Lecture Notes in Mathematics A collection of informal reports and seminars Edited by A. Dold, Heidelberg and B. Eckmann,...
27 downloads
740 Views
4MB Size
Report
This content was uploaded by our users and we assume good faith they have the permission to share this book. If you own the copyright to this book and it is wrongfully on our website, we offer a simple DMCA procedure to remove your content from our site. Start by pressing the button below!
Report copyright / DMCA form
Lecture Notes in Mathematics A collection of informal reports and seminars Edited by A. Dold, Heidelberg and B. Eckmann, Z0rich
263 T. Parthasarathy Indian Statistical Institute, Calcutta/India
Selection Theorems and their Applications
Springer-Verlag Berlin. Heidelberg. New York 1972
A M S S u b j e c t Classifications (1970): 49 A 35, 54 C 65, 90 D 15
I S B N 3-540-05818-4 S p r i n g e r - V e r l a g B e r l i n • H e i d e l b e r g . N e w Y o r k I S B N 0-387-05818-4 S p r i n g e r - V e r l a g N e w Y o r k • H e i d e l b e r g • B e r l i n This work is subject to copyright. All rights are reserved, whether the whole or part of the material is concerned, specifically those of translation, reprinting, re-use of illustrations, broadcasting, reproduction by photocopying machine or similar means, and storage in data banks. Under § 54 of the German Copyright Law where copies are made for other than private use, a fee is payable to the publisher, the amount of the fee to be determined by agreement with the publisher. © by Springer-Verlag Berlin • Heidelberg 1972. Library of Congress Catalog Card Number 72-78192. Printed in Germany. Offsetdruck: Julius Beltz, Hemsbach/Bergstr.
PREFACE
This volume of lecture notes contains results on selection theorems and their applications.
Some of the material of this volume had been
given as seminar talks at Case Western Reserve University during ]969 - 1970. This volume contains nine sections each of them followed by selected references.
We hope this volume will be profitable to
specialists in game theory, dynamic programming,
control theory, mathe-
matical economics as well as to all mathematicians
interested in this
area of Mathematics. I wish to express my sincere thanks to the following Professors: Henry Hermes, Marc Jacobs, Ashok Maitra and Sam Nadler Jr., for several useful suggestions. A particular measure of gratitude is due to Mr. Arun Das who patiently and accurately prepared the final typescript of this volume. My wife Ranjani proof-read the manuscript.
To her I owe my heart-felt
thanks. Finally I wish to express my gratitude to the Indian Statistical Institute for providing the excellent research facilities and to Springer - Verlag for undertaking the publication of these notes.
T. Parthasarathy November 20, 1971
Indian Statistical Institute
CONTENTS
Introduction
. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
I. C o n t i n u o u s
selections
. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
2. C o n t i n u o u s
selections
on m e t r i c
continuum
. . . . . . . . . .
I
3
14
3. C o n t i n u o u s s e l e c t i o n s and s o l u t i o n s of g e n e r a l i s e d differential equations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
24
4. M e a s u r a b l e
35
5. G e n e r a l
selections
theorems
6. T w o a p p l i c a t i o n s
7. v o n - N e u m a n n ' s
and an a p p l i c a t i o n
on s e l e c t o r s
selections
choice
theorem
8. On the u n i f o r m i z a t i o n
of sets
9.
on s e l e c t i o n
Supplementary
remarks
stochastic
games.
. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
of m e a s u r a b l e
measurable
to
49
. . . . . . . . . .
58
. . . . . . . . . . .
65
in t o p o l o g i c a l
theorems
spaces
.....
. . . . . . . . .
76
85
This volume
is dedicated
to my parents.
I 2~rRODU3 t'lo ~ The purpose of these notes is to prove a few selection theorems and to mention some applications of these theorems. briefly outline the contents of these notes.
We will now
These notes are divided
into nine sections. We start with a selection theorem due to Michael,
in section
one, which yields a characterlsation of paracompactness. 2 we are concerned with the following question. exists a continuous selection on subsets of some topological
Suppose there
2 )[ (= space of all nonempty closed
space X), then what can you say about X ?
In other words for what space section on 2 X
In section
X
does there exist a continuous
?
The aim of section three is to show how the existence of continuous
selection for certain set-valued ~aps leads to the
existence of classical solution of some generallsed differential equations.
In section four, we prove a selection theorem due to
Dubins and Savage and then we apply this theorem to prove the existence of optimal
stationary strategies for the two players in
zero-sum two-person stochastic games. In section five we establish the following result due to Kuratowskl
and Ryll-Nardzewskl.
metric space.
Let
F : X --> 2 Y
x " F(x) ~ G # @ ~ e S
Let
Y
be a complete separable
be a measurable map [That is,
whenever G is open in
Y
and
S
countably additive family induced by a field of subsets of Then there is a selector G is open in Y.
Y
such that
X].
f-l(G) e S whenever
We also deduce a few more selection theorems with
the help of this theorem. hypothesis,
f - X->
is the
In section six, assuming the continuum
%~ present an example (due to Orkin) of a non-analytic
subset of [0, I] which is a Blackwell space.
This example depends
on a measurable selection theorem proved in the previous section. In section seven we prove essentially the following measurable choice theorem due to von-Neumann.
Let
T = [0, I] and
arbitrary complete separable metric space. set-valued function from
t.
F
be an
is an analytic
T to X, then there is a Lebesgue measur-
able point-valued function almost all
If
X
f
: T -- X
such that
f(t) • F(t) for
We use this result while characterising extreme
points of sets of vector functions. Given a set E in the cartesian product and Y, a set and
I[X U
of
U
is said to uniformlse E, if the projections E
and
U
through
the set
Y
for each
x ~ ]IX E
above
consists of a single point.
x
X x y of two spaces X
onto
(~x) ,~Y)/] U
X
7[X E
coincide, and if,
of points of
Y
lying
In section eight, we are
concerned with the question of the existence of such uniformising sets. In the last section we mention further results on selection theory with some remarks.
I. CO~21NUOUS SELZCTIONS One of the most interesting and important problems in topology is the extention problem. T~o topolgical spaces given,
and
Y
together with a closed subset A of X, and we ~ u l d
know whether every continuous function to a continuous function U
X
A) into
Y.
f
from
g , A -~ Y
are llke to
can be extended
X (or at least from some open
Sometimes there are additional requirements on
which frequently take the following form ". for every must be an element of a preassigned
subset of
which we call the selection problem, the extention problem,
and presents
Y.
x ¢ X,
f,
f(x)
This new problem,
is clearly more general than a challenge even when
A
is
the null set or a one-point set (where the extention proble= is trivial). Let
X
and
Y
denote topological spaces and
family of non-empty subsets of Y. for
~
every
is a continuous
f : X--
If Y
$ : X -- 2 Y such that
2 Y denote the then a selection
f(x) z $(x) for
x ¢ X.
Example I.I: Let @(x) = u-l(x).
u
: Y -- X
Then
is continuous and
f
be onto.
is a selection for
f(x) ~ u-l(x) for every
Example 1.2: Let ~u." X -> 2 Y, let ~A.
Define
~ : X -" 2 Y by
@(x) = V ( x )
if
if and only if
x ~ X-A. f
Define
A < X
if and only if
and
f ". ~ -> Y
is a selection for ~
$
by f
x ¢ X.
~(x) = ~g(x)~
Then
$ ". X --~ 2Y
g if
be a selection for x s A
and
is a selection for
which extends
g.
The selection problem of the first paragraph can now be rephrased as follows : Under what conditions on " X-> ion for
2Y
can every selection for
@, or at least for
@IU
@iA
X,
A : X, Y and
be extended to a select-
for some open set
U ~ A
The purpose of this section is to give a solution to the above problem. Definition" Call ~ : X -~ 2Y lower semicontinuous l.s.c.) if
{x : $(x)~U~@}
is open in
X
(abbreviated as
for every open set U c Y .
The first step in answering the question, is provided by the following elementary but important necessary condition. Proposition I.I'.
If
~ " X -~ 2 Y has the property that, for every
Xoe X, there exists a selection for $~U (U a neighbourhood of which has a preassigned value
yo~ @(xO) at
xo)
xo, then ~ is lower
semlcontinuo us. Exsmple I.I*'. ~
is
I.s.c. if and only if
Example 1.2"" If ~ i s
u
is open.
l.s.c., A is closed in X and g
is continuous,
then ~ is l.s.c. Proof of proposition i.I: Let G = ~x : $(x) ~ V ~ ~}
V
be open in
is open in ~.
Y ~ we must show that
For each
Xo~ G, pick a
Yo ¢ #(Xo): then by assumption,
there exists a selection
for some neighbourhood
xo such that
U*o " Uo ~ x
Uo of
". fo(X) ~ V), then
is ~ontalned in
G.
Hence
f(Xo) = Yo"
fo for #~Uo, Now if
Uo* is a neighbourhood of
G
x0
which
is open and the proof is complete.
One can easily prove the following facts : (i) If
# : X -> 2 Y is l.s.c,
= ~
for every
x
where ~
of V(x) and #(x) respectively, (ii) If
# : X -~ 2Y is
with the property that the function (iii) If
Y
and if
l.s.c, #(x)NU
: X -~ 2 Y is such that and
then
(~x)
~ is l.s.c.
and if
U
is an open subset of
@(x) = U ~ $(x) is
is a topological linear space, and if ~
Y
is non-empty for every x ~ X, then
@ : X -~ 2 Y defined by
l.s.c., then the function
denote the closure
: X-~
l.s.c.
~ " X-,
~Y is
Z Y, defined by ~(x)--eonvex-hull
Now we are set to prove the following important result due to Michael which gives a characterisation of paracompact spaces. X
Recall
is paracompact if it is Hausdorff and if every open covering of
X
has an open locally finite refinement. Theorem l.l: The following properties of a
Tl-space
X
are equivalent
[i]. (a) X
is paracompact.
(b) If
Y
is a Banach space then every l.s.c, function ~'X -~ ~ ( Y )
(family of all closed convex subsets of Y) admits a selection. First we shall establish the follo~ing lemma. ~
~
If
X
semi-continuous and
is paracompact,
function from
X
Y
a normed linear space,
to the ~on-empty convex subsets of Y
r ~ O, then there exists a continuous
f(x) ~ S r ( T ( x ) ) Proof" Let
for every
~ a lower
x ~ X,
where
Uy = ~x : y ~ Sr(~Y(x)) )
f : X -~ Y Sr(Y(x))
for
y s Y.
such that
= ~y~d(y, ~y(x~)qr). Then
Uy = ~x ~ W~(x) C~ Sr(Y ) # ~}. Since y is l.s.c.,
U
is open for every
the open sphere of radius is a covering for
X
r with centre
and hence, since
open locally finite refinement if
~ # ~].
~W~ : ~ ~ A)
y]. X
W~ C V~ .
Clearly
Sr(Y) stands for ~Uy : y ~ Y) it has an
[ We assu~e V~ # V
there exists an open covering
Now we shall construct a family
~Poo : ~ ~ A) of continuous functions from interval with the following properties and
there
is paracompact,
~V~ " ~ ~ A).
By a theorem of Dieudonue, such that
y.
X
to the closed unit
" (i) p~ vanishes outside
~ p~ ~ ( Y )
( = closed convex subsets of
Then there
l.s.c, Y)
function
for which there
is no selection. Proof: Let
Z
be the set of rationals in
ordered as a sequence
Zl, z2, . . . .
y(x) # 0
for only finitely many
y(x) _~ 0
for all
/
x ¢ Z }.
C
if
X, and suppose
Let
Y = {y : y E
x ¢ Z ~ .
Finally
x ~ X-
Let
Z
is
~(Z),
C =~y'y ¢ Y,
let
Z
¢(x) C ~{
y " y ~ Y, y(z n) _> I/n }
It is easy to check that no selection for Suppose each
zn z Z
¢ is
l.s.o.
if
x -- z n.
Let us show that there is
¢.
f
were a selection for
has a neighbourhood
kf(x)](z n) • I/2n
X
f
is continuous,
such that
By induction pick a sequence k of distinct integers such that znk+l ~ ~ U for all k. i=l n i
{nk} Then
whenever
U n in
$ , since
x ~ ~n"
{ ~nk } is a sequence of closed subsets of
intersection property, then
and hence there is an
[f(Xo)](znk ) • 0
for all
X
with co finite
xo ~
~ k=-I
Unk.
But
k, which is impossible.
As applications of the above theorem we cite the following two propositions " Proposition 1.2 " Let and
X
be a paracompact space,
$ : X -~ F~(y), a l.s.c, function.
re(x) = inf { ~ l.s.c,
with
m(x) > O.
y ~L : y ~ ~(x) }
p(x) Z 0
for all
Y
Let
and suppose that x,
and
Then there exists a selection
a Banach space
p : X -~ R
p(x) > re(x) whenever f
for
$
such that
is
I0 llf(x) il_~ p(x) for every
x ¢ X.
~¢(x) N{
\ {o}
(x)
Let
y : Y ¢ Y, ~ Y
--> ~ ( Y )
• X
by
is
l.s.c.
@(x) -- y(x----~then
@
Hence if we define is also
l.s.c.
by the above theorem, there now exists a selection and
f
p(x)>0
i: p(x)--0.
It is not hard to check that ~ @
~ ~ p(x)} if
f
Hence
for
@
satisfies all our requirements.
Proposition 1.3 :
A topological space
X
is paracompact if and
only if it is dominated by a collection of paracompact subsets. Before proving proposition
1.3, we ~dll start with a
definition. Def~nltion :
Let
X
closed subsets of
be a topological space and d5 a collection of
X.
Then _~(Bn) continuously,
B n is as in the introduction.
of continuous (n norm, and
CLO, T] will denote the space
vector valued) functions on
Cb[O,T]
the compact subset of
[O,T] with the uniform
C[O,T] defined by
Cb[O,T] = { x : x ~ C~O,T], x(O) = x°,Ix(t)-x(t')l~ blt-t'l} . If
Q ~ C(B n)
and
y a En
we use the notation
p(y, Q) = inf { iy-qL " q ~ R } ,
while for
Ql' Q2 ~ -~(Bn),
h(Ql, Q2) denotes the Hausdorff distance between these sets. For
Q " [0,T] -> _9(Bn), define the variation of
subinterval
it - ~
t], ~ > O, denoted by
Vt
•
Let
P
denote a partition of
of points
(Q)
t-~
Property A " lira a- ~0
IT vt~ 0
=
For each
sup PeO
as follows.
it-a, t], i.e. a finite collection
For the partition
P,
k vt't-~ (Q • P) = ~=OZ h(Q(t ~+i ), Q(ty ))
vt (Q) t-~
on the
'
t-~ = to • t I < ... < tk+ 1 = t, and let
set of all such partitions.
Q
~
denote the
define
and
vt (Q, P). t-q
x ¢ Cb[O'T],
(R(x(.))) dt -- 0
vtt-~ (R(x(.))) ~ LI[O,T]
uniformly for
x s
Cb[O , T].
and
26
(Assume
x(t) = x(t) = x(O)
is defined for
Vt (R(x( • ))) t-~ This convention will be assumed throughout,
t-~ < O.
for
t < ~
so that
when necessary). At this Juncture we would like to make the following observations (i)
"
It is clearly possible that the variation
unbounded for some the special case
t, Q
yet
vt~
(Q) ~ L I.
t (Q) Vt_ ~
For example,
is
consider
a point valued function in the interval
[O,1]
defined by J(l-t)
Sin(l/l-t)
~en
t # I
when
t = I.
q(t) 0
(il)
If
R
is Lipschitzian,
say
h(R(x), R(x')) _~ Klx-x'l,
clearly property A is satisfied. Indeed vtt.~ (R(x(.)) ,P) -k k ~=07 h(R(x(t +i)), R(x(t ))) _< K b ~=OZ (t +l-t ) = K b ~ for x a Cb[O,T] . (iii)
Let
R " E n --> ~(B n) continuously and let
We define the variation of Let
R
in
S, d e ~ t e d
~y:
ly-x°l_~ b T}.
V(R,S) as follows.
k
be any finite collection of points yl ,...,yk+l in S such k that Z ly +i _ y ~ _~ b T and let /k denote the set of all such ~=i k collections. Let V(R,S,k) = Z h(R(yi+l), R(yi)) and V(RpS) is i=l defined as sup V(R, Stk) . If V(R,$) < oc we say R has bounded k~A variation in S. Clearly if R has bounded variation in S, then for any
x ~ Cb[O,T] ,
is finite for all In this case,
t
V~.~ (R(x(.)))
En).
Another way in which equation (I) appears is in the theory of control
33 systems having equations of the motion of the form ~ = f(t,x,u), 0 x(O) = x , where the control function u may be chosen as any measurable
r
vector valued function with value at time
a preassigned set
U(t) I , and, in this case, ~
is
fco. Strategies and stationary strategies for Player I!
are defined analogously. A pair (~, r) of strategies for Players I and II associates with each initial state
s
an
nth-day expected gain
rn(= , C)
(s)
for Player I and a total expected discounted gain for Player I c I(~', F ~) (s) F
We shall say that the stochastic game has a
sup inf I(~, F)(s) = inf sup I(~, F)(s) v
for all
F
for every
s ~ S.
42
In case the stochastic game has a value, the quantity sup inf I(~, F )(s), F ?r function.
as a function on
S, is called the value
The stochastic game problem was first formulated by Shapley [6] who took
S, 4
B
to be finite, assumed that play would terminate
in a finite number of stages with probability one, and considered only what we have called stationary strategies.
Shapley was able to
prove under these conditions that the stochastic game has a value and that both players have optimal strategies.
See [8] or [61.
We
shall prove a generalisation of Shapley's result under suitable assumptions on
S, A, B, q, r.
Specifically, we shall assume that
(1) S, A, B
are compact metric spaces, (ii) r
function on
S ~
and
b n -~ bo,
A ~B,
and (ili) whenever
is a continuous sn J
So,
q(-LSn, an, bn) converges weakly to
an -~ ao,
q(. ISo, ao, bo).
These conditions will remain operative throughout the rest of this section. In order to prove the main theorem, we need some lemmas. X
is a compact metric space, we denote by
probability measures on the Borel sets of
PX X.
If
the space of all It is well-known that
PX, endowed with the weak topology, is a compact metric space. Lemma 4.6 " S ×A
xB.
Let
i
be a continuous, real-valued function on
Then, i(s, ~, k) = IJ i(s,a,b) d ~(a)dk(b), s ~ S,
~ PA' k s PB, is a continuous function on
S x PA ~(PB"
For a proof see [4]. Lemma 4.7 " where
X
Let
u
be a bounded, continuous function on
is a Borel subset of a Polish space and
metric space.
Then
u* . X -~ R
defined by
Y
X ~
Y
is a compact
u*(x) -- max u(x,y) y~ Y
45
is continuous.
Moreover
u, " X --> R
defined by
u. (x) = rain u(x,y) is continuous. y~Y Proof of this lemma is easy and hence omitted. Lemma 4.8 : where
X
u
be a bounded,
continuous function
is a Borel subset of a Polish space and
metric space. into
Let
Y
Then, there exist Borel maps
such that
U(X,g(x)) =
f
Y
y
is a compact
and
u(x, f(x)) = max u(x,y), x z X y~Y
X x
g
from
X
and
rain u(x,y), x ~ X. y~Y
This lemma is an immediate consequence of theorem 4.1. If
X
is a topological space, denote by
all bounded,
continuous functions on
X.
C(X) the family of
For each
w ~ C(X), define
Kw(S,~,k) = r(s,~,k) + ~ I w(-) dq(. {s,@,k), s ¢ S, ~ ¢ PA' k ¢ PB
where
r(s, S, k) = ~I r(s, a, b) d @(a) d k(b)
and
q(.~s, S, k) = 5S q(.is, a, b) d iz(a) d k(b). It follo~s from lemma 4.6, S ~PA
XPB"
Kw
is a continuous function on
From Sion's minimax theorem Is] we have,
sup inf ~PAXSPB
Since
Kw
Kw(S,~,k) =
is continuous on
Inf XSPB
S ~
sup Kw(S,~,k) , s e S. SaPA
PA "( PB
it follows from lemma 4.7 that
sup
by max
Thus, we have
and mln, respectively.
max ~¢PA
mln XSPB
Kw(S,U,X) =
mln XSPB
and
and inf
PA' PB
are compact,
can be replaced above
max Kw(S,~,X) , s ~ S. ~ePA
44 Lemma 4.9 : from
S
For each
into
PA
max
and
w ~ C(S), there exist Borel maps PB, respectively,
f
and
g
such that
rain ke PB
Kw(s , ~, X) = rain k~ PB
Kw(S , f(s), X)
~ e PA
min XeP B
max ~eP A
Kw(S , ~, k) = max 6eP A
Kw(s , u, g(s)), s ~ S.
and
Proof "
We prove the first assertion.
S ~ S, ~ ¢ PA" S XPA.
By lemma 4.7,
~
Let
¢(s,s) = rain Kw(S,~,k) , Xe PB is a continuous function on
Hence, by virtue of lemma 4.8, there exists a Borel map
f " S -~ PA max
rain
~eP A
kaP B
such that Kw(S , ~, X)
~(s,f(s)) = max ~(s,N) = ~zP A for all
s s S.
On the other hand,
¢(s, f(s)) =
min Kw(S , f(s), X) for all X,P B the proof of the first assertion. For each Tw(s) =
w e C(S) define
max ~ePA
min XePB
Len~na 4.10 :
The operator
P_~
Wl, w 2 e C(S).
if
Let
w ~ C(S),
check,
T
T T
~ w Ii denotes
is monotone, we get
This completes
as follows •
Kw(S , @, X) = rain XePB
It is clear from lemma 4.7,
:
Tw
s $ S.
maps
max Kw(S , @, k). ~¢PA
C(S) into
C(S).
is a contraction mapping o n Plainly,
w 1 _< w 2 + LLWl-W211,
sup ~w(s) ~. ssS
C(S). where,
Since, as is easy to
Tw 1 _< T(w 2 + li Wl-W2i~ )
-- Tw 2 + ~liwl-w 2il
45 Consequently and
w 2)
Hence,
Tw~-Tw I _< 8 ~l-W21i , T
Similarly,
Twl-TW 2 --~ 8 ~tWl-W21L
which shows
is a contraction mapping as
(interchanging
wI
II Twl-TW2il ~ ~ ~ Wl-W21L
~ < I.
This completes the
proof of the lemma. Since
C(S), when equipped with the supremum norm, is a
complete metric space,
T
has a unique fixed point in
virtue of the Banach fixed point theorem. fixed point of
T.
Let
w~
C(S), by
be the unique
Then it follows from the definition of
Kw,(S , ~, k) and lemma 4.9 that there exist Borel maps from
S to
PA
and
PB, respectively,
f* and
such that, for every
g*
s ~ S,
w*(s) = min [r(s,f'(s),k) + 8 I w*(. ) dq (.Is,f*(s),k)] kcP B = max [r(s,~,g*(s)) + ~ I w~(.) dq(.Is,N,g*(s))] ~ E PA = r(s,f*(s),
...(*)
g*(s)) + 8 I w*(.) dq(.Is, f*(s), g*(s)).
We shall show after one lemma that
w* is the value function of the
stochastic game. Our next task is to solve the above functional equation (*). To accomplish this, denote by functions on function from to
PB,
S.
With each ordered pair (f,g), where
S to
S to PA
and
we associate an operator
(L(f,~)w)(s) = r(s,f(s),g(s)) We may interpret Player I,
M(S) the f~nily of all bounded Borel
g
f
is a Borel
is a Borel function from
L(f,g) - M(S) --> M(S)
S
defined by
+ ~ S w(.) dq(.Is, f(s),~(s)),
s ¢ S.
(L(f,g)w)(s) as the expected amount Player II pays
when the initial state of the system is
and II take actions according to
f(s) and
g(s),
s,
Players
I
and the game is
46
terminated at the beginning of the second day with Player II paying Player I
w(t) units of money, where
t
is the state of the system
on the second day. Lemma 4,11 " M(S)
and
The operator
L(f,g) is a contraction mapping on
l(fOo gO~ is its unique fixed point in
The proof is straight-forward and omit it.
M(S). Now we are ready
to state our theorem [4]. Theorem 4.2 :
Let
S, A, B
be compact metric spaces, let
continuous, real-valued function on moreover, that, whenever S ,~ A '~ B,
S ~
A
,( B,
converges weakly to
be a
and assume
(Sn, an, b n) -~ (So, ao, b o)
q(. ISn, an, b n)
r
in
q(. !So, ao, be) .
Then, the stochastic game has a value, the value function is continuous, and
Players
I
and
II
have optimal stationary
strategies. Proof:
Observe that the above functional equation (*) can be
rewritten as
L(f*, g~) w* = w ~.
w ~ = l(f.(oo), g,(Oo)).
It follows from lemma 4.11
that
In view of this we have,
I(f*(°°), g*(°°))(s) -- max [rCs,~, g*(s)) + asP A 8 I l(f *(°°),g*(°°))(.)dq(. Is,~,g*(s))]
= min [rCs, f*Cs),k) + ~ I ICf *(9°),g*(e('))( )dq(-Is, f*(s),k)] ke PB It follows from Blackwell
[Theorem 6, pp ~$2, [I]] or from
[Theorem 3.1 in [4]], that,
I(f *(~),g*(~))(s) = sup I (~, g*(~)) (s) 7r
=
inf l(f*(°°) C)(s) F
for
s ¢ S.
47 Consequently, l(f*(°°),g *(°°)) = sup I (~,g,(Oo)) Z inf sup I(~, C ). ?r v ?r On the other hand,
l(f*(°°),g *(°°)) = inf l(f "(°°) c ) < F
sup inf I( ~, V) ~ C
Hence, inf sup I( =, c) = sup Inf I(~, v). C ~ = f This proves that the stochastic game has a value, that the value function is I(f,(oo), g,(OO)) = w~ and so continuous, and that f, (co) g, (oo) , are optimal stationary strategies for Players I and II respectively. Remark 4.1 "
This completes the proof of theorem 4.2.
If in theorem 4.2 we allow
S
to be merely a Borel
subset of a Polish space, our proof breaks down because lemma 4.6 fails.
However, we can eliminate this difficulty by imposing
somewhat stronger conditions on
q
and
r, namely, that
should be a continuous function on
S ~
PA x p B
I w(.) dq (. Is, ~, k) for every when q
and
A
w ~ C(S). and
r,
B with
are finite]. A, B
and that
should also be continuous on [ ~te
r(s,s,k)
S ~
PA ~
that these conditions will be satisfied Then under these conditions on
compact metric spaces and
S
a Borel subset
of a Polish space, the conclusions and the proof of theorem 4.2 remain valid.
PB
48
REFERENCES
[1]
D. Blackwell, Stat
S6 [1968],
[2]
K. Kuratowski,
[3]
A. Maitra,
A. Maitra
226-235.
Topology
Vol I, Acad. Press, P.W.N. [ 1 9 6 6 ] .
Sankhya Series A. 30 [1968], 211-216.
and
T. Parthasarathy,
Jour. optimi, theory
[5]
Ann. Math.
Discounted dynamic programming on compact metric
spaces,
[4]
Discounted dynamic programming,
T. Parthasarathy
and
t~o-person games,
On stochastic games,
And its Appl , 8 [1970], 289-~00.
T.E.S. Raghavan,
Some topics in
American Elsevier Publishing Company,
New York [1971].
[6]
L. S. Shapley,
Stochastic games,
Proc. National. Acad. Sci
U.S.A., 39 [1983], i095-II00.
[7i
L.E. Dubins and L.J. Savage, Fow to gamble if you must, Xcgraw-~Ki!, New Yor~ [1965].
5.
GFz~ERAL THEORE~S ON SELECTORS
In this section we shall first prove a general theorem on selectors
due to Kuratowski
theorems on selectors Jacobs
and
[2].
Ryll-Nardze%,ski
and deduce a few
Lastly we shall state a theorem of
[3]. Let
space.
X
be a set o f arbitrary elements
Let
S
be a countably
additive
and
Y
a metric
family of subsets of
X
cO
[that is, if
An a S
for
the following statement Lemma 5.1 "
Let
f(x) = lim fn(X)
fn " X -- Y
Let
assumption Ifm
for
whenever
whenever
K = ~
c Y.
G
I/n
for
Then
G
Let
and let
is uniform.
is open in
is open in
Suppose that
Y
(I) n.
Y.
K n = ~ y " p(y, K) _
Y.
follows
is open in
f'l(G) e S
whenever
f(x) e F(x) according to
G
(2) n.
Y, this sequence By lemma 5.i, it Y.
Finally
Thus the proof of theorem S.l is
complete. Remark 5.1 : [namely by
The theorem remains true by replacing the condition
~ x " F(x) C~G # @ } E S
~ x "
F(x)~
K # ~ } e L
can be seen as follows. F
set
:
G = K IU
Y
K2•
whenever
whenever
G
is open in
K c Y
is closed.
being metric, every open ...,
where
Y ]
Kn = ~n"
This
G
PA ~
PB
where
rwCs) = ~[ (~',x') : max [r(s,s,~,') + ~ f w(-) dq(. Is,~,X')] = rain [r(s,t~',X) + ~ I w(.) dq(. Is,#',X)} k
Further-
63 and
w
is a bounded real-valued Borel measurable
These set valued functions Olech [2]. theorem 6.2.
rw
function on
S.
are measurable by a result of
Now one can use (the selection)
theorem 5.3 to prove
The rest of the proof follows along similar lines
to that of theorem 4.2, -with some minor ,~difications the proof of theorem 6.2 is omitted.
and hence
64 REFERENCES
[1]
D. Blackwell,
On a class of probability spaces, Proceedings
of the third Berkeley Symposium on Mathematical Statistics and Probability Vol 2, p 1-6, edited by J. Neyman, University of California Press [1956].
[2]
C. Olech,
A note concerning set valued measurable functions,
Bulletin De L'Academie Polonaise Des Sciences, S _ ~ ~e~ S i e ~ ,
[3]
M. Orkin,
~.ath, ~s~ro et Pl~vs. 13 [1965], 317-321.
A Blackwell space which is not analytic,
To appear.
[4]
T. Parthasarathy, Discounted and positive stochastic games, Bull. Amer, Math. Soc
77 [1971], iS4-136.
7.
VON-NEUMANN'S
MEASURABLE CHOICE THEOREM
The purpose of this section is to prove a measurable theorem due to von-Neumann.
choice
After giving the proof, we shall
mention a few consequences of this theorem. Choice Theorem 7.1 [4] ". Let
S
be a complete separable metric
space,
S
and
A
an analytic set in
defined and continuous for all values.
Let
assumes.
K
Let
A
and has real numerical
be the set of all values, which ~ (k)
is a monotone,
a ~
F(a) a function which is
be an arbitrary
nondecreasing,
F(a), a c A
N-function,
rlght-continuous,
that is,
T (k)
bounded function.
Under these assumptions we have (i)
K
is a
T (k)
measurable set.
(ii)
there exists a function
X ~ K
and assumes values in (a)
k ~ K
If
with (b)
Proof :
0
S
such that
is an open subset of
f(k) c 0 For every
is
S, then the set of all
"[ (X)-measurable.
k ~ K,
F(f(k)) = ~.
We shall prove the theorem when
and nowhere constant
~-i~anction,
a topological mapping of a ~ ~ • b
f(k), which is defined for all
where
a
=
T (k)
therefore
is a continuous
k -~ % (k) = ~
is
- co ~ k ~ oo on the finite interval T~(- co),
b
= p~(+ co).
The general
situation can be reduced to this case [4]. Let us now replace and then write again
X
F(a), f(k) by for
our assertions unaffected, ~.
The domain of
k
~.
(F(a)),
f("C-I(~)),
This leaves the structure of
but there are these changes regarding
is now
a
~ k • b
and
not
- oc ~ k • + co.
66 In this new domain we have to use the notion of common (Legesgue)measurability and not that one of T(k)-measurability. -9 I~(k)
[Our mapping
transformed the latter into the former].
We now introduce the '0 space of Baire', So, which is the set of all sequences
4 = (n!,n 2 .... ),
nl, n 2 ... = 1,2, . . . .
It is metrized by the definition Dist [(ml,m2,...) , (nl,n2,...)] = u
if
mv = nv
= _I_ if
vo
vo
for every
is the smallest
integer for which
Thus
SO
is a complete, separable metric space.
set of all those
~ = (nl, n2, ...), for which
a finite number of
vo
exists such that
mvo • %
establishes an ordering of all
~ ~ 4
we have sphere in 41, 42) . then
is open.
~ < 4 So
[The countable nv W i
occurs for
If
So.
(ml, m2,...) • (hi,n2,...) and If
p ~ 4, and
in the entire sphere is a set of the form
mv ~
= nv
for
P -- (nl, n2,...)
if a
is fixed, then the set of vo
is defined as above, then
Dist (~, B) • I/v o. ~l -< ~ ~ 42
Every
(with fixed ¢ ~ O,
belongs to it, if and only if,
Dist ~ (ml,m2,...) ' (nl, n2,... ) } < ~, where
So] .
v < vo ,
If its center is (ml, m2, ...) and its radius
v = 1,2, ..., v I
m v W nv.
v's only is obviously everywhere dense in
On the other hand the definition,
v.
vI
may be written in the form
that is
m v = nv
is the greatest integer
for
_< i/~.
This
~I -< p ~ c(2 if we put
~I = (ml'''',mVl-l, mvl, I, I, ...), ~2 =(ml,"',mVl-l, mvl+l,l,l, --~-
67 As
A
Is an analytic set In a complete, separable metric
space, therefore there exists a function and continuous for every
~ ~ So
and ~Lich maps
[The mapping may be many to one]. the set of all
There As
F(~(~)), ~ s So.
continuous for every
~ z So
~(~) which is defined
K
So
onto
A.
Is clearly
F(@(~)) also Is defined and
and the real numbers form a complete,
separable metric space, we can conclude that
K
is an analytic
set and consequently measurable. Consider now a wlth
F(@(~)) = X
k ~ K.
by
Denote by the set of all
T(A).
as
F(@(~)) Is continuous,
nI
with
As T(X)
(n I, n2, ...) ~ T(A)
the smallest
n2
(us, n4, ...)
by
with ~
k ¢ K,
Is closed. for auy
etc.
Let
for every