Idaho russets during the 1998–99 marketing season are given in Fig. 5.4. The ‘10 mesh’ grade is non-size A consumer pack potatoes in 10-pound (4.6 kg) mesh bags. Notice that the highest price level is for the 70-count cartons, which restaurants frequently serve baked in the skin. The lowest price is for the 10-mesh consumer packs. In between are the 100-counts, which in terms of size are close to the size border between cartons and consumer packs. Although the price level for all three packs moved upward together late in the season, prices moved in opposite directions early in the season. One possible explanation is that early harvested potatoes had a size profile skewed toward 125
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
smaller potatoes. In September when the Idaho crop is not fully mature, the scarcity of larger potatoes pushes up their price. Since growing seasons differ and the overall size profile of a potato crop varies from year to year, the price gaps between different potato sizes varies. Fresh potato prices are usually reported in a daily range. The fresh shippers at the top of the range have reputations for providing superior products and service. Although grade standards dictate tolerances for fresh potato defects such as misshapen and bruised potatoes, all shipping areas do not require inspection. Fresh shippers who operate in markets with mandatory inspection can choose to sort potatoes to barely meet grade tolerances or to be well within them. Shippers who consistently pack potatoes that are much better than minimum standards develop reputations for high-quality potatoes and obtain prices at the top of the range. For example, the market news for 25 January 2001 showed the following prices for Idaho russet count-carton potatoes: 40s = $5.00–$7.00 50s = $5.00–$7.00 60s = $6.00–$7.00, occasional higher 70s = $7.00–$7.50, few $8.00 80s = $8.00, some $7.00–$7.50, occasional higher 90s = $8.00, some $7.00–$7.50, occasional higher 100s = $8.00, few higher & lower. During that day in the same state for the same grades of potatoes prices varied over a wide range. Differences in reputation and perhaps marketing skills of the shippers account for some of these price differences that occur during any day in fresh potato markets. Private branding by region is another form of quality identification. North American regions that have mandatory inspection, such as Idaho, Colorado, Oregon and Washington generally get higher prices than states that do not have mandatory inspection. In the United States the ‘Grown in Idaho’ trademark has brought fresh market premiums for decades. The premiums at the retail level have been large enough to more than offset transport price differences and put Idaho FOB prices for fresh potatoes at the top. This situation may be changing with the introduction of new varieties.
Pricing mechanisms, institutions and information Pricing mechanisms Farm prices are established in a variety of different ways even for the same commodity. Analysts generally put pricing mechanisms into five categories: 126
PRICES
individual negotiations, organized exchanges, formula pricing, collective bargaining, and administrative pricing. The potato industry applications of these price discovery methods are discussed below.
(1) Individual negotiations Markets for fresh fruits and vegetables generally fall into the category of individual negotiations. Each year millions of produce transactions around the world are done under this pricing mechanism. In competitive markets with large numbers of buyers and sellers negotiated prices vary, depending on location, perceived or real quality differences and the trading skills of the people in the market. Fresh potatoes at the farm level are frequently sold under individual negotiations. Fresh potato transactions between brokers, wholesalers, restaurants and retailers have also traditionally been done through this type of pricing mechanism. At the consumer level prices are not negotiated in most developed country market channels. The prices posted on a restaurant menu or a potato display in the produce section of a supermarket are not negotiable. In developing countries, with less complex marketing systems, consumers bargain with sellers who may be the growers themselves.
(2) Organized exchanges This category includes auctions and futures markets. Although grains, livestock, cotton, tobacco, flowers and other agricultural products are commonly sold through exchanges, most potatoes are priced by other mechanisms. Organized potato auctions have operated and continue to operate in places around the world but they are losing ground to other pricing mechanisms. Some countries, such as Taiwan, have conducted auctions for potato imports, with the winning bidders getting the right to ship a certain quantity of potatoes into the country. Potato futures markets, which are discussed in Chapter 10, exist in some countries but have gone defunct in others.
(3) Formula pricing Formula pricing has been used in developed countries to price many farm goods, especially livestock products. The mechanism links prices paid to sellers to some other price, which may be a published price reported by an unbiased third party. The two main parts of a formula pricing mechanism are the establishment of a base price and the quantification of the link to that price. An example in the potato industry could be to link a transaction at 127
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY Table 5.6
Fresh potato formula pricing example
Product 10 # mesh 40-count cartons 50-count cartons 60-count cartons 70-count cartons 80-count cartons 90-count cartons 100-count cartons 10 oz min No. 2 Processed grade Total Packer charge Net price
Price ($/cwt)
Share (%)
Value ($/cwt)
9.75 16.25 16.40 17.10 19.65 20.00 19.50 17.45 12.20 7.30 2.00
30 1 2 2 4 4 5 4 2 8 38
2.93 0.16 0.33 0.34 0.79 0.80 0.98 0.70 0.24 0.58 0.76 8.60 3.50 5.10
95% of the closing price for April futures on the Amsterdam potato futures market. Formula pricing is commonly used to calculate prices between growers and fresh packers in North America. Although the grower–packer pricing mechanism has traditionally been individual negotiations in many fresh potato regions, formula pricing is becoming more common. The traditional ‘scoop up’ pricing of a flat price for all potatoes coming off the harvester or out of storage puts much of the price risk on the packer. With a change to formula pricing the market risk is shifted to the grower. The way formula pricing works in the fresh industry is that growers are paid on the actual pack out of their potatoes. The pack out is the percentages of potatoes that fit into each grade sorted by the packing house. An example pack out is in Table 5.6. Prices the packer received for each product shipped are in the first column. The next column is the portion of the grower’s potatoes that went into each pack. Value per cwt of $8.60 is determined by summing the values that each pack contributes to the total. The packer deducts a $3.50 packing charge to arrive at a net price to the grower of $5.10 per cwt. Assuming the packer charge includes a profit margin, the market price risk is borne by the grower. The packer’s incentive is to increase volume, which may in aggregate worsen the net prices to growers because of increasing supplies. For this reason growers often complain about this formula pricing mechanism and express a preference for pricing by individual negotiation, which provided incentive for packers to obtain high prices for the packed products. Some potato-packing operations 128
PRICES
are co-operatives that do indeed have an incentive to seek the highest possible prices for its grower members.
(4) Collective bargaining When growers become dissatisfied with prices or terms of trade they often turn to collective bargaining to deal with buyers. Facing one or several buyers they attempt to gain market power by uniting to increase their collective size. Their efforts are similar to workers who unite to form a labour union. Some governments grant antitrust exemptions to both labour unions and farmer groups in an attempt to provide them with market power. Growers have responded by using a variety of tools including co-operatives, bargaining associations and marketing orders to push up prices. Although potato processors compete for some product on the open market, they contract for a large portion of their potatoes. In potatoproducing areas where growers are geographically close together and willing to do so, collective bargaining has become a common mechanism for establishing contract prices. In North America potato-snack food growers are scattered across the continent and have not been successful in establishing collective bargaining associations. Some production areas have attempted to bargain, but processors shifted supply sources to other regions and broke the grower efforts. Since potato-snack processors rely on transporting raw product long distances, they have the flexibility to move away from areas that try to bargain collectively. Growers have been more successful in collective bargaining with frozen potato processors. In the frozen industry processing facilities are located in major potato-producing regions because it is more economical to transport final product than raw product. Processors who are dissatisfied with their growers cannot easily shift supply sources to other areas, because of high transport costs. Another difference between snack processors and frozen potato processors in North America is that the latter include price adjustments for the quality of potatoes that growers deliver. Whereas snack processors set quality standards and reject potatoes that do not meet them, frozen processors provide growers with economic incentives to produce highquality potatoes. Using an old metaphor, one uses a stick and the other uses a carrot to motivate growers to deliver high-quality potatoes. An example Idaho frozen potato processor contract during the 1990s specifies a base price of $4.35 per cwt, with the following quality-based premiums and discounts: 1
Specific gravity. An incentive of $0.03 per cwt will be paid for each 0.001 above 1.078. A penalty of $0.03 per cwt will be deducted for each 0.001 below 1.078. 129
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
2
US No. Ones (two-inch or four-ounce minimum size). An incentive of $0.01 per cwt will be paid for each percentage point above 60%. A penalty of $0.01 per cwt will be deducted for each percentage point below 60%. 3 Bruise-free. An incentive of $0.01 per cwt will be paid for each percentage point bruise-free exceeds 66%. A penalty of $0.01 per cwt will be deducted for each percentage point bruise-free is less than 66% down to 55% and $0.02 per cwt for each percentage point below 55%. 4 Size (over six ounces). An incentive of $0.03 per cwt will be paid for each percentage point the over 6 ounce percentage exceeds 50%, up to 70%, and $0.02 per cwt for each percentage point over 70%. A $0.03 per cwt penalty will be deducted for each percentage point below 50% down to 40%, then a $0.035 per cwt penalty will be deducted for each percentage point below 40%. 5 Dirt, rocks and foreign material. The price shall be increased $0.01 per cwt for each percentage point that dirt, rocks and foreign material tare is below 8% and shall be decreased $0.02 per cwt for each percentage point that dirt, rocks and foreign material tare exceeds 10% of the total weight delivered. The base price, incentives and penalties are all subject to negotiation each year during the bargaining process. Potato Growers of Washington (PGW) and Potato Growers of Idaho (PGI) are two grower organizations that have a history of bargaining for contracts with potato processors. Results have been mixed. Contract potato prices negotiated by PGI are given in Fig. 5.5. The 1990 figure is blank because bargaining was unsuccessful that year, marking the beginning of a loss of PGI bargaining power. During the rest of the 1990s PGI was involved in bargaining, but signing a contract with PGI was no longer critical to the potato processors. A significant number of non-PGI members would sign contracts with or without PGI approval. During the four decades of collective bargaining in Idaho, the contract price followed a pattern of three successive plateaus. The first plateau was in the $1.00 to $2.00 per cwt price range for 13 years. Prices remained constant for as long as three consecutive years. Then in 1974 the contract price jumped from $1.85 to $3.96, marking the beginning of a new 17-year plateau mostly in the $3.00 to $4.00 price range. The more than twofold price increase from 1973 to 1974 was a tribute to successful grower bargaining, but processor concerns about raw product procurement were also a factor. The next year processors negotiated the contract price down to $3.30, then down to $2.77 in 1977. The price then bounced back up into the $3.50 to $4.00 range and stayed there for 10 years. This decade of stability was fol130
PRICES $6.00
$5.00
$4.00
$3.00
$2.00
$1.00
19 61 19 63 19 65 19 67 19 69 19 71 19 73 19 75 19 77 19 79 19 81 19 83 19 85 19 87 19 89 19 91 19 93 19 95 19 97 19 99
$0.00
5.5 Idaho potato contract prices, 1961–2000.
lowed by the price impasse of 1990. Following that the price went to a new plateau in the range of $4.00 to $5.00. In the future changes in relative market power between processors and grower bargaining groups will determine future contract price patterns.
(5) Administrative pricing Administrative pricing requires one of two types of power – political power or market power – to set prices. Governments often use political power to set prices for agricultural commodities. In centrally planned economies the government fixes all the prices it chooses. In market economies the government often sets floor prices for agricultural goods at the farm level. Some impose ceiling prices to protect consumers from rising food costs. The other type of power needed for administrative pricing, market power, is available to monopolies and to a lesser degree oligopolies. In the potato industry growers do not have the power to administer prices. Snack food processors, especially in North America where the market is dominated by one firm, do have power to administer prices. Snack food growers sometimes complain that contract prices are administered at painfully low prices, but without effective bargaining associations they have 131
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
little countervailing power. When the snack food processors need raw product for which they have not contracted, they must buy in the open, competitive market, sometimes at very high prices. During years when they paid $5.00 per cwt for contract potatoes, snack-food processors have paid open market prices as high as $20.00 per cwt when high-quality potatoes became scarce. Most potato processors buy some potatoes on the open market where they lack the power to influence prices in the same way they do with contract prices. At the consumer level in developed countries most potato sellers do indeed use administrative pricing. Large fast-food chains, such as McDonald’s, may decide in corporate headquarters what will be the price of fries in their restaurants around the globe. In supermarkets the produce manager may decide how to price fresh potatoes, and other managers may decide how to price dehydrated, snack and frozen potato products. The other four types of pricing mechanisms are not often used at retail markets in developed countries, but individual negotiations are common at the consumer level in developing countries.
Government intervention Since hungry people become unhappy with their governments, there is a long history of government control of food production and marketing. Although political methods vary, nearly every country has some type of involvement in agriculture that affects prices. Governments intervene in farm prices to support farm income, preserve rural communities, enhance food security, lessen price and income instability and reduce consumer costs. Of course, government policy can have simple goals but complex results and some governments impose contradictory programmes. Potato markets, like markets for other fresh fruits and vegetables, have been relatively free of government intervention. Even in communist countries a large portion of the potato crop was traditionally grown on private plots, where the growers were free to eat their own potatoes or sell them to others. Most governments impose more regulations on grain markets than on potato markets. Sometimes the government programmes for other agricultural commodities can be detrimental to the potato industry. In Peru, the potato’s birthplace, potato consumption dropped from 100 kg per person in the 1960s to around 45 kg in the mid-1980s, as a consequence of government policy. According to Scott et al.,2 two driving forces caused the decline in potato production and consumption in Peru. First, the prices of cereals, a potato substitute, were driven to low levels by domestic subsidies and overvalued exchange rates that encouraged cereal imports. Secondly, price controls, tight credit policy and anti-middleman marketing 132
PRICES
regulations crippled the potato production and marketing industries. An economic downturn and record high potato : rice price ratios decreased potato demand. In the 1990s an economic recovery and changes in government policies allowed potato production and consumption to rebound. In developing countries cheap food policies and trade restriction policies can cause harm to domestic potato industries. When urban and industrial political interests are successful in passing laws that impose farm price ceilings, potato production will fall because of the high costs and risks of growing potatoes. When governments erect trade barriers to protect domestic industries, local demand for foreign currency falls. The resulting currency overvaluation lowers the price of imported cereals. The reduced substitute price drives down the demand for potatoes. In developed countries the same policies are important, but other types of policies come into play as well. In the United Kingdom a decades-long programme of potato market controls came to an end in the 1990s. Under the previous potato marketing scheme production quotas were used to support potato prices. When supply control failed to bring the desired prices, other tools of market intervention were used with costs shared by growers and the government. The quotas were rights to plant potatoes. Since the programme was successful, the quotas took on a value. In order to acquire the right to grow potatoes growers would lease or buy quotas, which were bid up to very high levels. According to Hinton,3 potato production was much more profitable than the production of any other crop. One indicator of the profitability was the price of potato production quotas that exceeded £2000 per hectare in some highly productive farming regions such as the Fens of East Anglia. In North America government intervention has been at a lower level. Although the US government sometimes provides diversion programmes to take potatoes off the market during low-price years, potatoes have not been among the commodities traditionally targeted for price support programmes. Grain production has been heavily supported, an action that can have an indirect affect on potato prices. Since grains are grown in rotation with potatoes, reducing the price risk for grains can tend to increase potato plantings and drive down potato prices. Potato growers who face less risk for rotation crops could feel compelled to increase plantings of potatoes, a crop for which there is a possibility of high prices. Export assistance is a government programme that can enhance potato prices. Researchers such as Topolewski4 have found that the amount of government-funded foreign advertising can boost export demand for US potato products. Consumer groups have criticized US policy that allows such government-funded export programmes because they may increase domestic potato prices. The US potato industry has been concerned with trade restrictions on potatoes going into Mexico and Canada. The complaint regarding Canada 133
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
has been about government subsidies giving the Canadian industry an unfair advantage in the US market. Canadians counter that the US government subsidizes their industry in other ways such as government irrigation projects that provide cheap irrigation water. The complaint regarding Mexico has been not about the US market, but about trade barriers against US potatoes going into Mexico. The North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) has scheduled progressive expansion and eventual elimination of potato export quotas going into Mexico, allowing its industry time to adapt. Research and education is another area of government involvement in the potato industry. According to Araji et al.,5 government investment in potato research provides very high returns on investment to society in general and to the potato industry in particular. Although private research in the potato industry is increasing, both developed and developing countries continue to invest public funds in potato research.
Market information Competitive markets operate most efficiently when buyers and sellers have access to accurate information about production, stocks, demand and prices. Farm leaders convinced government policy makers in many countries that government intervention was needed to provide market information. The rationale is that buyers could afford to collect and analyse their own proprietary market information and growers could not. In order to improve the balance of power between growers and buyers, many governments are involved in agricultural market information. Most government market information programmes focus on collecting and compiling information. Government market news reporters interview growers and industry personnel as well as conduct in-field yield surveys. The accuracy of the market information depends on grower co-operation. In some countries compliance is mandatory, while in others it is voluntary. Some co-operators try to give incorrect information in an attempt to impact prices in their favour. Most government market information agencies use other sources and methods to prevent manipulation of the system. Private organizations are also involved in market information. Large potato buyers invest in their own information systems that they do not share with others. Some grower organizations also collect information that the government does not provide but that is helpful to its members. Since most government market information is in the form of data, market analysis is up to others. Private analysts fill this gap in the potato industry with their market newsletters. Government sources provide statistics that give information about historical and current quantities and prices, but may not provide analy-
134
PRICES
sis, interpretation or forecasts. Private analysts use government statistics as a foundation for building their market reports.
Price changes through time Volatility Potato prices are volatile because the demand for potatoes is inelastic. Small changes in production can cause large changes in prices. Figure 5.6 illustrates this concept for potatoes in the UK. Although there are many other factors that influence prices, in general when potato production goes one way potato prices go in the opposite direction. A few striking examples are worth noting in the graph. First is the steep drop in production in 1975. The price response was a jump from £25 to £104 pet tonne, more than a fourfold increase in price for a 34% decrease in production. Two years later the dramatic move was repeated but in the opposite direction, when prices dropped from £133 to £43 per tonne. Subsequent increases in production
ODD tonnes 7500
£/tonne 200 Production Price
180
7000 160 6500
140 120
6000
100 5500
80 60
5000
40 4500 20 4000
0 1970 1972 1974 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998
5.6 UK potato production and prices, 1970–99. 135
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
were met with substantial decreases in price in 1984, 1988, 1992 and 1996. Price jumps in 1983, 1994 and 1998 resulted from drops in production. The UK market was quite a roller-coaster, but that is not uncommon in potato markets. Of particular interest is that the UK market was under serious government regulation during the 1970s and 1980s when the roller-coaster effect was quite pronounced. The vagaries of weather and its influence on potato supplies would seem to complicate analysis of potato prices through time. Although potato prices are indeed difficult to predict, many analysts believe that historical patterns of price movement can help predict prices in the future.Three types of price movement through time – trends, cycles and seasonal variation – are discussed here.
Trends Perhaps the most apparent feature of the potato price line in Fig. 5.6 is the volatility. A second feature that is readily noticed is the upward trend. Placing a ruler on the low price points or the high price points shows the increasing trend of British potato prices during the 1970–98 period. Statistical analysis shows that the trend is an average increase of £2.83 per year. What causes trends in general and the upward trend for British potatoes in particular? It might be useful to remember the demand shifters and supply shifters. A trend in any of the four demand shifters – population, income, prices of other goods, and tastes and preferences – could cause such a trend. Although the population of the UK grew during this period, it grew at a very slow rate of well under 1% per year. The other three demand shifters could have separately or collectively caused the upward trend. Supply shifter patterns could also be involved. One likely candidate is the ‘prices of other goods’ demand shifter. The price pattern for US potatoes is used to illustrate the importance of the ‘other goods’factor. Figure 5.7 shows a half-century of US potato prices that are different from the British prices in Fig. 5.6 by one important factor – they have been deflated by the consumer price index. The result is that after adjusting for inflation, or the prices of all other goods, US potato prices trend downward. The slope of the trend line is minus $0.11 per year expressed in 1983 dollars. Potatoes, especially at the grower level, should be considered commodities. A fundamental economic principle is that commodity prices trend downward. In relation to prices of other goods and services, which benefit from value-added manufacturing and branded advertising, farm-level commodities lose value through time. A contributing factor to this downward trend in potato prices is the technology supply shifter. As new yield-enhancing technology is developed and adopted by 136
PRICES $ 16.00
14.00
12.00
10.00
8.00
6.00
4.00
2.00
0.00 1950 1954 1958 1962 1966 1970 1974 1978 1982 1986 1990 1994 1998
5.7 United States potato price trend, 1950–99, (1983 dollars).
growers, more potatoes can be produced on a given area of land. This force brings down per unit costs and because markets are competitive, prices come down as well. Another observation about Fig. 5.7 is that US potato price volatility lessened during the later years. During the 1990s prices did not vacillate about the trend line as much as during the earlier decades. Expanded use of contracts, including multi-year contracts, may explain some of the reduced volatility.
Cycles Price cycles are well documented for some agricultural commodities. North American beef cattle prices reliably follow a 10- to 12-year cycle. The pattern has to do with producer responses to current prices. A high cattle price encourages producers to retain breeding stock and build up their herds. After a time lag the increased production brings down prices, causing producers to liquidate breeding stock and reduce production. This causes prices to rise again, completing the cycle. Owing to the multi-year time lag between the 137
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
decision to change production and the actual change in production the cattle cycle may be more reliable than a cycle for an annual crop like potatoes. A fundamental question is whether crop cycles are self-generating or caused by external events. An external event, like an early frost that cuts potato production, could start a cycle. Prices rise owing to the reduced supply, encouraging growers to expand production. The increase in supply then causes prices to go down, encouraging a cutback in production. The reduced supply then leads to high prices and the end of the cycle. The lack of another external event could cause the cyclical pattern to stop.The opposing hypothesis is that the cycles would continue to repeat, not because of biology or weather but because of human behaviour. Analysis of the price peaks in the British potato prices in Fig. 5.6 suggests a possible price cycle of several years. From the first peak in 1972 the next peak is four years later in 1976. Peaks recur in the following pattern of years between peaks: 3, 2, 2, 3, 3, 2 and 3. We do not know from the graph if 1998 is a true peak. During the 1970–98 period there are four cycles of two years, three cycles of three years and one cycle of four years. The graph of US prices shows a similar, but longer pattern of the following number of years between peaks: 2, 2, 3, 5, 4, 5, 2, 5, 3, 3, 3, 4, 2 and 2. The summary is five cycles of two years, four cycles of three years, two cycles of four years and three cycles of five years. The wide range of possible cycles from two years to five years makes it difficult to use cyclical patterns to predict prices.
Seasonal variation Prices for some commodities follow a pattern that is completed every 12 months. Price movements of this sort are called seasonal because they change with the season of the year. Seasonal patterns in supply or demand are the root causes of seasonal price patterns. For agricultural commodities biology and weather play important roles. Potato production in most regions consists of only one crop grown each year. Seasonal patterns develop from the weather-related supply situation of only one harvest per year of a perishable crop. Weather also plays a role in seasonal demand for potatoes. In temperate climates consumers prefer a different type of potato product during the hot summer months than during the cold winter months. While on summer holiday they are more likely to eat frozen potato products served at fast-food restaurants. In the winter they are more likely to buy fresh potatoes for at-home meal preparation. Seasonal price patterns are seen for grower-level prices in both the fresh and processed potato markets (Fig. 5.8). One observation is the upward trend in prices after October. Most US growers harvest potatoes in the fall, 138
PRICES £/cwt 9
8 Fresh market: Processed market: 7
6
5
4
0 Aug
Sep
Oct
Nov
Dec
Jan
Feb
Mar
Apr
May
Jun
Jul
5.8 United States fresh and processed potato monthly average prices, 1986–98.
and October is the month during which most of the fall crop is harvested. As one would expect the monthly average price is lowest in October, when potatoes in the US are most abundant. Growers who lack adequate storage will sell potatoes off the field in October, avoiding storage costs. Growers who choose to store potatoes are, of course, concerned about covering the costs of storage. On the average, growers must receive progressively higher prices during the storage season or they will get out of the storage business. The graph for fresh potato prices reflects the costs of storage, with average prices rising every month from October through July. Although some growers store potatoes into the following August, the majority of US potatoes sold then are from the new crop. Since most fall-crop growers harvest few potatoes in August, the relative scarcity puts August average prices well above prices in September and October when harvest becomes more active. The highest prices are in July when some Western growers still have old-crop potatoes in storage and growers in several regions harvest new potatoes. The graph for processed potato prices has two distinguishing characteristics. First, it is lower than the fresh potato graph. Secondly, it is less 139
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
steep. Grade differences explain some of the differences in price levels. Much of the fresh product is sold as US No. 1 grade. Potatoes that do not make grade for the fresh market because they are too small, misshapen or damaged are diverted to dehydrated processing at prices much lower than in the fresh market. Frozen and snack processors often buy directly from the growers at terms for grades US No. 2 or lower. Another factor is that in some states the growers are also the packers, and what are reported as growerlevel prices are actually shipper-level prices that include the value added through washing, sorting and packaging. There are several possible explanations for the processed graph being less steep than the fresh graph. Processors offer two types of contracts to growers – harvest-time and storage. Storage contracts include a schedule of increasing prices to account for storage costs. Growers who sign storage contracts forgo the opportunity of open-market price increases but eliminate the risk of prices going down. With a guaranteed price increase, even if it does not cover the full costs of storage, many growers chose to lock in a contracted storage return. Depending on their attitudes toward risk, processed growers with storage contracts may have more of an incentive to store than do fresh market growers who face the risk of prices going down. When fewer fresh growers choose to take on the risk of late-season storage, those who do are rewarded with higher open-market prices. The gap between the fresh and processed graphs later in the storage season is partially explained by the risk factor, but there are some other explanations as well. One is the Western tradition of marketing a large volume of dehydration-grade potatoes in the spring, which can skew downward the average processed prices during that time. Another is that snack processors, whose factories are scattered around the country near big cities, rely on potatoes harvested during the winter, spring and summer. Although frozen processors rely heavily on storage potatoes, year-round sales off the field to snack processors tend to dampen the seasonal upward trend in processed potato prices. The fresh price graph shows an average price increase from $5.16 per cwt in October to $7.55 in June to $8.65 in July, giving growers average returns of $2.39 and $3.49 per cwt respectively for storing into those two months. Many growers can store potatoes at costs less than those amounts, but risk is an important factor. First, there is the risk of quality deterioration when attempting to store potatoes for eight or nine months. Storage growers with old-crop potatoes that have been slowly losing quality face competition from high-quality new-crop potatoes. Second is the risk of prices in any particular year not rising enough to cover storage costs. Although storage can be profitable on the average, it can be a money loser in some years.
140
PRICES
Price forecasting Technical analysis Some market analysts pay little attention to the analysis of fundamentals – i.e. supply and demand. Problems they cite with fundamental analysis include: (1) nobody can know all the facts; (2) information is subject to error; (3) facts change continually; (4) buyers and sellers may deliberately give false information; and (5) the influence of each bit of information is not known. Instead they prefer to use something called technical analysis. People make markets. Human emotion – such as fear and greed – may influence markets more than fundamentals. For example, when prices are going up many farmers expect them to continue to go up. Prices do not necessarily depend on facts, but rather on what people believe the facts to be. Since the 1920s there has been a large group of technical traders. Technical analysis can be defined as ‘a study of market action with the purpose of determining probable price change’. The working tool of market technicians is the chart. For this reason they are also known as chartists. To forecast prices, technicians analyse historical price patterns and the strength of buying or selling pressures. An actively traded commodity, such as some futures markets, is needed for technical analysis. Chart forecasting consists of recognizing formations that have been associated with historical price movements. One of the primary formations that chartists look for is a trend. Chartists recognize that commodity prices tend to trade in channels. The top line of channels is called resistance. The bottom line is called support. A breakout is when the price crosses a channel line. Some trend-following rules are that prices are frequently in sideways channels, down trends usually turn into sideways trends and up trends often turn suddenly into down trends. Volume and open interest measure the activity coming into and leaving a market. Volume is the number of trades on a particular day. There is often a positive correlation between price and volume. However, a rapid increase in volume following a substantial up trend can signal that the trend may end. Open interest is the number of positions that have not been liquidated by delivery or an offsetting trade. It is not the same as volume. A high-volume day may have no impact on open interest. Open interest changes when old positions are liquidated or new positions are taken. Volume and open interest can often detect market activity that traders do not want known. For example, exporters often establish positions in the futures market before announcing a new export deal. Technical analysts use a variety of price movement formations to help forecast prices. One is the head and shoulders pattern. This is the oldest
141
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
and perhaps most reliable trend reversal pattern. The traditional head and shoulders shape can occur at the top of the market. At the bottom of the market the shape is an inverse head and shoulders. A rule of thumb is that once the neckline is broken the subsequent move will at least equal the distance from the top of the head to the neckline. Other commonly used formations include flags, pennants, triangles, gaps, saucers, bowls and double tops or bottoms. Analysts have developed numerous rules for detecting and responding to chart formations. Since many traders use similar computer systems, charts have a tendency to become self-fulfilling prophecies. Some market observers claim that charts work because chartists make them work. Pure technicians ignore fundamentals. They reason that the supply and demand information will be incorporated into the market and that they can observe it there. The key is when market information becomes public knowledge. Technicians believe they can tell from the charts when prices are going to move, for whatever reason, before the information becomes public. By the time everyone has the information, those with inside knowledge and the chartists have already responded. Where potato futures markets exist, technical analysis may be a useful price-forecasting tool. As mentioned earlier, potato futures markets are available in Europe, but have gone defunct in North America. During some earlier periods when potato futures were traded in North America, technical analysts actively traded them.
Fundamental analysis Technical analysts rely on human psychology to predict prices, while fundamental analysts rely on supply and demand economics. Although there is some crossover between the disciplines of psychology and economics, the philosophies of technical and fundamental analysts are quite different. Technicians say that supply and demand analysis doesn’t matter but fundamentalists say it is all that matters. Fundamental analysts try to account for the supply and demand factors that influence price. They want to be aware of the changes in the four demand shifters and seven supply shifters and how each change will impact on prices. Analysts who are mathematically inclined build econometric models to explain the economic interrelationships of a market. They use historical data and statistical analysis techniques to build equations that can be used to forecast prices. Models can be complex multiple equation systems with hundreds of variables or single-equations with a few variables. One University of Idaho researcher built an econometric model to forecast monthly Idaho potato prices. Nuesca6 built forecasting equations to 142
PRICES
predict Idaho grower-level open-market potato prices in the months of October to July. She included the following as explanatory variables: Idaho potato production, US frozen potato stocks, US winter potato production, US spring potato production, Idaho October potato price, Idaho potato stocks in storage, US potato stocks in storage, Idaho harvest progress and Idaho crop quality. Nuesca also developed models to forecast values of the explanatory variables. She found that the model performed well with outof-sample forecasts. The Nuesca model, which consists of 19 equations and 24 variables, is one example of a complex econometric model. An example of an accurate but simple model comes from an independent potato market analyst, Bruce Huffaker, whose North American Potato Market News has a wide subscription base in the potato industry. Huffaker calculates an ‘Idaho grower return index’ (IGRI) price series, which he designed to depict grower returns for a fixed-quality lot of potatoes. Since shipper prices are reported more consistently than grower prices, the IGRI provides a valuable price series for market analysis. Huffaker forecasts future values of IGRI based on changes in potato supply. For example, he forecasts IGRI for May based on changes in US potato stocks for the first of January. This simple one-explanatory-variable model explains 77% of the change in the May IGRI and may be more accurate than complex models with many variables. Since Huffaker has pinpointed the main determinant of the Idaho grower potato price, the model need not be more complicated. Analysts build econometric models to quantify the impacts of forces that affect potato prices. The equations can help provide insight into the complexities of potato markets. There are several drawbacks, however. First, econometric models are built on historical data and therefore may not be good at predicting the future as technology and market structure change. Secondly, the models are limited by the availability of historical data. Important information that could help predict prices may not be available from either public or private sources. Third is the difficulty of predicting future values of explanatory variables. To forecast future values of one variable, potato price, the analyst takes on the challenge of forecasting future values of all the important factors that affect that price.
References 1 H Fraser, Fraser’s Potato Newsletter, Charlottetown, PEI, Canada. 2 G Scott, M Rosegrant and C Ringler, Roots and Tubers for the 21st Century, Lima, Peru, International Potato Center, 2000. 3 L Hinton, Potatoes in Surplus, Occasional Papers no. 37, Cambridge University, Department of Land Economy, 1987. 143
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY 4
M Topolewski, ‘Impact of the fast food industry and advertising on US frozen french fry demand’, MS thesis, Moscow, Idaho, University of Idaho, 1997. 5 J Araji, F White and J Guenthner, ‘Returns from potato research: accounting for state and regional effects’, Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics, 1995 20:2. 6 M Nuesca, ‘Forecasting Idaho open-market potato prices’, MS thesis, Moscow, Idaho, University of Idaho, 1992.
144
PA RT
III THE TRADE
CHAPTER
6 Fresh potato trade
W
orld fresh potato trade is expanding. According to the United Nations,1 in the late 1990s the total value of fresh potato exports was bouncing around $1.5 to $2.0 billion (Fig. 6.1). The value of fresh potato exports has shown an upward but volatile trend since the late 1960s. The volatility of fresh potato value is tied to price variability. In 1993 fresh export value plummeted, based partly on a price drop from $0.20 to $0.17 per kg. Two years later, in 1995, the world potato price was at a record high of $0.31 per kg. Fresh export value also reached a record in 1995, increasing from $1.3 billion to $2.3 billion in two years. During the 1990s the year-to-year variation around the trend line was much larger than during earlier periods such as 1963–75. During the 1960s fresh potato export value was stable in the range of $180 million to $240 million. By 1975 exports exceeded $500 million, more than double the level of six years earlier in 1969. In the very next year, 1975, exports jumped above one billion dollars for the first time. Twenty years later, the $2 billion level was reached. The trend line in Fig. 6.1 indicates that fresh exports are increasing at the rate of about $50 million per year. If that trend continues fresh potato export value will reach $3 billion in 2023. Although fresh potatoes are bulky, perishable products that are expensive to transport, some producers have developed reliable markets in other 147
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY $2,500
$2,000
$1,500
$1,000
$500
$0 1963
1966
1969
1972
1975
1978
1981
1984
1987
1990
1993
1996 1999
6.1 Value of world fresh potato exports, 1963–99 ($ million) (FAO, United Nations).
countries. Consumers in some countries have come to rely on foreign potatoes, especially during certain seasons when domestic potatoes are scarce or of a different type. Many countries are both exporters and importers, with the net trade varying throughout the year. This chapter discovers who are the main players as well as what are some of the main issues in the international fresh potato market.
Fresh potato exports Fresh potatoes are traded across international borders all over the globe, but 70% of the export value came from European countries in 1999 (Fig. 6.2). The next largest exporting region was North and Central America at 13%, followed by Asia at 10%. On a global scale Oceania and South American fresh potato exports were relatively insignificant at one percent each. This does not suggest that potato production and consumption are unimportant in
148
FRESH POTATO TRADE
Asia 10%
S America 1% Africa Oceania 1% N & C America 5% 13%
Europe 70%
6.2 Fresh potato export value shares by continent, 1999 (FAO, United Nations).
Oceania and South America, but rather that the major fresh potato exporters are in other parts of the world. Fresh potato export data reveals three centres for export: northwest Europe, North America and the Mediterranean region. One-half of the 20 largest fresh potato-exporting countries are in Europe (Table 6.1). The four largest exporters – Netherlands, France, Belgium-Luxembourg and Germany – accounted for an average of $849 million of annual exports during the 1997–99 period. These four countries are in a contiguous belt of potato production in northwest Europe. By including North Sea neighbours the United Kingdom, the seventh largest exporter, and Denmark at number 14, the group exported nearly one billion dollars’ ($960 million) worth of fresh potato exports from this region each year. This group of six countries, all in a productive temperate growing zone, accounted for more than half the world’s potato exports during the late 1990s. The second region of export concentration is North America, with Canada and the United States holding fifth and sixth place respectively on the top 20 list. Together they accounted for nearly $200 million of fresh potato exports each year. Mexico and the Central American countries do not appear among the top 20. Canadian and US potato-producing regions are mostly in temperate zones with fall harvest and long storage seasons. The third centre of potato export activity is the Mediterranean region. The potato production zone named for this region features dry summers and cool, humid winters, with the coldest month averaging between 0°C and
149
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY Table 6.1
Top 20 fresh potato-exporting countries, 1997–99 average
Country 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20
Netherlands France Belgium-Luxembourg Germany Canada USA United Kingdom Italy Spain Egypt Israel Morocco Turkey Denmark Cyprus Syrian Arab Republic Belarus Pakistan China Poland
Value ($ million) 355 236 141 117 105 90 86 84 71 44 30 27 25 25 23 19 17 12 9 9
Region
Trade centre
Europe Europe Europe Europe N America N America Europe Europe Europe Africa Asia Africa Asia Europe Asia Asia Europe Asia Asia Europe
North Sea North Sea North Sea North Sea N America N America North Sea Mediterranean Mediterranean Mediterranean Mediterranean Mediterranean Mediterranean North Sea Mediterranean Mediterranean – – – –
Source: FAO, United Nations Trade centre accounts for three concentrated regions of fresh potato trade. A blank means that the country does not fit into one of the centre categories Cyprus is reported in the region assigned by the source
10°C. Italy, Spain, Egypt, Israel, Morocco and Turkey, which hold places eight to 13 on the top 20 list, all border the Mediterranean Sea. Adding Cyprus and Syria, in fifteenth and sixteenth places, gives a group of eight countries with Mediterranean ports that are quite active in fresh potato exports. Collectively they accounted for an annual average $331 million in potato exports during the late 1990s. Perhaps the opportunity to ship potatoes by sea is an important factor in the development of both the Mediterranean and northwest Europe centres for fresh potato exports. The top 20 export list includes countries from four continents: Africa, Asia, Europe and North America. The largest fresh potato-exporting countries from each of the four continents are Egypt, Israel, Netherlands and Canada. Values of fresh potato exports from each of these four countries for the 1961–99 period are given in Fig. 6.3. The Netherlands stands well above the other three countries, but its export values are quite volatile, especially during the 1990s. An example of the whipsaw pattern is the two-year extremes of the 1991–97 period. In 1991 Dutch fresh potato exports were 150
FRESH POTATO TRADE $m 600 Canada 500
Egypt Israel Netherlands
400
300
200
100
0 1961 1964 1967 1970 1973 1976 1979 1982 1985 1988 1991 1994 1997
6.3 Fresh potato export values for selected countries, 1961–99 ($ million) (FAO, United Nations).
at $527 million, then two years later dropped to $330 million. Two years after that, in 1995, export value leaped to $631 million. Following the pattern of the previous two-year cycle, exports dropped to $299 million in 1997. A similar, though dampened, pattern of fresh potato export values occurred in the other three countries graphed in Fig. 6.3. Export values in Egypt, Israel and the Netherlands usually went in the same direction, with rises in 1976, 1982, 1991 and 1995 and drops in 1978, 1985 and 1997. The fourth country, Canada, sometimes followed the patterns of the others but at times moved in the opposite direction. Prices in Netherlands, Egypt and Israel are linked by location. The shipping distance and costs are much lower in those countries bordering the Mediterranean and North Sea than between any of them and Canada, far across the Atlantic. General potato price levels in the region influence export values, but the location and strength of potato demand in importing countries are also important factors. Next we look at which countries have been importing fresh potatoes. 151
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
Fresh potato imports Europe dominates fresh potato imports, with 67% of global import value going into that region (Fig. 6.4). That figure is only slightly less than the 70% of fresh potato exports that originate in Europe. The import–export shares of the other continents are also similar. This similarity suggests that the exporting countries’customers are mostly on the same continent. Since fresh potatoes are bulky and highly perishable, shipping long distances to other continents may not be done as regularly as with grain or processed potato products. European countries made up 13 of the top 20 fresh potato-importing countries during the 1997–99 period (Table 6.2). Five of the North Sea countries – Germany, the United Kingdom, Netherlands, Belgium-Luxembourg and France – are in the top seven as they were in the top seven for fresh potato exports. Including the eighteenth and nineteenth countries on the import list, Denmark and Ireland, the North Sea band of nations accounts for an annual average of $704 million in fresh potato imports. This is $221 million less 935 million of exports (Table 6.1) from the top six North Sea nations. Although there is much trade between the North Sea countries, the $221 million gap means that they export to other countries as well. Some of the fresh potatoes undoubtedly go to other European countries, both within and outside the European Union. The North American fresh potato centre includes the United States at number eight and Canada at number nine on the list. Together they imported
N & C America 12%
S America Africa 2% 8% Asia 11%
Europe 67%
6.4 Fresh potato import value shares by continent, 1997–99 average (FAO, United Nations). 152
FRESH POTATO TRADE Table 6.2
Top 20 fresh potato-importing countries, 1997–99 average
Country 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20
Germany United Kingdom Netherlands Belgium-Luxembourg Spain Italy France USA Canada Portugal Algeria Greece Egypt Russian Federation Sri Lanka United Arab Emirates Malaysia Denmark Ireland Austria
Value ($ million) 161 141 137 133 119 98 96 92 63 47 45 37 33 24 23 21 20 19 16 16
Continent
Trade centre
Europe Europe Europe Europe Europe Europe Europe N America N America Europe Africa Europe Africa Europe Asia Asia Asia Europe Europe Europe
North Sea North Sea North Sea North Sea Mediterranean Mediterranean North Sea N America N America – Mediterranean Mediterranean Mediterranean – – – – North Sea North Sea –
Source: FAO, United Nations Trade centre accounts for three concentrated regions of fresh potato trade. A blank means that the country does not fit into one of the centre categories.
an annual average of $155 million worth of fresh potatoes during the late 1990s. This is $40 million less than the $195 million of exports (Table 6.1), making the centre a net exporter. Five of the countries on the top 20 import list are included in the Mediterranean trade centre region. Spain and Italy are in spots five and six. Algeria, Greece and Egypt occupy numbers 11 to 13. These five countries imported an average of $331 million of fresh potatoes during the late 1990s. The top 20 Mediterranean importing countries, although fewer at five against eight, import nearly the same as the annual export amount of $325 million. At first glance it appears that another possible fresh potato trade centre could be Asia, with Sri Lanka, United Arab Emirates and Malaysia ranked 15 to 17. Although they are all considered Asian countries the large distances that separate them make a common potato trade centre very improbable. The three countries probably import from different exporting nations. Although the FAO data do not have the detail to confirm the hypothesis, Sri Lanka’s proximity to the booming potato industry in the Indo-Gangetic 153
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
Plain makes it a likely customer for fresh potatoes exported from India and Pakistan. The top 20 list includes countries from four continents. The top importing countries within each continent are Algeria in Africa, Germany in Europe, Sri Lanka in Asia and the United States in North America. A graph of the export values for each during the 1961–99 period is given in Fig. 6.5. One observation is that Germany’s imports were consistently much larger than the others. German imports were under $100 million during the 1960s and early 1970s, then jumped into the $100 million to $260 million range during the mid-1970s and late 1980s. During the 1990s import value volatility increased, with annual figures varying from $150 million to more than $400 million. The German export graph shows a familiar cyclical pattern that was discussed for potato prices in the United Kingdom in Chapter 5. From a peak in 1962 the graph moved in the following pattern of years between value peaks: 3, 5, 3, 3, 4, 2, 2, 3, 4, 4 and 3. Although quantities also affect export values, it appears that the cyclical price patterns common in fresh potato markets create a similar cyclical pattern in European potato trade. The cycli-
$m 450 400
Algeria
350
Germany Sri Lanka USA
300 250 200 150 100 50 0 1961 1964 1967 1970 1973 1976 1979 1982 1985 1988 1991 1994 1997
6.5 Fresh potato import values for selected countries, 1961–99 ($ million) (FAO, United Nations). 154
FRESH POTATO TRADE
cal pattern may be in force in Africa and North America as well. The Algerian values peaked on a 4, 3 and 2 year pattern during the 1990s. The United States pattern was 4, 2 and 2 years during the same period. The situation in Sri Lanka appears more stable, but as that market matures it may develop a cyclical pattern.
Net trade for fresh potatoes Fifteen countries are on the top 20 lists for both fresh potato exports and fresh potato imports. These countries that are active on both sides of the market are listed in Table 6.3 according to their rank in terms of net trade. For this purpose net trade is defined simply as the total value of fresh potato exports minus the total value of fresh potato imports. At the top of the net trade list is the Netherlands. For the 1997–99 period the average annual Dutch net trade for fresh potatoes was $218 million. Another North Sea country, France, is in second place at $140 million. Other North Sea countries with a positive net trade are Belgium-Luxembourg and Denmark. Trade balances were negative in Germany and the United Kingdom.
Table 6.3
Net potato trade for selected countries, 1997–99
Country 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15
Netherlands France Canada Morocco Egypt Belgium-Luxembourg Denmark USA Lebanon Austria Italy Portugal Germany Spain United Kingdom
Value ($ million) 218 140 42 14 12 8 6 -2 -10 -10 -13 -40 -45 -49 -56
Continent
Trade centre
Europe Europe N America Africa Africa Europe Europe N America Asia Europe Europe Europe Europe Europe Europe
North Sea North Sea N America Mediterranean Mediterranean North Sea North Sea N America Mediterranean – Mediterranean – North Sea Mediterranean North Sea
Source: FAO, United Nations Selected countries were in the top 20 for both imports and exports Value = export values minus import values
155
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
The overall net trade for the North Sea countries in the table is a positive $273 million. For these six North Sea countries collectively, their fresh potato exports were larger than imports. One reason is that the North Sea zone is a temperate production zone with autumn harvest and a long storage season. With a year-round supply of potatoes, exporters in these countries have opportunities to serve potato markets in other countries where the fresh potato supply is more limited. Mediterranean fresh potato countries deal with the North Sea countries in both imports and exports. Although Morocco and Egypt at numbers four and five on the list have fresh potato trade surpluses, Italy and Spain have large deficits. Overall, for the five Mediterranean countries in the list the trade deficit is $46 million per year. This suggests that the lack of year-round fresh potato supplies in some of the Mediterranean countries creates an opportunity for exporting countries in the North Sea region. Some Mediterranean countries, such as Morocco and Egypt, may actually operate a trade deficit for more months than they have a surplus situation. The large volume of new potatoes shipped to European countries during a relatively narrow market window can more than offset fresh potato imports during the rest of the year. The trade in new potatoes in the UK is illustrated in Fig. 6.6. In all of the years new potato imports are larger than exports. One extreme example mt 1000
800
Imports Exports
750 700 650 600 550 500 450 0
1977
1980
1983
1986
1989
1992
1995
6.6 New potato trade in the UK, 1970–98 (1000 mt) (FAO, United Nations). 156
1998
FRESH POTATO TRADE
is in 1983 when the UK exported 28 000 metric tonnes and imported nearly 14 times that amount, 384 000 metric tonnes. The trend in the 1990s was a narrowing of the trade gap. In 1998 new potato imports were 246 000 metric tonnes and exports were 160 000 metric tonnes, a difference of 86 000 metric tonnes. The market window during which the British potato market takes new potato imports is shown in Fig. 6.7. The peak month is in June, when nearly a quarter of the total annual volume enters the UK. This is a time when only a few British potato producers can harvest new potatoes, and old-crop potatoes have lost consumer appeal following the long period in storage. July is also a strong month at 20% of the annual total. The threemonth period of May, June and July accounted for nearly two-thirds of the new potatoes imported. During the three-month period of August, September and October British imports of new potatoes are shut down because of the abundance of domestic new potatoes. Imports gradually increase during the following six months. The source countries for the new potato imports into the UK during the 1992–93 marketing season and their share of the total are:2 Belgium 1%,
% 30
25
20
15
10
5
0 Jun
Jul
Aug
Sep
Oct
Nov
Dec
Jan
Feb
Mar
Apr
6.7 UK new potato imports by month, 1992–93 (Potato Marketing Board). 157
May
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY
Channel Islands 26%, Cyprus 37%, Egypt 25%, France 6%, Greece 3%, Italy 4%, Portugal 1%, Spain/Canary Islands 3%, and other countries 1%. All of these new potato exporters were able to provide new potatoes during the critical May, June and July period when the British new potato market window is open for large amounts of imports. Two Mediterranean countries, Cyprus and Egypt, together made up 62% of total new potato imports. The new potato import pattern in the UK may be typical of trade between the Mediterranean area and the North Sea area. The flow of fresh potatoes from the Mediterranean is mostly new potatoes during the spring and early summer. There does not seem to be a reciprocal flow of fresh potatoes in the other direction during the rest of the year, at least not in similar volumes. During the same 1992–93 marketing season the UK’s main customers for fresh potatoes in rank order were: Canary Islands 50%, Ireland 27%, Sweden 4%, Belgium-Luxembourg 3%, and Germany, Portugal and Spain all at 2%. Cyprus and Egypt, the two largest sources of new potatoes in the UK, do not appear on its fresh potato destination list. Fresh potato exports from the Netherlands show a pattern of potato movement mostly to nearby neighbours. The top customers in rank order for the 1999–2000 marketing season were: Belgium/Luxembourg 44%, Germany 30%, United Kingdom 6%, Italy 4%, Africa 4%, Asia 3% and America 3%.
Fresh potato prices World fresh potato export prices are on an upward trend (Fig. 6.8). Currency exchange rates play an important role in potato pricing. Many international fresh potato trades deals are made with only two currencies – the money of the importing country and the money of the exporting country. Since currency exchange rates fluctuate daily, it is challenging to express world prices for any good in one currency, especially one that may not have been involved in most transactions. Recognizing the limitations, Fig. 6.8 uses the United States dollar as the single measure of value. The upward trend for the 1963–99 period is rather steep, running from a bit above $0.06 per kg in 1963 to $0.25 per kg in 1999. The trend line slope is an increase of about $0.005 per year. Actual fluctuations about the trend line have given prices as low as $0.05 per kg in 1964 to as high as $0.31 per kg in 1995. Two prominent price spikes are evident in the graph – the 1995 price as well as the 1976 price, which jumped to $0.25 per kg from $0.15 the previous year. The world fresh potato export prices given in Fig. 6.8 do not account for inflation. Deflating the prices with the United States consumer price 158
FRESH POTATO TRADE US$/kg 0.35
0.30
0.25
0.20
0.15
0.10
0.05
0.00 1963
1966
1969
1972
1975
1978
1981
1984
1987
1990
1993
1996
1999
6.8 World fresh potato export prices, 1963–99 (US$/kg) (FAO, United Nations).
index gives a graph of a very different pattern (Fig. 6.9). The price trend for deflated prices is slightly downward, with a slope of -$0.002 per year. This is confirmation of the economic principle, discussed in Chapter 5, that commodity prices trend downward. Deflating by the CPI accounts for changes in prices of other goods and services. After accounting for changing price levels, fresh potato prices go down in the long run. Apparently fresh potato exporters have not been able to differentiate their product. Fresh potatoes in the global market are indeed a commodity, with the inherent downward price trend that is associated with all commodities. Commodity pricing does not mean that there are no differences between fresh potato-exporting regions. Table 6.4 shows fresh potato import and export prices for six geographic regions as well as developed and developing countries. Prices in the ‘Exports’column are quite similar, ranging from $0.19 per kg in South America to $0.25 per kg in Oceania. The differences in the import column are much larger, ranging from $0.21 per kg in South America to $0.44 per kg in Africa. The high import prices in Africa and Oceania stand out from the others. In Africa the import prices are double the export prices. Another striking difference is the gap between import 159
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY US$/kg 0.50 0.45 0.40 0.35 0.30 0.25 0.20 0.15 0.10 0.05 0.00 1963
1966
1969
1972
1975
1978
1981
1984
1987
1990
1993
6.9 World fresh potato export prices, 1963–99, deflated (1983 US$/kg) (FAO, United Nations).
Table 6.4 Fresh potato export and import prices by region, 1999 Imports
Exports
$0.44 $0.27 $0.24 $0.27 $0.38 $0.21 $0.24 $0.33
$0.22 $0.22 $0.23 $0.25 $0.25 $0.19 $0.23 $0.21
Africa Asia Europe N & C America Oceania South America Developed countries Developing countries Source: FAO, United Nations
160
1996
1999
FRESH POTATO TRADE
prices in developed countries, $0.24 per kg, and developing countries, $0.33 per kg. The highest fresh potato import prices in the world are paid in places in Africa and other developing regions where hunger is a serious problem.
Fresh potato trade issues Governments set up trade barriers for a variety of reasons. One primary reason is to protect domestic industries. Several basic types of tools are used to restrict imports. One is a tariff, which imposes a percentage or per unit tax on imported goods. Tariffs raise the price of imported goods, making them less competitive with the locally produced product. Another tool is a quota, which imposes a ceiling on the amount of product that can be imported. Some quota systems include a tariff that is triggered when certain quota amounts have been met. A third type of trade barrier is government subsidies of the domestic industry putting it at a competitive advantage over foreign industries. A fourth type of restriction is called non-tariff barriers to trade. An example is a plant health quarantine against a particular region, in an effort to reduce the risk of the domestic potato crop being exposed to a new pest problem. Trade barriers in general may be applied to all countries or selected countries. Trade arrangements with regional or political interests are commonly done to allow favoured treatment to certain nations. Trade barriers of all types have been used to restrict potato trade. In this section we provide further discussion of three issues – tariffs, phytosanitary restrictions and trade disputes.
Tariffs The World Trade Organization (WTO) is a global entity consisting of 140 member nations (as of 30 November 2000) that deals with terms of international trade. In the Uruguay Round of negotiations in 1994, members agreed to reduce trade barriers over a six-year period (1995–2000) for developed nations and a 10-year period (1995–2004) for developing nations. In addition to reductions in subsidies the agreement called for replacement of quotas with tariffs. In developed countries tariffs were scheduled to decrease an average of 36% for all agricultural products and a minimum of 15% for individual agricultural products. In developing countries the targeted tariff cuts are 24% and 10%, respectively. Some nations chose to make deeper cuts than the minimum. The tariff reductions are phased in equal annual increments.3 Fresh potato tariffs for selected countries at both the beginning and the end of the tariff-reduction period are given in Table 6.5. All the listed nations 161
THE INTERN ATION AL POTATO INDUSTRY Table 6.5
Fresh potato tariffs in selected countries
Country
Egypt Morocco Namibia South Africa Swaziland Tunisia Bangladesh China Indonesia Israel Japan Philippines South Korea Sri Lanka Thailand Turkey Hungary Romania European Union New potatoes 1 Jan–14 May New potatoes 15 May–31 Oct Other Canada Mexico United States Australia New Zealand Argentina Brazil South America Venezuela
Base rate
Bound rate
15% 45% 77% 77% 77% 200% 200% 50% 90% 270% 5% 100% 338% 66% 139% 25% 52% 200%
10% 34% 49% 49% 49% 150% 150% 40% 50% 230% 4.3% 40% 304% 50% 125% 19.3% 44.2% 180%
15% 21% 18% 7.72 c/kg $354/t, but