O-PTIONS, FUTURES
AND
Exovic ERIVATIVES Theory, Application
and Practice
M. Bellalah
E. Briys
Université du Maine ...
138 downloads
2604 Views
21MB Size
Report
This content was uploaded by our users and we assume good faith they have the permission to share this book. If you own the copyright to this book and it is wrongfully on our website, we offer a simple DMCA procedure to remove your content from our site. Start by pressing the button below!
Report copyright / DMCA form
O-PTIONS, FUTURES
AND
Exovic ERIVATIVES Theory, Application
and Practice
M. Bellalah
E. Briys
Université du Maine
Lehman Brothers
F. de Varenne
H.M. Mai
FFSA
MONEP
OM A
jOHN WILEY & SONS Chichester
·
New York
-
Weinheim
Brisbane
Singapore
Toronto
O.
Mr
Boll OPTIONS,
UTURES
Exovic DERIVATIVES
*
Copyright
@ 1998 by John Wiley
& Sons Ltd, Baffins Lane, Chichester, West Sussex POl9 lUD, England National International
01243 779777
(+44)1243779777
e-mail (for orders and customer service enquiries): cs-books Visit our Home Page on http://www.wiley.co.uk
On teiItS
@wiley.co.uk
or http://wwwwiley.com The authors have asserted their right under the Copyright, Designs and Patents Act, 1988, to be identifiedw&e authors of this work. Reprinted
July 1998, October 1999
All rights reserved. No part of this publication rnay be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted, in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording, scanning or otherwise, except under the terms of the Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988 or under the terms of licence issued by the Copyright a Licensing Agency, 90 Tottenham Court Road, London, UK WlP 9HE, without the permission in writing of John Wiley and Sons Ltd., Baffins Lane, Chichester, West Sussex, UK POl9 lUD.
About the A
CHAPTER
1: FINANCIAL yggy
MAHi(ETS, INNOVATION ANÐ TRADING
Chapter Outline Introduction 1.1 Do Firms Care about Finance? 1.1.1 Finance is a fun game to play, hard to win 1.1.2 Some commonly encountered pitfalls 1.1.3 Some good reasons for hedgmg 1.2 How to Implement Strategic Financial Risk Management 1.3 Trading Mechanisms in Securities Markets
WlLEYVCH Verlag GmbH, Pappelallee 3, D-69469 Weinheim, Germany Jacaranda
XX
Foreword
Other Wiley Editorial Ogces John Wiley & Sons, Inc., 605 Third Avenue, New York, NY 10158-0012, USA
XVI
Preface
Wiley Ltd, 33 Park Road, Milton,
.
Queensland4064,
Australia
John Wiley & Sons (Asia) Pte Ltd, 2 Clementi Loop #02-01, Jin Xing Distripark, Singapore 129809 John Wiley & Sons (Canada) Ltd, 22 Worcester Road, Rexdale, Ontario M9W lLl, Canada Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Options, futures, and exotic derivatives : theory application and practice / authors, E.C. Briys [et al.]. p. cm. - (Wiley frontiers in finance) Includes bibliographical references and index. ISBN 0-471-96909-5 (cloth). ISBN 0-471-96908-7 (pbk.) 1. Options (Finance). 2. Futures. 3. Derivative securities. L Bnys, E.C. II. Senes. ...
HG6024.A30653 332.63'228-dc2l
.
1998
1.4 Trading Option Contracts 1.4.1 Options and synthetic positions 1.4.2 The basic option strategies 1.4.3 Trading straddles and strangles 1.4.4 Trading spreads 1.4.5 Trading ratios 1.4.6 Conversions and reversals 1.4.7 Trading a box spread
Summary Points for Discussion
2 2 5 7 9 13 15 15 16 20 2I 22
23 24 25 25
97-44712 CIP
CHAPTER British Library Cataloguing in Publication Data A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library 0-471-969095 (cased) 0-471-96908-7 (paperback) Typeset in 10/12 pt Times by Keytec Typesetting Ltd, Bridport, Dorset Printed and bound in Great Britain by Bookcraft (Bath) Ltd., Midsomer Norton, Somerset This book is printed on acid-free paper responsibly manufactured from sustainable forestation, in which at least two trees are planted for each one used ISBN
2: THE DYNAMICS OF ASSET PRICES: ANALYSIS AND A PP LI C AT IO NS
Chapter Outline Introduction 2. I Continuous Time Processes for Asset Price Dynamics 2.1.1 Asset price dynamics and the Wiener process Wiener orocess 2.1.2 Asset nrice dvnamics and the eeneralized
27 27 27 28 28 31
CONT
2.1.3 Asset price dynamics and the Itô process 2.1.4 The log-normal property 2.1.5 The distribution of the rate of return 2.2 Itõ's Lemma and its Applications 2.2.1 Intuitive form 2.2.2 Mathematical form 2.2.3 Generalized Itö's formula 2.3 Taylor Series, Itõ's Theorem and the Replication Argument 2.3.1 The relationship between Taylor series and Itö's differential 2.3.2 Itõ's differential and the replication portfolio 2.3.3 Itô's differential and the arbitrage portfolio 2.3.4 Why are error terms neglected? 2.4 Forward and Backward Kolmogorov Equations Summary Points for Appendix Appendix Appendix
CHAPTER
Discussion 2.A: Introduction to Diffusion Processes 2.B: The Conditional Expectation 2.C: Taylor Series
.
.
35 36
39 40 40 41 42 43 44 45 45 45 46
ASSET
Chapter Outlme
.
31 33 33 34
47
3: APPLICATIONS TO ASSET AND DERIVATIVE PRICING IN COMPLETE MARKETS
Introduction 3.1 Characterizations of Complete Markets 3.2 Pricing Derivative Assets 3.2.1 The problem 3.2.2 The partial differential equation method 3.2.3 The martingale method 3.3 Numerical Analysis and Simulation Techniques 3.3.1 Introduction to finite difference methods 3.3.2 Application to European calls on non-dividend 3.3.3 Simulation methods
ITS
.
paying stocks
Summary Points for Discussion Appendix 3.A: The Change m Probability and the Girsanov Theorem 3.A.l The equivalent probability 3.A.2 The Girsanov Theorem Appendix 3.B: Resolution of the Partial Differential Equation Appendix 3.C: Approximation of the Cumulative Normal Distribution Appendix 3.D: Introduction to Numerical Analysis 3.D.1 The heat transfer equation 3.D.2 Some numerical schemes Appendix 3.E: An Algorithm for a European Call Appendix 3.F: Leibniz's Rule for Integral Differentiation
49
49 49 50 51 51 52 53 56 57 59
61 62 63
63
CONTENTS
ER 4: ASSET PRICING IN COMPLETE NUMERAIRE AND TIME
MARKETS: CHANGING 73 73 73 74 76 78 78 8l 83
Chapter Outline Introduction 4.1 Assumptions 4.2 Valuation in the Black-Scholes Economy 4.3 Changing Numeraire and Time 4.3.1 The change of numeraire 4.3.2 The time change
Summary Points for Discussion Appendix 4.A: Application
83
5: ANALYTICAL
CHAPTER
84
to Barrier Options EUROPEAN
OPTION
PRICING MODELS
87
Chapter Outlme Introduction
87
5.1 Precursors of the Black and Scholes Model 5.1.1 Bachelier formula 5.1.2 Sprenkle formula 5.1.3 Boness formula 5.1.4 Samuelson formula 5.2 Black and Scholes (B-S) Model 5.2.1 The model 5.2.2 Applications 5.3 Black Model 5.3.1 The model 5.3.2 Applications 5.4 Garman and Kohlhagen, and Grabbe Models 5.4.1 The model 5.4.2 Applications 5.5 The Merton, Barone-Adesi and Whaley Model and its Applications 5.5.1 The model 5.5.2 Application of the model
88
-
87
Summary Points for Discussion
88 89 90 90 92 92 99 105 105 108 l 10 111 l 14 l 14 114 116 , 1=0 121
63
63 64
CHAPTER
6: MONITORING
POSITIONS
68 69 69
69 70 71
Chapter Outline Introduction 6.1 Option Price Sensitivities 6.l.l The delta 6.1.2 The gamma
AND MANAGEMENT
OF OPTION 123 123 123 124 125 126
CONTENTS
y¡¡¡
6.1.3 The theta 6.1.4 The vega 6.1.5 The Rho 6.1.6 Elasticity 6.2 Monitoring and Managing an Option Position in Real Time 6.2.1 Simulation and analysis of option price sensitivities 6.2.2 Monitoring and adjusting the option position in real time 6.3 The Characteristics of Volatility Spread Summary Points for Discussion Appendix 6.A: Greek-Letter Risk Measures in Analytical Models 6.A.1 B-S model .
.
127 127 128 128 129 129 134 149
,
150 150 151
6.A.2 Black's model 6.A.3 Garman and Kohlhagen's model 6.A.4 Merton's and Barone-Adesi and Whaley's model Appendix 6.B: The Relationship between Hedging Parameters Appendix 6.C: The Generalized Relationship between the Hedging Parameters
CHAPTER 7: EXTENSION TO AMERICAN OPTIONS: DIVIDENDS AND EARLY EXERCISE Chapter Outline
157 157 157 158 159 161
lntroduction 7.1 The Valuation of American Options: the General Problem 7.1.1 Early exercise of American calls 7.1.2 Early exercise of American puts 7.2 Valuation of American Commodity Options, Futures Options with Continuous Distributions 7.2.1 American commodity options 7.2.2 American futures options 7.2.3 Capped variable loan commitments 7.3 Valuation of American Options with Discrete Cash Distributions 7.3.1 Early exercise of American options 7.3.2 Compound option approach 7.3.3 Valuation of American options with dividends 7.3.4 Applications
Summary Points for Discussion Appendix 7.A: Simulation Results for American Cap Options 7.A.l Effect of a change in the underlying asset price and time to maturity 7.A.2 Effect of a change in the underlying and time to maturity CHAPTER
8: GENERALIZATION
Chapter Outline Introduction
.
151 152 152 153 154 154
163 163 166 168 170 170 171 175 176 177 177 178 178
asset price volatility
TO STOCHASTIC INTEREST
179
RATES
181 181 18 I
CONTENTS
ix
8.1 Derivation of Merton's Model 8.1.1 The model 8.1.2 Applications Model ; 8.2.1 The model for equity options 8.2.2 The model for bond options 8.2.3 Chen's correction 8.3 Pricing of Bonds and Interest Rate Options 8.3.1 Instantaneous interest rates under certainty 8.3.2 Instantaneous interest rates under uncertainty 8.3.3 Interest rate processes and the pricing of bonds and options
8.2 Rabinovitch's
·
Summary Points for Discussion CHAPTER
9: PRICING CORPORATE
BONDS
182 182 185 186 186 189 190 190 190 191 192 195 195 197
Chapter Outline Introduction 9.1 The Traditional Contingent-Claims Modeling 9.1.1 Assumptions 9.l.2 The pricing of corporate debt 9.l.3 The pricing of corporate spreads 9.2 The Limits of the Traditional Approach 9.2.1 The three weaknesses 9.2.2 Recent contributions 9.3 The Longstaff-Schwartz Model 9.4 The Briys-de Varenne Model 9.4.1 The model and its assumptions 9.4.2 The valuation of risky zero-coupon bonds 9.4.3 The valuation of corporate spreads 9.4.4 The interest rate elasticity of corporate bonds
197 197 198 198 200 202 203 203 205 205 207 208 210 212 219
Summary
224
Points for Discussion
224
CHAPTER
10: PRICING
INSURANCE
LINKED
BONDS
Chapter Outline Introduction 10.1 Natural Hazards, Insurance Risks and Insurance Linked Bonds 10.2 The Structure of Insurance Linked Bonds 10.3 A Simple Pricing Model of Insurance Nature Linked Bonds 10.3.1 The valuation model 10.3.2 The valuation of insurance linked spreads 10.3.3 The duration 10.3.4 Time-series properties
Summary Points for Discussion
225 225
225 226 228 230 230 233 235 238 239 239
COMTENTS
x
Appendix Appendix CHAPTER
10.A: Extension to Stochastic Interest Rates 10.B: Computation of the First Passage Time Distribution
240 240
11: FURTHER
GENERALIZATION TO JUMP PROCESSES, STOCHASTIC VOLATILITIES AND INFORMATION
COSTS
241 241
and the Constant Elasticity of Variance (CEV) 11.1 The Jump-Diffusion Model l 1.1.1 The jump-diffusion model 11.1.2 The constant elasticity of variance (CEV) diffusion process 1l.2 The Hull and White Model 11.3 Stein and Stein's Model 11.4 Generalization to Stochastic Volatilities 11.4.1 Heston's model 11.4.2 Hoffman, Platen and Schweizer's model 11.5 The Theory of Volatility Smiles 11.5.1 The smile effect in stock and index options 11.5.2 The smile effect for bond and currency options 11.6 Option Valuation with Information Costs: the Bellalah-Jacqudiat Model 11.6.1 The model 11.6.2 Empirical tests 11.7 Volatility Smiles: Empirical Evidence
Summary Points for Discussion Appendix l l.A: The Poisson Process CHAPTER
12: THE LATTICE
APPROACH AND THE BINOMEAL MODEL
Chapter Outline Introduction 12.1 Lattice Approaches l2.l.l A survey 12.1.2 The model for options on a spot asset without any payouts 12.1.3 The model for futures options 12.1.4 Model with dividends 12.1.5 Examples 12.1.6 The model for American options in the French market 12.2 The Lattice Approach for Interest Rate Derivative Assets 12.2.1 The Ho and Lee model for interest rates and bond prices 12.2.2 The Ho and Lee model for contingent claims 12.2.3 Deficiency in the Ho and Lee model 12.2.4 The Hull and White trinomial model Summary Pomts for Discussion -
242 242 243 244 245 247 248 249 250 250 250 251 251 252 256 256 257 257 259 259 259 260
260
-
261 263
264
'
CHAPTER
xi
13: NUMERICAL
METHODS FOR AMERICAN
OPTION
PRICING
281
Chapter Outline 241
Chapter Outline Introduction
CONTENTS
266 268 273 273 275 277 274 280 280
Introduction 13.1 Application to American Calls o Dividend Paying Stocks 13.1.1 The Schwartz model 13.1.2 The numerical solution 13.2 Application to American Puts on Dividend Paying Stocks 13.2.1 The Brennan and Schwartz model 13.2.2 The numerical solution 13.3 Application to Convertible Bonds 13.3.1 The specificities of convertible bonds 13.3.2 The valuation equation 13.3.3 The numerical solution 13.3.4 Simulations Summary Points for Discussion Appendix 13.A: The Algorithm for the American Call with Dividends Appendix 13.B: The Algorithm for the American Put with Dividends Appendix 13.C: The Algorithm for Convertible Call and Put Prices 13.C.l Initialization
CHAPTER
14: EXCHANGE,
FORWARD
START AND CHOOSER
OPTIONS Chapter Outline Introduction 14.1 Exchange Options 14.1.1 Identification and valuation 14.1.2 Applications 14.2 Options with Uncertain Exercise Prices 14.2.1 Analysis and valuation 14.3 Forward Start Options 14.4 Pay Later Options 14.5 Chooser Options 14.5.1 Simple chooser options 14.5.2 Complex chooser options
Summary Points for Discussion
CHAPTER
15: RAINBOWOPTIONS
Chapter Outline Introduction
281 281 282 282 282 284 284 284 285 285 286 287 288 290 290 290 291 293 293
297 297 297 298 298 300 301 301 304 305 307 307 308 310 310
313 313 313
CONTENTS
xii
15.1 Valuation of Rainbow Options 15.1.1 Analytic formulas 15.1.2 The discrete approach 15.2 Simulations M.; 15.2.1 Calls on the minimum 15.2.2 Calls on the maximum 15.2.3 Puts on the minimum Applications 15.3 15.3.1 Pricing currency bonds 15.3.2 Multi-currency bonds 15.3.3 Corporate option bonds 15.3.4 Spread options 15.3.5 Portfolio options 15.3.6 Dual-strike options 15.3.7 Delivery options and wildcard options
314
314 320 Y
4
Summary Points for Discussion
CHAPTER
325 326 326
327 327 327 328 33 I
333
Chapter Outline Introduction 16.1 Pricing valuation
context 16.1.2 Extendible calls 16.1.3 Extendible puts 16.2 Simple Writer Extendible Options 16.2.1 Simple writer extendible calls 16.2.2 Simple writer extendible puts 16.3 Applications 16.3.1 Extendible bonds 16.3.2 Extendible warrants
Summary Points for Discussion
CHAPTER 17: FOREIGN CURRENCY SECURITIES
324 325
×iii
17.2 Analysis and Valuation of Capped Options 17.2.1 The range forward contract 17.2.2 The collar
348 348
17.2.3 Indexed notes 17.3 Pricing Hybrid Foreign Currency Options 17.3.1 Tailoring hybrid foreign currency options: the Briysdrouhy approach 17.3.2 General pricing 17.4 Financing with Hybrid Securities: Peris 17.4.1 Specificities of the product 17.4.2 Cash-fiow identification 17,4.3 Valuation of perls
349 351
349
35 l 352
354 354 354 355
Summary
356
Points for Discussion
357
CHAPTER 18: BINARIES AND BARRIERS
359
331
16: EXTENDIBLE OPTIONS
16.1.1 The
323 323 324
ONTENTS
333 333 333 333 334 336 337 337 337
339 339 340 340 340
OPTIONS AND HYBRID
Chapter Outline Introduction 17.1 Equity-Linked Foreign Exchange Options and Quantos 17.1.1 The foreign equity option struck in foreign currency 17.1.2 The foreign equity option struck in domestic currency 17.1.3 Equity-linked foreign exchange call 17.1.4 The fixed exchange rate foreign equity options or quanto options
341 341 341 342 343 343
Chapter Outline Introduction 18,1 Analysis of Binaries and Barriers 18.1.1 Standard binary options 18.l.2 Complex binaries and range options 18.l.3 Barriers and structured barrier options 18.2 Valuation of Binary Barrier Options 18.2.1 Path-independent binary barrier options 18.2.2 Path-dependent binary barrier options 18.3 Valuation of Barrier Options 18.3.1 'In' barrier options 18.3.2 'Out' barrier options 18.3.3 Outside barrier options: an alternative approach 18.4 Analysis and Valuation of Standard and Exotic Options Using Binary Options 18.4.1 Example 1: Standard options 18.4.2 Example 2: Down-and-out call options 18,4.3 Example 3: Switch options 18.4.4 Example 4: Corridor options 18.4.5 Example 5: Knock-out range options 18.5 Continuous Strike and Continuous Barrier Options 18.5.1 Definitions and analysis 18.5.2 Valuation of the continuous strike option 18.5.3 Continuous strike range options 18.5.4 Soft barrier options 18.6 Static Hedging of Barrier Options 18.6.l Hedging at-the-money down-and-in cals 18.6.2 Hedging out-of-the-money down-and-in calls 18.6.3 Hedging in-the-money down-and-in calls
359 359
361 361 361 364
368 369 370 373 374 375 377 379 379 379 380 38 1 382 382
382 383
384 384 386 386 386
387
344
Summary
389
345
Points for Discussion
389
CONTENTS
xiv
CHAPTER
19: LOOKBACK
391
OPTIONS
391 391 392
Chapter Outline Introduction 19.1 Analysis of Lookback Options 19.1.1 Examplesofstandardlookbackoptions 19.1.2 The floating strike lookback 19.1.3 Fixed strike lookbacks 19.1.4 Lookback strategies 19.2 Analytic Formulas for Lookback Options 19.2.1 Standard lookback options 19.2.2 Options on extrema 19.2.3 Limited risk options 19.2.4 Partial lookback options 19.2.5 Simulations 19 3 Analytic Formula for an Exotic Tiratag Option:
394 395
395 396 397 398 399
tle BOMalah-PWgrat
Model 19.3.1 Analysis and valuation 19.3.2 Simulations and option characteristics 114 Analysis and Valuation of the Strike Bonus Option .
.
19.4.1 The strike option 19.4.2 The fractional bonus option 19.4.3 The hedging of strike bonus options Summary Points for Discussion
CHAPTER 20: ASIAN AND FLEXIBLE
About the Authors
392
393 394
ASIAN OPTIONS
409
Summary Points for Discussion Bibliography
425
Index
441
Introduction 20.1 The Average Price Options: Analysis and Valuation 20.1.1 Analysis 20.1.2 The valuation approaches 20.2 Analysis and Valuation of Basket Options 20.3 Analysis and Valuation of Flexible Asian Options 20.3.1 Flexible Asian options 20.3.2 Approximating flexible arithrnetic Asian options 20.3.3 Some properties
.
-
401 402 403 403 405 406 407 407 407
409 409 4l l 412 413 418 420 421 422 423 423 423
Chapter Outline
Professor Mondher Bellalah is Professor of Financial Economics at Université du Maine, France. He also holds teachmg and research positions at Université ParisDauphine, Université de Cergy-Pontoise and IHEC Tunis. He has been involved in activities at BNP. He currently acts as a financial engineering and market-making consultant for financial institutions. Associate Consultant at Philipponnat & Associés. Options, Futures and Exotic Derivatives is his third finance text. His articles have also appeared m the Financial Review and the Journal of Futures Markets. .
.
.
.
Dr Eric Briys is Director, International Fixed Income Research, at Lehman Brothers in London, UK. He was formerly Professor of Finance at Groupe HEC, one of Europe's leading business schools, where he was head of the Finance and Economics Department and Dean of the MBA programme. He is the Editor of the Review ofDerivatives Research and the former Editor of Finance, the journal of the French Finance Association. He has published widely in leading scientific journals such as the Journal of Finance, the Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, and the American Economic Review. Dr Huu Minh Mai holds a PhD in Finance from Université Paris-Dauphine. He is currently a financial statistician and a research officer at MONEP, the French Options Markets in Paris. Prior to joining MONEP he held research positions at Université-Paris Dauphine and Associés en Finance. His articles have appeared m Fmance. .
.
.
.
Dr François de Varenne is Head of Financial and Economic Affairs at the French Federation of Insurance Companies. He is also part-time lecturer at Groupe HEC and ISFA Lyon. A graduate of Ecole Polytechnique, he is a co-founder and co-principal of Dixon Associates, a consulting firm specialising for in asset-liability management msurance companies. He has widely published in leading scientific journals such as the Journal of Risk and Insurance and the Journal of Financial Quantitative Analysis.
We would like to thank Ahnani Mohamed for his computational
assistance.
PREFACE
xy¡¡
'dissection'
of (very)exotic ones. Again, our main instruments and ends up with the has exhaustive possible. This effort is indeed more than been be to concern as as necessary. Derivatives are still viewed as some kind of evil, of permanent threat to the socalled economy'. Any financial collapse is usually attributed to derivatives in the place: indeed, first a scapegoat is most useful when the outside world does not understand exactly what it is made of. In ancient Greece the messenger was often killed simply because he would carry bad news. Derivatives are like this messenger. This reminds us of Baron' WorralL The a famous Battle of Britain ace, the late Air Vice-Marshal John Baron led a Hurricane fighter squadron throughout the fall of France and the Battle of Britain. The story2 has it that in the middle of a fierce fight he held the following exchange with his controller: 'real
'the
'24
Our colleague and dear friend Jamil Baz has his own unique way of describing modern Wall Street. He likes to compare Wall Street to the pharmaceutical industry. According to giants engaged in a fierce and him, investment banks are nothing but pharmaceutical This molecule will help molecule. towards the next pathbreaking endless competition producing new drugs (readfinancial instruments or strategies) capable of curing the pains and diseases (readrisk exposures) of Main Street (readcorporations, investors, individuals). This analogy indeed makes a lot of sense. The modern theory of financial argument to provide the required derivatives' pricing uses an or created priced together and by putting basic moleculos to achieve Derivatives are answers. the desired cash-flow pattern. In his foreword Oldrich Alfons Vasicek reminds us that derivatives pricing deals with the valuation of a security, called the derivative, relative to the value of another security, the underlying. If this pricing is not properly conducted, the derivative and the underlying security can be arbitraged against each other through the generate a positive gain on a position (the riskless asset) use of another that necessitates no investment and carries no risk To put it in a nutshell this text is about this fascinating process. It starts in 'Wall Street labs' where rocket scientists try to provide the solutions so badly needed by the agents actively involved in the growth of our economies. This is not just another text on options and futures. It goes without saying that there are already outstanding textbooks on the subject in the bookstore next door. It is less obvious, at least to the best ofour knowledge, that there are numerous textbooks that cover the A to Z of derivatives pricing. By A we mean the scientific and mathematical foundations. By Z we mean the study of the latest instruments insofar as it is possible to write (andpublish) as fast as Wall Street launches currently new exotjes! By the intermediate letters we mean the tools and techniques action'. available that we describe and analyze Three main blocks can be distinguished. The first and surely inescapable one deals with the economic foundations of the theory of derivatives (Modigliani-Miller propositions, arbitrage versus equilibrium, complete versus incomplete markets, notion of numeraire). It goes hand in hand with the second building block. This block develops the mathema_ tical toolkit that really leverages the previous concepts (stochasticcalculus, Itõ's lemma, Girsanov theorem, partial differential equations, numerical and simulation techniques). The third block combines the two previous blocks. It starts with the analysis of standard 'replication'
'assembly'
'to
'molecule'
.
'in
Controller: bombers with 20 plus more behind them.' Worrall: 'Got it.' plus more bombers and 20 fighters behind and above.' Controller: Warrall: 'All right,' Controller: 'Now 30 more bombers and further 100 plus fighters following.' Worrall: 'Stop. No more information please. You are frightening me terribly.' '20
Derivatives are in a sense very similar to Air Vice-Marshal Worrall's controller. That is why so many people are so frightened by them. We hold the opposite view and sometimes ask ourselves how people could make it without derivatives! In any case it is our hope that this textbook along with former and future ones will pave the way towards a better understandmg of the numerous benefits of financial markets. This book could not have been in your hands without accumulating a significant leveraged position (in many different currencies!). Indeed, we are indebted to many people for their invaluable help at different stages ofthe manuscript. Oldrich Alfons Vasicek has written a useful and insightful foreword that reallv helps to set the landscape. An old friend is the one who is always there to offer his advice and give you a hand when you need it. No doubt that Oldrich genuinely belongs to this most sought after category! Nassim Taleb, a best-selhng author of John Wiley & Sons and a truly remarkable ethnologist of financial markets, has done a superb job (beyondduty) in helping us improve what was m the begmnmg a very'rough draft. He has all our gratitude. This book is a joint effort between (former)academics and practitioners. In that last respect we owe special thanks to Lehman Brothers. Thanks to its friendly and highly professional atmosphere it has helped one ofus in his migration from an academic position into (hopefully!) a fully fledged investment banking role. This book is also the reflection of real life on a trading floor. It has benefited from the views, explanations and market insights of Alexandre Abadie, Kaushik Amin, Sandro Anchisi, Makram Azar, Riccardo Banchetti, Mark Benson, Robert Campbell, Glauco Cerri, Jos Corswarem, Benoît d'Angelin, Milena Dapcevic, Karim Derhalli, Dan Donovan, Adrian Fitzgibbon, Aògan Foley, Reza Ghodsi, François Girod, Lennart Hergel, Michael Hof, Roger Howgego, John Hunt, John McDonald, Benoit Migeot, Daniel Morley, Ken Nadel, Cyrille Paillard, Theo Phanos, Nicolas Pourcelet, David Prieul, Harsh Shah and Aubin Thomine-Desmazures. 'very
PREFACE
PREFACE
xviii
A book is like good wine. It has to age before it stands on bookstore shelves (nottoo long, hopefully). Even if they often do not realize it, a lot of different people contribute to make this aging period a very profitable one. Many thanks to Ramasastry Ambarish, Citibank; Michel Antakli, Morgan Stanley; Jo Assaraf, Discount Bank and Trust Company; Pierre Bernhard, Ecole Supérieure des Sciences Informatiques; Jean-Pierre Bobillot, Predica; Driss Ben Brahim, Goldman Sachs; Evert Carlsson, Skandia Investment Management; Jean Castellini (BARRA); Fred Célimène, Université des Antilles et de la Guyane; Jean-Louis Charles, AXA; Gilles Dupin, Groupe Monceau; Romain Durand, SCOR; Christian Ferry, Generali Finance; Claudio Giraldi, Istituto Nazionale delli Assicurazioni; Jean-Michel Hainard, Providentia; Denis Kessler, AXA; Ambroise Laurent, Paribas; François Martin, Assurances du Crédit Mutuel; Alessio Matteuzzi, Instituto Nazionale delli Assicurazioni; Philippe de Moustiers, Citibank; Gérard Pellieux, Caisse Nationale du Crédit Agricole; Michel Pelosoff, Union des Assurances Fédérales; Lester Seigel; Yves Simon, Université Paris-Dauphine; Denis Talay, Institut National de Recherche en Informatique et Automatique; Jean-Luc Vila, Convergence; and Patrick Werner, French Federation of Insurance Companies. Last but not least, Jamil Baz. Jamil loves the subway, especially the London Circle Line! This is a convenient way for exchanging ideas and turning a whole series of concepts upside down. Believe it or not, Jamil Baz and Eric Briys never missed either Liverpool Street station or High Street Kensington station! This book owes a lot to Jamil and his deep and sincere friendship. Jamil is indeed a rare combination: option theorist, option practitioner, math addict, philosopher and a fork'! We have also run into debt'. Many thanks to the Mathematics and Finance and Economics faculties and students of Groupe HEC, of Institut Supérieur de Finance et Assurance (ISFA), of Université des Antilles et de la Guyane (Martinique), of Institut National de Recherche en Informatique et Automatique (INRIA), of Université ParisDauphine, of Université de Cergy, of Université du Maine and of Université de Genève. There is another academic debt that we will never be able to repay. We have been bold enough to augment it. Robert C. Merton has kindly accepted! We are deeply honored by his words of endorsement. Paul A. Samuelson has described Robert C. Merton as a giant among the giants. If needed, our bibliography is a standing proof of it. Robert C. Merton has influenced the work and professional lives of numerous scholars and practitioners. We are very proud to be part of them. The professional staff at John Wiley & Sons is first class. Having heard our countless promises, we are sure they know exactly what default risk means, when an option is in or out of the money, what a forward position implies, what it means to be long or short. In any case, they can be sure that they taught us something very special indeed: trust. First, our deepest gratitude to Nick Wallwork who first decided that it was worth entering the forward contract. We hope that he did not leave London for Singapore because of us! Our editor, David Wilson, who took over from Nick, is now a close friend. We owe him a lot. He knows why! We are also grateful and proud of Louise Holden and Jennifer Mackenzie. They have done a terrific job even though we kept changing our minds. At the Oscar ceremony in Hollywood, movie directors, actors and actresses apologize for not naming people whose contribution was none the less instrumental. The same applies here. Our sincere apologies to those we have inadvertently omitted. These last few weeks have been a period where the four of us have gone hunting. More precisely typos, errors and inconsistencies hunting. We are afraid that in this matter zero 'solid
'academic
4
,
default does not any errors in the our manuscript. publisher permits
y¡
exist and we feel very sorry for that. Please let us know if you discover text or, on a more positive note, if you know about ways of improving Our only excuse is that this is the first edition. Hopefully and if our we will not have to invoke it again in the future!
Mondher Bellalah Eric Briys Huu Minh Mai François de Varenne
FOREWORD
Foreword
The theory of derivative asset pricing, or options pricing as it is more often referred to, is one of the great achievements of modern finance. It has become an essential tool in the valuation of derivatives. It is indispensable in risk management of derivative books. It allows valuation of corporate liabilities given the value of the firm assets, or valuation of corporate debt given the value of the firm equity. Besides its immense practical applicability, options pricing has also greatly advanced the theoretical understanding of financial markets and has led to many new insights. It fostered the development and application of new techniques, such as valuation in continuous time (whereasset prices are represented by Itö processes or other continuous time stochastic processes). It has led to the concepts of risk-neutral valuation and of the pricing probability measures. And it has engendered new areas of finance, such as models of the term structure of interest rates, What is options pricing? It deals with the valuation of one asset, or security, called the An asset is derivative, relative to the value of another asset or security, the underlying. called a derivative with respect to another if all of its payouts depend only on the value of the underlying. A simple example is a call option on a common stock. The payout on the call is determined solely by the value of the stock: it is the excess of the stock price over the strike price if the call is exercised, or zero if not. Another example is the value of a is the market value of the firm's assets (that corporate bond. In this case, the underlying is, the value of its ongoing business). It is obvious that the price of the derivative asset must be related to the price of the underlying one. Since the payout on a call option on a stock depends only on the stock price, the price of the call must be a function of the stock price. But which function'? Options pricing provides the answer. The function must be such that the return on the option (whichis given by the percentage increment of the function) in excess of the riskless return must be proportional to the return on the underlying asset in excess of the riskless return. If this were not the case, the option and the underlying asset could be arbitraged against each other (with the use of the riskless asset) to generate a positive gain on a position that necessitates no investment and carries no risk. This should not be possible in an efficient market. It turns out (and this is one of the achievements of the theory of options pricing) that function in relationship such a condition on the increment of the unknown to the increment of the underlying asset value, together with the specification of the option nrovisions, snecifies the function in full The ftmetion navouts nrovided bv its contractual
xx¡
can be sought out in either of two equivalent ways. One way is to determine the option value as the solution of a partial differential equation to which the price of any derivative asset must conform (this equation was initially derived by Black and Scholes, and independently, by Merton), subject to boundary conditions given by the form of the payout. This equation was originally solved by Black and Scholes for the European call and put, to yield their celebrated formula. The other way to get the option value has the tremendous appeal of bringing out the economic, rather than only mathematical, aspect of the options pricing theory, It is shown that the option is priced as the present value (discountedat the riskless rate) of the mathematical expectation of the payouts; provided, however (and this is a deep and subtle is calculated not with respect to the actual point of the theory), that the expectation probability distribution of the payouts, but rather with respect to an alternative probability distribution. This alternative distribution, called the pricing distribution, is the one the payouts would have in a risk-neutral economy. In such an economy, the expected rate of return on all assets is the riskless rate. The pricing probability distribution is thus obtained as if the underlying asset appreciated on average at the riskless rate, rather than at its own actual expected rate of return. The reason here is that the relationship of the option price to the price of the underlying does not depend on investors' attitudes toward risk, and therefore must be the same as in a risk-neutral world (and in a risk-neutral world, we know how assets are priced: as the expected present values of their payouts). Besides valuation, the theory yields powerful results for risk measurement and managenient. The hedging ratios, or deltas, for hedging the risk of derivatives positions can be calculated by differentiation, with respect to the price of the underlying asset, of the option value. These hedge ratios also provide a measure of elasticity, or exposure to the risk of the underlying security. By reducing the delta of a derivative portfolio (they combine linearly), the exposure to a given risk source is reduced. Other risk measures (gamma,theta, etc.), highly useful in managing a derivatives book, are likewise determined from the valuation formulas. By inverting the formulas, it is possible to obtain measures of stock volatility implicit in the market price of an option. Altogether, options pricmg is one of the most fascinating (not to mention useful m practical applications) areas of finance. Hundreds, if not thousands, of articles and tens of books have been written on the subject. Why, then, this book? One of the merits of this book is that it is self-contained. It was written for the sauvage intelligent: it does not necessitate any previous knowledge of the field. It can be read and understood by any quantitatively oriented person. One could well envision an investment bank or a brokerage firm hiring a PhD in physics, say, turning the book over to him and say: 'Read this, and develop for us a system for valuation and risk management of our derivatives portfolio'. It is both a textbook and a reference book. It covers the basics of the theory, as well as the techmques for valuation of many of the more exotic derivatives. It contains a detailed of knowledge of the field. What is more, however, it is written with a deep understanding the economics of finance. Not only how, but why of the options pricing; not only a compendium of existing results, but a methodology for deriving new ones. Congratulations on your selection, Oldrich Alfons Vasicek Managing Director The KMV Corporation, San Francisco, USA
Financial
CHAPTER This chapter
Markets, Innovation and Trading Activity
OUTLINE' is organized as follows:
1. Section 1.1 shows why and how managing financial risks may yield improved corporate returns. 2. Section 1.2 gives insights into the implementation of financial risk management. 3. Section 1.3 presents the main trading mechanisms in securities markets. 4. Section 1.4 illustrates the main trading strategies that are feasible with options.
INTRODUCTION Have you ever been in San Francisco at the auction house of Buttlerfield and Buttlerfield? No. Well, you should! The reason? In California, when a red wine is 10 years old, its owner can sell it legally without a retailer's license. It is still time to get there: the 1982 Bordeaux were something special. Their prices have been skyrocketing over the last ten years. Sell your 1982 Léoville-Las Cases now for a net hammer price of $700 a case and you will enjoy a nice 15% a year average return. Basically, it boils down to making a liquid asset really liquid! Assume now that you love wine so much that you are a shareholder of Léoville-Las Cases. Well, it sounds a lot more difficult to make your shares as liquid as your wine! Léoville-Las Cases is not quoted on the Paris Bourse. Many people will argue that you do not have to worry about it. After all, you own one of the safest assets in the world: a unique Bordeaux chateau producing a most prestigious wine! Well, things are not that simple and you will soon discover that your investment is both interest-rate and exchange-rate sensitive. How come? Wine has to age in cellars. As a consequence cash is tied up in the production process. The clientele base is primarily abroad and
his chapter
draws heavly on Briys and Crouhy 0993¾
OPTIONS,
2
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
FINANCIAL
most of the sales are dollar-denominated. Now, the question is: should Léovile-Las that is Cases hedge itself or should it just concentrate on its secular savoir-faire, Is there any value in managing financial risks should it just stick-to-the-knitting? instead of relying solely upon weather forecasts? Does it really improve the shareholders' situation? Does it help enhance the quality of wine? For a wine connoisseur all these questions may seem surprising and even spoil the genuine pleasure of winetasting! The authors of this book are nevertheless (not to say, obviously) wine lovers! They the deep purple color, the are convinced that there is much finance can do to unusual nose and blended flavor of a 1985 Cöte Rotie Cõte Brune. In other words, the authors truly believe that overlooking fmancial risks and their strategic implications and can even result in painful corporate always entails devastating consequences
MARKETS,
INNOVATION
Its supporters among Wall Street for long-term planning.
'hedge'
bankruptcies.
AND TRADING
analysts
ACTIVITY
say that the company
3
ís being penalized
To put it in a nutshell, the stock market is claimed to be too short-sighted to be trusted. But why is it so that modern finance theory has so far been so stubborn as not to recognize the obvious? The only answer is that its message has been misunderstood and deserves some clarification. Such a misunderstanding is all the more surprising since this message is so intuitive that it should appeal to everybody. First, it says that the benchmark is the share value: no surprise! As a manager you have got to care for your owners! You are in charge because they wanted you to be in charge. As long as you can show them that you care and do deliver, there is a fairly good chance that you will stay on board. Then, the message says that you cannot fool your fellow shareholders or outside analysts even by using the most inventive cosmetics. Well, again, a simple result: trust the law of supply and demand, the famous Invisible Hand. As they used to say in Chicago can fool some of the people some of the time, but you cannot fool all the people all of the time'. The market is a powerful machine for assessing and processing information. As a manager, you have to be humble enough to recognize that this machine is stronger than you. Last part of the message: the market will not pay at a premium for what it can undo. That is certainly the most controversial and vividly discussed part. Basically, it says that there is not much finance can do to enhance corporate share value. Nevertheless, there are virtues of financial decisions. For instance, corporate still a lot of believers in the thought financial leverage is by many to add value to the firm. Note that at the same time these people argue that in the current period of economic downturn German firms are better off than French firms because their leverage is much less. It is rather astonishing how Modigliani and Miller's simple proposition has been misinterpreted. It simply boils down to: you cannot change the size of the cake by the way you cut it. What matters is the ability of the firm to produce the cake (read:economic cash-flows). Afterwards, it does not take an expert to cut a cake (read:the market can undo it) but it takes a 'Three Star Michelin' baker (read:efficient, innovative and gifted human capital) to cook a tasty one! To many people and especially managers all this is too simple to be true. It contradicts casual daily observation: firms do care about finance. They hire CFOs, treasurers, etc. who spend days, not to say nights, balancing equity and debt, tuning corporate hedging sophisticated issuing warrants and convertibles. So, how come there is such a programs, gap between what theory says and what practice does? Well, the gap is artificial and it succumbs to a more careful analysis. It is true that firms do care about finance but not for the reasons that are most often quoted. For instance, some five years ago, it was commonplace to hear that the French corporation Thomson was making two-thirds of its profits in the financial area (throughits bank Altus). It was even suggested that financial investments with their appealing yields were cannibalizing Thomson's industrial efforts. Finance was even said to jeopardize the real economy. Such an analysis is obviously too superficial and too often confuses profits, earnings per share, cash-flows, stock prices, etc. There are only two ways whereby a firm can add value for its shareholders: either by mcreasing operating cash-flows or by lowering discount rates. The first solution is precisely what the corporation is all about. Based on its expertise, competitive edge, cash-flows. There patents, R&D expenses, etc., the firm has the ability to is not much the CFO can do inthat respect, except maybe teach the'cash-flow attitude' to 'you
DO FIRMS CARE ABOUT
I.!
FINANCE?
This section attempts to answer the following questions: .
• • • •
.
.
.
Why and how should one formulate efficient financial risk management policies? How do these policies impact in turn on company performance'? Why does proactive financial risk management add value to the firm'? How is this done? Are there good reasons for using financial markets for hedgmg purposes?
'real'
.
•
f.I.1
Finance
is a Fun Game
.
to Play, Hard to Win
Since the seminal paper by Modigliani and Miller (1958) much has been said about the objectives of the firm and the real impact of financial decisions on the firm's value. Modern finance theory contends that share value is the relevant benchmark for measur sinc$ ing performance it reflects both risk and the time value of money. An optimal by precisely focusing on those decisions allocation of corporate efforts is achievable value. Needless to say that this rather simple proposition which maximize shareholder analysts, CEOs, and policy_ has been (is still) subject to sharp criticism. Many shortmakers still consider this proposition to be a dangerous one: by over-emphasizing term effects (the price of the stock tomorrow) it penalizes long-term thinking which after all is the key to future prosperous growth. According to many critics (Hayes and Abernathy, 1980; Hayes and Garvin, 1982) such concepts as Net Present Value taught in most prestigious MBA courses are weird instruments which account for the decline of Corporate America. For instance. Lawrence M. Fischer wrote in the New York Times (May 20, 1991):
Ènancial
The more by Apple Computer to gain machines hui the resuhing is succeeding,
market strain
bv introducing lower-priced on profits has driven its stock down. share
\
'manufacture'
OPTIONS,
4
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
his colleagues. The second solution is precisely the battlefield of the CFO. But is it really that easy to modify the corporate discount rate, namely the cost of capital or the rate of things: first, return required by fund providers? A discount rate is basically made of two will have that chance fair Alan Greenspan, it is Unless you is a your name an interest rate. nevertheless slight exception to this: taxesThere is interest rates. a time lowering hard a After-tax rates are obviously lower than before-tax rates because the firm is subsidized by the government. Interest charges are deductible from taxable corporate income. Things this subsidy gives an obvious advantage to debt are even more complicated. Although they also equity, investors taxes: may prefer receiving dividends or capital gains pay over rather than interest payments. It depends on their tax brackets and the current fiscal which on regime. The CFO had better be smart to play around with these tax penalties time. changing over top of that are The second component is a risk premium. It is there to reward shareholders for carrying the risks of the business they own. Shareholders face two basic risks. The first the firm is involved in. Some businesses are more one is related to the type of business environment. volatile than others; they react more strongly to changes in the economic This kind of volatility cannot be changed in the short run: it takes major modifications and significant transaction costs to lower the business risk. The room for manoeuvre is noted that conglomerates of the sixties were assembled in narrow. In passing it should be would pay. 2 + 2 5 was the credo at the time. As diversification that corporate the hope time went by it soon became apparent that 2 + 2 was still equal to 4 in the best cases or add value. The market can just undo it even to three! Corporate diversification does not stocks. of In portfolio their famous 'In Search of Excellence', well-diversified by buying a should corporations that to the knitting'. The clear make and Waterman it Peters second risk is known as financial risk and arises mainly because of the use of debt leverage. We are back to the good old cake story. The situation seems to be hopeless for =
'stick
the poor CFO. Virginia, there is hope'. Indeed, the cake story As the Deep South song has it, holds true as long as some assumptions are met. For instance, every market player has to and know exactly what the cake is all about, its size, its composition (what Modigliani cake of the cherries should part There be perfect call on any information). no Miller (Modigliani and Miller initially assumed no taxation, hence no tax shield). The knife for cutting the cake should come for free (Modigliani and Miller assumed no transaction costs). The sliced cake (read levered) and the unsliced cake (read unlevered) should come risk for both the from the same baker (Modigliani and Miller assumed identical business levered and the unlevered firm). Some skeptical people will immediately argue that much is too much'. So many drastic assumptions cannot really account for the intricacies of the corporate environment. Assumptions should be taken the other way round. Now enhance that we know that in a so-called perfect world, corporate finance cannot result whether still holds the true when corporate share values, we should next ask result gives benchmark the another it To put way, are (re)introduced. indications to CFOs where to look so as to add their own part to the cake. At any rate, the imperfections, to take advantage of them, in other game for the CFO is to track those clientele. Brealey and Myers (1988) give a nice example of words to find the untapped attitude. In October 1970, ATT decided to issue Ma Bell savings bonds. such a proactive directly sold bonds to investors through the roughly two thousand ATT These were yield business offices. Up to now nothing really exotic. The clever idea was simply the 'yes,
'too
'imperfections'
FINANCIAL
i
, '
MARKETS,
INNOVATION
AND TRADING
ACTIVITY
5
offered. ATT savings bonds were copycats of US savings bonds because of ATT's high credit rating. Instead of offering a 5.5% yield like the US government, ATT offered for the same maturity 6.5%, namely a spread of 100 basis points. The issue was a success because it attracted an untapped clientele. Indeed, the rate on federal savings was locked in by law to protect savings institutions from a so-called destabilizing rate competition and to give people a less costly access to housing. As a result small investors snapped up ATT's offer. A good bargain for ATT: a regular issue on the bond market would have cost 8.6%! Nevertheless, ATT was forced to capitulate. The federal government required a cancellation of the total issue! Whatever the end, this story perfectly illustrates what we call hunt for the white elephant'. The CFO has to realize that he is not the only smart in the market. In capital markets, investors will try (and often be successful in) hunter there is no such thing as a patent in a stealing a brilliant idea from him. And remember financial market: that is why it is deemed to be efficient! 'the
1.1.2
Some
Commonly
Encountered
Pitfalls
In a recent Harvard Business Review paper Rappaport (1992)quotes a survey that had been conducted by Louis Harris and Associates in 1987 just one month before the market crash. The pollsters asked a sample of one thousand CEOs the following question: 'Is the current price of your company's stock an accurate indicator of its real value?' Fifty-eight percent answered no, and according to Rappaport most of them truly believed that the their shares. market was undervaluing the strategist guru of Harvard, supports the same view. According to Porter (1992a,b), him, the US economy is plagued by three major flaws: • • •
markets are only interested in short-term gains; Investors are impatient and they force managers to behave in a myopic manner; Managers are more interested in dealmaking than in production, service and long-term corporate strategy.
US financial
At the same time some companies like PepsiCo argue that shareholder value-based resources allocation (at all levels) ends up in truly competitive advantage. Their daily management practice does not seem to fit well with Porter's arguments. It is also true that many managers believe that the stock market does not fairly price their company's shares. They are deeply convinced that Earnings Per Share (EPS) is the real key to the game. In the Wall Street Journal (October 1, 1974) one could read that lot of executives apparently believe that if they can figure out a way to boost earnings, their stock prices will go up even if the higher earnings do not represent any underlying economic change'. and the manager is In other words, the market is only smart guy in zero upstairs' town'! The EPS or cosmetics mystique still remains very strong. But, how come managers can still reasonably advocate the foolishness of the market to justify their own behavior? According to Rappaport, the first obvious reason is that know more about their businesses than the market does and thus arrive at a different, often higher, value for their company's sharcs'. Managers strongly believe that even with fully disclosed information the market is still at a disadvantage when it comes to decipher the true and only corporate message. This belief has its roots in a second 'a
'a
'managers
'the
6
OPTIONS,
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
FINANCIAL
'short
termism vs. long termism'. The market is said not to reason which is usually called be able to decipher because it is too impatient. A lot of managers are convinced that the market does not take the long view and cares more about visible short-term results. This argument even leads some of them to sacrifice crucial investments to concentrate on more impressive short-term gains. General Electric and Westinghouse are good examples when they decided to leave the industrial robotics arena. Porter has recently argued that the reason for such mistakes lies in the widely dispersed ownership of American companies. According to him, Germany and Japan are much less exposed because of more concentrated ownership. Needless to say, this line of reasoning is rather dubious and not at all supported by empirical evidence. Nevertheless, a lot of managers continue to worship EPS although there is now ample evidence that the market knows how to read between the lines. To paraphrase Bernstein (1992),'American financial markets suffer from the ignorance and longstanding suspicion of people who function outside those markets. If something is wrong in the real economy, why not find a way to pin the blame on financial markets?'. McKinsey (1990)classifies the evidence against the hypothesis' into three classes: .
.
.
'scapegoat
•
Numerous studies show that accounting earnmgs are not very well correlated with share prices. The market is not reacting myopically to changes in EPS. As Rappaport appropriate, the market uses unexpected changes in earnings as a useful has it, 'when
•
•
proxy for reassessing a company's future cash flows.' Numerous studies show that earnings window dressing does not enhance share prices. Announced changes in accounting methods that impact on reported earnings but not on cash flows do not affect stock prices at all. For instance, switches from LIFO to FIFO (or the other way round) in inventory accounting do not affect corporate cash flows except for increased or decreased taxes. Numerous studies show that the market does indeed take the long-term view. A simple test of the time honzon of the stock market is to examine how much a company's current share price can be accounted for by its discounted expected dividends. Rappaport (1992)quotes a recent study by the Alcar Group which is quite revealingThe Alcar Group analyzed the stock prices of 30 Dow Jones Industrial companies. It found that between 80% and 90% of the stock prices were attributable to expected cash flows paid out in the form of dividends beyond five years'. Table 1.1 summarizes their results. 'typically
In the same vein, studies on R&D expenses reach the same conclusions. Studies by SEC (1985)and Randall Woolridge (1988) show that companies with the highest levels of spending on R&D tend to have the highest P/E ratios. This obviously contradicts the standard EPS view that the market working horizon does not go beyond its is king'! The market believes in one single god: cash fiow. There The truth is that is not much cosmetics can do. The irony is that even though more and more managers message' tend to recognize this, they still argue that they have to depart from the They simply forget that the market because of free-riders or aggressive competitors. analyzes not only the outputs of the decision to invest but also the damaging long-term of being able to sustain a real competitive consequences of not investing. The credibility advantage in the long run does not come for free. 'nose'.
'cash
'key
MARKETS,
I.I
TABLE
INNOVATION
The Stock
Market
AND TRADING
Takes
7
the Long View
Price of3 (os I Dec. 9 I)
Company
ACTIVITY
CumulativePresent Volue of Five Year Dividend Forecost
% o¶Current Share Pace . Attributable to E×pectations 8eyond Five Years
--
ALCOA Anled-Signal American Express
$
AT&T Bethlehem steel Boeing
14.00 47.75 43.88 69.00 80.25 I 14.50 46.63 48.25 60.88 76.50 28.88 53.50 89.00 70.75 38.00 166.50 95.25 68.63 80.25 93.88 37.88 61.25 20.25 54.25 18.00 26.50
caterpillar Chevron Coca-Cola
Disney Du Pont Eastman Kodak Exxon General Electric General Motors Goodyear
IBM international
Paper
McDonald's Merck 3M
J.P. Morgan Philip Morris Procter & Gamble
Sears, Roebuck Texaco
Union Carbide United Technologies Westinghouse Woolworth Source: Briys and Crouhy
1.1.3
Some
Good
64.38 43.88 20.50 39.13
$
6.22 3.56
3.80 5.92
2.15 5.! I 5.02 \3.59 4.72 3.l8 7.00 7.42 i \.36 8.77 6.06 l.79 19.73 6,65 l,6l I l.5l 12.67 7.96 10.05 9.45 7. I2 12.56 3.56 6.86 5.07 4.43
90.3% 91.9 81.5 84.9
84.7 89.3 88.6 80.3 94.I 97.2 85.0 84.6 8 i.3
88.5 79.0 96.7 77.8 90.6 95.8 93.1 86.7 88.4 87.5 89.9 8l 79.5 82.4 87.4 71.8 83.3 .2
(1993) Reasons
for Hedging
Before going into details of how a firm should hedge, the first question to be answered is whether a firm should hedge. As the reader may recall from the Introduction, the issue is not as straightforward as it might initially appear. Hedging is a financial decision which at first sight does not modify the size of operating cash flows. Moreover, even though wipe out financial risk, it does not pay a corporation hedging, asset/liability management to eliminate fmancial risk if shareholders can achieve the same result for the same or lower cost. The market does not value what it can undo. Nevertheless, as we have seen in our brief overview of Modigliani and Miller, some reasonable arguments can be put forward to legitimate proactive risk management.
OPTIONS,
8
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
1. Taxes again play a significant role. The following example based on Stulz and Smith why taxes may induce a firm to hedge. Assume that the before-tax corporate income may take only two values with equal probability, namely 200 and -100. The tax rate is 40% and there is no loss offset. In other words, when the firm experiences losses, it is not entitled to any tax credit. The expected after-tax corporate income is equal to:
(1985)shows
l /2(200 80) + 1/2(-100)
=
-
10
The expected income before tax is equal to: 1|2(200)
Namely, an after-tax
amount
equal
+ 1/2(-100)
=
50
MARKETS,
INNOVATION
AND TRADING
ACTlYITY
9
disastrous ventures in the high technology business filed for Chapter 11 protection. The Multigraphics Division of AM International had seven presidents in as many years. It is rather obvious that shaping a so-called corporate culture becomes rather difficult in such an environment. 5. Bankruptcy is usually a very costly procedure: legal fees, transaction costs, etc. Fund providers usually ask to be compensated for these extra costs through higher returns. 6. Loan covenants may sometimes be stringent enough to motivate a proactive risk financial risk may even reduce the corporation management. To some extent managing borrowmg costs.
to 30.
The firm is better off in the second case which is precisely the case whereby any variance in the profit function has been eliminated. The firm gets a clear incentive to undertake risk management policies. Note that in the case of a linear tax schedule (i.e. full loss offset) there is no room for hedging. Again, a market imperfection (non-linear tax schedule) helps justify a financial decision and improves the shareholder's position. 2. Shareholders may not know exactly the current risk exposure of the firm (asymmetric information) and even if they did they may not have easy access to risk control instruments. Levi (1990)for instance reports that a shareholder whose share exposure is $100 might face a bid-ask spread fifty times that of the company whose exposure is, say, over $1 million. In some cases, the shareholder may not have access to hedging instruments at all. 3. As Jensen and Meckling (1976)put it, a firm is just a nexus of contracts. A stable corporation may find it easier to negotiate its contracts with suppliers, clients, etc. No default could obviously be a strong selling argument. Reputation effects may also be very damaging. For instance, the value clients place on service agreements, warranties or technical assistance obviously depends on the firm's financial stability. This is especially goods, namely goods or services for which quality and care are true for credence important but for which quality and care are difficult to assess prior to consumptionWine, restaurants, hotels, air travel belong to this category. Frequent travelers knew exactly what it meant when it came to travel on Pan Am. Customers tend to think that product quality (read safety in the case of air travel!) is lowered when the firm is on shaky ground. A weak firm will have a hard time convincing its clients that it can really deliver. That is precisely why Lee Iacocca decided that Chrysler should not file for bankruptcy:
Our situation was unique. It was not like the cereal business. If Kellogg's was known to be going out of business, nobody would say: well, I won t buy their cornflakes today. What if I get stuck with a box of cereal and there is nobody around to service it? (Fortune, November 26, 1984) 4. Corporate employees suffer from poor asset diversification: slavery is prohibited and within the company. There is now ample evidence that more their human capital is risky firms command higher wages. A lower employment uncertainty, other things being equal, means lower risk premiums, namely lower wages. This in turn may increase operating cash flows. Moreover, financial distress may be conducive to a high turnover of Shapiro and Titman (1986) quote the example of AM International which after managers. 'stuck'
FINANCIAL
1.2
HOW TO IMPLEMENT RISK MANAGEMENT
STRATEGIC
FINANCIAL
exposure to risk on expected cash fiows jeopardizes the future of the corporation as the previous section has shown. As risk goes up, the corporation's cost of simply doing business rises and renders its survival precarious. Just the rumor of some prophecy) whereby clients, difficulties is conducive to a bandwagon effect (self-fulfilling suppliers, distributors, subcontractors and so on run away from the firm. Usually, firms which produce goods or services that require maintenance or repair, that are based on credence, that involve significant switching costs, whose production mainly depends upon intangible assets (managers,brand names, savoir-faire), are likely to suffer greatly from
Large corporate
risk exposure.
As a consequence, the first duty of the CFO is to determine the corporation's global risk profile. Some businesses are more exposed than others. Indeed, the very nature of the business the corporation runs is sometimes highly conducive to financial risks exposure. A few examples are in order. The introductory exampic of the vineyard business is the most obvious one. Indeed, the process of wine-aging exposes the producer to the volatility of interest rates. The airline industry is another industry whose financial risks. A famous example is the wellbusiness cycle carries numerous documented case of Lufthansa. In 1985, Lufthansa placed an order with Boeing for know that aircraft delivery takes place much later some $500 million. Airline companies on. In the case of Lufthansa the deadline was one year. At the time of the order the dollar was very strong vs. the Deutsche Mark and a lot of people believed that the dollar was on the verge of reversing its upward trend. After much debate, Lufthansa decided to hedge only half of the amount by buying dollar forward. The rest of the position was just left open. Ex post the story was that Lufthansa would have been off' not hedging at all. In other words critics were just recommending straight speculation! The truth is that Lufthansa should have first looked at its entire currency which is not exposure and then decided to cover the residual component hedged. Instead of running a careful investigation, Lufthansa just picked the least flexible instrument in the range. Airline companies are not only exposed because of the purchase of planes. They are also exposed because of the fierce competition on airfares. Deregulation which is now part of their daily business has forced them to ofTer not only competitive prices but also to these prices over a contractual time span. Needless to say, in the meantime the price of kerosene might have gone through the roof' Another example is the pharmaceutical industry. R&D is one of the crucial keys 'better
'naturally'
'freeze'
OPTIONS,
10
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
in that business. For instance, Merck funds its US R&D through worldwide sales of which 40% are in foreign currencies. Any adverse change in currencies might endanger Merck's capacity to strengthen its R&D efforts. Some more subtle risk effects are also pervasive. Indeed, tackling the corporate risk issue requires taking a comprehensive view of the firm. The right approach has to encompass many dimensions such as investment, production, input-mix, pricing policies and financial decisions. These different items shape the structure of assets and liabilities, the stream of expected future cash flows, and obviously the risk profile of the firm. Risk is itself manifold and can be channelled to the firm through currencies, commodities and interest rates. The management of foreign exchange, commodity and interest rate risks has to be part of the global strategy of the firm. A comprehensive risk management program should incorporate expectations about changes in exchange rates and interest rates in all the above mentioned corporate decisions which affect the future cash flows, the financial structure, and the corporate risk profile. The question 'What is at risk?' must be treated stepwise. The identification procedure is based on a top-bottom approach rolling down from the strategic level to the financial level.
Strategic
FfNANClAL
DERIVATIVES
Level
The answers directly affect the investment, pricing, marketing and contracting policies of the firm. Foreign exchange swings may affect the company's competitive position. For example, whose costs are denominated in a depreciating currency will have a greater competitor a pricing flexibility and thus a potential competitive advantage: barriers to entry may become less effective and competition may affect profit margins. This is true even for domestic companies which buy and sell in their home currency. A purely domestic firm usually feels comfortable because it does not have the explicit burden of managing an interest rate or foreign currency exposure. This is the so-called 'I don't sell abroad, I don't have any exposure' syndrome. For instance, Nordic aluminum producers consume mainly local hydro-electricity and do not use imported oil. At first sight they do not have to worry much about the dollar's possible movements. Well, we are not so sure. A falling dollar may result in more competitive foreign producers. A falling dollar may even attract in Deutsche new market players. A firm need not pay bills in dollars or get revenues Marks to be exposed to currency risk. The very fact that its competitors are or could be thus exposed is enough to generate a strategic exposure. The message is then simple: are not exogenous, they are with your business'. The threat of functional substitutes should also be considered, whereby consumers switch from one product to another one. For example, a dollar appreciation against European currencies may alter the taste of Californians who will consider drinking French or Italian white wines instead of their tasty Chardonnays from the Nappa Valley. Foreign exchange and commodity movements may change the relative prices of raw materials and other key inputs of the industrial process, which may trigger technological changes. In most cases when these shocks are temporary, the best hedge could be a flexible oroduction process which allows for different input-mixes.
MARKEW dilillillillbaha11--IINiimliatagotNG ACTIVITY
¡¡
Economic Level "
A
The answers should come from a simultaneous analysis of asset and liability exposures, and in trying to locate natural hedges in the balance sheet. Changes in exchange rates, inflation, interest rates and commodity prices affect the company's cash flows, both: • •
directly, through interest rate payments, raw materials purchases or indirectly, for instance through the impact of higher financing costs for customers on the demand for the company's products; these gyrations may also induce a relative price effect which affects differently the costs and the revenues, putting the firm in a squeeze regarding its profitability.
Interest rate risk deserves special treatment since it cannot be dissociated from inflation risk. The main determinant of long-term yields is expectations of inflation. Therefore, for those companies whose long-term operating profits follow closely innation, higher inflation means higher revenues to offset the increase in financing cost. For such companies, fixed-rate debt increases the interest rate risk exposure since it will generate an unexpected loss when the rate of inflation (i.e. of interest and of revenue growth) unexpectedly slows down. On the contrary, it will provide a windfall gain to the company when interest rates and inflation increase. Thus, while fixed-rate debt seems to eliminate uncertainty about interest rate payments, it represents a bet on inflation. Floating rate debt, by contrast, offers a long-term natural hedge against inflation risk, although interest rate payments will fluctuate over time. It is the other way around for companies whose operating profits are quite insensitive to changes in interest rates, Finance Level At this stage the company is concerned only with the residual financial risks that, by any means, it wants to shift away from the balance sheet to the capital markets. This is a purely technical approach for which the company can hire the skills of fmancial managers recently trained in modern investment banking. Hedging tells you what type and how many forward contracts, futures contracts, swaps, options to use to transfer the undesired risks to speculators who stand ready to bear these risks for a reward (i.e. a positive expected profit). Financial engineering can be helpful in designing securities which bring together issuers and investors (read which complete the market) and allows firms to hedge at a lower cost than with traditional instruments.
'risks
Forward Rote Contracts They are the simplest and most basic hedging instruments. A forward contract is an agreement between two parties to set the price today for a transaction that will not be completed until a specified date in the future. For example, a forward contract for $1 million, to be delivered in 6 months, at a price of FF6.00 for a dollar. These terms oblige the seller of the contract, for example the bank. to transfer on the specified date, $1 million on the company's account, for the price set today. On the other hand, the buyer has no alternative than to accept delivery under the terms of the the contract at a later date, is to contract. The only possibility for the buyer to 'cancel'
12
OPTIONS,
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
FINANCIAL
MARKETS,
INNOVATION
AND TRADING
ACTIVITY
13
enter into a reverse forward contract, with the same bank or another institution, but at the expense of a loss (or a gain) since the new forward rate will be set at a new equilibrium level Forward rate contracts are flexible and allow for customized hedges since all the terms with the counterparty. However, each side of the contract bears the risk can be negotiated that the other side defaults on the future commitments. This is the reason why futures contracts are often preferred to forward contracts.
indexed Bonds When the operating profits of a corporation are exposed to the fluctuations of an index, as with a commodity price like oil, aluminum, or inflation - the exposure risk can be partially hedged by issuing bonds whose interest payments and/or principal repayment is linked to the index, in such a way that the effective cost of debt is movement reduced when there is an unfavorable in the price index, and is increased to the when the of the is favorable investors movement to the firm. benefit Some bond issues can be split into two parts: the bull and bear tranches, so that investors can choose only one side of the risk exposure. These bonds allow some investors
Like forward contracts, futures contracts Futures Contracts are used to lock in the company interest rate, exchange rate or commodity price. But futures markets are organized in such a way that the risk of default is (almost) completely eliminated. This is possible by trading futures contracts on an organized exchange with a clearinghouse which steps in between a buyer and a seller, each time a deal is struck in the pit. The clearinghouse adopts the position of the buyer to every seller, and of the seller to every buyer, i.e. the clearinghouse keeps a zero net position. This means that every trader in the and has strong expectations futures markets has obligations only to the clearinghouse, that the clearinghouse will maintain its side of the bargain as well. The credibility of the system is maintained through the requirements of margin and daily settlements. The main purpose of the margin is to provide a safeguard to ensure that traders will perform their obligations. It is usually set to the maximum loss a trader can experience in a normal trading day. Daily settlements or marking-to-market impose on each trader an obligation to realize any losses (or gains) on the day they occur. Since for each trader who loses (gains)there is another trader who gains (loses), this is a zero sum game. Marking-to-market just consists in a transfer of cash from one account to another. The elimination of default risk has a cost: contracts are standardized in order to bring liquidity to the market, there are only a few financial assets which are traded on futures markets and they do not necessarily correspond to the risk to be hedged. Therefore, there is no perfect hedge with futures contracts. The hedgers keep what is called a basis risk and a correlation risk which cannot be fully eliminated.
to take risky positions which are not directly available to them, or not allowed, on organized markets. Investors are ready to pay a premium for these opportunities which is translated into a reduced financing cost.
Swaps allow the exchange of one type of debt for another: fixed rate debt against rate debt, in the same currency or in a different currency. All combinations are possible. Like forward contracts, swaps are OTC instruments and subject to default risk. Swaps
floating
When a corporation has a low credit rating and must Warrants and Convertibles implement a large investment program to survive, it may well be too costly to issue standard debt, while raising equity might dilute considerably the current shareholders' position. Then, warrants (bondswith attached warrants) and convertibles become the only affordable financing instruments. When Faust struck his deal with the Devil, he ended up holding a naked position. Needless to say he would have been much better off reading our book and hedging his and financial very risky position. Obviously, the Devil would have been disappointed markets are certainly absent from Hell! Like Faust, any corporation strives for better returns. Unlike Faust, it knows it has to monitor the level of risk taken. Imagine a world without any financial instruments, any derivative assets, any financial engineering. Corporations would end up in a Faustian position with their fates gyrating at the same pace as currencies, interest rates or commodity prices. Their normal business course of action would be polluted by financial risks. Corporate performance would be affected by the dice thrown by the Devil. It would become hard distinguishing talented corporations because of a thick financial fog! Not many solutions are available to disentangle corporate performance from purely financial risks. Financial markets are the most natural candidates to fulfil this thorny task. They innovate every day to provide corporations with the most suitable risk hedging they also enable range. They not only serve as a most useful value barometer, entrepreneurs to demonstrate their true talents.
Options are more flexible than forwards and futures in the sense they provide Options the buyer with the protection needed, and leave him with the full benefits associated with a favorable development of the commodity price, interest rate or exchange rate. This nice feature has a price: the option premium. On the contrary, forward prices, futures prices and swap rates are set at a level such that the initial price of the contract is exactly zero. A cap is a series of interest rate options which allow a corporate borrower to put a ceiling on the borrowing cost of a floating rate debt.
Trading is done in several ways around the world and across financial markets and assets. The most common trading mechanisms are the continuous quote-driven system and the
There is no such thing as a free lunch in finance. The protection brought by Hybrids options is appreciated by corporate treasurers, but is very often considered too expensive. Hybrids (cf. Briys and Crouhy, 1988) are special options, or packages of options, whereby the upfront premium of the protective option is reduced by giving up part of the benefits derived from a favorabic movement in the market.
order-driven system. firm price In a quote-driven system, known also as a continuous dealer market. This is quotations can be obtained directly from market makers before order submission. the case, for example, in the NASDAQ the London International Stock Exchange. In or an order-driven system, orders transmitted by investors go through an auction process. This system can be continuous system or continuous or periodic. In the continuous
I.3
TRADING
MECHANISMS
IN SECURITIES
MARKETS
OPTIONS,
14
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
FINANCIAL
1.4
auction, orders submitted by estors can be executed immediately by dealers on the floor or against limit orders submitted by public investors or dealers. Since orders are executed upon arrival, the system is continuous. Yet, it operates as an auction since prices are determined multilaterally The Paris Bourse operates à la criée or as an open-outcry system and as an electronic system for options. The market is electronic for stocks. For more details, see, for example, Bellalah and Jacquillat (1995), The Swiss Option and Financial Futures Exchange (SOFFEX), the Toronto Stock Exchange's Computer Assisted Trading System (CATS), the Frankfurt Stock Exchange, and the Tokyo Stock Exchange's Computer Assisted Routing and Execution System (CORES) are also examples of continuous
of orders, no more market-on-close
l.4.I
compete The market giving their bid and ask quotes. The best quotes are displayed on the screen of the exchange. For more details, see Berkman (1992).
'strike
Options
and Synthetic
Long a synthetic
underlying
Short a synthetic. underlymg .
asset: long a call + short a put
asset:
=
(0,
1) +
(1, 0)
short a call + long a put
(-l,
-1)
=
(0,
'
l) +
(-1,
'
0)
.
Long a synthetic call: long the underlying
side.
book when on the floor
'maturity
Positions
(1, l)
1)
(0, Short a synthetic
i
=
call: short the underlying
(0, -l)
'open
with each other and with orders in the limit order
15
Options enable investors to customize cash-fiow patterns. We illustrate some of the most commonly used option strategies which apply to options on a spot asset, to options on a futures contract and in general to options with any particular pay-off. These strategies are illustrated with respect to the diagram pay-offs or the expected return and risk trade-off of standard options. The understanding of option strategies is based on the use of synthetic positions. Synthetic positions can be constructed by options on spot assets, options on futures contracts and their underlying assets, If we use the symbol 0 to denote a horizontal line, the symbol - I for the slope under 0 and the symbol 1 for the slope above 0, then it is possible to represent the diagram payoffs of a long call by (0, 1), a short call by (0, -1), a long put by (- 1, 0) and a short put by (1, 0). Adopting this notation for the basic option pay-offs, it is possible to construct all the synthetic positions as well as most elaborated diagram strategies using this representation. We give now the basic synthetic positions when the options have the same strike prices and maturity dates.
For more details, see Brock and Kleidon (1992) The EOE market combmes the features of a dealer market and an auction market. The outcry system' with competing market makers on the fioor. trading begins with an makers
ACTIVITY
CONTRACTS
'underlying
intermediary. However, in practice we observe a combination of the two systems. For example, on the Chicago Board Options Exchange, the NYSE, the European Options Exchange and others, the best quotes in the market can come from a dealer who is a market maker quantity or a specialist or from limit orders. A sell limit order can be defined by the with order and buy limit defined the limit, can be a to be sold at a stated price, called order limit is stated price. the quantity Hence, the a be bought at respect to to comparable to the quote of a market maker standing to sell at his ask quote and to buy at his bid quote . We give two examples of options markets: the NYSE and the European Options Amsterdam. (EOE) in Exchange The NYSE opens with a call market where the specialist matches buy and sell orders. Any resulting imbalance is made up from the inventory of the specialist. Then continuous double-sided auction trading is observed until the close. The usual procedure before the orders either by hand or by the close is that the specialist matches market-on-close automatic trading system, Opening Automated Report System (OARS). If there is an imbalance
OPTION
AND TRADING
'hors
The same trading mechanisms apply also to options markets where often a distinction is made between dealer markets and auction markets. In a dealer market, dealers provide liquidity by displaying quotations at which they are willing to trade. In auction markets, the orders emanating from the public are matched with other public orders without an
on the excess
TRADING
INNOVATION
This section illustrates the many possibilities offered by a specific set of derivative assets, namely options. It is a kind of d'oeuvre' to Chapters 5 and 6 where standard options are covered in a lot more depth. Some preliminary definitions are in order. We nrstdefine a call option. A call option is the right, not the obligation, to buy a specific security (the asset') at a specific price (the price') until a specific date (the date'). A put option is just the same, except it is a right to sell the underlying asset. When the right to buy ('call') or to sell ('put') can only be exercised at the maturity date, the option is said to be 'European'. When this right can be exercised at any time, the option is said to be 'American'.
auction systems. The second type of order-driven system, where orders are stored for execution at a single market clearing price, is known as a periodic auction. This is often used at the opening of many continuous markets such as the New York Stock Exchange (NYSE) and the Tokyo Stock Exchange. In practice, most trading mechanisms are complex hybrids of these systems. For example, at the open, the NYSE operates as an auction market and then switches to a dealer market. For more detail and an excellent analysis of the merits of each system, see, for example, Madhavan (1992).
orders are submitted
MARKETS,
=
asset + long a put (I, l) +
'
(-1, 0)
asset + short a put,
(-l, -- l)
+
(1, 0)
Long a synthetic put: short the underlying asset + long a call,
(-1,
0)
=
(-1,
-1) +
(0,
1)
OPTIONS,
16
FUTURES
FINANCIAL
ANDEKOfiCOGIU¥ATIVES
I.4.2
The Basic Option
=
INNOVATION
AND TRADING
ACTIVITY
=
(1, 1) + (0, -1)
Strategies
=
to trade
of options. The best known strategies in portfolio management involve combinations volatility They include vertical spreads, calendar spreads, diagonal spreads, ratio spreads, spreads and synthetic contracts. with the A vertical spread involves the purchase of an option and the sale of another produces the different strike When strategy and maturity a cash time pnce. to a same outtlow, we say that the investor is long the spread. When the strategy generates a cash intlow, the investor is said to be short the spread. The strategy can be implemented by calls or puts using different strike prices. option For example, when an at-the-money option is bought and an out-of-the-money is sold, the strategy is a vertical bull spread. The calendar spread strategy represents a position where the investor is long an option with a longer term and short an option with a short term for the same strike price. The diagonal spread involves the purchase of an option with a longer term and the sale of another with a short term where both options have different strike prices. The diagonal spread is bullish when the purchased option is at parity and the short option is out-of-thenao
Examples of l tility strategies are often based on the underlying asset volatility. corresponds combinations. A to the straddle volatility strategies include straddles and maturity A date. the and strike with the price call and same purchase of a same a put combination is a straddle for which the option exercise prices are out-of-the-money. when it When the strategy implies a cash outflow the investor is long the strategy, and the strategy. involves a cash inflow the investor is short of a A synthetic forward contract can be created by the purchase of a call and the sale synthetic long the forward the investor this is price. In with strike the case, same put that the contract. The main difference between forward contracts and option contracts is establish position. forward options nothing but to a investor pays a premium for
=
spread. The decision to trade an option with a given strike price depends on the trader's the market direction. If he thinks that the underlying asset price expectations regarding will end above 1040 at the maturity date, he can buy a near-the-money option with a strike price of 1000 at 34. If the underlying asset price is 1040 at maturity, the position shows a profit of 6 points, or (1040 1000) 34 6. If the trader estimates that the underlying asset price would not hit 1040 at the maturity date, he can sell the 1050 or 1100 calls. The sale of the 1050 call at 16.7 generates a gain of 16.7 if the underlying does not attain 1050 at the maturity date (since the call is worthless at that asseetLprice
Since there are at least three maturity dates and from three to sometimes 12 strike prices which option quoted on official option markets, the fundamental question is to determine
Trading the Underlying
a
-
Asset
If we put the underlying asset price on a horizontal line and the profit or loss on a vertical lme, the pay-off at maturity date to a long or a short position in the underlying spot asset is represented as shown m Figure 1.1. If the asset price rises or falls by one point, the profit or the loss will be of the same amount. Trading Calls When an investor buys a call with a strike price of 1000 at 34, the profit-loss relationship at the maturity date is represented as shown in Figure 1.2. When the underlying asset price is less than 1000, the call is worthless and the position shows a loss of 34. When the underlying asset price is 1034 (1000 + 34), the option is worth 34 and the position shows neither a profit nor a loss. This is the break-even point. Above 1034, the profit from the 1000 call is unlimited. On the other hand, under any circumstances the loss can not exceed 34 lf the investor is long the 950, 1000 and 1050 calls, the profit-loss relationship is represented by Figure 1.3. If the investor is short the 950, 1000 and 1050 calls, it is Profit
Consider, for example, an underlying asset with options traded on it. This asset is currently quoted at 990. Table 1.2 shows the call and put market prices for various strike TABLE
I.2
Call and Put Market
Prices for Different
Strike
i
Underlying asset
Prices
Strike Price, K
Call price, c Put price, p
17
10% and the volatility prices when the maturity date T 0.25 year, the interest rate r of the underlying asset is 20%. These prices correspond to the middle of the bid and ask
Short a synthetic put: long the underlying asset + short a call, (I, 0)
MARKETS,
850
900
950
I 000
I 050
I l 00
|39.2 2.7
96.4 8.4
60.43 2l
34 43
I6.7 73.7
109.8
4.
FIGURE
I.I
Long and Short
the Underlying
Asset
at 990
OPgligilig,4GTURES
AND EKORIG
iiafVATIVES
FtNANCIAL
Profit
i di
4AND
TRADING
ACTIVITY
19
Profit
E
=
1000
!
i
34
FIGURE 1.2
MARKETS,
i
1034
950
FIGURE I.4
Long a Call
Short
1000
Calls with D fierent
I
Underlying
105
asagt
Strike Prices
Profit Profit
950 950
i
1000
g
Long Calls with Different
1050
-
Underlying asset
Underlying asset
6
FIGURE Strike
i
t · .
(3) FIGURE 1.3
1000
105
Prices
I.5
Long Puts with Different Strike
Prices
Profit
represented by Figure 1.4. Note that the previous results are inverted, since the investor trades the same calls by taking the other side of the transaction. Trading Puts
Figure 1.5 represents the pay-off at the maturity date of a strategy which consists in buying the 950, 1000 and 1050 puts. Figure 1.6 corresponds to the sale of the 950, 1000 and 1050 put options. It is in some when the market way the inverse of the preceding one. Each position shows a limited gain risk unlimited when the market and falls. rises an It must be clear that the option seller assumes an unlimited risk, since he receives the option premium.
950
FIGURE
1.6
Short
s
1ooo
0
i
1050
Puts with Different Strike
Prices
Underlying asset
OPTIONS
20
1.4.3
Straddles
Trading
BITWRES AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
FINANCIAL
INNOVATION
AND TRADING
ACTIMIT¥
11
Profit
Strangles
and
MARKETS,
When an investor trades a call and a put at the same time with the same strike price and maturity, this strategy represents a straddle. When the options have different strike prices, the strategy is a strangle. 77
Uf ±1y
Buying a Straddle
923
The straddle strategy can be implemented, for example, by paying 34 for the 1000 call and 43 for the 1000 put, or 77 (Figure 1.7). If the underlying asset is above 1000 at the maturity date, the put is worthless and the call is in-the-money. However, if the underlying asset is below 1000 at the maturity date, the call is worthless and the put is in-the-money.
or a Strangle
I.8
Short
g asset
107
(1)
FIGURE Selling a Straddle
1000
(2)
a Straddle
Profit
When the investor has strong expectations that the underlying asset price will lie in the interval (923, 1077) at the maturity date, he can sell the 1000 call and the 1000 put simultaneously. This is a straddle since the options have the same strike price. The profit this from strategy is limited to the option premium, 77, and the loss is unlimited when the market rises (Figure 1.8). When the options have different strike prices, the strategy is referred to as a strangle (Figure 1.9). If the investor does not expect great variations in the market until the maturity date, he can, for example, sell the 950 put for 21 and the 1050 call for 16.7. The profit from this position will be 37.7 when the underlying asset price is within the interval (950, 1050)· Note that the profit on this position, 37.7, is less than that on the previous one, 77, since reduction in risk must be accompanied by a decrease in the expected return a
1077.7
922.3
eso
1000
(1) FIGURE 1.4.4
I.9
Trading
Short
Underlying asset
1oso
(2) a Strangle
Spreads
The Can Spread Profit
0)
The strategy which consists in buying, for example, the 900 call for 96.4 and selling the 1000 call for 34 is known as a spread. If the underlying asset price is less than 900 at the options' maturity date, the options are worthless and the maximum loss is limited to the premium paid, 62.4 or (96.4 34) as shown in Figure 1.10.
(2)
923
1000
1077
e
.
Unde yingasset
If the underlying asset price is above 1000, the 1000 call is worth 100, i.e. (1000 900) and the maximum gain is 37.6 or (100 62.4), as also shown in Figure 1.10. with strike price. The investor sells the call spread when he is long the call a higher
77
The Put Spread
When the investor is long the 1050 put FIGURE
I.7
Long a Straddle
strategy is implemented
by paying
at 73.7 and short the 1000 put at 43, a put spread 30.7, or (73.7 43), as shown in Figure 1.11. The -
22
OPTIONS,
FUTURES
AMD EKOTIC DERIVATIVES
FINAg
INNOVATION
MARKETS,
AND TRADING
ACTIVITY
23
Profit
Profit
900
.. 950
37.6
g I
1000
Underlying assef
950
Underlying asset
i 1050
.
62.4
FIGURE 1.12 FIGURE
1.10
A Call Ratio
A Bullish Calt Spread
If the underlying asset price is 1050, the 1050 calls are worthless and the 950 call is worth 100, or (1050 950). The position is worth 89.67, or (100 10.33). Since the investor is long a call and short three calls with different strike prices, this position is similar to the sale of two units of the underlying asset. Hence, an increase in the underlying asset price by one point yields a loss of two points in the position.
Profit
16.3
Underlying asset 50
FIGURE
I.! I
A Bearish
Trading
Conversions
and Reversals
A strategy can be implemented by going long the 1000 call at 34 and short the 1000 put at 43. If the underlying asset price is above 1000 at the option's maturity date, the put is worthless and the call's value corresponds to the intrinsic value. The position will behave exactly as the value of the underlying asset. However, if the underlying asset price is below 1000 at the option's maturity date, the call is worthless and the put's value is its
Put Spread
investor is said to be long the put spread. This strategy is appropriate if the investor expects a falling market, If the underlying asset price is 1000 at the maturity date, the 1000 put is worthless and the 1050 put is worth 50. The maximum profit is 19.3, or (50 30.7). The investor can be short the put spread if he sells the 1050 put for 73.7 and buys the 1000 put for 43. This strategy implies an entry of cash equal to 30.7.
1.4.5
1.4.6
30 7
intrinsic value. The position will again asset, and is represented in Figure 1.13.
behave exactly as the value
Profit
Ratios
oo
A call ratio strategy (Figure 1.12) can be implemented by buying an option and selling more options with different strike prices. Similarly, a put ratio strategy can be implemented by selling an option and buying more options with different strike prices. The investor can construct the position by going long the 950 call at 60.43 and short three calls, strike price 1050 at 16.7. This call ratio implies a cash outlay equal to 10.33. If the underlying asset price is 950 at the option's maturity date, the 1050 calls are worthless and the loss on the position is equal to 10.33, or (60.43 3 × 16.7)
-
of the underlying
34
FIGURE
1.13
Long a Call, Short
a Put
Underlying asset
24
OPTIONS,
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
Buying the call and selling the put is a position equivalent to buying the underlying relationship asset. More generally, the following no-arbitrage (also called put-call parity, shown call, Chapter 5) between c, a put, p, the underlying asset price, S, and the as a m strike price, K, must hold: c- p where
=
S - Ke
"
(1)
for the riskless interest rate and Tis the option's maturity date. A conversion is a strategy based on the above relationship. It can be written as: short a call + long a put + long the underlying asset r stands
.
=
Areversal
short a synthetic underlying
corresponds
asset + long the underlying
simply to the reverse
long a call + short a put + short the underlying =
long a synthetic underlying
asset
conversion:
Trading
ACTIVITY
25
for the value
(6) premium
of the early exercise
for calls and puts
These relations account with different strike prices. If condition (5) were not satisfied then selling the American call and buying the European call (with a strike price K2), or buying the American call and selling the European call (witha strike price Ki), would allow an immediate profit. If the American call with a strike price K2 is not exercised before the maturity date, the position produces a zero cash flow at that date. If the call with a strike price K2 is exercised, the option with a strike price Ki can be exercised to generate a cash flow (K2 ¯ Ki) which will be invested until the maturity date T If the option with a strike price K2 is exercised before the maturity date at a date ti < T, the result at maturity is > K2
- Ki for options
(7)
traded on the Chicago the box strategy of the no-arbitrage years and found some violations when transaction profitable opportunities disappeared condition. However, the costs were taken into account. They concluded that the market is globally efficient.
(1989) tested
Board Options Exchange over
eight
SUMMARY a Box Spread
-
.
.
•
AND TRADING
P(K2) - p(K2) > P(Ki) - p(Ki)
Aimec and Ehud
with options on spot or options The box spread strategy can be implemented on futures. In the following discussion, c(K,), c(K2), p(Ki) and p(K2) denote respectively the Urices of calls and puts with strike prices K, and K2, with K2 > K,. Consider a portfolio correspondmg to the following strategy:
•
INNOVATION
(K2 - Ki) e' asset
If we substitute the underlying asset by a synthetic underlying asset in the conversion strategy for a different strike price, this eliminates the risks associated with the variations of the underlying asset price and gives a well-known strategy, the box spread. The box spread is simply a strategy equivalent to borrowing or lending money for a certain period.
1.4.7
MARKETS,
asset
+ short the underlying
asset
FINANCIAL
long a bullish call spread: buy c(Ki) and sell c(K2) long a bearish put spread: buy p(K2) and sell p(Ki).
This strategy is a box spread which costs
the practice of financial risk management are In this chapter, the main reasons underlying detailed The different tradmg mechanisms in securities markets are studied. In particular, a distinction is made between continuous mechanisms and periodic mechanisms. .
.
-
In particular, Fmally, the main trading strategies in options markets are illustrated. strategies involving calls and puts, straddles, strangles, conversions and reversals and the box spread are studied. These tradmg strategies can be used for most of the derivative implemented using options with any assets covered m this book, since they can be particular pay-off.
c(Ki) - c(K2) - p(Ki) + p(K2 The following non-arbitrage
condition must be satisfied:
POINTS
< (K2 c(Ki) - c(K2) - p(Ki) + p(K2) - Ki)e result At the maturity date, the of the strategy is always (K2 using - Ki). In fact, inequality (3),the pay-off of each option is
(3) •
the
•
max [Sr - Ki, 0] - max [Sr - K2, 0] - max [Ki (4) - Sr, 0] + max [K2 - S,, 0] This shows that the box is worth (K2 value is less than Ki) the maturity If date. its at Ki), then riskless arbitrage would be possible. the discounted value of (K2
Consider the following two relationships American options C and P:
between
European
options
e and
•
p and
• • •
• •
C(Ki)
- c(Ki)
0 then E(X/N) > 0 if C is a sub-tribe of9, then E[E(X/F)/€] E(X €) E(X). If Xis independent of N, then E(X/El) =
=
=
E[ZE(X
Y such that for
(91)
)
Yis known as the conditional expectation of X given II, or E(X/N). The conditional expectation operator obeys the following properties:
)]
=
E(ZX)
+
(n -
1)!
f""
.
(92) we
"(x)h"¯
(93)
i
d'fÏx, ?)
2
Dy2
k2 +
82f(x, y) h Ox
by
1 82 (x, y) 8 (x, y) k+h 2 dy Ox-
Ox8y
hk
D2f(x, y) - Oy
Similar expressions can be derived for functions of three or more variables.
P).
EXPECTATION
a sub-tribe of
...
in Taylor series expansions
D (x, y) h dx
l
Consider a probability
+ - f'"'(x)h" n!
f,"'(x*)h"
n!
Definition
+ (f"(x)h2
where x* is in the region (x, x + h). A function of two variables x and y is represented
f(x+h,y+k)=/(x,y)+
2.B: THE CONDITIONAL
...
up to order n exist in the same region, then usingTaylerseries
its derivatives
Definition
APPENDIX
+
have (x + h)
An example of stochastic processes often used in continuous-time the valuation of financial assets is the Brownian motion.
"(x)h2
(94)
Applications to Asset and Derivative Asset Pricing in Complete Markets
CHAPTER
OUTLINE
This chapter is organized as follows: 1. In section 3.1, we give some definitions and characterize complete markets. 2. In section 3.2, derivative assets are priced with respect to the partial differential approach. Both methods are applied to the equation method and the martingale valuation of stock options. 3. In section 3.3, we introduce numerical analysis and simulation techniques. 4. Appendix 3.A presents the change in probability and the Girsanov theorem. 5. Appendix 3.B gives in great detail the resolution of the partial differential equation under the appropriate condition for a European call option. 6. Appendix 3.C gives two approximations of the cumulative normal distribution function. 7. Appendix 3.D introduces finite difference methods with respect to the heat transfer equation. 8. Appendix 3.E lists an algorithm for a European call. 9. Appendix 3.F states Leibniz's rule.
INTRODUCTION The pricing of derivative assets is usually based upon two methods which use the same basic arguments. The first method involves the resolution of a partial differential equation under the appropriate boundary conditions corresponding to the derivative asset's pay-offs. This is often referred to as the B-S method. The second method initiated by Harrison and Kreps uses the martingale method, and Pliska (1981), where the current price of any derivative asset is a nd (1979) Harrison
OPTIONS,
50
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
by its discounted expected future pay-offs under the appropriate probability probability. Both methods measure. The probability is often referred to as the risk-neutral pricing call options. the of for illustrated in detail European are Unfortunately, for most problems in financial economics, and in particular for the pricing of American options, there is often no closed-form solution and option prices
given
Therefore, financial economists often resort to numerical must be approximated. niques. A brief presentation of these methods is given in the present chapter.
3.1
CHARACTERIZATIONS
OF COMPLETE
APPLICATIONS
TO ASSET PRICING
IN COMPLETE
MARKETS
5i
If we consider a contingent claim specified by its final pay-off h which is of the form (S, K)* for a European call and h (K - S,)* for a European put, then an attainable strategy ¢ simulates or duplicates the option price when its pay-off at the maturity date T is equal to h, or:
h
=
=
-
V,(¢)
tech-
=
h
(1)
The sequence of the random derivative asset prices between the initial time 0 and the under the uníque probability P*. Hence, we have option's maturity date T is a martingale Vo(¢)
MARKETS
=
E*[Vr(¢)]
(2)
E*(h/Sr)
(3)
and In financial markets, there are two classes of financial assets: securities and derivative assets. Securities correspond fundamentally to common stocks and bonds. Derivative assets are contingent claims characterized by their intermediate and final pay-offs. There are several definitions of complete markets. The idea of complete markets was first proposed by Arrow and Debreu (Arrow, 1953, 1970; Debreu, 1954). They defined a complete market with respect to state securities or state contingent claims. A state security or an Arrow- Debreu security is a security which pays off one dollar if and only if a given state of nature occurs. A state of nature or a possible state in the economy is said to be an insurable state when it is possible to construct a portfolio of assets which has a non-zero return in that state. In this economy, the price of each traded asset at the beginning of the period is ps. where every state is insurable, a price vector can be completely For an economy determined with unique state prices. This implies the absence of arbitrage opportunities. A contingent claim is attainable if there is a strategy that gives the same value at the derivative asset maturity date as the contingent claim terminal pay-off. Hence, a complete market can be defined as a market in which all the contingent claims are attainable, i.e. all the contingent claims are obtained by implementing a replication or a duplication strategy. In this sense, they are redundant. A complete market can be defined with respect to the concept of a viable financial market. A viable financial market is a market where there is no profitable riskless arbitrage opportunities The absence of riskless arbitrage opportunity. means that a with a zero cost must have a zero which initial implemented the time is at strategy terminal value. It is important to note that there is a relationship between the notion of arbitrage and the martingale property of securities prices. The latter means simply that the best estimation of the future price is derived from the latest information. Hence, when historical security price data are used to predict the future price, only the most recent information matters, i.e. the last price. This concept also defines that of an efficient markcL
ln mathematical terms, a financial market is viable if and only if there is a probabihty P* which is equivalent to a probability P, under which the discounted asset prices have the martingale property. This is so under the theorems of the change in probability and, in particular, the Girsanov theorem: see Appendix 3.A for more detail. A viable financial market is complete if and only if there is a probability P* equivalent to the probability P under which the martingale property is satisfied by security prices. It P* is unique. can be shown that this probability
'°(¢)
=
If at the initial time a derivative asset is sold at its expected price, E*(h/Sr), then an investor following a replication strategy can obtain the exact pay-off h at time T.
3.2 3.2.1
PRICING
DERIVATIVE ASSETS
The Problem
Since each financial asset is specified by its intermediate and terminal pay-offs, option pricing consists in finding the fair price at the initial time when the derivative asset is bought or sold. There is a unique approach for the pricing of derivative assets. The value of each option is given by its expected terminal and intermediate pay-offs discounted to the present. However, there are two methods for the pricing of options. The first was initiated by Black and Scholes (1973).The second is the martingale approach due to Harrison and Kreps (1979) and Harrison and Pliska (1981) The first method, known as the B-S method, is based on the resolution of the following partial differential equation: (a2S2 -
ß2c Sc + rS + OS2 BS
-
Oc -
-
-8t
rc
=
0
(4)
under the appropriate boundary conditions. The second is based on the use of martingale techniques. In either the first or the second approach, the boundary conditions are the same. These conditions refer to the appropriate pay-off conditions corresponding to the value of European and American contingent claims. For a European call, the final pay-off is given by c
=
max
[0, Sr
- K]
max
[0, K
- Sr]
(5)
For a European put, the final pay-off is p
=
For an American call, the following additional differential equation:
condition
(6) must
be satisfied by the partial
Eg
OPTIONS,
C
>
max
FUTURES
[0, S, -
AND EM
1AII libERIVATIVES
K]
(7)
The difference from the condition for a European call is that the American call holder can exercise his option at each instant. This condition indicates that at each instant, the American call value must be at least equal to or greater than the intrinsic value, which corresponds to the value of a European call at maturity. For an American put, the following additional condition must be satisfied since the put holder can exercise his option at each instant: P
>
max
- S,]
[0, K
(8)
This condition shows that at each instant, the American put value must be at least equal to the intrinsic value. All these conditions apply in the absence of dividends. When there are distributions to the underlying asset, there are in general no explicit solutions to these problems and numerical methods are often used. First, we illustrate the partial differential equation method for the valuation of European call options. Second, we illustrate the use of the martingale approach for the pricing of European calls. The reader can verify that the price of the call is the same under both methods, Third, since it is difficult to get closed-form solutions for American options with and without distributions to the underlying asset, financial economists often use numerical methods. Therefore, we develop the main principles of these techniques in the last section of this chapter
APPLICATIONS
MARKETS
IN COMPLETE
TO ASSET PRICING
53
where N(.) is the cumulative normal distribution function. A detailed resolution of this system is given in Appendix 3.B. The approximation the cumulative normal distribution function is provided in Appendix 3.C.
3.2.3
The Martingale
of
Method
The B-S pricing of options requires first the knowledge of the probability under which the In the B-S context, there is an equivalent probability to P asset price S, is a martingale. under which the discounted expected stock price, S*
is a martingale. In fact, if one we have
e "S,
=
uses the stochastic
dS*'
differential equation for theateck price,
"'S, di + e
-re
=
(15)
"
dS,
(16)
or dS*
S*[(µ
=
-
'
r)dt
+ od W,]
(17)
r)/a]t
(18)
If we put the change in variables W*
W, +
=
[(µ -
then 3.2.2
The Partial
Differential
Equation
Method
4
dS,
Consider
the search for the solution to the following partial differential equation, under the boundary condition corresponding to the call's pay-off at the maturity date:
82c
(a2S2
c(S, T) Using an appropriate
=
change of variables, =
c
(Oc
rS (ßc
OS2
SN(di)
max
-
[0, S, -
rc
=
0
K]
(9)
- Ke
"'
"N(d2)
ln(S/K)
d2
+
=
ln (S/K) + =
(r
í¤2X T
(1l)
- t)
T (r - ¼¤2)(
=
Si
t)
=
-
S* exp [a W* -
jo
2
t]
(20)
.
with
di
(19)
Using the Girsanov theorem, 8, (µ r) o, there is a probability P* equivalent to P, under which ( W*),,,, is a standard Brownian motion. For more detail, see Appendix 3.A. Hence, under the probability P*, we deduce from equation (19) that S is a martingale and
(10)
the European call's value is given by
S,e a d W,e
=
.
In the B-S model, each derivative asset is defined with respect to its terminal pay-off, is positive and F,-measurable under the probability P*. Hence, at each instant of expected time, the option price is given by its conditional terminal value under the same probability P*:
which
V,
(12)
=
E*[e
'
"h/F,]
with
h
(S, - K)
=
=
f(S,)
The option price at time t can be expressed as a function of time and the underlying price, In fact:
(13)
V,
=
E*[e
"^
"h|F,]
(21) asset
(22)
and N(d)
=
-
exp
-
dx
(14)
V, Smce for all t,
=
E*[c-ar
"f(S,e"T
"exp
{o(W*
-
W*) -jo2(T
-
t)}] F,]
(23)
S,
Soexp [oW
=
-
ja
2
LICATIONS
Alli$$$2ENVATIVES
FUTURESA
oPTIONS,
s4
t]
(24)
TO ASSET PRICING
IN COMPLETE
( r-
exp{-r(T-t)}xexp
H(t,x)=E
o
MARKETS
55
2
(T-t)+o(W,-W*)-K
and at the option's maturity date Sr
Soexp[o W*
=
Ü2T]
(25) =E*
the value of =exp[o(W*-
W*)-la2(T
'
S,
-
2
t)]
(26)
where
r
=
oYn--r
xexp
-Ke"
2
(34)
T -- i. This last formula is equivalent to equation(28)
by (z, K) Now, using the
where
f(x)es
laced
.
Since the random stock price S, is F,-measurable and (W* - W P*, it can be shown that
) is independent
of Fr
under
V,
H(t, S,)
=
notation
(27)
In
di
with
H(t,
x)
=
E*
'"
Under the probability P*, (W Y When (W, - W*) =
exp {-r(T
-
t)}
-
W*)
(T - t)
-
W*) follows Gaussian law N(0, a and Y follows N(0, 1), then:
-
=
H(t, x)
o(W*
"exp
xe'"
"f
e
xexp
H(t, x)
dy
exp
=
=
exp
dy
E
\
xexp
\
r
de
(T - t)+ o(W,
2/
K)
E[(Z-
(35)
a
K - W,) -
(36)
]= E(((Z- K)]1z,«]
the condition Z E,.[G(
e
)Y)
1
1
(30)
since =
=
(37)
where
When Y follows N(0, 1), under P*, then
H(t, x)
d2
Using the following lemma:
(29)
Es-[h(Y)]
2)r
o
weconsader again the equation
)
(T - t) + oy
r -
(28)
(r
=
(31)
xexp
>
K is equivalent
[a Y
ifZ>
K
(38)
__
,,
to
a2r]
K
>
[oY
or
-
þr24>
M
X
where
Hence G(
)Y
=
f
i)Y
o(v
xexp
r -
(T
-
t)
(32)
l exp
(
y')
(33)
the call's pay-off function, h
=
(S, - K)*, then using equation
(28):
,
(40)
,
or }'
under P*. If we replace
'
Y
and Y follows N(0, 1) with a density
>
-d
or Y + d2
Using this remark, H(t, x) can be written as
>
0
(41)
OPTIONS,
FUTURES
AND EXO1WCOERIVATIVES
APPLICATIONS
1Y+dp0
3.3.1
«2
H(t, x)
=
=
E
oY
xexp
('
=
x exp
xexp
/
- Kexp(-rr)
-r U2
a Y
r
-JY
-r
- K exp
(42)
1
(-rr)
exp
(-jy') dy
exp(-jy2)dy
- Kexp(-rr)
(43)
TO ASSET PRICING
MAIWETS
IN COMPLETE
to Finite Difference Methods
Introduction
The non-existence of analytic solutions to some types of partial differential equation leads to the choice of an appropriate numerical scheme. This allows the approximation of to the real solution. For an introduction to finite difference methods and their applications the heat transfer equation, see Appendix 3.D. Consider, for example, the discretization of the B-S partial differential equation
(44) 472S2
82c
+ rS
Oc
Oc -
This integral can be divided into two integrals: d2
2
x exp
YO -
-a
2
r
exp
O
,
(-jy2) dy
da
+
exp(-¡y2)dy
- Kexp(-rr)-
(45)
57
rc
=
(49)
0
asset price S and on The discretization of a function c(S, t) depending on an underlying time t requires the division of the asset price (the state variable) and the time period until the maturity date T (the time variable) into a finite number of equally spaced intervals of length AS and At. For example, the time to maturity, T - t, can be divided into M subintervals of length At with At (T - t)/M. This gives M + 1 time points from 0 to T. The underlying commodity price can be divided into M sub-intervals of length AS with AS So N where So is the highest underlying asset price. This gives N + l stock prices 1) for 0 to Sm. This formulation can be represented on a diagram with (N + 1)(M =
=
The second integral is equal to -Ke "N(d2). If we use the change in variables z y + a can be written as =
,
or y
=
z - a
,
then the li
integral
pomts. k as the step with respect to the time variable, or the time step, We will refer to At respect to the state variable, or the state step. the with and AS h as step =
Jx
xexp
a2
-a(z-an)O--r
1
=
exp(-(z-of)2)dz
(46)
Developing this quantity and simplifying gives exactly xN(di). Finally, the sum of the two integrals gives the following formula for a B-S call option: H(t, x)
=
xN(di)
- Ke "N(d2)
(47)
with
N(d)
=
exp
-
dx
The implicit Difference
Scheme
The option price c(S, t) is represented in the diagram by a point (i, j) where i refers to the space index and j refers to the time state variable. Each interior point c(i, j) can be approximated at point (i, j) by either a forward difference 1, j)
c(i,
j)]
(50)
l c(i - 1, j)] -h [c(i,j) -
(51)
[c(i +
=
(48)
-
or a backward difference
Oc OS
3.3
NUMERICAL ANALYSIS TECHNIQUES
AND SIMULATION
or an average of the two approximations
Oc There are many problems in financial economics which do not have closed-form solutions analysis and or analytical approximations. However, it is always possible to use numerical simulation techniques to approximate derivative asset prices. Numerical methods are often based on the discretization of the state and time variables. Simulation methods rely on simulating random variables. The price of any financial asset can be simulated when it can be expressed in the form of an expected value of a random variable. The best known method is the Monte-Carlo technique which allows the calculation of an option price. This method is only used when there is no other method to value the contingent claim
1
+ g [c(i
¯
1, j)
-
c(i
-
(52)
1, j)]
The term 82c/BS2 in the partial differential equation can be apptoximated point by 42 =
-
[c(i +
¯ hy [c(i +
c(i, j)] l, j) - -
[c(i, j) -
2c(i, j)] 1, j) + c(i - 1, j) -
c(i
-
et the
(i, j)
1, j)]
(53)
OPTIONS,
58
AND EXOTIC
FUTURES
The partial derivative with respect to time, ßc/8t, can be approximated bv the forward difference:
l
oc
=
-
[c(i, j +
at the
(i, j)
1) - c(i, j)]
PRICING
ßc 8t
po
(54)
IN COMPLETE
=
k
[c(i,j+
If we replace these derivatives by their values get the following system:
in the B-S partial differential
these partial derivatives with their values 1 to N - l and j 0 to M - l: we get, for i
If we replace equation.
DERIVATIVES
c(i, j)
a*c(i
=
1, j+
-
MARKETS
59
1) - c(i, j)]
(62)
in the B-S partial differential equation,
1) + b c(i, j+
1)+ c*c(i+
1, j+
1)
we
(63)
=
=
reti.j)=jo2i2h
[c(i+l, j)+c(i-1,
h
with
j)]
j) -2c(i, 1
1 +rih-[c(i+l,j)-c(i-l,j)]+-[c(i,j+1)+ 2h
a
(55) (i,j)
0
×
else
0
exp
(t -
- r
lf we make the change in variables p
=
-
t
dq
-
)
,
exp
-
dq
(127)
q then
with y(u, t)
k
in
=
exp
=
r
(118)
(t -
t*)
exp
dq
exp
'3N(d - Ke'"
(128) or
.
Usmg the fact that
(119)
ln
and letting p
hence S Applying this condition,
a2(t
_
equation
=
K exp
=
(120)
- t)
(129)
the integral can also be written as
q + o
)dq
(-qa
exp
=
exp
-
dq
(l15) becomes
Making a change in variables, equation (l21) becomes
=
exp
(t - t)
exp
(t*
-
1)
exp
(q +
exp
(
) dq
a
p')dp
(130)
)
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
t*) SN(di)
'UN(d2) - Ke'"
OPTIONS,
=
=
e'"
'Dexp
a2(t
t*)
(t -
r 2 -
exp
-
DERIVATIVES
SN(di) - Ke"' 'UN(d2)
(132)
APPLICATIONS
TO ASSET PRICING
APPENDIX ANALYSIS
3.D: INTRODUCTION
3.D.I
The Heat Transfer
IN COMPLETE
MARKETS
69
TO NUMERICAL
Equation
with In
d'
K/
=
(t*
r
\ 2
Using an appropriate change in variables, most equations of the parabolic type in financial economics can be transformed into the heat transfer equation. We restrict the analysis to the
t)
-
(133)
a
d2 whichäthefordwikforàEuropean
(134)
=
calL
equations
with one state variable,
u(0, t)
APPENDIX 3.C: APPROXIMATION OF THE CUMULATIVE NORMAL DISTRIBUTION we have to calculate the cumulative N(d)
("
I =
/
exp
,
x
u(x, 0) standard normal distribution:
x2\
dx
- 2
(135)
We give two methods for the approximation of the cumulative normal distribution which has a precision of order 10 3, is as follows If x The first approximation, coefficients
the formula
=
a2
=
a3
=
0.000 344
a4
=
0.019 527
The second approximation,
~
l -
(1 +
aix
0.115 194
which has a precision of order 10
=
82u/8x2
=
u(L, t)
=
uo(x)
Condition (139) is the heat transfer certain value L.
equation
Some
Numerical
(140)
for 0 ExsL
(141)
for which the state variable x lies between 0 and a
(x, t)
+ a4x")-4
(136) ,
then with
where each point M(j, n) is determined by its position
Suppose that the discrete option values u(j, n) are known for all the space indexes j at each instant of time 0, 1, n - 1, n. We will look for the values u(j, n + 1) and we limit the analysis to the schemes with two steps, i.e. u(j, n + 1) are calculated using only the uU, n) The heat transfer equation is discretized in points MU, n) The time derivative, Bu/St, is approximated by the finite decentered difference: .
as follows. If x>
(139)
for t > 0
Schemes
Uh,nk).
is
for 0 ExsL
Condition (140) is a boundary or a limit condition which indicates that the option is worthless asset is zero. Condition (141) is a limit or a boundary condition which indicates the option's value at the
Consider a grid of points in the plane
2,
0
=
is to ftad the value
when the underlying
3.D.2
+ a2x2 + a3x
instant of time, the
maturity date.
is
N(x)
at each
0, then with
0.196854
a,
t. Hence,
At the option's maturity date, time 0, the value of u(x, t) is given and the probkm of u(x, t) which satisfies the following system: Bu/St
When pricing derivative securities,
x, and a time variable,
derivative asset price can be written as u(x, t). The simplest form of the heat equation is
.
.,
"'+
p
bi b2 b3
=
=
=
=
«U, n +
0.231 6419
c
=
1.78 1 477 937
"(.j,
N(x)
1-
n + l) - 2u(
n) + u(j -
1, n)
by the finite centered
o(h2)
=
(143)
1.330274429
This gives what is often known as the explicit scheme:
1 (1 + px)
u(j, (l/vi¯T)cxp(-x2/2)(bic
(142)
which is exact to the first order. The derivative with respect to the space variable, 82u/8x2, is approximated difference:
-0.356563782
the formula is ~
o(k) '
=
b,
«U, n)
0.319381530
/>4 -L821255978 =
1) -
+ b2c2 + b3c3 + b4
4
5
(137)
n + 1)
=
u(j,
n) +
k
-[u(j+ h2
This scheme is accurate to the first order, if k
=
1, n)
o(h).
-
2u(j, n)
u(j
-
1, n)]
(144)
70
FUTURES
OPTIONS,
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
It is also possible to apply (143) at the level (n + 1) rather than n. If we replace (142) and by
(143)
APPLICATIONS
TO AiglET
PRigglilBdillCOMPLETE
g (n) u (n, j) 1 down to 1 For i = n -u(i)u(i+1, u(i, j)g(i) end for End(forj=1tom)
MARKETS
71
=
-
Du
utj, n + 1) - utj, n) k n+1)-2u(j,
u(j+1,
L
n+1)+utj-1,
uso
+ o(k)
n+1)
we get the totally implicit numerical
scheme
u(j, n + 1)
-[u(j+
u(j, n) +
k
We can take the average of the numerical Nicholson numerical scheme: u(j, n + 1)
u(j, n) +
=
-2u(j,
1)
UU,n)
=
(144) and
(146)
1, n + 1)1
uU -
(147)
(147) to obtain the well-known
1, n) - 2u(j, n) + u(j-
1, n) + u(j+
(148)
k + - {(I -
0)[uU+
1, n) - 2"(1, n) +
0
97
di
=
2.8017 implying N(di)
=
0.997
d2
=
2.7268 implying N(d2)
=
0.996
the formula for the put price is written as p
(29)
N(-d2)
14.629(1 - 0.996) 18(1 - 0.997) -
=
14.629(0.004)
=
- 18(0.003)
=
0.0045
-
(30)
.
We give here five examples to illustrate determination of call and put prices.
MODELS
Example 3
+ Ke-,r
-SN(-di)
=
PRICING
Using the same data, what is the put price? Since the values of di, d2, N(di) and N(d2) are respectively
(28)
In both cases, the investor makes a profit without initial cash outlay. This is a riskless arbitrage which must not exist in efficient markets. Therefore, the above put-call parity relationship must hold. Using this relationship, the European put option value is given in the B-S model by
p(S, T)
OPTION
Example 2
lf S,, < K, the put is worth its intrinsic value. Since the investor is long the put, he exercises his option. He receives upon exercise the strike price, dehvers the stock and closes his position in the cash account. The call is worthless. Hence, the position is worth '
EUROPEAN
the application
of the B-S model
for the
Using the call price,
what
is the put price when the put-call
parity relationship
applies?
The put price is given by p=c-S+Ke-,r 3.3659 - 18 + 15 e-0.l(0.25)
=
=
Example
I
When the underlying asset S 18, the strike price K 15, the short-term interest rate r 10%, the maturity date T 15%, 0.25 and the volatility a the call price is calculated as follows. First, we compute the discounted value of the strike price: =
=
=
=
*
Ke Second, the values
di
=
15 e
2"
0.0045
This price is exactly the same as that given by the application in the B-S model.
of tle put formula
=
14.6296
=
Example
4
of di and d2 are calculated:
ln(18/l5)+[0.1
(0.l5)2(0.5)]0.25 0.21013
=
0.075
0.15
2.8017
the underlying asset S=18, the strike price When the volatility a=0.15, 0.1 and the time to maturity Tis 6 months, we have 15, the interest rate r K =
=
di
d2
=
0.15B
d -
=
2.7267
C
l8N(2.8017)
- 15 e
d2
C
18(0.997)
=
2.1373
implymg
=
0.9876
=
0.9844
.
N(d2)
.
The "
2"
N(2.7267)
Using the approximation of the cumulative normal 2.8017 and 2.7267, the call price is 3.3659, or =
2.2433 implying N(di) .
Replacing these values in the formula gives =
=
- 14.6296(0.996)
distribution
c- p
call =
price S - Ke
is '
3.7461
and
the
3.3659
put
is
0.0084.
:
c
at the points
-
p
S - Ke =
price
This result shows that the put-call
=
*
3.73 =
3.73
parity relationship
is satisfied.
Also,
since
98
FUTURES
OPTIONS,
Example
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
•
sivis
PRICING
MODELS
99
5
In this example (Table 5.5), call and put prices are simulated using the B-S formula. Figures 5.1 and 5.2 show the same results graphically for a volatility a of 25% and for a range of striking prices K from 80 to 120.
20 18 16
TABLE 5.5 10% r
and
Black
Scholes
European
Option
Values:
S
=
100,
-
-
-
14
-
=
12
Time to Maturity
i
O.
10
-
-
.0
Call Volatility
8
Put
6
Striking Price
0. /
0.5
90 \00 i10
(0.90 L8 1 0.00
14.42 5.85 \.\4
90 100 110
11.14 3.66 0.59
90 100 1 IO
12.92 6.78 3.06
-
-
0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0,4 T: Time to matut®y 0.20.3
.0
.0
0. /
0.5
f
4
!8.63 10.31 4.22
0.00 0.82 8.9|
0.03 0.97 5.78
0.07 0.79 3.75
2-
16.09 9.58 5.\2
21.16 14.97 10.16
0.24 2.66 9.50
1.70 4.70 9.76
2.60 5.46 9.69
K: Striking price
2\.44 16.26 12.16
28.64
2.02 5.79 I l.97
7.05 i I.39 16.79
10.08 14.41
FIGURE 5.2 Black and Scholes 25% 10%, « r
!
_
'
(0%
25%
50%
23.93 19.93
·
0
_
60 84 6 100104108112 ¾6120
=
Put Values
0.1
Function
of (K, T): S
=
100,
=
19.46
5.2.2
Applications
Valuation and the Role of Eguity Options 25 _ 20 15
io
_
-
1.0 0.9 0.70.8
-
5
-
O
-
80 84 06 92
0.6 0.5 0,4 T: Timeto maturity 0.20.3 96 100 104108
K: Striking price
FlGURE 5. I Black and 25% 10%, « r =
=
Scholes
0.1 112 116 120
Call Values
Function
of(dt. T): S
=
100,
Broadly speaking, there are four groups of equity options: traded options, over-thecounter options, equity warrants and covered warrants. Traded options are standardized contracts which are listed on options exchanges. These options are not protected against dividend and their strike prices and maturity dates are set by the exchange. Over-the-counter options are tailor-made to the investor's needs and are usually written by investment banks. Equity warrants are long-term options and are often traded in securities markets rather than in option markets. When these options are exercised, new shares are issued by the company. Covered warrants are over-the-counter long-term options issued by securities houses. All these equity options can be valued using the B-S model. However, the following specificities of these instruments require some adjustments to the B-S model. First, these options are frequently traded on an asset which distributes dividends and they are quite often of the American type, namely they can be exercised before maturity. Second, the assumed diffusion process may not represent reality since equity prices may jump downward or upward in response to bad or good news. In addition, the issue of new shares upon exercise triggers the question of dilution. Third, it is more dif6cult to justify a constant volatility for the underlying asset when
OPTIONS,
100
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIYES
ANALYTICAL
the option maturity is long. The same argument applies for the riskless interest rate. In this chapter, we restrict our analysis to the assumptions of the B-S model, which will be relaxed afterwards when studying the extensions and generalizations of the model. Many strategies can be implemented with equity derivatives. These strategies are obviously not specific to equities. They also apply to options on other types of underlying Buying or assets. Equity options can be used in several ways in portfolio management. selling options involves the payment or the receipt of the option premium at the initial time when the transaction is done. Smce the option pay-off is asymmetric, this gives rise to an asymmetric distribution of returns. Hence, options can be used in portfolio manage ment to structure the distribution of expected returns The best known strategies in portfolio management involve combinations of options. They include vertical spreads, calendar spreads, diagonal spreads, ratio spreads, volatility spreads and synthetic contracts (see Chapter l for more details) The main difference between futures contracts and option contracts is that the investor pays a premium for options and nothing to establish a futures position Calls and puts are bought or sold in anticipation of future cash flows, for defensive purposes or speculative reasons. The investor must choose the appropriate options to be bought or sold. Therefore, the question of the management of an option position is as important as the question of option valuation and strategies. We deal with the question of monitoring options with respect to their sensitivities in the next and managing chapter Valuation
and the Role of Index Options
Stock index options and futures markets have experienced remarkable growth rates. Stock index options are of the European or the American type and often involve cash settlement procedure upon exercise. Stock index options are traded on the major indices around the world. Options on the spot index are cash-settled and there is no physical delivery of the underlying index, i.e. of a weighted average of prices of the stocks that constitutes the
EUROPEAN
OPTION
PRICitiG
MODELS
10 i
with di
.
l a
and d2
=
di
--«
.
Se-dT 2)
ln
=
(r + (o
- K
.
index
The formula for a European
¡>(S, T)
=
Ke
*N(-d2)
(32)
put is
- Se
Table 5.6 lists a selection of B-S index option call Figure 5.3 shows call results graphically for a volatility
T
"
N(-di)
and
(33)
put values of 20%.
for S
=
100,
while
Arbitrogebetween Index Options and Futures It is convenient to note that the same strategies for stock options can also be used in portfolio management with index options. Also, these options can be used in asset allocation and portfolio insurance. Since these financial instruments are based on the same underlying index, their prices must be should instantaneously interrelated. If this is not the case, the relative mispricing disappear given the variety of cross-market strategies. These strategies include arbitrage between index options and index futures, and between index futures and the stocks comprising the index. Many researchers have studied these arbitrages which imply that significant deviations from prices dictated by the relevant market interrelationships should disappear. It is of the no-arbitrage often found that there are some violations bounds. However, when taking into account transaction costs, the futures price lies between the no-arbitrage bounds. Even if all tests and published studies are in favor of market efficiency and integrated markets, it is often reported that relative mispricing does exist between index options and futures contracts. For more details, see, for example, Evnine and Rudd (1985),Brennan and Schwartz (1990)and Lee and Nayar (1993)among others.
index. There are several weighting schemes. The most commonly used is the market capitalization scheme where each equity price is weighted by the market capitalization of the firm, i.e. the number of shares times the share price. Two alternative methods are sometimes used: equal weighting and price weighting. The than do last two methods assign greater relative weight to smaller company constituents capitalization-weighted indices Index options are also sold in the OTC market as over-the-counter warrants. In this case, they refer to long-term options on the spot index. Because they are traded on OTC markets, they are subject to credit risk.
TABLE 5.6
Adjustment of the 8-S Model for Index Options When the option underlying index is constructed to pay continuous dividends, the index price is adjusted by the discounted value of the continuous dividend yield. The appropriately adjusted B-S version when the continuous dividend yield is d corresponds to the following formula for a European index call:
c(S, T)
=
Se '"N(di)
- Ke
N(d2)
(31)
Index Option
Values:
S
=
100, r
=
10%, d
=
4%
Time to Moturity Put
call
.
.
Black and Scholes
Votatility
Striking Price
0./
0.5
l.0
\00 110
10.50 1.56 0.00
12.47 4.32 0.60
25%
90 100 I 10
10.76 3.43 0.53
50%
90 100 i lo
12.60 6.56 2.93
10%
90
0.I
0.5
I.0
14.78 6.96 2.1\
0.00 0.97 9.31
0.06 l.43 7.22
0.l4 1.37 5.56
14.44 8.30 4.26
17.92 12.23 7.98
0.27 2.84 9.83
2.03 5.4l 10.88
3.27 6.63 I l.43
l9.99 \5.03 I I.\3
25.72 21.29 17.57
2.1 I 5.96 12.24
7.58 I2.\3 17.74
I LO7 15.69 21.02
OPTIONS,
102
FUTURES
ANALYTICAL
AND EXOTICDERIYATIVES
EUROPEAN
OPTION
PRICING
c(B, T)
=
MODELS
BN(di) - Ke
103 "
N(d2)
(34)
with 25-
di
1 =
o
20
and d2
10
a 0
In
-
=
di - o#,
B -K
+
(r 4
la2)
T
(35)
where:
B is the bond's price, K is the option's strike price, Tis the option's time to maturity, o is the instantaneous standard deviation of the bond price, r is the spot rate on a risk-free investment with a maturity date T
-
_
Using the put-call
d Dividend
parity relationship,
the put's value is given by
-
84
es
p(B, T)
92 96 1001041081121161200%
=
-
BN(-di)
+ Ke
N(-d2)
(36)
However, other European models, which are extensions or generalizations of the B-S model, such as Merton's (1973a)model are more appropriate for the pricing of these
K: Striking price
options. FIGURE 5.3 Black and Scholes 20% 10%, « r
Call Values
Index
Fune iam
of
(K, d): S
=
100,
=
=
On the other hand, despite the controversy about index arbitrage and program trading, these financial instruments are beneficial to stock portfolio managers and institutional investors. Before the emergence of these contracts, market participants could not hedge and control the market risk of their portfolios. Even if there is some evidence that trading in index futures increases cash-market volatility, arbitrage activities via program trading may cause prices to adjust more rapidly to new information. This helps to keep the movements of index futures prices and the value stock index more synchronous. The deviations of futures prices from their and substitutability between spot including various considerations imperfect results from futures markets, the speed with which mformation is incorporated in prices in the different markets, and market imperfections including transaction costs and regulatory
Interest rate options are often used in the management of interest rate risk in the same way as equity options. A direct implication is that option strategies for equity options apply directly to interest rate options. The most common and specific strategies based on short-term interest rate options are caps and floors. These strategies place either a cap on the future level of interest rates on a floating instrument or a floor on the interest rate receivable on deposits. A cap is an option strategy which protects from a rise in interest rates and allows a profit when interest rates are falling. A floor is an option strategy which protects from a decrease in interest rates at the time when the deposit rate is reset. When an investor buys a cap (floor) and sells the floor (cap), this strategy is known as the collar,
'fair'
.
constraints,
Valuation
.
.
among other thmgs. and the Role of Short-Term
Options
on Long-Term
rates. short-term
The B-S model is sometimes used to price counon bonds. In this context, the call's value is given by
European
.
The price of any financial asset is given by the present value of its expected cash ows. The first step m determimng the bond's price is to determine its cash flows, i.e. the periodic coupon interest payments until the rnaturity date and the par value at maturity.
Bonds
markets. Short-term options on long-term bonds are often traded on over-the-counter These options may be of the European or the American type. There is a traded option on the Chicago Board Options Exchange which is based upon the yield to maturity on a portfolio of bonds. The yield to maturity is driven by changes in the term structure of mterest
Valuation and the Role of Bond Options
options on zero-
Since the bond price is given by the present value of the cash flows, its price is given by adding all the discounted future payments at the appropriate interest rates. Some bonds do not make any periodic coupon payments and the interest due to the bond holder is given by the difference between the maturity value and the purchase price. This class of bonds is referred to as zero-coupon bonds. It should be emphasized that there are several types of bonds: bonds with call provisions,
putable bonds, convertible
bonds, bonds with warrants attached, exchangeable bonds, etc. A bond with a call provision gives the right to the issuer to call the issue before the
104
OPTIONS,
specified redemption
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
ANALYTICAL
date. The call price is different from par and is specified at the bond
•
EUROPEAN
Nine-month
PRICING
OPTION
interest
MODELS
105
8.5%.
rate:
issue.
A bond with a put provision gives its holder the right to put the bond back to the issuer at a fixed pnce. It is a putable bond A convertible bond entitles its holder to convert the bond into a certain number of units of the equity of the issuing firm or into other bonds. This number is often called the rate of conversion which is specified when the bond is issued. A bond with an attached warrant is simply a package comprising the bond and a It allows the holder to purchase the equity of the issuing firm. Most of these warrant. bonds are eurobonds issued in international capital markets. An exchangeable bond is similar to a convertible bond, with the exception that it gives its holder the right to exchange the bonds for the equity of another company. The call or the put provision in these bonds can be valued using the B-S model. However, the model is not appropriate if there are many call or put dates and if the embedded options in the bonds are of the American type. We now give an application of the model to options on zero-coupon bonds and options on coupon-paying bonds under the B-S assumptions. Zero-Coupon Bonds When there are no coupon payments, follows for bond options: =
c
P=
BN(di) - Ke
-BN(-di)
Ke
"
The option has a strike price equal to 100 FF and its maturity The present value of coupon payments is 9.59 FF, or *
5e
+ 5e
""
""
4.9 + 4.69
=
=
date is inene yeat
9.59 FF
Applying the B-S formula gives
96 - 9.59 86.41 FF [In (86.41/100) + 0.1 + 0.0032] 0.080 B
di
=
da c
=
=
=
di - 0.08
=
86.4l N(-0.5358)
=
l.25 FF
× l
=
+ 100e
=
-0.5358
-0.6158 "
N(-0.6158)
'incoherence'
with this model since it assumes It is convenient to note the and time the stochastic rates interest bond price. constant at same a
the B-S model is applied as
N(d2) "N(-d2)
(37)
5.3
90
5.3.1
BLACK MODEL The Model
with
di
=
-
o and d2
=
di - a
v'†
ln
K
+
(r +
lo 2)
T
(39)
Using some assumptions similar to those used in deriving the original B-S option options and formula, Black (1976)presented a model for the pricing of commodity forward contracts.
VT. The Model
Coupon-Poying Bonds If the bond is a coupon-paying bond, then the present value of all coupons due during the option's life must be subtracted from the bond's price.
Example
for Forward,
Futures and Option
Contracts
In this model, the spot price S(t) of an asset or a commodity is the price at which an investor can buy or sell it for an immediate delivery at current time, t. This price may rise steadily, fall or fluctuate randomly. The futures price F(t, t*) of a commodity can be defined as the price at which an investor agrees to buy or sell at a given time in the future, t*, without putting up any t*, the futures price is equal to the spot price. money immediately. When t A forward contract is a contract to buy or sell at a price that stays fixed until the maturity date, whereas the futures contract is settled every day and rewritten at the new futures price. Following Black, let v be the value of the forward contract, u the value of the futures contract and c the value of an option contract. Each of these contracts is a function of the futures price F(t, t*) as wel as other variables. So, we can write at instant i the values of =
Consider a European call for which the following characteristics: • • • • • •
the underlying
Bond's price: 96 FF One-year interest rate: 10% Time to maturity: 10 years Volatility of the bond's price: 8% Coupon payments: 5 FF in three months Three-month interest rate: 8%
asset is a coupon bon&with
and nine months
these contracts respectively as v(F, t), u(F, t) and c(F, t). The value of the forward contract depends also on the price of the underlying at time /* and can be written v(F, t, K, t*).
asset, K,
106
OPTIONS,
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
ANALYTICAL
It is important to distinguish between the price and the value of the contract. The futures price is the price at which a forward contract presents a zero current value. It is written
0
MODELS
107
(42)and (44),the
v(F, t*, K, t*)
F - K
=
value of a commodity
option
=
F - K*
if F else
f
0
>
K'
(42)
-
K*N(d2)]
(46)
di
l =
F -K*
In
-
a
e
4
+
(jÛ2
(47) .
Ö.
It is convenient to note that the commodity option's value is the value the of an option on a security paying a continuous dividend. The rate of same as s, is substituted in the distribution is equal to the stock price times the interest rate. If Fe original formula derived by B-S, the result is exactly the above formula. In the same context, the formula for the put option is given by and d2
d, - o
=
.
.
p(F,
T)
+ K* N(-d2
e "'[-FN(-di)
=
(48)
The value of the put option can be obtained directly from the put call parity.
The Put-Call
Parity Relationship
The put-call parity relationship
for futures options is
contracts and comrnodity options, Black assumes that:
In order to value commodity
p - c
The futures price changes are distributed log-normally with a constant variance o2 All the parameters of the Capital Asset Pricing Model are constant through time. There are no transaction costs and no taxes.
Under these assumptions, it is possible to create a riskless hedge by taking a long position in the option and a short position in the futures contract. Let [8c(F, t) BF] be the weight affected to the short position in the futures contract, which is the derivative of c(F, t) with respect to E The change in the hedged position may be written as Oc(F, t) - [8c(F,
(43)
t)/8F]OF
Using the fact that the return to a hedged portfolio must be equal to the risk-free rate and expanding ßc(F, t) gives the following partial differential equation:
at
t)
- rc(F,
t) - 2la
F
82c(F,
t)
- F)
(49)
nows
interest
(44)
¿)µ2
e "(K
=
This relationship can be explained as follows. Consider a portfolio where the investor is long a future contract, long a put on the future contract and short a call with the same time to maturity and strike price. Note that the combination of the call.and the put is equivalent to a short synthetic future. At expiration, the pay-off is given by the difference between the option's strike price and the current futures price. Hence, the current value of that portfolio must be equal to the present value of this difference, Since these options are European, they have the same cash as options on the spot asset. This is because at the maturity date the futures price is equal to the spot price. We now give some examples for the calculation of option prices using Black's formula.
Example Sc(F,
•
When F
I 80, K
=
100, T
=
0.25,
=
«
0.2 and r
=
0.08, the call price, c, is
=
zero.
or
• •
lo2F2
[FN(d,)
e
with
(41)
At maturity, the value of a commodity option is given by the maximum of zero and the difference between the spot price and the contract price. Since at that date, the futures price equals the spot price, it follows that c(F, t*)
'
=
(40)
-
•
and using equations - t
c(F, t) =
This equation says that the forward contract's value is zero when the contract is initiated and the contract price, K, is always equal to the current futures price, F(t, t*) The main difference between a futures contract and a forward contract is that a futures contract may be assimilated to a series of forward contracts. This is because the futures contract is rewritten every day with a new contract price equal to the corresponding futures price. Hence when F rises, i.e. F > K, the forward contract has a positive value, and when F falls, F < K, the forward contract has a negative value. When the transaction takes place, the futures price equals the spot price and the value of the forward contract equals the spot price minus the contract price or the spot price:
•
t*
=
PRICING
OPTION
as v(F, t, F, t*)
•
Denoting T
EUROPEAN
' -
rc(F,
t)
' =
0
(45)
When F 100, K When 120, F 19.7754. c =
=
=
=
0.08, then c 100, T 0.2 and r 0.25, « 3,9087. 0.25, 100, T 0.2 and 0.08, then K r o =
=
=
=
=
=
=
=
108
FUTURES
OPTIONS,
Example
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
2
Table 5.7 simulates European call and put futures prices using Black's model.
TABLE 5.7 10% r
European
Futures
Values
by
Black's
Model:
S
=
100
'
=
Time to MoturitY Coll Volatility
Striking Price
Put
OPTION
PRICING
109
MODELS
the valuation of these options. However, when these options are of the European type, Black's model is often used in pricing them. The various strategies applied with options on individual assets can also be used for options on index futures. Index futures and options on index futures are often used in asset allocation and refers to the structuring of a multi-asset portportfolio insurance. Asset allocation with weightmg scheme of asset classes. Strategic and the the respect type to folio asset allocation is the construction of a portfolio such that long-run objectives are attained when the different classes of assets are transacted at their long-run equilibrium values. allocations
known also as market timing, involves short-term .
0.I
0.5
I.0
0./
0.5
l.0
90 100 I l0
9.90 I.25 0.00
9.70 2.68 0.29
9.69 3.6! 0.86
0.00 1.25 9.90
0.19 2.68 9.80
0.64 3.6 I 9.91
25%
90 I00 110
10.22 3. I2 0.46
12.22 6.70 3.27
\ 3.82 9.00 5.60
0.32 3. I2 10.36
2.70 6.70 12.79
4.77 9.00 14.65
50%
90 100 I \0
12.14 6.24 2.75
17.99 13.35 9.76
21.86 17.86 14.56
2.24 6.24 12.65
8.47 |3.35 l9.27
I2.8I 17.86 23.61
Options
EUROPEAN
Tactical asset allocation,
10%
5.3.2
ANALYTICAL
Applications on Equity index Futures
Options on index futures require upon exercise the exchange of a long position in the future contract for a call and a short position in the future contract for the put. Hence, a call is exercised into a long position in the future contract and a put is exercised into a short position in the same contract. The underlying futures contract does not requite a physical delivery but rather is settled m cash. The amount received corresponds to the difference between the current and the future level of the underlying index. In this context, the futures contract is regarded as an agreement to pay or receive a cash payment based upon the difference between the current and the future values of a specified index.
Options on index futures are often treated as options on an asset paying a continuous stream of dividends, regardless of whether the underlying spot index pays a continuous or a discrete dividend. Since the assumptions used by Black are similar to those in B-S, some of them are also questionable, such as the constant volatility and the certainty of interest rates. In fact, the non-stationarity of volatility causes some problems in the pricing of options on index futures. As we will see later, some extensions on Black's model are more appropriate for
toward rismg markets and away from fallmg markets. Portfolio msurance refers to a group of techmques that msure a portfolio against fallmg in value below a certain specified level, the floor level. This level does not eliminate the potential profits from a rise in the asset value.
Options
on Currency
Forwards and Options
on Currency
Futures
Options on currency forwards are traded in the OTC market. This market is regarded as the major market for currency options. The growth of the OTC market is due to its flexibility, since many banks and financial institutions offer options with tailor-made characteristics in order to match their chents' needs. Options on currency futures have been traded since 1982. These options are standardized contracts and can be inflexible. They are priced off the underlying futures contract. When exercised, the call buyer receives a long position in one futures contract marked to market at the current price. In the same way, when exercised, the put holder receives a short position in one futures contract. These options must have the same value as European options on the spot currency since they are not exercised before the maturity date, at which the futures price is equal to the spot price. The similarity between forward and futures prices suggests the use of Black's model for the valuation of these options. Currency futures and currency forwards are often used to hedge currency risks. Options strategies of on currency futures are applied m currency risk management. The basic volatility spreads, and calendar vertical, the calls and diagonal, selling and buymg puts, used m markets. also be options They also the applied futures can currency are m portfolio msurance. of currency futures and options are used to manage currency Several other applications .
.
.
.
.
.
.
risks. Examples mclude basket options, average rate options, cylinder options and many other exotic options. .
Futures Margined
.
American
Options
and
Options
on Bond Futures
Traded
on the LIFFE
There is an important difference between options traded on the LIFFE and other markets. For these options, the premium is not paid up-front and the option contract is margined like the futures contract.
'
I10
FUTURES
OPTIONS,
AND EXOTIC
Even if these options are of the American type, there is no incentive for early exercise. of the margined Hence, the European Black's model can be used for the valuation American options traded on the LIFFE, Black's model for the valuation of a European option on a forward or a futures contract when the underlying asset is an interest rate is given by c
-
KN(d2)]
' =
e
[-FN(-di)
EUROPEAN
OPTION
MODELS
PRICING
I11
important volume of transactions implies the use of an option pricing model. A simple and interesting analytic model was provided by Garman and Kohlhagen (1983).
The Model
(50)
and p
4
5.4.1
e "[FN(di)
=
ANALYTICAL
DERIVATIVES
+ KN(-d2)]
(51)
+(jo')T
(52)
Foreign currency options are priced along the lines of B-S (1973)and Merton (1973). Specifically, Garman and Kohlhagen (1983)and Grabbe (1983)presented models for riskless hedge portfolio can be currency options which are based on the assumption that a and the option. bonds domestic in formed by investing foreign bonds,
with
di and d2
=
di - od,
l =-
in
F -
The Currency
Using the same assumptions as in the B-S (1973)model, Garman and Kohlhagen presented the following formula for a European currency call:
where:
N(d2)
(1983) (53)
with
di
Note that the interest rate does not appear in this formula except for the discounting. This implies that the problem of the volatility of interest rates is solved within the context of this model. There is a simple adjustment to the model which needs to be multiplied by e" to account for the payment at the future date Options on bonds traded on the LIFFE are also margined in the same way as short¯ term interest rate options. Since there is no incentive in exercising these American options before the maturity date, Black's model also applies with the same modifica tion
GARMAN AND KOHLHAGEN, MODELS
N(di) - Ke
Se
=
c
F is the futures price, K is the option's strike price, r is the short-term interest rate, a is the volatility of futures prices, Tis the option's time to maturity.
5.4
Call Formula
AND GRABBE
and d2
=
da - a
,
ln
=
s' -
+
r*
(r -
+
(a2)T
(54)
where:
Sis the spot rate, K is the strike price, r is the domestic interest rate, r* is the foreign interest rate, o is the volatility of spot rates, Tis the option's time to maturity Adopting an approach similar to that in Black formula for the currencv call: c
=
B(T)FN(di)
(1976),Grabbe (1983) gives the foËowing - B(T)KN(d2)
(55)
with a formula for the valuation of foreign options. These traded options currency are on the foreign exchange market, which is fundamentally an interbank market where transactions are conducted over the telecommunications The foreign exchange market, called also the FX market, system. internationally 24 hours a day; the major participants are commercial banks operates around the world and treasury departments of large corporations. risks, the various participants search for hedging exchange As in other markets, arbitrage speculation and the implementation of strategies. options satisfy Foreign currency some of the needs of these participants and the
Garman and Kohlhagen
(1983) provided
d, and d2
=
di - o vi,
1 =
E (F' Iln
K,
+
(a T
where:
F is the forward price of the foreign currency, B(T) is the price of a domestic currency discount bond, a is the volatility of the foreign forward exchange rate.
(56)
f 12
OPTIONS,
The Currency
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
ANALYTICAL
Put Formula
Table 5.8 shows
The formula for a European currency put is p
EUROPEAN
"
Kc
=
N(-d2)
- Se
N(-di)
Ii3
MODELS
values
Garman call and put option
various
Garman
TABLE 5.8 ,·r
PRfCING
OPTION
Values:
Option
Currency
(57)
S
=
for S
100, r
=
=
100.
10%, r,
=
4%
Timeto Maturity
Note that the main difference between these formulac and those of B-S for the pricing of equity options is that the foreign risk-free rate is used in the adjustment of the spot rateThe spot rate is adjusted by the known i.e. the foreign interest earnings, whereas the domestic risk-free rate enters the calculation of the present value of the strike price since the domestic currency is paid over on exercise.
Put
Coli Strikmg Price
'dividend',
-
volot¡¡ity
-
0.5
l.0
0.;
0.5
l.0
90 100 i10
I0.50 1.57 0.00
12.48 4.4| 0.69
14.82 7.17 2.41
0.00 0.98 9.31
0.07 l.52 7.30
0.I8 I,57 5.87
25%
90 |00 i 10
10.76 3.44 0.53
\4.47
0.27 2.84 9.84
2.06 5.45
4.3\
18.00 I2.34 8.10
10.92
3.36 6.74 1I.55
90 100 I 10
12.6| 6.56 2.94
20.01 15.05 I I.IS
25.77 21.34 17.63
2,\ \ 5,97 12.24
7.60 12.\5 17.76
I l.13 15.75 21.08
Currency
Options
Examples Assume that the US dollar/sterling spot rate is 1.8, the time to maturity is three months, the three-month dollar interest rate is 7% and the sterling interest rate is 10%. When the volatility is 20%, the option price is 6.3817, calculated as
0.I
%
·
50%
8.35
follows: C di
=
=
"'°2"
'
180 e
N(d
)-
"'
180 e
N(d2)
5 0.5(0.2)2)0.25]/0.2v'Ï -0.05
[ln(180/180)+ (0.06- 0.10
=
The interest
Rate Theorem
and the Pricing of Forward
-0.15
d2
=
N(di)
C
=
di - 0.2 0.4801, N(d2)
84.284 - 77.896
=
=
6.3817
=
Since the option's delta or partial derivative with respect to the underlying price is given by Ae
=
'
e
The interest rate parity theorem states that the forward rate is equal to the spot tate compounded by the differential between the foreign and domestic interest rates. Using continuously compounded interest rates, the forward exchange rate is
0.4404
=
asset
/
c Ao
'
e
"'°2"0.4801
Se"
'
(58)
which means simply that the formula for the pricing of a European call on a spot currency can be rewritten as
N(di)
its value is =
=
0.4682
=
e
=
f N(d ) -
KN(d2)]
(59)
with
The delta for the currency put is A, which
=
e
N(- di)
=
e "(N(di)
gives a value of A,
and d2 =
e
"'
(0.4801 -
1)
=
0.5070
Note that the value of N(d ) is discounted to the present using the foreign interest rate. This is because this rate is assumed to correspond to a continuous dividend stream on the underlying asset. In the same way, we can calculate the risk parameters of other options. These calculations are held over to the next chapter.
di
- 1) =
- o
K
(jo2)T
(60)
di - ov'¯7. The formula for the European currency put is p
=
e
fN(-di)
KN(-d2)]
(61)
where all the parameters have the same meaning as before, except for the spot exchange rate S, which is replaced by the forward exchange rate f. Note that the mterest rate differential is not explicitly taken into account in the above formula. This is because all the available information about spot rates and the interest rate differential is integrated in the forward exchange rate via the interest parity theorem.
\ 14
5.4.2
OPTIOftS,FUTURES
AND EKOT1C
ANALYTICAL
DERIVATIVES
EUROPEAN
PRICING
OPTION
can be constructed and adjusted continuously, be satisfied by the option price, c, is
Applications
Currency options were traded on the spot currency for the first time in 1982 at the Philadelphia Stock Exchange. Since that date, currency options have been traded in many other financial centers. However, trading on the OTC market seems to be more important. The strategies discussed for stock options also apply to currency options and currency futures options, As we will see in the second part of this book, several financial OTC currency products can be valued using the Garman and Koh1hagen model, It is convenient to note that in the model proposed by Garman and Kohlhagen (1983), the foreign and domestic interest rates are constant, while in Grabbe's (1983) model these rates are stochastic. In the latter model, where the approach parallels that in Merton (1973a),bond price dynamics follow geometric Brownian motion. The assumption of Brownian motion for the bond returns may be criticized since it may imply negative interest rates, i.e. the bond's price may be greater than its face value and the variance will not be nil at maturity Chiang and Okunev (1993) presented another model for the pricing of foreign currency options where the domestic and foreign bond processes follow Brownian bridges. This process may also be criticized since there is also a possibility that the bond's price may be greater than its face value. Yet, it has the advantage of describing better the characteristics of the bond. In fact, with this process, the price of the bond is known with certainty at the maturity date and its variance is nil. The formula presented by Chiang and Okunev resembles that of Grabbe (1983), except that the variance and covariance terms (1993) estimated using approach. different are a
jo'S2
82c(S, t)
I 15
the partial differential equation
Oc(S, t)
+ bS
OS2
MODELS
Oc(S, t)
- rc(S, t) +
that must
0
=
(65)
This equation first appeared indirectly in Merton (1973a). When the cost of carry b is equal to the riskless interest rate, this equation reduces to that of B-S (1973). When the cost of carry is zero, this equation reduces to that of Black (1976). When the cost of carry is equal to the difference between the domestic and the foreign interest rate, this equation reduces to that in Garman and Kohlhagen (1983). It is convenient to note that the short-term interest rate, r, and the cost of carrsing the commodity, b, are assumed to be constant and proportional rates. Using the terminal boundary condition
c(S, T)
(1973b)showed
Merton
=
max
[0, Sr - K]
(66)
indirectly that the European call price is
c(S, T)
=
"N(d2) - Ke
Se" '"N(di)
(67)
.
with
d' .
and d2
=
S'
i oy'¯†
=
+(b+¼o2)T
(68)
K .
di - o v'T. Usmg the following boundary condition: p(S, T) max [0, K - Sr]
(69)
=
5.5
the European put price is
THE MERTON, BARONE-ADESI AND WBUM.EY MODEL AND ITS APPLICATIONS
p(S, T) Table 5.9 shows various
5.5.1
=
Ke-,rN(-d2)
Se
-
'1"N(-di)
BAW European option values for S
(70)
100.
=
The Model -
The model presented m Barone-Adesi and Whaley (1987), known as the BAW model, is a direct extension of models presented by B-S (1973), Merton (1973a) and Black (1976). The absence of riskless arbitrage opportunities implies that the following relationship exists between the futures contract, F, and the price of its underlying spot commodity, S: F
Sear
=
(62)
where T is the time to expiration and b is the cost of carrying the commodity. When the underlying commodity dynamics are given by dS/S=adt+odW
TABLE 5.9
a is the expected instantaneous relative price change of the,codamodity and a is its standard deviation, then the dynamics of the futures price are giventy the following differential equation:
Assuming
that a hedged portfolio
F
=
(a
-
containing
b)dt + od W the option and the underlying
(64) commodity
S
Values:
=
100, r
=
10%, b
=
4%
Put
call Volatility
25%
where
dF
Option
Time to Maturity
10%
(63)
BAW European
50%
Striking Price
0.I
0,5
l.0
0.I
0.5
l.0
90 100 Il0
10.30 1.46 0.00
\ 1.53 0.52
13.03 5.82 1.76
0.00 \.06 9.5\
0.10 1.86 8.11
0.28 2.13 7.12
90 100 110
10.58 3.33 0.51
13.70 7.77 3.94
16.53
0.28
I l.15 7.l9
2.93 10.0!
2.26 5.85 11.53
3.79 7.45 12.54
90 100 !!0
12.45 6.45 2.87
19.32 14.47 10.67
24.41 20.13 16.56
2.15 6.06 l2.38
7.88 !2.54 18.26
|1.67 16.44 2f.91
3.78
5.5.2
AND EXOTIC
OPTIOMS,FUTURES
116
Application
of the
DERIVATIVES
EUROPEAN
OPTION
MODELS
PRICING
tion of forward and futures prices on securities which and other income to the underlying asset.
Model
Forward and Futures Commodity
ANALYTICAL
117
provide
(and do not
provide) cash
Contracts
Sehr, is useful. The proposed relation between the futures price and the spot pricc, F Recall that F is the futures price, S is the spot price, b corresponds to the carrying cost applies to futures prices and to forward and T is the time to maturity. This relationship prices as well. =
When the cost of carrying an asset refers to the storage of commodity such silver costs a as or gold and when these costs are proportional to the commodity price, the futures price is given by
FuturesContractson Commodities
F
Se
=
,_or
(76)
where a stands for the storage costs. Forward Prices and Futures Prices Futures prices and forward prices are often regarded as being equivalent. However, this is true only if the risk-free interest rate is constant or a known function of time. The proof of this equivalence is based on a rollover strategy proposed in Cox, Ingersoll and Ross (1985a). In this strategy, the investor buys e' futures contracts at the end of the first day of trading (initialtime, day 0), e2; EUtUTCS contracts at the end of day 1, e futures contracts at the end of day 2, etc., and e" futures contracts at the end of day i - lSince, at the beginning of day i the investor has e" contracts in his position, the position on that day shows a profit (loss)of (F, - F, i)e". When this amount is invested until the day N corresponding to the contract's maturity date, where the number of days i is between 0 and N, this amount will be (F, The sum of the amounts of profit
F,_i)c"c(N-"'
=
(F, -
F,_i)eN
(loss)from day 0 until day N turns
(71) out to be
Fo)eNr
(FN
Fo)eNr -
is equal to the spot
Fo)eN'
(S, -
=
(73)
corresponds to this strategy and an investment Using a portfolio in a risk-free bond, gives the following pay-off at time T: which
(Sr -
Fo)eNi
N'
=
(74) the result
SveNr
with no-arbitrage they must have the same value in capital markets result, SreN', the opportunities, arbitrage futures price Fo profitable opportunities. In the absence of relation applies for futures proposed price the Hence, the equal forward to must be fe. and forward prices and we have
f
=
2'
400e'
=
Sc^r
Some examples are given below to illustrate the use of this relationship
'
=
410.126
Futures Contracts on a Security with No Income When there is no distribution to the underlying asset, the cost of carry is equal to the riskless interest rate. The futures price is given by F More generally, this relation represents spot price S. It applies to the valuation provides no income.
Se"
=
(77)
the forward or futures price F as a function of the of forward or futures contracts on a security that
Example
Since for a strategy in futures contracts no funds corresponds to the investment of Fo in the risk-free bond. Another strategy can be constructed to give the same pay-off as the preceding one. In fact, if fo stands for the forward price at the end of day 0, then a strategy which consists eN' contracts also 10 fOrward of investing this amount in a riskless bond and an amount gives a final pay-off at T equal to SreNr Since the two strategies require an investment of an amount Fo, (fo) and yield the same
=
F
of an amount Fo
SveN'
are invested,
F
Consider a six-month futures contract on silver or gold. Assume that the asset price is 400, the risk-free rate is 7% p.a. and the storage costs correspond to 2% of the commodity price. In this case, the futures commodity price is given by
(y )
-
However, since at the contract's maturity date, the futures price F, price, Sr, the terminal value of this investment strategy is (FN
Example
(75) in the determma-
Consider the valuation of a forward contract on a non-dividend paying stock. Suppose the maturity date is in three months, the current asset price is 100 and the three-month risk-free rate is 7% p.a. In this case, S 100, T 0.25 year and r 0.07, so the futures or forward price is given by =
=
=
F
=
"
100e'
25
=
101.765
Futures Contracts on a Security with a Known Income For dividend paying assets, the cost of carrying the stocks is given by the difference between the riskless rate and the dividend yield, d. This gives the following relation: F This relationship
=
Sc"
(78)
gives the forward price F as a function of the spot price S for a forward contract on a security that provides a known dividend yield.
OPTIONS,
I 18
Example
AND EXOTIC
FUTURES
DERIVATIVES
ANALYTlCAL
EUROPEAN
OPTION
PRICING
MODELS
I 19
bonds and some In the case of stocks paying known dividends, coupon-bearing commodities for which there are storage costs, the formula for future prices becomes
i
Consider the valuation of a three-month forward or futures contract on a security that provides a continuous dividend yield of 5% p.a. Suppose that the current 100, rate is 7% p.a. In this case, S asset price is 100 and the risk-free T 0.25 year, r 0.07 and d 0.05, so the futures or forward price is given
F
(S - I)ecr
(80)
to an income and is negative when it refers to a cost.
where I is positive if it corresponds
=
=
=
=
=
-·
by F
Example
100e'°°'
=
26
"
Example
100.501
=
Consider the valuation of a one-year forward contract on a two-year bond. The two-year bond's price is 800, the delivery price is 820 and two coupons of 50 will be paid in six and 12 months. The riskless interest rate is 8% p.a. for six months and 9% p.a. for 12 months. In order to apply the formula, the value of I must be discounted to the present at the appropriate interest rate. In this case, I is given by
2
Consider the valuation of a three-month forward or futures contract on the CAC 40 stock index. The index provides a continuous dividend yield of 4% p.a. Suppose that the current index price is 1000 and the risk-free rate is 7% p.a. In 1000, T 0.25 year, r this case, S 0.07 and d 0.04, so the futures or forward price is given by =
=
=
F
I
F
1000e(0.07-0.04)0.25 1007.528
=
50e
=
"*°*
"
+ 50e
=
48.039 + 45.696
=
93.735
and the forward price is given by
=
=
(800
'"
93.735)e
-
=
'O
706.265e
=
772.777
=
Futures Contracts on Foreign Currencies The cost of carrying a foreign currency is given by the difference between the domestic riskless rate and the foreign riskless rate, r*. This gives the following relation between the futures price and the spot price of the currency: F
=
(79)
Se"
This relationship also gives the forward price F (or foreign exchange rate F) as a function of the spot price S for a forward contract on a currency. It is often known in international finance as the interest-rate
I
parity theorem.
Example
2
of a one-year forward contract on a stock with a Consider now the valuation price equal to 100. When the dividend is 2 and the interest paid at the end of the year is 10% p.a., the present value of dividends is I
2e
=
""
=
1.8096
and the forward price is given by F
=
(100-
1.8096)e
""
=
108.516
Example
forward or futures contract on a foreign currency. If the spot price is 180, the domestic risk-free rate is 7% p.a. and the 180, T 0.07 and 0.25 year, r foreign risk-free rate is 6% p.a., then S is given 0.06. The future forward by r or price
Consider the valuation of a three-month
=
=
.
=
.
=
F
=
180e'
63°26
=
180.45
Example
3
.
Consider the valuation of a one-year futures contract on gold. If the cost of carry is 3 per ounce paid at the end of the year, the spot price is 500 and the risk-free rate is 10% p.a., the value of I is given by I
Futures Contracts on a Security with a Discrete lncome When the cost of carrying the commodity is not a constant proportional rate, the formulas above must be slightly modified.
=
3e
""
=
2.7145
and the futures price is given by F
=
(500 + 2.7145)e
""
=
555.585
OPTIONS,
120
Commodity
Options
and
Commodity
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
DERiYATIVES
Futures Options
A commodity call gives the right to its holder to buy a specific commodity at a specified price within a specified period of time. A commodity put gives the right to its holder to buy a specific commodity at a specified price within a predetermined period of time. A commodity futures option is an option on the futures contract having a commodity as an underlying asset. The commodity may be a precious metal such as silver or gold. It may be a financial instrument such as a common stock, a treasury bond or a foreign currency. For example, if the commodity option is written on a foreign currency, the option refers to a currency option. If the commodity option is written on a stock index, the option is an index option. Since all the analytical models for European options presented in this chapter can be obtained by modifying the parameters in the Merton (1973a) and BAW (1987)model, all the applications presented here are also true for this model. For example, when the option's underlying asset is an index which is constructed to pay continuous dividends, this version is a particular case of the Merton and BAW model for commodity options. When the continuous dividend yield is d, the formula for European commodity options is rewritten for index options with b r - d. For a European index call, the formula is =
c(S, T)
=
Se-dTN(d
)-
ANALYTICAL
POINTS
• • •
•
ln
=
a and d2
=
di - on.
K /
+
2)
(r + (0
T
(82)
• • •
For a European index put, the formula becomes
p(S, T)
=
Ke "N(-d2)
"N(-di) - Se
•
(83)
• • •
SUMMARY This chapter presents in detail the basic concepts and techniques underlying rational derivative asset pricing, in the context of analytical European models along the lines of B-S, Black, Garman and Kohlhagen, and Merton-BAW. First, an overview of the analytical models proposed by the precursors is given. Second, the simple model of B-S is derived in detail for the valuation of options on spot assets and some of its applications are presented. Third, the Black model, which is an extension of the B-S model for the valuation of futures contracts and commodity options, is analyzed. Also, applications of the model are proposed. Fourth, the Garman and Kohlhagen model is presented for the valuation of currency options, and some applications of the model are provided. Fifth, the Merton and BAW model is applied to the valuation of European commodity options and commodity futures options. Again, some applications contracts, commodity
MODELS
121
FOR DISCUSSION
What is wrong What is wrong
• •
•
di
PRICING
natural extension of these models must introduce the possibility of early exercise and discrete distributions. However, before making some extensions of the basic analytical models, it is useful to study, in this simple context, the option price sensitivities and the use of the so-called Greek-letter risk measures in the monitoring and the management of an option position. The question of managing an option position is as important as some issues regarding option pricing. This is the subject of the next chapter.
•
with
OPTION
of the model are given. Note that this model reduces to the models in B-S, Black, and Garman and Kohlhagen for some values of its parameters. Since all these models are concerned with the valuation of European-style options in a continuous time framework (withoutdiscrete distributions to the underlying asset), a
•
Ke-rrN(d2)
EUROPEAN
•
• •
•
• • • •
• • •
with the Bachelier formula? with the Sprenkle formula'?
What is wrong with the Boness formula? What is wrong with the Samuelson formula? What are the main differences between the Black and Scholes model and the precursor models? for options on spot assets? How can we obtain the put-call parity relationship How can we obtam the put-call parity relationship for options on futures contracts? What are the main specificities of index options and their markets? How is the Black and Scholes model adjusted for index options? What are the implications of arbitrage for index option markets and their assets? How are indexes constructed? What is the main difference between zero-coupon bonds and coupon-paying bonds? What are the different types of bonds? What are the main specificities of short-term options on long-term bonds? What are the main specificities of bond options? Is the Black and Scholes model appropriate for the valuation of derivative assets whose values depend on interest rates? Justify your answer. of derivative assets whose values Is the Black model appropriate for the valuation depend on interest rates? Justify your answer. 1s there a difference between a futures price and the value of a futures contract? How can we obtain the put-call parity relationship for futures options from that of European spot options? What are the specificities of options traded on the LIFFE? What is the appropriate model for their valuation? What does the interest rate theorem tell us'? What are the main characteristics of currency options and their markets? What is the main difference between Black and Scholes' model and Black's model? What is the main difference between Black and Scholes' model and Garman and Kohlhagen's model? What is inappropriate in the derivation of Garman and Kohlhagen's model? Black and Scholes' model? What do you think of the assumptions underlying underlying Black's model? What do you think of the assumptions
122
• • • • • • • •
What What What What What What What How
OPTIONS,
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
'
do you think of the assumptions underlying Garman and Kohlhagen's model'? are the main differences between futures and forward contracts?
is a commodity option? is the formula for a futures contract on a security with no income? is the formula for a futures contract on a security with a known income? is the formula for a futures contract on a foreign currency? is the formula for a futures contract on a security with a discrete income? can we obtain the formulas in Black and Scholes' model, Black's model and Garman and Kohlhagen's model usmg the formula m Merton and BAW?
e
4
Monito rmg an dM an age ment Of Ûpt|On
CHAPTER
OUTLINE
ŸOSitiODS
.
This chapter is organized as follows: 1. In section 6.1, option price sensitivities are presented and the formulas are applied. 2. In section 6.2, the Greek-letter risk measures are simulated for different parameters. The issue of monitoring and managing an option position in real time is studied for the different risk measures with respect to an option pricing model. 3. In section 6.3, some of the characteristics of volatility spreads are presented. 4. In Appendix 6.A, we give the Greek-letter risk measures with respect to the analytical models presented in the previous chapter. 5. In Appendix 6.B, we show the relationships between some of these Greek-letter risk measures. 6. In Appendix 6.C, we present the relationships between these parameters of a more general equation for the pricing of derivative securities.
in the context
INTRODUCTION in a derivative asset price with respect to its to monitor the variations which the determinants or enter the option formula. These variations are often parameters named Greek-letter risk measures. The most widely used measures are known as the delta, charm, gamma, speed, color, theta, vega, Rho and elasticity. The delta measures the absolute change in the option price with respect to a small variation in the underlying asset price. Charm corresponds to the partial derivative of the delta with respect to time. The gamma gives the change in the delta, or in the hedge ratio asset price changes. Color corresponds to the gamma's derivative with as the underlying the change in the option respect to the time remaining to maturity. The theta measures price as time elapses, namely the time decay of the option. The vega or lambda is a measure of the change in the option price for a small change in the underlying asset's It is important
volatility. In this chapter, we show how to calculate some of these parameters
within
the context
124
OPTIONS,
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
MONITORING
of each analytical model presented in the previous chapter. Also, we develop examples to show how to use the Greek-letter risk measures in the monitoring and the management of an option position in response to changing market conditions.
6.1
OPTION
.
with respect to the parameters
sensitivities
POSITIONS
entering
125
the option formula. We begin our
discussion with the delta.
6.I.I
PRICE SENSITIVITIES
The sensitivity parameters are important in managing an option position. The delta measures the absolute change in the option price with respect to a small change m the price of the underlying asset. It is- given by the option's partial derivative with respect to the underlying price. It represents the hedge ratio, or the number of asset options to write or to buy in order to create a risk-free portfolio. Call buymg involves the sale of a quantity delta of the underlying asset in order to form the hedging portfolio. Call selling involves the purchase of a quantity delta of the asset to create the hedging portfolio. Put buying requires the purchase of a quantity delta of the underlying asset to hedge a portfolio. Put selling involves the sale of delta stocks to create a hedged portfoho. The delta varies frorn zero for deep out-of-the-money options to l for deep in-themoney calls. This is not surprising, since by definition the delta is given by the first partial derivative of the option price with respect to the underlying asset. For example, the value which the of a deep in-the-money call is nearly equal to the intrinsic value (S - K), for with partial S first derivative respect to is 1. Charm is a risk measure that clarifies the concept of carry in financial instruments. The concept of carry refers to the expenses due to the financing of a deferred dehvery of commodities, currencies or other assets m financial contracts. Charm is given by the derivative of the delta with respect to time. Even though charm is used by market participants as an ad hoc measure of how delta may change overnight, it is an important measure of risk since it divides the theta into its asset-based constituents (seeAppendix 6.C). The gamma measures the change in delta, or in the hedge ratio, as the underlying asset price changes. The gamma is greatest for at-the-money options. It is nearly zero for deep in-the-money and deep out-of-the-money options. Roughly speaking, the gamma is to the delta what convexity is to duration. The gamma is given by the derivative of the hedge ratio with respect to the underlying asset price. As such, it is an indication of the vulnerability of the hedge ratio. of an option The gamma is very important in the management and the monitoring position. It gives rise to two other measures of risk: speed and color. Speed is given by the gamma's derivative with respect to the underlying asset price. Color is given by the gamma's derivative with respect to the time remaining to maturity. The theta measures the change in the option price as time elapses, since the passage of time has a negative impact on option values. Indeed, options are wasting assets. Theta is given by the first partial derivative of the option premium with respect to time. the change in the option price for a change in the The vega or lambda measures volatility. underlying's given It is by the first derivative of the option premium with asset respect to the volatility parameter. option price is not sufficient and the for the monitoring The knowledge of the management of an option position. Therefore, it is important to know the option price
OF OPTION
AND MANAGEMENT
The Delta
The Call's Delta The delta is given by the option's first partial derivative with respect to the underlymg asset price. It represents the hedge ratio in the context of the B-S model. The option's delta is given by
.
A Applying this formula
N(di)
=
the calculation
needs
in d
(1)
of di:
Ky
=
(2)
5
a
Example 15, the short-term 18, the strike price K Let the underlying asset S 15%. 0.25 and the volatility a 10%, the maturity date T =
=
.
rate r
in di
18
interest
=
=
=
(0.1+
((0.15)2)0.25 =
=
0.15VT25
2.8017
N(2.8017) Hence, the delta is Ae 0.997. This delta value means that the hedge of the purchase of a call requires the sale of 0.997 units of the underlying asset. When the underlying asset price rises by l unit, from 18 to 19, the option price rises from 3.3659 to (3.3659+ 0.997), or 4.3629. When the asset price falls by one unit, the option price changes from 3.3659 to (3.3659 0.997), or 2.3689. =
=
-
The Put's Delta
The put's delta has the same meaning as the call's delta. It is also given by the option's first derivative with respect to the underlying asset price. When selling (buying) a put option, the hedge requires selling (buying)delta units of the underlying asset. The put's delta is given by A,
'true'
=
A, - 1
Using the data fiom the call example, A, 0.997 - 1 -0.003. The hedge ratio is 0.003. When the underlying asset price goes from 18 to 19, the put price changes from =
4
(3) =
*
AND EXOTIC
FUTURES
OPTIONS,
6.1.3
The Theta
with respect to the time the option's first partial derivative The option's theta is given by by is given model, the theta remaining to maturity. In the B-S San(di) (7) N(d2) + rKe oc Oc 2d BT =
The Calfs Gamma option's second partial derivative with respect The option's gamma corresponds to the derivative with respect to the asset price partial the underlying asset or to the delta's In the B-S model, the call's gamma is given by
Son
BS
to
(4)
n(di)
=
=
(5)
di)
(
exp
=
-
-
in the example above: or using the same data as Oc 0.2653 1.4571
option price decreases by maturity is reduced by one day, the the call's price When the option's time to maturity is shortened by 1% of a year, 1.1918 units. When the time to 3.3659 to from changes 0.011918, and its price decreases by 0.01 (1.1918),or (3.3659 0.011918), or 3.3540,
The Put's Theta put's theta is given by In the B-S model, the Son(di) op 8, 2d ST =
1 e
=
"23°"
0.09826
=
the example above, or using the data from
=
5
18(0.5)
(0.09826)
8
0.0727
=
0.997, a fall in the asset price by one When the underlying asset price is 18 and its delta is 0.0727), or 0.9243. Also, a rise in 0.997 to from (0.997 delta in the unit yields a change the delta from 0.997 to (0.997+ 0.0727), the asset price from 18 to 19 yields a change in deeply in-the-money, and its value is given by its the option is or 1. This means that apply to put options. The cal and the put arguments K). The same mtrinsic value (S .
Using the same 0.002
reasoning,
=
(
b¯"N(-d2)
=
-
-0.2653
Ee
-1.1918
=
-
=
--+
Using the same data as in the example: n(di)
=
-
-
with n(di)
187
POSITIONS
The Call's Theta
The Gamma
Ye
OF OPTION
AND MANAGEMENT
DERIVATIVES
18 to 17, the put price rises 0.0045 to (0.0045-0.003), or 0.0015. When it falls from from 0.0045 to (0.0045+ 0.003), or 0.0075.
6.1.2
MONITORING
-0.2594
+ 0.0058
the put price changes
=
from 0.0045 to
(0.0045 0ß025), -
or
-
have the same gamma.
6.1.4
The Vega
The Cau's Vega win the option price derivative The option's vega is given by given by model, the call's vega is parameter. In the B-S
The Put's Gamma
ve
The put's gamma is given by
f"
=
BA" 8S
1 =
-
So
(6)
n(di)
R
Er
=
(0.09826)
=
0.0727
unit, the put price changes by the When the asset price changes by one the delta chances bv an amount eaual to the samma,
dekt
amount and
-
oc SRn(di) =
volatility
(9)
da
or using the above data: De
Using the same data as in the example,
=
respect to the
=
18v'n5(0.098
26)
=
0.884 34
by 0.884 34. The rises by I point, the call price increases 3.3659 to Hence, when the volatility from price the option by 1% changes changes from increase in volatility price the put context, the same or 3,37474. In volatility falls by 1% the [3.3659+ 1%(0.884 34)], 434. When the 0.133 34)], 1%(0.884 or 0.0045 to [0.0045+ 3.361 56. In the same 1%(0.884 34)], or call's price changes from 3.3659 to [3.3659 -
OPTIONS,
FUTURES
way, the put price is modified from 0.0045 to option prices can not be negative.
[0.0045-
128
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
MONITORING
OF OPTION
ANDFIANAGEMENT
l%(0.884 34)], or zero since
Elasticity
=
S
POSITIONS
N(di)
=
c
129
(13)
c
or usmg the above data:
The Put's Vega
8
Elasticity In the B-S model, the put's vega is given by vp -
-
SÑn(di)
(10)
or using the above data: v
18NZŠ(0.09826) 0.88434 =
=
0.997
=
3.3659
5.3317
=
The elasticity shows the change in the option price when the underlying asset price varies by 1%. Hence a rise of the asset price by 1%, i.e. 0.18, induces an increase in the call price by 5.33%. The put price changes by 12%. Hence, when the asset price changes from 18 to 18.18, the call's price is modified from 3.3659 to [3.3659(1 5.33%)], or 3.545. In the same way, the put price changes from 0.0045 to [0.0045(1 12%)], or 0.0504.
It has the same meaning as the call's vega. The Put's Elasticity 6.1.5
The put's
The Rho
elasticity
is given by Elasticity
The Call's Rho
Oc
Rhoc
=
=
-
K(t*
or
- t)e
(11)
t is the current time and t* is the maturity date. Using the above data: Rhoc
15e
=
"
2"(0.996)(0.25)
=
3.64
The Put's Rho the put's Rho is given by Rho,
=
-K(t*
=
ßr
t)e
"'n(d2)
or using the above data: -l5e-0
Rho
=
Elasticity
-3.64 1(0.25)(0.996X0.25) =
(12)
-[N(dt)
-
1)
(14)
p
18 =
0.0045
[0.997-
The knowledge of the variations in these parameters of an option position. and the management
6.2
The Rho does not affect call and put prices in the same way. In fact, a rise in the interest rate yields a higher call price (positiveRho) and reduces the put price (negativeRho).
S
=
or using the above data:
"'n(dg
where
6.1.6
Ap Sc
The option's Rho is given by the option's first partial derivative with respect to interest rates. In the B-S model, the call's Rho is given by
In the B-S model,
=
MONITORING AND MANAGING POSITION IN REAL TIME
l]
=
-12
is fundamental for the monitoring
AN OPTION
Since option prices change in an unpredictable way in response to the changes in market conditions, traders, market makers and all options users must rely upon some model to monitor the evolutions of their profit and loss accounts. Such a model allows them to quantify the variations in option price sensitivities and their risk exposure. With such of option positions are more easily quantities the monitoring and the management achieved. We will illustrate the management of an option position in real time using the model proposed indirectly in Merton (1973a) and derived afterwards in Black (1975a) and BAW (1987)for the valuation of European futures options. First, option prices are simulated and the sensitivity parameters are calculated. Second, we study the risk management problem in real time with respect to option price sensitivities. .
Elasticity 6.2.1
Simulation
and
Analysis
of Option
Price Sensitivities
The Call's Elasticity For a call option, this measure
is given by
Recall that the commodity call price and the commodity futures call price ifrthe context of Merton's (1973a)and BAW's (1987)model is given by
130
OPTIONS,
c
Se"' '"N(di)
=
-
AND EXOTIC
FUTURES
DERIVATIVES
Ke "N(d2)
ORING AND MANAGEMENT
(15)
TABLE 6.3 In-the-money in the time to maturity 0.I, S a= 0.2, r= 0.08, b
where b stands for the cost of carrying the underlying commodity. By the put-call parity relationship or by a direct derivation, the put's value is given in the same context by p
=
Ke
'"
N(-d2)
-
Se"
'"
N(-di)
=
callprice 9.875 9.849 10.08 10.563 10.946
(16)
where
all the parameters have the same meaning as before. For a non-dividend paying asset, b r. For a dividend paying asset, b r - d where d stands for the dividend yield. For a currency option, b r - r* where r* stands for the foreign riskless rate. Tables 6.1-6.12 simulate option values and sensitivity parameters for calls and puts in the context of the above model. =
=
=
=
=
Colíprice 0.095
0.439 l.392 3.294 6.250 10.080 i 4.473 19.l59
=
=
Gommo
Theto%
Vego%
75 80 85 90 95 100 105 i10
0.037 0.127 0.294 0.507 0.705 0.844 0.92 I 0.959
0.007 0.019 0.033
-1.056 -2.891 -5.023 -5.842
2.8i8 7.836 14.07\ 17.509 I 5.988 I1,080 6.295 2.912
0.039 0.034 0,022 0.0 I2 0.005
-4.567 -\.997 -0.579
-0.477
call price sensitivities TABLE 6.2 In-the-money asset prices using the following in the underlying 0.08, b 0.25, K 0.2, r « 0. I, T I 00 =
=
=
=
0.004 0.034 0.175 0.631 I 3.659 6.567 10.287 .705
assetprice 75 80 85 90 95 100 105 I 10
0.988 0.950 0.844 0.744 0.685
0.006 0.0 I6 0,022 0.020 0.018
=
5.774 6.403
Theta % -1.584 -0.485 -1.997 -1.750 -1.322
call
price sensitivities the following 100 100, K
using =
for changes parameters:
for changes parameters:
Gamma
Theta %
Vego %
0.05
0.542 0.526 0.507 0.489 0.475 0.46I
0.088 0.062 0.039 0.027 0.021 0.018
-16.378 -!!.221 -6.491 -4.0 I 3 -2.879 -2.I90
8.876 !2.49 19.455 26.834 32.053 36.098
=
=
Volatility 0.05 0.10 0.20 0.30 0.40
9.3 I3 9.352 10.08 I 1.404 12.963
i 1.224 20.316 26.674
Delto
=
Callprice
0.569 3. I6
=
TABLE 6.5 call price sensitivities In-the-money using the following in the volatility parameter 0.08, b 0. I, S I 00, K 90 T 0.25, r =
Vega %
Maturity
0.l0 0.25 0.50 0.75 0.75
4.925
for changes parameters:
=
°/o
Delto
Gamma
Thetc %
Vega
0.975 0.959 0.844 0.762 0.716
0.000 0.00| 0.022 0.020 0,0160
-2.694 -2.I59 -1.997 -6.420 -10.504
0.006 2.5i7 I 1.224 14.783 16.252
=
Underlying
Callprice
0.05
=
3.659 Delto
Gammo
0.75
for changes parameters:
90
=
Deka
0.50
1.727 2.402
=
the following
100, K
=
13 I
sensitivities
price
Moturity 0. I0 0.25
callprice
POSITIONS
using
At-the-money in the time to maturity 0.2, r 0.08, b 0.I, S a
for changes parameters:
Underlying ossetprice
call
TABLE 6.4 =
TABLE 6. I At-the-money call price sensitivities in the underlying asset prices using the following 0.08, b 0.f, T 0.25, K 90 0.2, r «
OF OPTION
Delta
Gammo
Theta%
0.002 0.014 0.056 0.154 0.3 I4 0.507 0.687 0.82 I
0.001 0.003 0.0 I 0
-0.092 -0.499 -1.672 -3.713 -5.766
0.022 0.034 0.039 0.035 0.025
-6.491
-5.306 - 2.83 \
Vega%
0.243 l.325 4.477 10.112 I6.229 !9.455 18.152 \ 3.643
"t
call price sensitivities TABLE 6.6 At-the-money using the following in the volatility parameter 0.08, b 0.1, S 100, K 100 T 0.25, r =
Call price 0.750 |.7 I5 3.659 5.604 7.546
=
=
=
Volatility
Delto
0.05 0. IO 0.20 0.30 0.40
0.492 0.497 0.507 0.5l7 0.526
for changes parameters:
=
Gomma 0.15!
0.077 0.039 0.026 0.0 19
Theto %
Vega %
-l.Ol6 --2.8 I 5 -6.491 -l0.l72 3.836 - I
19.!19 I9.40 I 19.455 (9.437 I9.399
OPTIONS,
132
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
TABLE 6.7 At-the-money put price sensitivities asset prices using the following in the underlying 0.I, T 0.25, K 90 « 0.2, r 0.08, b =
=
Put price
=
=
for changes parameters:
AND MANAGEMENT
=
Vega %
Put price
-0.938
0.007
-0.849 -0.682 -0.468 0.27 I -0.132
0.019 0.033 0.039 0.034 0.022
- I.3 I 3 -3.636 -6.256 -7.562 -6.775 -4.692
2.8 I8 7.836 14.071 I7.509 I5.988 11.224
0.000 0.039
Put
price
Underlying asset
24.876 20.029 I5.293 I0.873 7.07 I 4.148
TABLE 6.9 Out-the-money es in the time to maturity 0.I, S 0.2, r 0.08, b o =
=
=
changes meters: Put
Delto
Gamma
Theto %
Vego %
-0.973 -0.961 -0.9I9 -0.82 1 -0.662 -0.468
0.001
-0.435 -0.460 -2.I2I -4.648 -7. I90
0.243 1.325 4.477 i 0. I I2 I6.229 19.455
price
75 80 85 90 95 100
133
Gommo
Theto %
Vego %
0.000 0.001 0.022 0.020 0.0 I6
-0.00 I -0.537 -4.692 -9.I I5 - I 3. I99
0.006 2.517 I 1.224 i4.783 I6.252
sensitivities 6.12 price At-the-money put using the following in the volatility parameter 100 0.08, b 0.I, S 100, K T 0.25, r =
=
0.014 0.127 0.767 I.9I I 2.93 \ 3.829
Moturity 0.05 0.\0
0.25 0.50 0.75 l.00
0.003 0.0I0 0.022 0.034 0.039
-8.402
put price sensitivities the following 100, K 100 using
=
price
Volatility
l.239 2.204 4.148 6.093 8.035
Sensitivity Parameters
for changparameters:
0.05 0.10 0.20 0.30 0.40
Delta
Gommo
Theto %
Vega %
0.151 0.077
-2.927 -4.726 -8.402 -I2.083 - I 5.747
l9.I 19 19.40\ 19.455 I9.437 I9.399
-0.483 -0.478 -0.468 -0.459 -0.449
for Call
0.039 0.026 0.0 I9
Options
Table 6.1 gives call prices, delta, gamma, theta and vega when the underlying commodity price varies from 75 to l 10 in steps of $5. For example, when the volatility 20%, a 8%, b 10% and T 3 months (0.25year), the price of an at-the-money call for r K 90 is 3.294 The call has a delta of 0.507, a gamma of 0.039, a theta of and a vega of 17.504. Note that an at-the-money option has more theta and vega than in-the-money and out-of-the-money calls. Using the same data except for the strike price which is modified from 90 to 100, Table 6.2 shows that an at-the-money call has more gamma, theta and vega than in- and out-ofthe-money calls. Table 6.3 shows call prices and sensitivity parameters for in-the-money calls (S> K) when the time to maturity varies from 0.05 to 0.75 year. Note that the call price, the vega and the theta increase with the time to maturity. However, the delta falls when the time to maturity is longer. Table 6.4 gives call prices and sensitivity parameters for at-the-money calls when S K 100 and the time to maturity varies from 0.05 to one year. Note that the call price, its delta and vega are increasing functions of the time to maturity. However, the gamma and the theta are more important for near-maturities. Table 6.5 gives in-the-money call prices (S 100, K 90) for different levels of the volatility parameter. When the delta is equal to 1, the gamma is nearly equal to zero. Also, the vega is nearly ml and the theta is weak. Table 6.6 gives the same information as Table 6.5, except that calculations are done for at-the-money options (S K 100). =
=
=
Delto
Gamma
Theto %
Vega %
-0.007 -0.04 -0.132 -0.207 -0.243 -0.263
0.006 0.016 0.022 0.020 0.0 I8 0.016
-l.l94 -3.242 -4.692 -4.344 -3.8 I8 -3.375
0.569 3.I6 1 l.224 20.316 26.674 3\.448
TABLE 6.10 At-the-money in the time to maturity «=0.2,r=0.08,b=0.I,S= es
=
=
-5.842
for changput price sensitivities the following parameters: 100,K= 100 using
=
Put price I.826 2.600 4.148 5.88 I 7.176 8.231
Delta
Moturity 0.05 0.10 0.25 0.50 0.75 l.00
.
for para-
=
=
=
Put price
para-
=
=
0.000 -0.016 -0.132 -0.2I3 -0.259
=
for
=
=
=
=
for changes parameters:
Delta
0.05 0.10 0.20 0.30 0.40
0.767
=
=
Volatility
2.09I 3.650
TABLE
=
POSITIONS
sensitivities TABLE 6.1 I Out-of-the-money put price in the volatility parameter using the following meters: T 0.25, r 100, K 90 0.08, b 0.I, S
Theta %
TABLE 6.8 In-the-money put price sensitivities in the underlying asset prices using the following 0.25, K 100 0.2, r 0.I, T 0.08, b a
OF OPTION
changes
Gomma
Delta
75 80 85 90 95 100
MordTORING
=
Underlying asset price
I5. I65 10.632 6.708 3.734 I.8 I 3 0.767
DERIVATIVES
-0.453 -0.464 -0.468 -0.462 -0.453 -0.443
Gammo 0.088 0.062 0.039 0.027 0.021 0.018
Theto %
Vego %
-18.360 -13.184 -8.402 -5.839 -4.622 -3.853
8.876 12.49 19.455 26.834 32.053 36.098
=
=
-
.
t
=
,
=
=
OPTIONS,
134
Sensitivity Parameters
for Put
FUTURES
AND EXOT1C DERIVAT!
AMOBRMiBIGEMENT
=
35
-
=
3o
-
2o
-
15
-1.0
.
io
-
=
0.7 0.6
5
e
_
Monitoring
and
0.1
12o
S: Underlying asset price
=
Position
T: Timelomaturity
0.2
92 96 100 104108 112 116
are the sensitivity parameters. Table 6.12 shows at-the-money put prices (S 100) for different levels of the K volatility parameter. Note that the put price, the delta (in absolute value), the vega and the theta are increasing functions of the volatility parameter.
the Option
0.4 0.3
(
80 84
varies from 0.05 to Table 6.11 gives out-of-the money put prices when the volatility 0.40. When the volatility is respectively equal to 0.05 and 0.10 the put price is nil and so
and Adjusting
=
-
25
maturitieS'
Monitoring
,
=
=
=
K 100 r = 8% b 10% o 25% =
=
=
6.2.2
135
Parameters =
=
POSITIONS
Options
Table 6.7 gives put prices and the sensitivity parameters when « 0.2, r 0.08, b 0.1, T 0.25 and K 90. For an at-the-money put, the gamma and the vega are important. The put theta increases when the option tends to parity and decreases afterwards. The same behavior applies for the put gamma and vega. Table 6.8 gives the same information as Table 6.7, except for the strike price which is changed from 90 to 100. For in-the-money puts, the delta approaches 1, the gamma and vega are not important and the theta is very weak. 100, K Table 6.9 gives out-of-the-money 90) and the put price put prices (S sensitivities when the time to maturity varies from 0.05 to one year. The values of the delta and gamma are weak. However, the vega and theta are greater for longer maturities Table 6.10 shows the same information for at-the-money put prices (S K 100). Note that the deltas and gammas are decreasing functions of the time to maturity. For an at-the-money put, there is more theta on short maturities and more vega on longer =
OF OPTION
it
*The
call Values
by Underlying
Asset
Price and Time
to Maturity
in Real Time
Managing the Delta
Parameters
The call delta lies between zero and 1 and the put delta between zero and - L When the delta is 0.5, the call price rises (falls)by 0.5 point for each increase (decrease)in the asset price by l point. A delta of0.5 corresponds to an at-the-money call. For a deep in-the-money call, the variation in the asset price by one unit implies an call is almost equivalent variation in the option price. The delta of an out-of-the-money zero and of a deep in-the-money call is almost 1 Figures 6.1-6.4 are drawn according to the data in the preceding tables. and zero, a rise in the asset price Since the put delta lies in the interval between implies a fall in the put price and vice versa. The delta is for an at-the-money put, -1 for a deep in-the-money put and zero for a deep out-of-the-money put. Using the data in the preceding tables, Figure 6.2 shows the put price as a function of .
-
=
-\
18
=
16 14
12 io
-l
the asset price The call delta is often assimilated to the hedge ratio. Since the underlying asset delta is and that of an at-the-money call is 0.5, the hedge ratio is 1 0.5 or 2/1. Hence, we need 1 at-the-money calls to hedge the sale of the underlying asset. two The delta corresponds also to the (risk-neutral)probability that the option finishes in the money at the option's maturity date. Hence, when the delta is 0.6 for a call (-0.6 for a put), this means that there is a 60% chance in the risk-neutral economy that the option
K 100 r 8% b = 10% ci 25% =
20
o
6 6 4
o
-
-
-
-
¯ -1.0
0 9
_
0 7
-
a 80 84 66 92 96 100 104108
:)
i
Time
to nakisty
2
112 116 120
S: Underlying asset price
FIGURE 6.2
The Put Values
by Underlying
Asset
PrtgegiendTiitmaW9taturity
OPTIONS,
136
FUTU
EG AIIIBMIIR Ild IlialVATIVES
MONITORING
AND MANAGEMENT
OF OPTION
POSITIONS
137
finishes in-the-money at maturity. Note that the delta is calculated K 100 r 8% b = 10% a = 25% =
1.00
=
-
0.90
-
o.80
-
0.70 o
0.60
¯
0.50
-
0.40
-
0.30
1.0 0J30.9
-
0.20
-
o.1o
-
0.7
0.6
o.5 0.4 0.3 0.2
0.00
so
84 88 92 96 100104108112 116 120
T: Time . to maturity
0.1
S: Underlying asset price
PIGWila 6.3
The BAW Call's Delta
Parameters K r
o.oo-
=
100
=
8%
o
-0.20 -0.40-0.60
_
-o.80
_
-1.00-
-1.20¯
1.0 0.9 0.8 0·7
-1.40¯ -1.60-1.80-2.00
_
80 84 88 92 96 100 104 108
0.1 112 116 120 S: Underlying asset price
FIGURE
6.4
The BAW Put's
Delta
0.5 0.4 0.20.3
in practice using the volatility. the implied or Delta-neutral hedging requires the adjustment of the option position according to the variations in the delta. When buying or selling a call (put), the investor must sell or buy (buyor sell) delta units of the underlying asset to represent a hedged portfolio. In practice, the hedged portfolio is adjusted nearly continuously to account for the variations in the delta's value. An initially hedged position must be rebalanced by buying in the delta through time. and selling the underlying asset as a function of the variations The delta changes as the volatility, the interest rate and the time to maturity are modified. Table 6.13 shows how to adjust a hedged portfolio in order to preserve the main characteristics of delta-neutral strategies. It is important to note that delta-neutral hedging strategies do not protect completely the option position against the variations in the volatility parameter. Table 6.14 shows when volatility the position changes. adjust the how to It is also important to note that delta-neutral hedging does not protect the option position against the variations in the time remaining to maturity. Table 6.15 shows how to adjust the position when the time to maturity changes. Figure 6.5 shows the effect of the volatility parameter. When the volatility rises or the time to maturity is lengthened, options which are out become at parity or in-the-money and vice versa. Note that deltas are additive. For example, when buying two calls having deltas of 0.2 and 0.7, the investor must sell 0.9 units of the underlymg- asset in a delta-neutral strategy. Option market makers often implement delta-neutral hedging strategies in order to maintain a nil delta (in monetary units). When the delta of an option position is positive, this means that the market maker is long the underlying asset. It can be interpreted as a bullish position. If the asset price rises, he makes a profit since he will be able to sell it at a higher price. However, if the asset price decreases, he will lose money since he will sell the underlying asset at a lower price. When the delta is positive, the investor is over-hedged with respect to delta-neutral strategies. When the delta (in monetary units) is negative, the investor is short the underlying The holds investor asset. asset price rises, the investor a bearish position. If the underlying 10Ses money since he adjusts his position by buying more units of the underlying asset. However, when the asset price falls, he makes a profit since he pays less for the underlying asset.
observed volatility
Parameters
°
TABLE 6.13 Adjustment lying Asset Price
of the
Hedged
Portfolio
as a Function
Asset Price Rises: SÎ
Asset Price Falls:Si
Oþtions
Delta Hedging
Delta Hedging
Longa call Short a call Longa put Short a put
Delta Delta Delta Delta
T: Time to matufüy
increases: sell more buy more decreases: sell more decreases: buy more increases:
S S S S
Delta Delta Delta Delta
of the
decreases: buy more decreases: sell more increases: buy more increases: sell more
S 5 S S
Under-
OPTIONS,
138
TABLE 6.14
Adjustment
of a Hedged
FUTURES
Position
AND EXOTIC
when the Volatility
EMENT OF OPTION
MO9NT
DERIVATIVES
POSITIONS
139
Changes
Parameters
Adjustment of o Hedged Position Options Long a call: in-the-money at-the-money out-of-the-money
1.2
VolatilityDecreases
Volatilitylacreases
=
1.0
Delta increases: buy more S Delta non-adjusted Delta decreases: sell more S
Delta increases: sell more S Delta non-adjusted Detta decreases: buy more S
Delta decreases: resell of S Delta non-adjusted Delta increases: buy more S
Delta increases: buy more S Delta non-adjusted Delta decreases: sell more S
Delta decreases: resell of S Delta non-adjusted Delta increases: buy more S
Delta increases: buy more 5 Delta non-ad¡usted Delta decreases: sell more S
0.8
o
Short a put: in-the-money at-the-money out-of-the-money
0.4
0 Jiim 0.4$ 0.40 0.35
-
Delta increases: buy more S Delta non-adjusted Delta decreases: sell more S
0-
I
80 84 88 92
Delta increases: sell more S Delta non-adjusted Delta decreases: buy more S
96
100 104 108
112 116
0.30 0.25 a: VolaWW 0.20 y 0.15 0.10 1200.05
S: Underlying asset price
¥lGURE
6.5
The Call's Delta and the Volatility
When a portfolio is constructed by buying vj, the portfolio value is given by
(selling)the
securitiesandderivgive
Adjustment
of a Hedged
Position
as a Function
of Time
Options
Adjustment of the Hedged Position as a Function of Time
Longaco. in-the-money at-the-money out-of-the-money
Delta rises: sell more s Delta non-modified Delta decreases: buy more S
Short o coll: m-the-money at-the-money out-of-the-money
Delta nses: buy more S Delta non-modified Delta decreases: sell more 5
Long a put: m-the-money at-the-money out-of-the-money
Delta rises: buy more 5 Delta non-modified Delta decreases: sell more S
shorta put: m-the-money
at-the-money out-of-the-money
where n, stands for the numbers of units of the assets bought or sold. The delta's position, or its partial derivative with respect to the securities and derivative assets, is _BS
Sv3
Sv,
Ovi
Delta nses: sell more S Delta non-modified Delta decreases: buy more S
assets
(17)
P=niv,+n2v,+n3v3+...+nyv TABLE 6.15
10%
0.5
-
0.2~
Longa put: in-the-money at-the-money out-of-the-money
_
100
8%
0.6 -
Short a call: in-the-money at-the-money out-of-the-money
K= r= b= T
-
n2
BS
n3
--BS
+...+ny
Sv; -BS
(|8)
+ n,A niAi + n:A2 nsA3 (19) Delta-neutral hedging is convenient for an investor who does not have prior expectations about the market direction. However, if the investor expects a rising market, he can have a positive delta, i.e., long the underlying asset, so he can self at a higher price when the market effectively rises. If the investor expects a down market, he can have a negative delta, i.e., short the underlying asset, so he can buy it at a lower price when the market effectively goes down. =
Monitoring
---
and Managing
.
.
.
the Gamma
The gamma is given by the second derivative of the option price with respect to the . underlying asset price. A high value of gamma (positiveor negative) shows a higher nsk for an option position. The gamma shows what the option gains (loses) in delta when the underlying asset price rises (falls).
140
OPTIONS,
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
For example, when the option's gamma is 4 and the option's delta is zero, an increase by 1 point in the underlying asset price allows the option to gain 4 points in delta, i.e. the delta becomes equal to 4. When the delta is constant, the gamma is zero. The gamma varies when the market conditions change. Figures 6.6 and 6.7 show the relationship between the call's gamma, the underlying asset price, the time to maturity and the option's volatility. The gamma is highest for an at-the-money option and decreases either side when the option gets in- or out-of-the-money. The gamma of an at-the-money option rises significantly when the volatility decreases and the option approaches its maturity date When the gamma is positive, an increase in the underlying asset price yields a higher delta (Table 6.16). The adjustment of the position entails the sale of more units of the underlying asset. When the asset price falls, the delta decreases and the adjustment of the option position requires the purchase of more units of the underlying asset. Since the adjustment is made in the same direction as the changes in the market direction, the monitoring of an option position with a positive gamma is easily done When the gamma is negative, an increase in the underlying asset price reduces the delta. The adjustment of a delta-neutral position implies the purchase of more units of the underlying asset. When the asset price decreases, the delta rises. The adjustment of the option position requires the sale of more units of the underlying asset. Hence, the adjustment of the position implies a rebalancing against .the market direction which produces some losses. In general, the option gamma is a decreasing function of the time to maturity (Table 6.17). The longer the time to maturity, the weaker the gamma and vice versa. When the option approaches its maturity date, the gamma varies significantly.
POSITIONS
Parameters K = 100 ° br
o.12-
T
0.10-
=
o.S
0.06E O
0.04550 0.040.30
0.40 35
0.025 a: Volatility
_
o.oo
80 84 88 92 96 100
4
112 116120
0.05
S: Underlying asset price
FIGURE 6.7
The Gamma
and Volatility
TABLE 6.16
Adjustment
of a Hedged
Position
and
the Gamma
Adjustmento¶the Hedged Position and the Delto
Parameters K 100 r 8% b = 10%
OF OPTION
AND MANAGEMENT
MONITORING
Ef¶ect on the Position
Position
Gammo
Long options
Positive
Market-up: sell more S Market down: buy more S
Easy adjustment,
Short options
Negative
Market up: buy more 5 Market down: sell more S
Difficult adjustment,
=
0.050¯
=
0.045-
a=25%
0.040¯ 0.035-
yields profits
yields losses
0.0300.025-
0.020-
1.0 0.9 0.8
0.0150.010
0.60.7
-
0.005¯ 0.00080 84 88 92 0.2 96 100 104 108 112 116 1200.1 S: LJnderlying asset price
FIGURE 6.6
The Gamma
and
Time to Maturity
0.5 0.4 0.3
TABLE 6. I 7
T: Time to maturity
Gamma
The Variations
in Gamma
and the Time
to Maturity
Longer Maturity
Short Moturity
Near Moturity
Low
High
High for at-the-money low for out-of-the-money
Effecton the option position
Low
Easy adjustment position
of an option
options; very options
Delta very sensitive to the asset price; gamma used with care
142
OPTIONS,
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
The variations in the gamma for in-, at- and out-of-the-money options are explained in Table 6.18. The management of an option position with a positive gamma is simple. When the market rises, the investor becomes long and must sell some quantity of the underlying his delta-neutral position. When the underlying asset decreases, the asset to re-establish investor becomes short and must buy more units of the underlying asset to re-establish his delta-neutral position. This yields a profit The management of an option position with a negative gamma is more difficult when the underlying asset's volatility is high. When the market rises, the investor becomes short and must buy some quantity of the underlying asset to re-establish his delta-neutral position. This produces a loss. When the underlying asset decreases, the investor becomes long and must sell more units of the underlying asset to re-establish his delta-neutral position. This yields a loss.
Examples If E 30 an increase in the asset price by $1 yields an increase of the delta and produces a gain of $30. If f -30 an increase in the asset price by $1 yields a decrease in the delta and produces a loss of $30 145, A When the underlying asset price S 32, an increase in 97 and f 146) gives a new delta: A' 129. However, a A + T 97 + 32 S by $1 (S decrease in S by $1 gives a new delta: A' A - T 65. The delta-neutral strategy implies the sale of 65 units of the underlying asset. When S 135 and T -26, an increase in S by $1 gives a new 360, A 135 - 26 109. A decrease in S by $1 gives a new delta: A + F delta: A' 161. The delta-neutral strategy implies the sale of A' A- F 135 + 26 161 units of the underlying asset. It is possible to have a negative delta and a negative gamma. For example, when S and T 378, A -8, an increase in Sby $l gives a new delta: 167 - 8 -175. The delta-neutral strategy implies the purA' A+ T chase of 175 units of the underlying asset. A decrease in S by $1 yields a new A delta: A' F -167 + 8 -159. The delta-neutral strategy implies the purchase of 159 units of the underlying asset. =
=
=
=
=
=
In general, one should be careful when adopting a positive gamma strategy since the option position loses from its theta when the market is not volatile. In this context, it is volatile, a position with a better to have a negative gamma. However, when the market is underlying the asset positive gamma allows profits, since the adjustment requires buying the market rises. when selling it when the market falls and The gamma of an option position with several assets is Foss
For delta-neutral strategies, change rapidly and a negative
DA, =
ni
-
BA2
+ n2 -
BA;
.+
+
.
n,
.
and Managing
Monitoring
the Theta
The theta is given by the option's partial derivative with respect to the remaining time to maturity. Figures 6.8 and 6.9 show the relationships between the call and put prices and the time to maturity. As the maturity date approaches, the option loses value. An option is expressed as a function of the number of points lost a wasting asset. The theta is often each day. A theta of 0.4 means that the option loses $0.4 in value when the maturity date is reduced by one day. In general, the gamma and the theta are of opposite signs. A high positive gamma is associated with a high negative theta and vice versa. By analogy with the gamma, as a high gamma is an indicator of a high risk associated
=
Parameters
35
=
K br
-
=
=
-
-
conditions
-
-167
=
=
(20)
-
a positive gamma allows profits when market gamma produces losses in the same context.
=
=
=
BA =
=
=
=
143
POSITIONS
=
=
=
=
=
=
=
=
=
=
OF OPTION
AND MANAGEMENT
MONITORING
=
25
¯
20
-
-
1510
°/
25%
_
=
100
_1.0
0.9 0.8
-
0.7
TABLE 6.18
Effect of the Gamma Out-of-theMoney Options
Gamma
Near zero
Effect on the option position
Weak
on an Option
Position
5 In-the-Money Options
At-the-Money Options High for shorter longer maturity
maturity; stable
Gamma is fundamental the option position
for
to managing
Near zero for near maturity
0
0.6 0.5 T: Time to ma 0.4 0.3
-
-
80 84 88 92 96 100 104108
0.2
0.1 112 116 120
S: Underlying asset price
Weak
FIGURE 6.8
The Call Price and the Time
to Maturity
:Ry
144
OPTIONS,
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
AND MANAGEMENT
MONITORING
DERIVATIVES
OF OPTION
POSITIONS
145
-1500
When f for an option position, theta may be 10 000, i.e. a gain of $10000 each day. However, the position implies a loss on the underlying asset since the adjustments are made against the market direction when the gamma is negative. =
Parameters 0 20 18
-
b
_
=
10%
-
a=25% 16
14 12 10
6 4 2 0
-
-
The theta of an option position with several assets is
-
-
Oposition
0.80.9
-
,
0 5 04
-
+ n3
.
(21)
ny
.
T Time to maturity
y Parameters
100 104 112
1Ñ6 120
0.1
S: Underlying asset price
6.9
n2
20 3
80
FIGURE
ni
O7 06
-
-
.+
=
25
The Put Price and the Time to Maturity
20
B
with the underlying asset price, a high theta is an indicator of a high exposure to the passage of time. An at-the-money option with a short maturity loses value much more than a corresponding option on a longer term. The theta of an at-the-money option is often higher than that of an equivalent in-the-money or out-of-the-money option having the same maturity date. Figure 6.10 shows the relationship between the theta, the asset price and the time to maturityThe option buyer loses the theta value and the option writer the theta value (Table 6.19).
15
K r b
-
a
10% 25%
-
19.0
o.e
'
0.60.7
-
o.5
'gains'
g
=
=
100
8%
-
10
5
=
=
0.4 0.3 0.2
_
so e4
88 92 96 100104108112 116120
T: Time to maturity
0.1
S: Underlying asset price
Examples
FIGURE 6.10
A theta of $1000 means that the option buyer pays $1000 each day for the holding of an option position. This amount profits the option writer. The theta remains until the last day of trading. When a position shows a positive gamma, its theta is negative. In general a high gamma induces a high theta and vice
TABLE 6.19
The Theta
The Option
versa.
For example, when C 1500 theta may be -$10 000, i.e. a loss of $10 000 each day for the option position. This loss is compensated by the profits on the positive gamma since the adjustments of the position imply sellmg (buymg) more units of the underlymg . asset when the market rises (falls). =
Value and the Theta
--
Loss in time value Effecton an option position
Longer Moturity
Shorter Moturity
Near Moturity
Low
High
Very high
Needs passive monitoring
Profit for the seller, loss for the buyer
Profit for the seller, loss for the buyer
146
OPTIONS,
Monitoring
and Managing
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC DERIVATIVES
,
,...n...a
'T OF OPTION
emmam
147
POSITIONS
the Vega
Parameters
The vega is given by the option's derivative with respect to the volatility parameter. It shows the induced variation in the option price when the volatility varies by 1%. The vega is always positive for call and put options since the option price is an increasing function of the volatility parameter (Figures 6.11 and 6.12). A vega of 0.6 means that an increase in the volatility by 1% increases the option price by 0.6. For a fixed time to maturity, the vega of an at-the-money option is higher than that of an in-theoption. money or out-of-the-money Figure 6.13 shows a decrease in the vega when maturity is shortened, i.e. a longer-term option is more sensitive to the volatility parameter than an otherwise identical shorterterm option. Since all the option pricing parameters are observable, except the volatility, buying (selling)options is equivalent to buying (selling)the volatility. When monitoring an option position, a trade-off must be realized between the gamma and the vega. Buying options and hence having a positive gamma is easy to manage. However, when the implied volatility falls, the investor must adopt one of the following two strategies (seeTable 6,20):
K = 100
'
°/
35
-
T 25
2
Ë o
o.5
=
-
20 15
-
¯
19.0
0.8
10
-
5
-
601
O
O 0.5 0,4 a: Volatility 3
/
.
80 84 88 92
T -'
im
112 116
120
S: Underlying asset price •
He can preserve a positive gamma if he thinks that the loss due to a decrease in will be compensated by adjusting the gamma in the market direction. He can sell the volatility (options)and re-establish a position with a negative gamma. volatility
•
The Put's Price
ggi ggligggt
and
the Volatility
Parameters Param1e0ters
45-
r=B% b 10% T 0.5 =
40
35 30
b=10% 35
-
a
30
-
15
1.0
-
0.9 0.8 0.7
1.0
15
0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0,5 0.4 a: Volatilitý 0.3
10
0
-
_
80 84 88 92 96 100 104108
1200.10.2
10
5
¯
0.6 0.5
-
-0.4
0
-
80 84 88 92 96 100 104108
112
S: Underlying
S: Underf ying asset price
FIGURE
25%
-
25 -
-
20
5
=
=
6.1 I
The Call's Price and the Volatility
FIGURE 6.13
The Vega
0.3 0.2 112 116
asset price
1200.1
T: Tirne to maturity
MS
OPTIONS,
TABLE 6.20
Effect of the Volatility Volatility
Options
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
on a Portfolio
DERIVATIVES
MONITORING
AND MANAGEMENT
The vega of an option position
of Options
Ef¶ect
Op
Vega Long
Long
Profit
Short
Short
Loss
(loss)when the (profit)when the
volatility rises volatility
(falls) rises (falls) 6.3
In this case, the losses due to the adjustments compensate for the decrease in volatility.
of the delta must be sufficient to
Tables 6.21 and 6.22 show the effects of the vega on the option position with respect to time to maturity and option type. The impact of the vega on an at-the-money option is
highest.
Example When the vega is $500, this means that a rise in the volatility by 1% produces a profit of $500. However, when the volatility decreases by 1%, this implies a loss of $500 When the vega is $500, an increase in the volatility by 1% implies a loss of $500 and a decrease by 1% yields a profit of $500.
TABLE 6.2 I
Effect of the Vega with
Respect
e,
to Time to Maturity
Longer Maturity
Shorter Maturity
Near Maturity
Vega
High
Low
The implicit volatility is affected by factors other than time
Effect on the position
Very sensitive to volatihty
Little sensitivity to volatility
The implicit volatility is affected by factors other than time
=
n,
OF OPTION
with several assets
Ov;
+ n2
-
149
POSITIONS
is
+ n3
Ov3 -
+
.
.
OF VOLATILITY
THE CHARACTERISTICS
,
+ ny
Üvj
-
(22)
SPREAD
theta and As a simple standard option, a spread is also characterized by its delta, gamma, positions option as a vega. These sensitivity parameters allow the investor to manage his of strategies based consequence of the changes in market conditions. The implementation the use of delta-neutral strategies to be able to predict on volatility spreads often implies the variations in the market conditions. When the changes in the underlying asset value give more value to the spread, the negative when the variations gamma is positive. On the other side, the spread's gamma is value. spread underlying the price reduce the in asset Since the effects of the changes in the underlying asset price and the time to maturity negative theta operate in opposite directions, a spread with a positive gamma exhibits a various sensitivity effect of the the summarizes on parameters Table and vice versa. 6.23 spread strategies. The investor can implement delta-neutral strategies when he has no prior anticipations resort to bullish and bearish spreads as to where the market is going. However, he can abilities. market timing This leads him to be long or short his about confident when he is the underlying asset. when When the options used are over-valued (accordingto the investor), for instance volatility normal level), and the its volatility historical high is the implied (withrespect to the investor can sell some puts if the market rises and some calls if the market falls. when When the options are under-valued (againaccording to the investor), for instance normal level), volatility and its the implied volatility is low (withrespect to the historical the investor can be long calls and puts when the market falls.
TABLE 6.23
Characteristics
of Volatility
Spreads
¯
Nature of the Spread
Short a call spread Short a put spread TABLE 6.22
Vega
Option position
Effect of the Vega on the Option
Price
Out-of-the-Money Options
At-the-Money Options
to-the-Money Options
Depends on the time to maturity
For a given maturity, the vega is higher
to maturity
Low
High
Low
Depends on the time
Long a straddle Longa strangle Short a butterfly Long a call (ratio)spread Long a put (ratio)spread Short a straddle Short a strangle Long a butterfly
Position in Delta
Position in
0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
+
Gamma +
Position in Theto -
-
Position in Vego
OPTIONS,
I50
FUTURES
AND EKOTIC
DERIVATIVES
SUMMARY
MONITORING
• •
This chapter presents the main Greek-letter risk measures, i.e. the delta, gamma, theta and vega in the context of the European analytical models developed in the previous chapter. These risk measures are simulated for different parameters which enter the option formulas. Then the magnitude of these risk measures is evaluated in connection with the management and the monitoring of an option position. The knowledge of the changes in these risk parameters is necessary for the manage' ment of an option position and for the determination of the profits and losses associated with the position. To put it differently, the pricing of a European call option can be viewed inputs (the underlying asset and the treasury bill) and a production as requiring technology (the hedge portfolio and the Greek-letter risk measures). In a B-S world, by tracking continuously the hedge ratio (beingdelta-neutral), the investor makes sure that the option. In the duplicating portfolio does mimic the call option, namely does the course of doing so, the investor controls his production costs and protects his mark-up on the option. However, these risk measures depend on the theoretical model used for the valuation and the management of the option position. There is what one could call a technological risk. This position must be adjusted nearly continuously in response to the changes in
AND MANAGEMENT
6.A.1
Call Sensitivity
Parameters
N(di)
F
• • • • • • • • • •
•
•
•
•
•
son(d,)
oc
BT
Rhoc
Put Sensitivity
n(di)
BS ¯ So
Da
FOR DISCUSSION
What is an option delta? What is the charm? What is the gamma? What does spread mean? What does color mean? What does theta mean? What does vega mean? What does Rho mean? What does elasticity mean? Why is the knowledge of Greek-letter risk measures important? How does the delta change in response to the changes in the option valuation parameters? How does the gamma change in response to the changes in the option valuation parameters? How does the theta change in response to the changes in the option valuation parameters? How does the vega change in response to the changes in the option valuation parameters? asset in response to changes in the underlying How is a hedged portfolio adjusted price? How is a hedged portfolio adjusted in response to changes in the volatility parameter?
tM
B-S Model
ve -
•
RISK MEASURES
APPENDIX 6.A: GREEK-LETTER ANALYTICAL MODELS
conditions.
POINTS
IN
POSITIONS
How is a hedged portfolio adjusted in response to changes in the time to maturity? What are the main characteristics of volatility spreads?
'produce'
market
OF OPTION
=
rKe-rN(dy)
(23)
2R -
=
SÖn(di) K(t*
"'
- t)e
N(d2)
Parameters
A
f
Ae - I
=
n(di)
=
=
BS
So
Son(d ) _
UT
_
Rho
=
=
Or
-
2
rKe¯"N(,di)
SRn(d ) -K(t*
- t)e
"
N(d2)
-
ear
(24)
152
6.A.2
OPTIONS,
Black's
Call Sensitivity
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
Model
e
N(d,)
BA, BS
c¯
Oc
A "
=
8 BS
n(di)
rN(-di)+rKe¯"N(-d2)+
_ Se
'on(di)
+ rSe¯"N(d,)
2
-
rKe¯"N(d2)
v
on(A
(28)
=
Br
TKe
N(-di)
and Barone-Adesiend
Merton's
Whaley's
Model
'
Call Sensitivity
BA
Parameters
n(di)
Ac
o n(di)
Se
N(-di)
e'
N(d
) n(di)
rKe "N(-di)
Op
8
Model
Ke--r Da -
Rhoe
s
Oc - -
N(da) + rKe-,rN(d2) +
(b - r)Se'
BT
v
and Kohlhagen's
=
(26) - rSe
n(di)
S
=
'
n(da)
Ke
-8¤
Rho'
n(di)
l
Op
Ke
(25)
6.A.4
A - Ae - e
Call Sensitivity
e-
Sa
Op
Agt gensitivityParameters
Garman
) + 1] r
*
e
Oc
6.A.3
r[N(-d
-e
Sonn(ds)
Oc - -BT -
=
=
y
Se ve - Ba -
vp
153
OSITIONS
put Sensitivity Parameters
Parameters Ae
OF OPTIOM
AND MANAGEMENT
MONITORING
Ke-cran(d2)
2R
(29)
n(d2)
N(di)
- - TSe
Parameters Put SensitMty he
, =
E
e
Parameters
r N(di)
A
BAe
e
OS
Sa
n(di)
Oc Be=-=-r*Se
rN(di)+rKe¯"N(d2)+
BT
=
-et
[N(-d e F* if F é µ*
(46)
with
7.2.2
American
Futures
From the analysis in BAW are no carrying costs is
C(F, T)
F*
--{l
--
A,
-e
=
"N[-d
(F*)]}
(47)
Options
(1987),the
American
c(F, T)+A2(F F - K
futures call option formula F
if F F*
)
when
there
M
2r/o2
=
and k
=
(1 -
e
")
(49)
carrying costs, the formula for the American put is 37) P(F,
T)
p(F, K-F
=
T) + Ai(F
F*)*
if
F > F ifFGF
(50)
with F* A2=-[1-e 42
*N[d(F*)]] 1+
42
l+4M
=
2
k
(38) (39)
--{1
A, qi
=
=
([-(N
y*
-e" - 1) -
'orN[-d,(F*)]} (N - 1)2 + 4M/k]
(51) (52)
Agg
OPTIONS,
M
2r
=
«2,
N
=
The critical futures price corresponding the following equation: K - F
=
p(F
2b/o2
and k
AND EXOTIC
(1 -
=
DERIVATIVES
e-,r)
(53)
to an optimal early exercise is calculated
F* T) - -
,
FUTURES
{l
-
e" "'N[-di(F*)]}
usin 8
(54)
When the futures price is above the critical price, the American futures option price is j given by the sum of the European price and the early exercise premium Ai(F F*)q,. 4 When the futures price is above the critical futures price, the American futures option value is equal to its intrinsic value, (K - F).
Examples
=
=
=
N(-di)
N(-d2)
p
P
90
0.8522 0.5 i99 0. I 826 0.0364
0.8375 0.480 I 0. I57 I 0.0289
10.2300 3.9087 0.9607 0.l7l4
10.6500 4.0 I99 0.9807 0.1795
I00 I l0 120
OPTIONS:
DIVIDENDS
AND EARLY EXERCISE
commitments
Chateau
fo no+
nio
=
is a random
(55)
where è financing is a forward mark-up. For example, a forward rate of9% is composed of an uncertain cost of funds of 7% and a forward mark-up of 2%. Capping the commitment rate and then allowing for early exercise represents the question of valuing American capped variable rate commitments. This cap is introduced by a constant, k > 1, say for example 1.16, in the form cost and E
F*
kfa
=
f,
_
86.530 86.074 86.732 86.664
169
represent an optimal risk-sharing scheme in competitive extends this valuation literature in two ways, first by intro(1990) ducing a cap on the maximum rate charged by a bank on a variable rate commitment, and second by allowing the commitment holder to exercise the cap prematurely. period during which an intermediary writes an American Let [0, T] be the commitment commitment option for a 100 dollars, one year credit. The forward variable rate at the period's beginning is given by
(1987),find that
equilibrium.
k[ëo + mo]
=
This yields a ceiling rate, which applies if the forward We define the differential rate as
=
5
TO AMERICAN
o
and American TABLE 7.5 European Futures 0.25, b 0, 0.08, T 100, r Put Prices: K 0.2 « =
EXTENSION
=
kno - 2, +
(56)
variable
(k -
rate moves above this rate.
1)Ro
(57)
Equation (57) renects the difference between the forward variable rate at date t and the initial capped rate. This rate differential implies the following debt instrument: -
S,
Lexp
=
2, +
[(kno-
(k -
1)mo)(ti
-
t)]
(58)
where
TABLE 7.6 European and American Futures 0.08, T 0.25, b 0 Call Prices: K 100, r 0.2 « =
=
=
value of the borrower's indebtedness if he borrows L, L is the maximum amount to be borrowed, ti - t is the duration of the loan.
S, is the economic
=
=
5
I I10 120
N(di)
N(da)
0
0
0.8428 0.9710
0.8173 0.9635
C
c 360 10.7600 19.7750
0 10.8380 20.0250
F*
Using the same approach as in BAW (1987), Chateau formula for the pricing of the American commitment put:
0 122.02\ 122.021
P(S, t)
Ai
The difference between European and American call option prices corresponds early exercise premium attached to American options.
to the
-(N
Capped
Variable
Loan Commitments
An isomorphic correspondence between loan commitments and put options on stocks has been shown by Ho and Saunders (1983). Some authors, including Thakor and Udell
(59)
SGS
N[-di(S*)]}
- 1) -
(60)
(N - 1)2 + 4k
(6 1)
2 N
7.2.3
if
{l -
=
the following
S>S*
MS0 L- S
=
(1990)presents
=
2r a2, k
di(S*) where r and a correspond
respectively
=
ln (S* =
2r
(o'(l -
L) + (r +
e
"))
(62)
(a2)t
to interest rate and the volatility
(63) of in (S)
L is the
OPTIONS,
170
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
EXTENSION
DERIVATlYES
strike price and S* is the indebtedness value critical boundary below which the American put should be exercised. The value of S* is given by solving the following system:
S* L - S
=
p(S
,
t, L) - -
{l
-
N[-di(S*)]}
"
7.3.2
(64)
The difference between the American put price and the European put price (P p) corresponds to the value of the early exercise premium. The simulations of this model and the effect of the changes in its parameters on option values are reported in Tables 7.8-7.11 in Appendix 7.A.
TO AMERICAN
Compound
DIVIDENDS
OPTIONS:
Option
AND EARLY EXERCISE
171
Approach
A compound option is an option whose underlying asset is an option. Since an option may be a call or a put, we may fmd four types of compound options: a call on a call, a call on a put, a put on a put, and a put on a call.
~
7.3 7.3.1
Geske's Approach
The theory of options on option, or compound options, was initiated and applied by Black and Scholes (1973),Cox and Ross (1976), Geske (1977),Roll (1977)and Myers (1987)
VALUATION OF AMERICAN OPTIONS WST&i DISCRETE CASH DISTRIBUTIONS Early Exercise
of American
Call on a Call
for a
Options
Most of the traded stock and index options around the world may be exercised before their expiration dates and are therefore of the American type. Early exercise of these options is often induced by the payment of dividends on the underlying asset. For stock options, it may be optimal to exercise a call on the last cum-dividend day to receive the dividend. In this case, the adapted versions of the B-S model proposed by Roll (1977) Geske (1979a, 1979b) and Whaley (1981)can be used. For an index option, when the dividends are distributed fairly evenly over time, B-S type models may be used. However, when the dividends tend to be clustered, early exercise may be triggered at many points in time and B-S type models cannot be applied Another potential dividend-induced reason for early exercise is asset carrying costs. When these costs are different from the riskless interest rate, early exercise is also possible. Hence, for many reasons, the B-S model does not price adequately American commodity and futures options since, by definition, the model is to European paying stocks. options on non-dividend Whaley (1981, 1982, 1986) and Whaley and Harvey (1992)showed that ad hoc valuation procedures sometimes produce large pricing errors because of the discrete and seasonal pattern of dividends on some indexes like the S&P 100 index portfolio. Such ad hoc valuation procedures for index options include European-style formulas approximation methods where it is assumed that the index pays and American-style dividends at a constant proportional rate as those presented in the previous section. The most commonly used methods are the B-S model adjusted for dividends because of its ease of computation and the American-style option pricing approximations with a constant proportional dividend yield. These include the quadratic approximation of BAW binomial method under the assumption and the Cox, Ross and Rubinstein
among others. To understand the nature of compound options, consider a firm whose capital structure is composed of stocks, S, and bonds, B. Assume that bonds are discount bonds, paying M dollars in T years. Assume also that the firm plans to liquidate at that date, paying off the bonds and any remaining value to stockholders as a liquidating dividend. In this setting, bondholders have given the stockholders an option to buy back the assets at date T. In fact, if at that date the firm's value, V is less than M, bondholders get the assets V and stockholders receive nothing. If V is greater than M, bondholders get M and stockholders receive ( V - M). The pay-off to stockholders is then max (0, V - M). Hence, a call on the firm's stock is an option on an option, or a compound option Following Geske (1979a),the compound option is written as
'
C(V, t)
(1987)
(1979)
proportional dividend yield rate. The appropriate approach for the valuation of American options when there are discrete dividends is based on the compound option approach. Several models are proposed in this option approach to the pricing of context. Given the contribution of the compound American options, this approach is now presented in detail.
f(S, t)
=
f(g(V,
t), t)
(65)
Hence, changes are expressed as a function of the changes in the firm's value and time. The dynamics of the returns on Vand C are described by the following equations: in the call's value
dV/V=a,dt+o,dW, d C/C
'reserved'
of a constant
=
=
(66)
ac dt + ac dW
(67)
'
respectively
where as, as, ao and ¤c correspond to instantaneous expected rates of return on the firm (on the call) and instantaneous volatility of return on the firm (onthe call). Using Itö's lemma gives the following dynamics for the call option:
dC
=
Ot,
dt+
\BV}
dV -E
V2a dt
2\8V2,
(68)
Followmg Merton (1973a), a three-security riskiess hedge portfolio, H, containing the firm, the call and a riskless asset can be created for zero net investment. If dH is the mstantaneous dollar return to the hedge portfobo, then dH
=
nt
(d V/
V) + na(d C/C) + vns di
(69)
where the n, terms correspond to portfolio weights. Substituting for the stochastic return on the firm and the call, choosing n so that the Wiener term corresponding to V is zero implies that dH 0. Simplifying yields the familiar partial differential equation =
172
OPTIONS,
BC Ot
Sincethe eaWe value
rC - rV
=
AND EXOTIC
FUTURES
ßC
1
82C
DV
2
BV2
V2a 2 *
DERIYATIVEs
nr "
C,.
=
(0, S,. - K)
max
OPTIONS:
TO AMERICAN
using
The value Veris calculated A
t*, is either zero or the intrinsic value
at expiration,
EXTENSION
S,-K=VN(h2+o,f)-Me"N(h2)-K=0
(71)
dynamics are given by
173
the following equality:
with
this boundary poses a problem from the perspective of the stock as an option on the value of the firm. In fact, the variable determining the option value in equation (70)is not S but V However, since the stock is an option on V it follows a related diffusion and again its
AND EARLY EXERC1SE
DIVIDENDS
I
=
r,
=
(78)
T - /* t* - t
r2
0 or T oo, the stockholder's option to repurchase the firm from Note that when M and the formula reduces to that oñB-S applied to a call disappears bondholders the wntten on the equity of an all-equity-financed firm. =
=
.
BS -8t
rS - rV
=
BS
1
82S
BV
2
ßV2
The solution to this equation subject to the condition equation:
S
=
VN(h2 + a
)
S,
V2
'
'
Generalization max [0, Vr - M] is the B-S
=
"
Me
-
2 "
N(h2)
(73)
(1993),the
Following Rubinstein
Option
Approach are used:
following notations
the value of the compound option, the time t value of the underlying option, Ke the strike price of the compound option, K the strike price of the underlying option, option, t the time-to-maturity of the compound t* the time-to-maturity of the underlying option with t* > i, R one plus the riskless interest rate, d one plus the payout rate, value 1 (-1) when the underlying option is a call (put) r¡ a binary variable taking the variable taking the value 1 (-1) for a call on a call and a call on a put (a binary a ¢ put on a call and a put on a put).
C, c
with
of the Compound
=
=
=
h2
=
ln ( V M)
=
o )(T - t)
(r
(74)
=
=
At the call's expiration date, exercise will depend on the relationship between S and K. t*, the firm's value, Ver, that makes the holder of an option on the stock When t indifferent between exercising or not is the solution of the integral equation S* - K 0 with r T - t*, where S * is given by equation (73).For values of the firm less than V., the call on the stock remains unexercised. Given equations (70) and (72) and their boundary conditions, the compound option value given by Geske (1979a)is =
=
=
=
=
=
=
C, C
=
VN hi + a
h2 + o,¾,
,
(75) Me
"2
N
h
,
- Ke¯"'
h2,
=
as yK|t*])
[0, ¢PV,(max (0, QSc -
max
C,
R 'E[max
=
{0,¢c(S,,
(79)
- ¢Ke]
where PV,(.) is the present value after time t of (.). The current value of the compound option is given by its expected appropriate probability measure:
N(hi)
value under the
t) - ¢Ke }]
(80)
expectation operator and c(S,, t) is the B-S call formula. where E is the mathematical This can be written in an integral form as
with
hi and
option can be written
The pay-off of a compound
ln(V
V
=
)+(r-jo
)ri
(76)
C,
=
R
'
max{0,
t) -¢Ke}f(u)du
¢c(Se",
(81)
with
. In(V/M)
h2
=
(r-jo
)r2
u
=
In(S,/S)
(82) "'72
where
N(A, B, p) stands for the bivariate cumulative
normal
distribution.
f(v)
=
o
vdii
e
(83)
174
OPTIONS,
v
(u
=
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
µt)/o
-
µ=ln(R/d)
a
The above integral can be valued using a decomposition corresponding off variables, S, K and Kc, denoted respectively by I(l), I(2) and /(3): I(l)=¢SR'
I(2)
¢KR
N(z,
=
¢qKR
TheValuationFormula
I(3)
=
'
¢KeR
¢ya
f(u)du
=
gy KR
-
175
Options with Dividends
Consider the following portfohos: purchase of a European call with strike price K and maturity date T European call with strike price See and maturity date t-e (b)A purchase ofa where 2 > 0, S, is the ex-dividend stock price above which the option will be 0), e (e exercised early and (c) A sale of a European call on the call given in (a) with strike price Se, + D - K maturity date (t E).
(a) A (86)
-¢>1
-
are equivalent to that of an American call, the absence of costless arbitrage implies that the American call's value is equal to that of these portfolios. Hence the application of the B-S (1973)formula for the first two options, (a) and (b), and the Geske (1979a,1979b) formula for the third option, (c), gives the American call option pricing formula. The formula was derived by Whaley (1981) for the valuation of American call options
Since the pay-offs of these portfolios
yoÑ, ¢p)
'N(¢>¡\
AND EARLY EXERCISE
DIVIDENDS
OPTIONS:
of American
Valuation
(85)
(87) N(¢yx -
TO AMERICAN
7.3.3
)f(u)du
a
EXTENSION
(84)
to du three pay-
¢ySd'"N(¢yx,yy,¢p)
e"N(z,)f(u)du=
=
DERIVATIVES
E)
(88)
where
on stocks with known dividends: 0
in
(89)
=
call
American
ce
In
=
SN(ai, bi,
b - qKR
N(z
)
Ke
0
di
z
=
Se d KR
by ¢qSd -
¢KeR
N(¢qx, 'N(¢Qx
gy, ¢p) - ¢qKR -
¢ya0)
+
In(S/Se,) =
(r
)-
+ (a2)T
(r+)a2)t
(96)
N(d2)
(Se, + D) e
N(a2, b2,
In(S (Sc, + D)) =
(Sc, + D - K)e
and
a2
and
b2
(r + la2N
and
(97)
=
N(b2)
60
a
(99)
bi - o
(100)
a,
=
"
d2
=
-
di
(101)
a
where N(a, b, p) stands for the bivariate cumulative normal density function. Using the N(a) - N(a, b, p) and gathering the terms in S and K property that N(a, -b, gives the following formula: =
c(S, T, K)
=
S[N(bi) + N(ai, bi, -
=
(95)
Cc
-p)
(93)
This equation gives the value of the critical underlying asset price, Se,(S,). It can be calculated using an iterative procedure. The current value of a compound option is given
Cap
Ke
-
(92)
with
ln
"
=
and Se, is the solution to the following equation: =
SN(di )
ln(S/K) a
-
=
)-
(91)
QSc,d
ca + cb ¯
=
N(aa)
SN(aa) - Ke
=
c, cb
"N(z)
call(c)
-
with
Sd
(90)
"
call(a) + call(b)
=
'N(¢yx -
¢yan,
r¡y -
Ke
"[e
"
N(b2) + N(a2, -b2, -
The critical stock price is found by applying following equation:
r¡oÑ, ¢p) (94)
C(So, T, K)
)] + De
=
a numerical
Se, + D - K
"
N(b2)
(102)
E
search procedure
for the
(103)
176
OPTIONS,
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
EXTENSION
DER1VATIVES
Simulations
•
• • • •
(1981) is used
to generate call option prices. Using the -
Strike price, K 100 Ex-dividend date, t 6 months Time to maturity, T 1 year Interest rate for 6 months, r 0.04 Volatility of the stock (6 months), « Dividend, D 5,
DIVIDENOS
AND EAREYRKERCISE
177
This chapter presents in detail the basic concepts and techniques underlying rational derivative asset pricing. This is done in the context of analytical European models along the lines of B-S, Black, Garman and Kohlhagen, and Merton-BAW.
=
This chapter extends the European analytical models presented in the previous chapters
to the valuation of American options. Our attention is focused on the question of dividend and the distinguishing feature of early exercise. First, the general problem of valuing American options is analyzed in three different asset, when there is a contexts: when there are no distributions to the underlying constant proportional distribution rate, and in the presence of discrete cash distribu-
=
=
=
=
0.2
=
Option prices are reported
in Table 7.7.
TABLE 7.7 Price
*
Option
Price
and
Critical
Stock
S
5 ex-dividend
Se,
C(S, T, K)
82 85 87 90 92 95 97 100
77.196 80.196 82.196 85.l96 87.196 90.196 92.196 95.196 97.196 100.196 102.196 105.196 107.196 i I0. I96 I12.196 I \5.196 I 17.196 ]20.196
123.5818 123.5818 I23.58\8 123.5818 123.5818 123.5818 123.5818 123.5818 123.5818 123.5818 !23.5818 123.58l8 123.5818 I23.58 I8 123.5818 123.5818 123.5818 l23.58l8
3.8050 4.8175 5.5758 6.8389 7.7645 9.2759 10.3636 I2.I I 13 13.3506 15.3155 16.6922 18.8509 20.3486 22.6759 24.2774 26.7476 28.4363 31.0255
102 105 107 I10 i 12 I I5 I17 \20 122 125
tions. The analysis covers American options on spot assets and American futures options. The main results reported in the literature regarding the pricing of American calls are reviewed. Some models are presented in detail and simulations are run. of a put-call parity theorem for American options implies a specific The non-existence options. The pricing of American puts is rather a difficult task, even in for put treatment the absence of distributions to the underlying asset. However, some interesting results are presented in the absence of dividends and when there is a continuous dividend rate. In the case of discrete distributions to the underlying asset, the formulas proposed in the literature are not so efficient as those proposed for American calls. In all cases, there is still no published analytical formula for the pricing of American calls or puts when there asset. Therefore, these problems can be are several discrete distributions to the underlying handled using binomial models or finite difference methods, which will be presented
later.
POINTS • • •
•
•
Applications
The different applications presented for European options in the previous chapters can be used with American optionsThe compound option approach also applies to the valuation of wildcard options, options. These applications will be studied in Part 3 of this some exotic and complex book
FOR DISCUSSION
What is meant by early exercise? What is an early exercise premium? Can an American call option be exercised
in the absence of distributions to the underlying asset? Can an American put option be exercised in the absence of distributions to the underlymg asset? When is an American call option exercised in the presence of continuous distributions to the underlying asset? When is an American call option exercised in the presence of discrete distributions to the underlying asset? distributions When is an American put option exercised in the presence of continuous asset? to the underlying When is an American put option exercised in the presence of discrete distributions to the underlying asset? Explain the incentives for early exercise of American call options on a spot asset. Explain the incentives for early exercise of American put options on a spot asset. Explain the incentives for early exercise of American call options on a futures contract. ·
•
7.3.4
OPTIONS:
SU MMARY
The formula obtained by Whaley following parameters:
•
TOlkWERICAN
•
•
• • •
178
•
OPTIONS,
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
EXTENSION
DERIVATIVES
7.A.2
Explain the incentives for early exercise of American put options on a futures contract. What is meant by a contact condition'? What is a capped variable loan commitment? What is a compound option? 'high
• • •
OPTIONS:
TO AMERICAN
in the Underlying
Effect of a Change Time to Maturity
TABLE 7.10 30% «
DIVIDENDS
and
European
AND EARLY EXERCISE
Asset
American
Price Volatility
Cap Prices:
L
=
179
and
100, r
10%,
=
=
t
APPENDIX 7.A: SIMULATION AMERICAN CAP OPTIONS Effect of Maturity
7.A.!
TABLE 7.8 «
=
a Change
in the Underlying
European
Asset
and American
FOR Price and
Cap Prices:
L
ga
=
100, r
10%,
=
20% t
=
0.25
t
B-S
Cap
S
Put
Put
100 99 98 97 96 95 94 90
2.826 3.227 3.668 4. I49 4.672 5.236 5.840 8.640
TABLE 7.9 20%
«
RESULTS
3,064 3,552 4.008 4.544 5. I 32
5.797 6.500 10.00
European
and
=
0.50
t
=
0.75
B-S Put
Cap Put
B-S Put
Cap Put
3.400 3.749
3.92) 4.330 4.793 5.288 5.820 6.402 7.040 10.083
3.65)
4.457 4.859 5.292 5.76 I 6.266 6.810 7.397 10.259
4.124 4.528 4.959 5.420 5.910 8.\73
American
Cap Prices:
3.963 4.295 4.650
5.027 5.426 5.850 7.790
L
=
100, r
=
\
t=3
5
B-5 Put
Cap Put
B-S Put
100 99 98 97 96 95 94 90
3.573 4.036 4.336 4.654 4.990 5.346 5.722 7.432
4.658 5.228 5.649 6.10\ 6.587 7.\09 7.67! 10.374
3.156 3.309 3.469 3.636 3.8\0 3.993 4.183 5.033
B-S
Cap
Put
Put
2.694 2.8 i I 2.934 3.062 3.195 3.334 3.479 4.122
6.2\8 6.568 6.942 7.34| 7.766 8.220 8.707 11.018
6.052 6.38 I 6.762 7.\60 7.600 8.063 8.557 10.916
t
" S Put
Cap Put
B-5 Put
Cap Put
B-S Put
100 99 98 97 96 95 94 90
4.751 5.\69 5.6 13 6.084 6.582 7.108 7.066 10.l55
4.976 5.4\9 5.890 6.392 6.925 7.490 8.087 (0.8f 4
6.029 6.404 6.798 7.210 7.64\ 8.091 8.56 \ 10.643
6.560 6.975 7.4 I 3 7.873 8.356 8.863 9.390 I l.790
6.759 7.104 7.463 7.837 8.226 8.63\ 9.05 \
and American
European
t
×
100 99 98 97 96 95 94 90
t=4
Put
0.50
=
Cap Prices:
L
=
0.75
=
Cap Put 7.602
8.002 8.4 t 8 8.855 9.311 9.789 10.287
100, r
=
10%,
=
10%,
Cap
t
S
TABLE 7.1 I 30% a
=
t=
0.25
=
'
=
1
t
=
3
t
B-S Put
Cap Put
B-S Put
Cap Pt
7.2\7 7.538 7.870
8.391 8.678 9.I88 9,60! 10.039 10.497 i0.973 13.088
7.686 7.890
i \.358 \ \.697 |2.048 12.412 12.789 13.179 I3.584 l5.359
8.2lS 8.573 8.944 9.328 !!.003
8.099 8.3\5 8.536 8.763 8.996 9.994
B-S Put 7.240 7.409 7.582 7.760 7.942 8.129
8.320 9.136
=
4 Cap Put 12.0\2 12.34| |2.68i 13.033 \ 3.395 13.774 I4. I64 15.874
Generalization
to Stochastic Interest
CHAPTER
Rates
OUTLINE
This chapter is organized as follows: 1. Section 8.1 presents in detail Merton's option pricing model for the valuation of stock options under stochastic interest rates. 2. Section 8.2 develops the main results in Rabinovitch's model. It presents the model and some of its applications to the valuation of stock index options. 3. Section 8.3 reviews the main results in some of the more specific models for the pricing of bonds and bond options, in particular those of Vasicek (1977),Cox, Ingersoll and Ross (1985a)and Heath, Jarrow and Morton (1992).
INTRODUCTION Several authors have derived alternative formulas to the basic B-S model for the pricing of stock options, index options, bond options and foreign currency options, when interest rates are not constant. However, until 1989, all the proposed models, except Merton (1973a),used the assumption of a constant free rate prevailing during the option's life, i.e., the effects of the interest rate's variance and covariance with the underlying asset's return on the option's price were precluded from models other than that of Merton. This chapter presents some models for the analysis and valuation of derivative assets whose values depend on stochastic interest rates. Since Merton's model represents a convenient starting point for most of the complete option pricing models, it deserves a special treatment in this chapter. Using Merton's approach, Rabinovitch (1989)derived valuation formulas for options under the assumption that the interest rate follows a mean reverting process. However, Rabinovitch's formulas apply only to stock and index options. They do not apply for the pricing of bond options since there is a deficiency in his model. We present the necessary of bonds and contingent corrections and propose other specific models for the valuation claims whose values depend directly on the dynamics of interest rates.
l82
OPTIONS,
8.1
DERIVATION
FUTURES
OF MERTON'S
A940 EXOTICOERIVATIVES
MODEL
8.1.1
(dS)2
(dS)(dP)
The Model
Let C(S, P, r, K) be the option price function depending on the stock price S, the bond price P, the exercise price K and the time-to-maturity r The stock price dynamics are represented by the following stochastic differential equation:
(1)
T)
(4) (5)
JöSP(d
W)(dq)
öpaSPdt
=
coefficient between the returns
correlation
(2), equation (3) is rewritten
82C BS2
-
BC BS
OC -OP
82C
2S2dt+2
BSSP
(2)
orina
BC
+µP
82C
+)ö2,2
The bond price dynamics are given by the following equation: µ(r) dt + ö(r) dq(t,
aS
dC=
.
=
=
-OP2
on the stock and
as
BC
[µPdt+öPdql+
82 C
JöpSPdt+
dr
-87 -
ö2P2dt
(7)
OP2
BC
SP
+)o.2S2
Br BC
dt+aS
-OS
82C -BS2 BC
dW+õP
-BP
öpSP
82C -
OSSP
dq(t, r)
(8)
dC=ßCdt+yCdW+yCdq =
1
+ aS
dq(s, r)dq(t,
on any ofthe assets:
among the returns T)
dq(s, r)dW(t)
=
=
dq(t, r)dq(t,
for
0,
T)
( ß2C g) DC -
+ oöpSP + µP
=
s
__
pa dt
y
=
82 C
C
+ (ö2P
/ 82C\
OC
DC S
¢ t for s ¢ t
0,
(9)
with
1,
=
Assume that there is no serial correlation
(6)
simple form
where P(x) is the price of a discount bond with maturity r satisfying P(0) µ(r) is the instantaneous expected return, ö2(r) is the instantaneous variance with ö(0) 0, dq(t, r) is a standard Gauss-Wiener process.
are
which is equivalent to
the instantaneous expected return on the common stock, is the instantaneous variance of return, restricted to be a knowafettetienktime.
dP/P
+ öPdq)
OC [aSdt+oSdW]+ -DS 1
is
.
of (dS)2, (dP)2 and (dS)(dP)
(aSdt + «Sd W)2 __ 2S2dt
=
(aS dt + oSd W)(µPdt
2
·
a
=
dC=
where
02
183
(dP)2=(µPdt+öPdq)2=ö2P2dt
where p is the instantaneous on the bond. Substituting from (1) and
dS/S=adt+adW
RATES
calculus, the values
Using the properties of stochastic given by
Consider the basic case of a European option with no pay-outs to the underlying asset Assume that there are no transaction costs, that trading takes place continuously and that no restrictions are imposed on borrowing and short selling. Assume also that the borrowing rate is equal to the lending rate.
INTEREST
TO STOCHASTIC
GENERALIZATION
(10)
DC BS /
ö
(12)
where
p, may be less than 1 for r ¢ T. When the interest rate is constant over time, this means that ö 0, µ r and P(r) e Assuming that investors agree on the values of (ö, a), Itö's lemma gives the change in the option price over time: =
=
=
".
BC -OS
dC=
BC -
ßP
dP+
82C (dS)2+2 2 \DS2/ l
+
dS+
BC dr ßr
!
The expression for ß represents the instantaneous expected return on the option. Consider now a hedged portfolio with the underlying asset, the option and riskiess bonds where the portfolio weights wi, w2, w3 are chosen to eliminate market risk. The aggregate investment in the portfolio y is zero when investors are allowed to use proceeds from short sales and to borrow without restrictions to finance long positions, so that w,+w2+w,=0
-
82C -BSOP/
dSdP+
82C \8P2)
In this context,
(dP)2
(3)
the instantaneous
dollar return,
dy, may be
dy=wi(dS/S)+w2{ßdt+ydW+ydq}+{-wi-w2}(dP
written
as P)
(13)
184
PTIBMS;FUTURESAND
EKOTK
ERIVATIVES
GENERALIZATION
change in variables, x thecallpriceis
or
dy=wi{adt+adW}+w2{ßdt+ydW+r¡dq}+{-w,-w2}{µdt+ödq} Rearranging
(14)
y(x, T)
(15) h ' ¯- -
=
and whèté erfc is the derer complement
This linear system presents a solution if and only if
(ß -
µ)/(a
µ)
-
=
y a
erfc y)/ö
(ö -
=
(17)
y a
r¡ ö)
(1 -
afinitionof y and equation S(BC/BS)/C
(18)
(9)that (19)
(27)
2 e
y
dw
(28)
=
=
SN(di)
-
P(r)KN(d2)
(29)
with ln(S/K)
S(OC/OS) + P(BC/8P)
=
,
.
or
C
1- -
=
=
c
1 - [P(OC BP)/C)
=
,
function:
(h)
=
This implies from the
17 2
For more details about the solution method, see Merton (1973a). 1, equation (25)is identical to the B-S 0, a2 1 and K In the special case when r equation. The call price in the context of Merton's model can be written in a B-S form as
(17)holds, then =
(26)
.o
0
=
'
[o2+ö2-2paö]du
T=
(16)
(y - ð)
(25)
(h2)]
r
y=0
ö+ w
-w
erfc
¼T
ln(x)
ha - -
(ß-µ)=0
(a-µ)+w
w o+w
If
([xerfc (hi) -
=
(1973a)for
where
Now consider a strategy where the weights w, w are chosen so that the stochastic terms in (15)affecting dW and dq are always zero. The expected return on this strategy must be zero since it requires zero investment. Hence: w
185
RATES
S/KP(r) the solution presented in Merton
=
terms yields
{wi(a-µ)+w2(ß-µ)}dt+{wia+w2y}dW+{pw2-(w;+w2)ð}dq
dy=
INTEREST
TO STOCHASTIC
d'
(20)
=
- ln(P) + a,
(o2r
and
d2
=
di - a,f
(30)
The put price is given by
Using (17)gives
(ß Recalling the defmitions of 0
=
ß and
(o2S2
µS BS
µ)
y(a - µ) a
=
p
(21)
+ µP
ac
OP
p2
+
OSOP
ac
-SN(-di)
ln(S/K)-ln(P)+
ß2C
+ oöpSP
=
(3l)
+ P(r)KN(-d2)
with
y in (9),we have
82C -ßS2
ac
-
2
di
82C BP2
P(r)
- µC
87
Ur
and
=
(22)
,
1
d2
=
(32)
di - a
" =
(33)
e
'
[o2+ö2-2paöjdu
a;=-
(34)
0
Using
(9) and 0
rearranging
=
2
o2S
terms,
\8S2
(22)can be rewritten 2aöpSP
OSSP
as
+ö2P2
2C ßP2
BC Or
8.1.2
(23)
. This is a second-order linear partial differential equation of the parabolic type. The price of any option in Merton's economy must satisfy equation (23).In particular, the price of a European call must satisfy that equation and the following boundary conditions: .
Options
-
C(0, P, r, K)
C(S, 1, 0, K)
=
=
.
[0, S
- K]
(24)
on Bank Deposit
Rates and on Treasury
Bill Yields
.
Options on yields of short-term financial instruments are traded m the over-the-counter market. These fmancial products are in the form of bank deposits, certificates of deposit, Treasury bills, commercial paper, and so on. Treasury securities are backed by the faith and credit of the government. They are
0 max
Applications
se
regarded as having no credit risk. The interest rates on Treasury securities
are often
used
OPTIONS,
186
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
as a benchmark in national and international capital markets. There are two categories of government assets: discount and coupon assets. Treasury bills are securities issued with maturities of a year or less as discount securities, which do not make periodic payments. All the assets having a longer maturny are issued as coupon securitics. When the maturity is between two and ten years, the issued security is a note. When the maturity is greater than ten years, the Treasury security is a bond. An option on the yield of the most recently issued 13-week Treasury bill is traded on the Chicago Board Options Exchange. This option is based on an interest rate coraposite, i.e. 100 times the yield on the 13-week Treasury bill. Recall that a fundamental property of a bond is that its price moves in the opposite direction with respect to the required yield, i.e. when the required yield increases, the present value of the par value and the coupon decreases and vice versa. In general, the price yield relationship is convex. The yield on any investment corresponds to the interest rate which makes the present value of the cash flows equal to the cost of the investment. The yield is simply an implicit interest rate. In practice, two measures of yield are used: the current yield and the yield to maturity. The current yield gives the relationship between annual coupon interest and the market price. It is simply given by the ratio of the annual dollar coupon interest to the market price. The yield to maturity is the implicit interest rate that makes the present value of the future cash flows until the bond's maturity date equal to the bond's price. Merton's (1973a) model can be applied to the valuation of these options and is more appropriate than the B-S (1973)model since interest rates are stochastic. Short-Term
Options
on Long-Term
RABINOVITCH'S
187
RATES
where a is constant and o is a deterministic function of time. The dynamics of the interest rate r(t), defined as the yield to maturity on a bond paying one dollar in the next instant, are given by
dr
q(m - r) dt + vd W2
=
(36)
pdt for t with dWi(t)dW2(s) s, and zero otherwise, where p is the correlation coefficient between the two processes. The parameters m, q and v' are constants with the following meaning: =
=
riskless interest rate r, m is the long-run mean of the of speed of the adjustment is interest rates towards that mean, q q(m - r) is the instantaneous expected change in the short-term rate, v2 ÍS the instantaneous variance of interest rate.
The above process is an Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process, a Gaussian diffusion process, implying the long-run possibility of negative interest rates. As in Vasicek (1977), the bond price P can be written as a function of r(t) and time to maturity, r: P
(seeVasicek,
1977; Rabinovitch,
P[r(t),
=
r]
(37)
the following
(37)gives
Applying Itô's lemma to (36) and
solution for the bond price P
1989): P(r)
Ae"
=
(38)
with
Bonds ,
Transactions on short-term options on long-term bonds take place often in the OTC market. Some options are also traded on organized markets. These options may be European or American. A European short-term option on a long-term bond is traded on the Chicago Board Options Exchange. This option is similar to the option on yield of short-term financial instruments traded on the CBOE and is cash-settled. The interest rate corresponds to the average of the yields to maturity of the two most recently auctioned seven-year and two most recently auctioned ten-year treasury notes and also the two most recently auctioned 30-year treasury bonds. The average of the yield to maturity of these six instruments gives the interest rate on which the option is priced. This option can be priced using Merton's model which is more appropriate than the B-S model in the context of stochastic interest rates.
8.2
TO STOCHASTICtNTEREST
GENERALIZATION
,
B - B(r)
.
(1 -
=
exp [k(B
A
=
A(r)
k
=
m + v1
A
=
(y -
)
e
=
(v
q -
q
-
q)2
T)
-
(vB/2)2|q)
/2
r)/ö
correspond respectively where y and to the bond's expected return and variance and 2 l. (a constant) stands for the market price of risk. It is convenient to note that P(0) 0. A(0) 1 and B(0) From Itõ's lemma ö is a known function of r,
o2
=
=
=
ö(r)
=
vB(r)
(39)
According to equation (25),a call H, with a strike price K, a time to maturity r and an underlying asset S is given in the Merton (1973a)model by H
MODEL
T)
(40)
([xerfc(hi)-erfc(k2))
(41)
KP(r)y(x,
=
with 8.2.1
The Model for Equity Options
y(x, T) In this model,
=
the stock price dynamics are described by the famikar equation dS=aSdt+aSdW
(35)
x
=
KP(x)
(42)
I 8
OPTIONS,
ln
hi
=
-
h2
=
-
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
D
TIVES
T
(x)
(h)
RATES
189
-1, the unanticipated returns on the stock and the bond move in opposite When p These trends are directions and the variance effect on the option's price is maximum. shown in Table 8.1.
TABLE 8.1 0.06, A
h
2
1
=
INTEREST
(44)
function:
erfc
TO STOCHASTIC
=
(43)
ln(x)-¼T
where erfc is the error complement
GENERALIZATION
y
""
dw
e
=
=
Rabinovitch 0.2
Call
Values:
S
100,
=
(45)
r
=
10%,
-0.25 Time to Maturity =
Jo
[a2(4 ö2(s) -
2pö(s)r>(s)] ds
(46)
Volatility
Under the assumption of a constant stock volatility, substituting the solution of T from (46),ö2 from (39)and P(r) from (38)into equation (40),Rabinovitch gave the following formula for a call option with a stochastic default-free rate: H
SN(di) - KP(r)N(d2)
=
0%
25%
(47)
where
di
=
ln
-
d2 T
=
a2r +
(r -
=
KP(r))
di -
+)T
- B)
solution is simple and useful, since it shows the effect of stochastic interest rates on option values. The difference between this formula and equation 29 of Merton (1973a)is that equation (47) reflects the effect of the mean reverting terni structure on options values. When compared with the B-S formula, this formula takes into account not only the stock's volatility, but also the volatility of the interest rate and its correlation with the stock's returns. It can be shown that partial derivatives with respect to the stock price, the strike price and the interest rate are given by Hs HK
N(di)>0
=
-Ae
H,.=
BKAe
"N(d2) T,. He also assumed the existence of another bond paying one dollar with certainty at time T, and denoted by Pc[t, TL, r(t)] and T, - t. the prices of these bonds with r, P,[t, T,, r(t)] respectively T, - t and r, results the longer-term and Itö's lemma in Merton (1973a), he for bond Using some concluded that formula (40)also applies for the pricing of call options on the long-term
(1973a),Rabinovitch (1989)presented
Following Merton
formula for the pricing of bond options
when
=
=
bond, with x=
=
P,[t,
T,, r(t)]
KP,[t,
T,, r(t)]
(53)
and T,
T
=
[U2(To
O
ö2(T,, s) -
2pa(TL,
s)o(T,, s)]ds
(54)
«209
+ ö2 - 2pöu is lowest when compared with other values of p. --
=
K
N(d2)>0
1, the It is convenient to note that when the correlation coefficient is l, i.e. p unanticipated the same returns on the stock and the bond behave statistically as instrument. The total variance, given by v2
q
(50)
This closed-form
=
0.I,
(49)
:
- 2po(r
2B) +
50%
(48)
N
=
Rho
and T
m
Rabinovitch presented a solution in the form of the B-S formula for stock options where the long-term bond replaces the stock price. His solution is similar in form to that of Cox,
190
OPTIONS,
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
Ingersoll and Ross (1985a)for options on discount bonds. However, his paper was the subject of a reply by Chen (1991)who showed an incoherence with the formula in Rabinovitch.
8.2.3
Chen's
=
P(t, T)
PRICING OF BONDS AND INTEREST OPTIONS
=
of
r(s) ds
(59)
),
the future interest rates, R(u, T), are wthaean and models of interestratesmustbeestablishedtofmdtherelationshipsbetweestibesergtes.
8.3.2
Instantaneous
Rates under
interest
Uncertainty
Under uncertainty, the instantaneous interest rate r(t) is a stochastic times t and t + dt. If we consider a riskless asset, then its price is given by B(0, t)
the dynamics
exp
In a context of uncertainty,
RATE
The pricing of bonds and interest rate options needs a specification interest rates under certainty and uncertainty.
191
RATES
INTEREST
Consider a zero-coupon bond, which is a bond paying 1 dollar with certainty at its l. The price of this bond at time t, P(t, T), in this context (in maturity date, P(T, T) with no risk, where all future interest rates are known) is given by economy an
Correction
The model presented by Rabinovitch for the pricing of stock and bond options when the short-term interest rate is stochastic and follows a mean reverting process, reduces to those presented by Chaplin (1987)and Jamshidian (1989). In fact, careful attention to the assumptions in Rabinovitch shows that the two factors d Wi and d W2 reduce to just one factor, since the bond price is determined by the same current interest rate r(t). Given the assumption of a mean reverting process for r, the bond price can only follow a log-normal process. Hence, there is no need for an additional assumption for the bond price, When the correlation coefficient equals 1, the model simplifies to those in Chaplin (1987)and Jamshidian (1989).
8.3
TO STOCHASTIC
GENERALIZATION
DERIVATIVES
=
exp
process between
r(s)ds
Lo
#90) -
Assumption H Consider a process P(t, u)os,ss satisfymg the boundary condition l. Then, as for the processes of stock prices, it can be shown, with no arbitrage P(u, u) opportunities, that there is a unique probability P* equivalent to the probability P under =
8,3.1
Instantaneous
interest
which the process
.
Rates under
Certamty
When an investor borrows $l at time t, he must pay F(t, T) at time T where T is the maturity date of the debt. This amount corresponds to an average interest rate R(t, T) which applies over the period [t, T]. It is given by F(t, T)
e""
=
"'
"
(55)
P(t, u)
=
F(t, u)F(u,
for all t(u,
=
E*
exp
-
r(s)
P*, we have
ds
0
(62)
(56)
1 allows one to show that, there is an Using this equality and the fact that F(t, t) instantaneous interest rate r(t) such that in the absence of arbitrage opportunities, the amount F(t, T) is given by F(t, T)
r(s)ds
exp
is a martingale for each u in the time interval [0, T]. This is an interesting assumption since, under the new probability
In the context of certainty, when the interest rates are known over the period, the function F is given at each instant by F(t, s)
=
(57)
)
or P(t, u)
=
E*
exp
r(s)
ds
F,
If one compares this formula with formula (59),we notice that the prices of bonds depend only on the process P(t, u)os,,,, under the probability P*.
(63) zero-coupon
Assumption H allows the identification of the probability density of P*, denoted, LT, with respect to P. In this context, it is possible to show that there exists a stochastic process q(t)os,s, such that for all t in the interval [0, T]:
192
OPTIONS,
L,
=
FUTURES
q(s) dW
e×p
GENEllALTEM10N
AND EXOTltWVATIVES
(64)
o
Using equation
(64)and
the following property E*[X F,]
=
E[XLr|F,]
is
Li
possible to show that the price at time t of a zero-coupon given by
It is
P(t, u)
=
E exp
/
("
(65) bond
"
r(s) ds +
with a maturity
"
q2(S)
q(s) dW
Û',
Rate Processes
and
the Pricing
ds |Fr
=
(P(r,
Co×, ingersofi and Ross Model In the context of this model, the dynamics of the instantaneous interest rate are described by the following equation:
of Bonds and Options
T) - K)*
(67)
(K - P(r, T))*
(68)
For a put option, this pay-off is given by c
=
Yasicek Model The presentation here uses equations (63)and (66) Vasicek (1977)used the following process for the dynamics of the interest rate r(t): dr(t)=a[b-r(t)]dt+adW,
(69)
where a, b and o are constants. If we suppose that the process q(t) is constant equal to -1, then a dr(t)
=
a[b*
-
r(t)]dt
+ o
with
b*
=
b
2¤ a
dÑ7,
W, + At
(66)
Several interest rate models are based on the spot rates where the spot interest rate is the underlymg state variable. This is the case for the models of Vasicek (1977), Hull and White (1987,1988, 1990, 1993), Cox, Ingersoll and Ross (1985a),etc. These models require as inputs different parameters to describe the possible future paths of the spot rate. This implies that the models have to be calibrated in such a way that zero-coupon bond prices are close to market prices. Another way is to use the Heath, Jarrow and Morton (1992)model. Once these problems are solved, the option value can be calculated using the appropriate boundary conditions. Hence, a European bond option with a maturity date r bond with a maturity date T is an option characterized by its terminal on a zero-coupon pay-off. For a call option, this pay-off is given by c
=
The process in equation (69)can be shown to be an Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process. The valuation of bond options in this context can easily be done since the OrnsteinUhlenbeck process is a Gaussian process.
dr(t) Interest
193
date u
The probability is often referred to as the risk-neutral probability
8.3.3
REST RATES
and
q2(s) ds
-
TO15TOCMiliB%WO¾tW
(70)
=
a[b
-
r(t)]
where a and a are positive and b is a real number. In this context, the process q(t) takes the form q(t) number.
Heath, jarrow
and Morton
dW,
dt + o =
-aß
(71) where a is a real
Model
The main drawbacks of the Vasicek (1977)and the Cox, Ingersoll and Ross (1985a) models are that these models do not account for the observed term structure of interest rates. Ho and Lee (1986)proposed an interesting discrete-time model which is appropriate for the description of the whole-term structure of interest rates. The same ideas were used in a continuous-time version of this model by Heath, Jarrow and Morton (1989,1992), hereafter HJM. The HJM interest rate model is based on a new approach to interest rate option pricing. As in the BS model, the HJM model requires the underlying asset (the initial term structure) and a measure of its volatility as the only inputs. The HJM model uses all the available information in the term structure. The model accounts for several features of the term structure movements. It uses a methodology which is often applied in multi-factor models of the term structure risk. In this continuous-time model, the returns of zero-coupon bonds of different maturities are not perfectly correlated and volatility functions are directly calculated from data of changes in the term structure of interest rates. bonds, they are used Smce forward rates are more stable than the prices of zero-coupon in a two-factor model. The two factors are the changing level and the changing slope of to these two factors the term structure. The two stochastic processes corresponding prevent the perfect correlation between bond prices or forward rates. The model has many similarities with the B-S model since it needs only the knowledge The use of multiple of the underlying term structure and its associated volatilities. volatility functions gives the model a certain flexibility since it can accommodate the volatility of the term structure resulting from changes in the level, the slope and the curvature of the term structure. More formally, denote by f(t, u) the forward interest rate, i.e. the rate at which an investor can contract at date t to borrow and lend for a short period at a future date u. The
194
OPTIONS,
AND EXOTIC
FUTURES
initial forward rate curve is taken from market data and
used
DERIVATIVES
GENERA41IlllKTION
TO STOCHASTIC
as an input in the HJM
C(t)
model volatility
of each forward rate is specified in the model. The forward rate for date The u can change over the instant of time from t to t + dt in the following way:
f(t The volatility structure. When o(
+ dt)
function a(
f(t,
=
+ drift(-)dt
u) + o(-)dW
of each forward rate describes
)
with
=
INTEREST
a
In
h
of the term
and the entire a constant, all the forward rates have the same volatility forward curve is submitted to parallel shocks. In this context, the HJM model is the continuous-time limit of the Ho and Lee model. Consequently, the model shows the same drawbacks as that of Ho and Lee, namely, the possibility of negative interest rates. A more interesting model is obtained by HJM when o(-) is a function of the maturity (u - t) of the forward rate f(t, u). " then the model with a>0 and Jo>0, For example, when a(ut)=aae proposed in Vasicek (1977)and studied in Hull and White (1987,1988, 1990, 1993) is obtained-
195
P(t, T)N(h) - KP(t, t*)N(h - q)
(72)
the dynamics
RATES
P( t, T) KP(t, t*))
=
q q2
) is
=
(T
-
t')(l'
4a2 - t) +
[e
and where P(t, T) is the bond with an exercise t* 6 T.
'
-
e
]'[e
' -
e^']
price K and a maturity
t* where
Osts
"
For more details and other applications of the model to the pricing of an entire book of estimation, see Heath, Jarrow and Morton (1992) and Spindel options and volatility
(1992). Example
i
SUMMARY
f(t,
T)
f(0, T) +
=
a2t
t
T
In this chapter, the model developed in Merton (1973a)for the pricing of stock options in the context of stochastic interest rates is presented in great detail. This model represents a starting point toward the theory of option pricing when interest rates are uncertain. The main ideas in Merton's model were used later by many authors for the pricing of a large number of interest rate sensitive claims. For example, Rabinovitch presented an extension of Merton's model for the valuation of stock and index options when the interest rate is uncertain. This model is presented as an alternative to Merton's model for the valuation of long-term stock options. However, it is not appropriate for the valuation of interest rate options and bond options since it
+ a W(t)
In the HJM model, the price of a European bond option is given by C(t)
=
P(t, T)N(h) - KP(t, t*)N(h - q)
with
ln
h
=
is
As
+ '
if
-
o(T - t*) bond with an exercise price K and a maturity q
and where P(t, T) Ostst*GT
P(t, T) KP(t, t*)
=
t* where --
Example
2
df(t,
presents some deficiencies. The literature on the pricing of bonds and bond options is concerned mainly with the stochastic process describing the dynamics of interest rates. Since there are several approaches for the modeling of term structure dynamics, we give the main results from the work of Vasicek and of Cox, Ingersoll and Ross. We present also an interesting model of interest rates, the Heath, Jarrow and Morton model, which accounts for several features of term structure movements. Much work is currently under way on term structure modeling. .
POINTS T)
=
a(t,
T) dt + oi d Wi(t) + o exp
l
A
-(T
-
t) dW2(t)
• • •
In the HJM model, the price of a European bond option is given by
•
FOR DISCUSSION
What are the different categories of government What is a treasury security? What is the main property of a bond? What are the different measures of yicids?
assets?
OPTIONS,
196
•
• •
• • • •
Can t nesRabinovitch model
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
be used for stock options and stock index options? J
Can the Rabinovitch model be used for bond options? Justify your answer. Which of the models presented in this chapter is appropriate for the pricing of shortterm options on long-term bonds? What are the valuation parameters in Merton's model? What are the valuation parameters m Rabmovitch's model? What are the valuation parameters in Heath, Jarrow and Morton's model? What are the specificities of Heath, Jarrow and Morton's model?
riCin
CHAPTER
g
CO rpO
rate
BOn
ds
OUTLINE
This chapter is organized as follows: modeling along the lines of 1. Section 9.1 introduces the traditional contingent-claims Black and Scholes (1973)and Merton (1974).It is shown that default risk is equivalent to a European put option on the corporate assets. A risky discount debt is priced and the corporate spreads are given. 2. Section 9.2 shows the limits of this traditional approach which has three weaknesses: and the deviations the interest rate uncertainty, the bankruptcy-triggering mechanism from the strict priority rule. A survey of recent contributions is also given. 3. In section 9.3, the Longstaff and Schwartz (1995)model is developed. The building assumptions are given and the resulting price of a corporate zero-coupon bond. 4. Section 9.4 is devoted to the Briys and de Varenne (1997)model which tries to correct a defect of the Longstaff and Schwartz approach. The price of a risky discount bond is given by a closed-form solution. Corporate spreads and interest rate sensitivity are also derived and analyzed.
INTRODUCTION For corporate bondholders, default by the bond issuer is a possibility that cannot be ignored. Expectations of possible future losses are reflected in current bond yields. For angels' do command instance, bonds issued by so-called a higher yield than an otherwise identical Treasury bond. This extra yield, the corporate default spread, rewards the corporate bondholder for carrying the risk of not being repaid. Even though the contingent claims analysis has delivered many insights into the modeling of default, corporate bonds turn out to be more difficult to price than equivalent Treasury bonds. Black and Scholes (1973)and Merton (1974)have been the pioneers in the pricing of claim franiework. They modeled corporate liabilities corporate bonds using a contingent total value of the firm. Default is assumed to occur and debt) options the (equity as on when the debt expires and when the firm exhausts its assets. Because of the limited 'fallen
198
FUTURES
OPTIONS,
AND EXOTIC
gigiglMIO
DERIVATIVES
thus equivalent to a European put option on the corporate assets. Corporate zero-coupon bonds consist of a portfolio with an otherwise equivalent Treasury bond and a short position into a put-to-default. Since the seminal papers of Black and Scholes (1973) and Merton (1974),the contingent claims analysis has been extensively used to price corporate bonds. Black and Scholes (1973)and Merton (1974)have modeled corporate liabilities as options on the total value of the firm. Merton (1974)and its refinements (Lee, 1981; Pitts and Selby, 1983) analyze default spreads of pure discount corporate bonds and the risk term structure of interest rates. In these models, default is assumed to occur when the bond matures and when the firm exhausts its assets. The term structure of interest rates is assumed to be flat and deterministic. Of course, the contingent claim approach has been extensively used to price and to securities. Black and Cox (1976)examined the effects of some study more complex indenture provisions (subordination arrangements, safety covenants). Ingersoll (1977a) and Brennan and Schwartz (1980)valued callable and convertible bonds. Geske (1977) showed how coupon bonds can be viewed as portfohos of compound options. Smith (1979)is a good survey of the traditional contingent claim approach for the pricing of corporate debts. However, this traditional modelmg has shown three limits: interest rates are assumed to be constant, or deterministic, default can occur only at the maturity of the bond, and deviations from the absolute priority rule are ignored. As will be shown below, it is now well documented that these three points play a crucial role in determining the size of the risky spreads. Recent contributions in the default risk literature have proposed modeling frameworks where these issues are explicitly taken into account. The purpose of this chapter is to show how the contingent claim analysis is a useful framework for the study of corporate default risk. Throughout this chapter, we only consider the case of a corporation which issues only two classes of securities: a single homogeneous debt, consisting of a zero-coupon bond, and equity. .
.
TE BONDS
199
TABLE 9.1
The Corporate
Balance
Assets
Liabilities
y
Assets
Sheet
Equity
E,
Debt
D,
A,
bond) (zero-coupon
,
{A.I) Complete
Financial Markets
Financial markets are assumed to be complete and frictionless. Tradmg takes place continuously. There is no taxation, nor transaction cost. Under this hypothesis, - as shown in a previous chapter, one can show that there exists a unique probability measure Q, the risk-neutral probability, under which the continuously discounted price of any security is a
Q-martingale.
(A.2) Corporate
Asset Process
The total value A, of the assets of the firm at time t is governed under the probability Q by the following stochastic differential equation: dA, =
r dt + ogd W,
risk-neutral
(l)
where the continuously compound interest rate r is a constant and the constant a represents the instantaneous standard deviation of the return on corporate assets. W, is a standard one-dimensional Brownian motion.
9.1 9.1.1
THE TRADITIONAL MODE LING
COgg¶lM
NEAI LAINS (A.3) Modigliani-Miller
which issues at time t We consider a corporation 0 two different classes of securities: a single homogeneous debt consisting of a zero-coupon bond and the residual claim, namely equity. The debt has a face value F and a maturity E In this and the following sections, we derive the time t value D, of the corporate zero-coupon bond and the time t value E, of equity. The total value of the corporate assets is equal to A,. The balance sheet of such a firm is given by Table 9.l. valuation Black and Scholes (1973)and Merton (1974)developed a continuous-time risk. model for corporate debt which accounts for default They made the following four =
assumptions.
hnances its total assets at time t 0 by issuing equity. In the absence of taxes and bankruptcy costs, the total independent of this capital structure decision. In other words, (1958)proposition does hold. Cash outflows are assumed to be securities.
The corporation
Assumptions
Theorem =
a zero-coupon bond and value of the firm A, is the Modigliani-Miller financed by issuing new
(A.4) Limited Liability
It is assumed that sharehoMorshave a Manitedliability.ffthings they simply walk away.
go wrong in their firm,
200
9.1.2
OPTIOf¾¿FUTißlllES4hNO The Pricing
of Corporate
EXO
ERIVATIVES
PRICli
201
G CORPORAgg
Equity
Debt
An obvious advantage of the contingent-claims analysis is that it captures the share holders' option to walk away if things go wrong in their firm. At maturity T of the corporate bond, they assess the net worth of the corporate assets and check whether the company is solvent or not. In this traditional approach, if at maturity assets are found to be less than the face value F of the debt, the corporate assets are costlessly transferred to bondholders. Indeed, because of their limited liability, shareholders are not obliged to issue new shares or bonds to raise the cash to repay bondholders if the assets are less than the face value F. To clarify the valuation procedure, we first look at the cash flows which bondholders are entitled to under the various scenarios following potential cash flows.
at maturity
T They have a claim on the
Debt
a FIGURE 9.1
Shareholders'
As far as equity is concerned,
its value at time tsT E,
Solvency
Final Pay-offs
Bondholders'
and
=
is
given by
Cs(A,, F)
(7) T, with
call option
In the first case, the firm is able to fulfill its commitment to bondholders. Assets A, generate enough value to match the face value F, namely Ar a F. Bondholders receive the promised payment F: Dr
F
=
if
A, a F
maturing at date where Cs(A,, F) is a European From Black and Scholes (1973),the value of Ca(A,, F) is given by CE
=
A,N(di)
an exercise price E
o N(d2
- Fe
where
(2)
Insolvency
F)
I,
Ay
di
In(A,/F)
+
=
a /2)(T - t)
(r +
d2
=
A
¯
and N( ) denotes the cumulative normal distribution. Equity is equivalent to a long position in a European call option which characterizes to walk away if things go wrong the shareholders' limited liability. They have the in their firm. As far as liabilities are concerned, their final pay-offs indicate that they can be priced 'option'
In this case, the firm is totaly insolvent: the net worth of its assets is below the guaranteed liability F, namely A, < F. The company is declared bankrupt, and the bondholders receive what is left: Dr=Ar
if
Because of limited liability, the shareholders' Er are as follows: E,
Ar l) are characterized by spreads inversely related to the level of qa. In such cases, bondholders discount negatively the absence of any safety covenant. In that respect, it is interesting to underline that, other things being equal, the less lo-solvent the firm, the larger the corporate spread. Violations of the strict priority rule also have a strong influence on the level of corporate spreads as displayed by Table 9.2 and Figure 9.6. The less bondholders receive upon bankruptcy, the larger the corporate spreads. Figures 9.5 and 9.6 also suggest that the corporate spread is more elastic to changes in i and/or 2 than to changes in qa. Figures 9.7 to 9.9 capture the effect of corporate asset volatility on the level of spreads. Merton (1974) showed that the corporate spread is an increasing corporate function of corporate volatility. Decamps (1994) proved that this result was a direct product of the constant interest rate assumption. According to Decamps (1994), when
200
.1
O
4
2
o
6
FIGURE 9.6 Yield Spreads as a Function 0.05, p 0.06, o 0.02, ro 0.2, a 0.2, b =
=
=
=
=
i
i
i
I
'
I
8
10
12
14
16
18
of Time-to-Maturity: -0.25
20
Maturity
(yrs)
to
=
0.8,
«»
=
correlated, the corporate interest rates and the value of the firm's assets are negatively spread is a single peaked function (first decreasing, then increasing) of the volatility of the firm. Figure 9.8 indicates that neither Merton's result nor Decamps's proposition extends to our setting (see, for instance, Panels A and C). coefficient p on the level of Figure 9.9 describes the impact of the correlation For positive values of the corporate spreads as a function of the firm's asset volatility. monotonically while for negative relationship increasing, correlation coefficient p, the is
Yield spreads
Yield spreads
(bps)
(bps)
1000
700
800 600
Panel A : lo
=
600
_
"v
-
1.1
=
500
0 3 a
400
=
o
=
400
himbf A : lo -
o2
-
0.1
qa= 0.9 le
300 200
200
100
2
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
20
0.20
0.15
0.25
Asset volatility
0.30
(bps) 450
go= 0
400
1000
a
=
0 3
350 300
800
00
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
20
·
qa= 0.9 le
00
MatuSrty
Yield spreads
0.05
0.10
0.20
0.15
0.25
0.30
Yield spreads
(bps)
(bps)
140
200
120
qa=0
-
o,=0.3
100
to
0 10
Yield spreads
1200
0.4
0.05
(yg
(bps)
:
-
00
Mategy
Yield spreads
Panet C
·
-
0
=
0
°=
-
150
-
80
·
qa=0.91,
-
60
°v=02
-
40
Panel C
:
to
=
0.4
100
=
no
-
lo
-
50
·
200
FIGURE 9.7 Yield Spreads f2 0.8, a 0.2, b 0.06, « =
=
=
=
0
2
i
'
I
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
of Time-to-Maturity: as a Function 0.05, p = -0.25 0.02, ro
18
20
Maturity
go
O
(yrs) =
0.914,
fi
=
=
FIGURE 9.8 0.8, a
=
0.2, 6
0.05
O
0.10
0.15
0.20
Yield Spreads as a Function of Asset -0.25 0.02, ro 0.05, p 0.06, «
=
=
=
0.25
Volatility:
0.30
Asset volatility
T
10,
=
f,
=
f2
=
=
values
of the same coefficient this is no longer true. As a matter of fact, corporate is measured by the quantity Ï(t, T) which is the volatility of the ratio A,/P(t, T). As already mentioned above, this last quantity is the forward price of assets, namely the relevant corporate zeroasset for pricing the corporate But Ï(t, T) is a monotonically increasing function coupon bond under the Q-economy. of the asset volatility Ja if p is positive, while it is first decreasing, then increasing, if p is negative. volatility
'underlying'
9.4.4
The Interest
Rate Elasticity
of Corporate
Bonds
model has interesting implications for both portfolio and asset-liability management (ALM). Indeed, bond portfolios and the balance sheets of many institutions movements in the are interest rate sensitive. To protect these latter against unexpected term structure of interest rates, the investor needs to evaluate his risk exposure accurately.
This valuation
220
OPTIONS,
AND EXOTIC
FUTURES
MiiRIVATIVES
Yield spreads
PRICING
CORPORATE
BONDS
gli
Let r¡n denote the interest elasticity
(bps)
1 8 Do
340 r¡n 330 -
1.1
320
By applying obtams:
0.5
=
p
Panel A : \p
.
p
300
0
=
=
-,
I
'
'
'
0.05
0.10
0.15
0.20
025
0.30
Itô's lemma to the closed-form
o
=
N(-d
lo
)- -
N(-ds)
-
(1
)
n(di)
250
-
150
100
(1 - fa)
N(-di)
d3)
- N(
Ï(0, T)
n(d3)
qan(ds)
qan(d4)
Ï(0, T)
Ï(0, T)
Ï(0,
=
p
-
From the expression for yo, several polar cases can be recovered. The first deals with the situation where there is no violation of the absolute priority rule and where the safety 1). Under these assurnptions, the interest rate covenant is fully protective (i.e. a elasticity of the corporate bond is given by Vasicek's formula for the interest rate elasticity of a riskless zero-coupon bond:
0.5
-
,
=
o_o
=
p'
0
0.05
-o.5
'
'
'
'
0.10
0.15
0.20
0.25
0.30
Asset volatuity
r¡o
Yield sppsreads
=
r¡,
=
-
B(T)
(60)
In the second case, no safety covenant is attached to the corporate zero-coupon 0). There is, however, still no deviation from the strict priority rule (fi a As a result, r¡o collapses to Merton's formula extended by Decamps (1994): =
2oo 150 1oo
so
p=0.5
fi
=
f2
9.9 =
0.8,
r¡s=
·
_0 5 I
0.05
0.10
I
I
'
0.15
0.20
0.25
Yield Spreads as a Function of Asset Volatility: 0.25 0.06, « 0.02, ro 0.05, p 0.2, b a =
=
=
=
-B(T)+
+B(T) a
-
o0 FIGURE
bond (i.e. =
f2
=
1.0).
·
p=o.o
PanelO: ¼=04
(59)
T)
-
50 0
Do, the following expression
2n(ds)
N(-d3)
3oo
-
solution
with
Asset volatility
(bps)
Panel B : Io ¯ 0.8
(57)
-
Do Bro
0.0
Yield spreads
200
of the corporate bond:
measure
=
0.30
T
=
Asset volatility
10, go
=
0.914,
Interest rate elasticity and duration measures are now commonplace. Nevertheless, most of them are quite restrictive and apply only under a specific set of assumptions. Corporate default, for instance, is rarely taken into account. This is unfortunate and produces biased estimates of the true elasticity of a corporate bond: see Ambarish and Subrahmanyam (1989)and Chance (1990). In that respect, this model corrects these deficiencies. Moreover the simple structure ofour corporate bond pricing formula makes it easy to compute the relevant elasticity measure.
Do
.N(-d,)
(6!)
A careful inspection of this last expression enables a better understanding of the more complex expression for yo. Indeed, the last formula is basically composed of three terms which can be disentangled as follows. As already mentioned above, the first term corresponds to the interest rate elasticity of a riskless zero-coupon bond. The second term (withmbrackets) is equivalent to the interest rate elasticity gap between the firm's assets and the default free zero-coupon bond. This is so because the ratio pos/o measures the interest rate elasticity of the firm's assets. At this point it is worth mentioning the crucial role that the correlation coefficient p plays in the determination of the overall interest rate elasticity of the corporate bond. Other things being equal, a negative p entails a higher interest rate elasticity. The third term can be defined as a probability adjusted ratio. The general expression for yo is obviously more complex. The full Ro term reflects the impacts of both the safety covenant and the violations of the absolute priority rule. When it comes to immunization or related techniques, practitioners use the duration tool (especiallyMacaulay duration) more frequently than the interest rate elasticity itself Duration-matching methods, for instance, are quite popular. The accuracy of these methods, however, crucially depends on the correct measurement of duration. To provide results that are closer to current managerial practices, we now define the effective .
-
.
.
222
FUTURES
OPTIONS,
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
PRI ING CORPORATE
Duration
duration of the corporate zero-coupon bond. This duration Ao is defined as the maturity of the default-free bond which exhibits the same interest rate elasticity as the risky corporate zero-coupon bond, namely =
Qo
-
a
p(0,
(yrs)
=
-
-
6
A p)
(62)
-
=
5
PMWBA : qa Oh =
4 3 -
1
(63)
o0
90 T
(years) Ao
(years)
=
«
Ao as a Function of Time-to-Maturity: -0.25 0.02, ro 0.05, p =
90 Ao
0.2,
=
fi
=
| 5 10 I5 20 Panel I 5 IO IS 20
=
,
.
8
10
12
14
.
•
16
18
(years)
=
0.9/o Ao - T T
go Ao
(years)
=
Panel
C: lo - 0.4
I 5 10 l5 20
I.00 4.90 8.64 i i.i i |2.63
(yrs)
11- I2 - 1ß
-
12
-
10
Panel 8 : go
=
0.9 le
8
-
i
6 4
(2
=
·
-
4
0
=
t2 0.6
-
10
12
14
16
18
20
Maturity
(yrs)
Duration
0
(yrs) =
20
Ao - T T
2
1.0
·
2-0.8
176.0% -10.6% -21.0% -27.5% -34.3%
4.20 4.14 6.83 9.2I i I.02
320.0% -17.2% -31.7% -38.6% -44.9%
3.73 3.79 4.80 5.4| 5.75
273.0% -24.2% -52.0% -63.9% -71.3%
Panel C : go
-
le
10
-
2=0.6
5 -
0
0
I
I
2
4
I
6
'
8
I
·
·
·
'
10
12
14
16
18
20
0.8
2.02 4.43 7.57 10.23 12.23
Maturity
20
I.I
2.76 4.47 7.90 I0.87 13.14 B: 12
,
6
16 14
15
PanelA:Io
=
,
4
=
=
10 Ao - T T
Ja
,
2
ouration (yrs)
2
=
=
¯
2
In (1 + aq,,)
Table 9.3 and Figure 9.10 give some numerical insights into the behavior of the duration of the corporate zero-coupon bond. Table 9.3 is quite informative about the influence of the early default ratio on the effective duration. Indeed, other things being equal, the closer qa gets to zero, the smaller is the effective duration. This result makes sense if one remembers that a safety covenant is equivalent for bondholders to a long position on a put option. If this long position is progressively lifted, a gradual decrease in the duration of the corporate bond is rather intuitive. Table 9.3 also delivers that the effective duration is usually smaller than the maturity, i.e. the Macaulay duration. But this result is not general and does not carry over to short-term bonds. In Panel A, the duration of a one year to
=
1.o 0.8 0.6
=
=
-
a
TABLE 9.3 Duration 0.06, 0.8, a 0.2, b
t f, y - (2 fi I2 =
7
In a Vasicek framework, this can be rewritten as Ai,
223
BONDS
102.0% -I l.4% -24.3% -31.8% -38.9%
l.82 4.27 6.77 8.84 10.40
82.0% -I4.6% -32.3% -4l.l% -48.0%
l.76 4.20 5.77 6.49 6.78
76.0% -|6.0% -42.3% -56.7% -66.\%
0.0% -2.0% -13.6% -25.9% -36.9%
l.00 4.90 8.45 10.42 i I.46
0.0% -2.0% 15.5% -30.5% 42.7%
l.0 4.91 8.35 9.74 9.91
0.0% -1.8% -16.5% -35.1% -50
FIGURE 9.10 Duration as a Function -0.25 0.06, « 0.02, ro 0.05, p =
=
of Time-to-Maturity:
lo
=
Maturity
(yrs) 0.8, a
=
0.2, b
=
=
1.1 and qa maturity corporate bond, for instance, is 3.73 years (when lo 0). This In a constant interest rate environment, Leland result may seem quite counter-intuitive. (1994a,1994b) obtained the result that effective duration is always less than Macaulay duration. This is not true here. This point is confirmed by Figure 9.10. In the three panels, effective duration is greater than Macaulay duration for short-term bonds. Moreover, this holds true whatever the intensity of the deviations from the strict priority rule. In the specific case where qa 1.0 (Panel C), effective duration is equal to lo and i f Macaulay duration (45° line). But in this scenario the risky bond becomes a riskless bond. =
=
=
=
=
224
OPTIONS,
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
This lengthening of the effective duration finds its roots in the interest rate elasticity gap between the firm's assets and the default-free bond. This gap is one of the determinants of the overall interest rate elasticity of the corporate bond. For short maturities, the quantity B( T) is small. Moreover, Figure 9.10 displays results in the case of a negative correlation coefficient p. Other things being equal, this entails a stronger clasticity r¡n which in turn translates into a higher duration. For a positive correlation coefficient, Leland's result would be recovered. Finally it is worth pointing out that more stringent deviations from the strict priority rule contribute to shorten the effective duration.
•
•
Ÿricing
IRSurance
•
Linked SOnds
SUMMARY The purpose of this chapter is to show how the contingent-claims framework is appropriate for analyzing the effect of default risk on corporate bonds. Black and Scholes (1973)and Merton (1974) have modeled corporate liabilities as options on the total value of the firm. Since their seminal papers, this approach has been extensively used to price more complex securities. More recently, contributions have proposed modeling frameworks where new issues are taken into account: interest rate uncertainty, the bankruptcy-triggering mechanism and deviations from the strict priority rule. The Longstaff and Schwartz (1995)model introduced default risk and interest rate risk. Financial distress occurs when the value of assets reaches a barrier. Briys and de Varenne (1997)develop a corporate bond valuation model which avoids some of the shortcomings of the previous models. The bankruptcy-triggering mechanism is directly related to the pay-off received by bondholders when early bankruptcy is forced. Because it accounts for stochastic interest rates, default risk and deviations from the absolute priority rule, their model is capable of producing quite diverse shapes for the term structure of corporate spreads. Interest rate elasticity and duration measures have also been derived. Among other things, effective duration has been shown to be significantly different from the traditional Macaulay duration.
POINTS • • • • • •
• • •
OUTLINE
This chapter is organized as follows:
Genoese 1. Section 10.1 starts this chapter by telling the story of a thirteenth-century merchant who protected his business by issuing what could be called the ancestor of insurance linked bonds. This transaction is indeed very similar to the type of transaction that nowadays involves insurance companies and capital market players. Some of these modern transactions are then briefly described. Finally, this section draws the analogy between insurance linked bonds (alsocalled nature-linked bonds) and junk bonds. 2. Section 10.2 describes the basic features of an insurance linked bond. It shows how such a bond is created and what the basic transactions involved are. 3. In section 10.3, the pricing model is built and the various assumptions underlying it are presented. A closed-form solution is derived under the assumption of constant interest rates. This section delivers an in-depth analysis of the spread over Treasury of an insurance linked bond and of its duration. Implications of the pricing model on the validity of traditional performance statistics (suchas mean return and standard deviation of return) currently used in the analysis of insurance linked bonds are also analyzed.
FOR DISCUSSION
What are the underlying assumptions of the Black-Scholes model? What is a put-to-default? Wliat is the deviation from the strict priority rule? Give some examples of deviations from the strict priority rule Why is the contingent-claims framework so useful in modeling default risk? What does default' mean? What are the three weaknesses of the traditional approach? Describe the Longstaff and Schwartz (1995) model What is the main defect in their model? Describe the Briys and de Varenne (1997) model· 'carly
•
CHAPTER
INTRODUCTION Insurance risk or nature risk is considered by many as an emerging asset class. Indeed, the record number of natural catastrophes topped by the significant number of man-made catastrophes has raised concern about the available capacity in the insurance and reinsurance markets. While a S10 billion fluctuation is easily absorbed by the capital markets, the same is not true for the insurance industry. These facts have led to the idea that insurance or nature risks can also be directly priced and exchanged on capital based on markets. The Chicago Board of Trade has introduced derivatives contracts insurance indices. More recently, investment banks have structured private placements involving bonds with coupons and/or principal exposed to insurance or nature risks.
226
OPTIONS,
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
DERæ
The purpose of this chapter is to examine such bonds. More specifically, it addresses the issues of the pricing and interest rate risk of insurance linked bonds. These questions are important since insurance linked bonds are often presented as overperforming financial instruments. It is claimed, for instance, that they outperform Treasury bonds while exposing the investor to a lower risk level. This last claim is carefully investigated in this chapter. It is shown that it is rather dubious, given the embedded non-stationarity of insurance linked bond returns The purpose of the present chapter is twofold. First, it proposes a simple pricing model for insurance linked bonds and derives spread over Treasury and duration measures for such bonds. Surprisingly enough, the whole issue of duration measurement has been neglected in most publications dealing with insurance linked bonds. Such an omission is rather unfortunate. Indeed, we show hereafter that an insurance linked bond is quite sensitive to interest rate movements. Second, based on the simple pricing model, it reexamines the case for outstanding performance of insurance linked bonds. Among other things, it shows that the methodological critique addressed by Ambarish and Subrahmanyam (1989)to performance studies of junk bonds applies also to insurance linked bonds-
10.1
NATURAL HAZARDS, INSURANCE INSURANCE LINKED BONDS
RISKS AND
Quirksof Mother Nature have always been threatening mankind. In ancient times, peasants whose sole means of subsistence were agricultural had to resort to some naïve pantheon animated by benevolent saints and gods. In Burgundy, a French province famous for its magnificent wines, wine growers prayed to Saint Médard and Sainte Barbe for favourable weather. Saint Médard was venerated on the grounds of his ability to make rain while Sainte Barbe was invoked to chase away lightning. This celestial type of coverage was usually rounded off by some more terrestrial type of hedging. For instance, sea navigators would not only pray to Saint Guénolé but also arrange some contracts to mitigate their exposure to sea perils. Indeed, in 1298, a famous Genoese merchant, Benedetto Zaccaria, structured an interesting deal with two Genoese bankers, Baliano Grilli and Enrico Suppa (see Favier, 1987). Zaccaria had to ship 30 tons of alum from Aigues-Mortes in France to Bruges in Belgium. The only way to deliver such a heavy quantity of alum was to freight a vessel Zaccaria, like his contemporary fellow merchants, knew that sea navigation was a very risky venture. The odds that the vessel would never reach its final destination were fairly high. Sea hazards and unexpected storms could simply send the vessel and its valuable freight to the bottom of the ocean. Even if the seas were quiet, there was always the danger of greedy buccaneers and corsairs preying on merchant shipping. In both cases, the freight would be lost and the merchant would eventually face bankruptcy. Zaccaria was well aware of these contingencies. With the help of Grilli and Suppa, he designed a contract to shift the risk away from his business. The deal was the following. Zaccaria sold the alum to Suppa and Grilli on the spot at an agreed price. The alum was then loaded on the vessel that headed to Bruges. If the vessel safely reached Bruges, Zaccaria had to purchase the alum back from Suppa and Grilli. He then sold it to its local client. The repurchase price was obviously much higher than the price of the initial transaction. If things went wrong, say because of a storm, and the alum went lost during i
i
PRICING
INSURANCE
127
LINKED BONDS
the maritime trip, Zaccaria did not owe anything to Suppa and Grilli. In other words, Suppa and Grilli granted Zaccaria an option to default on the repurchase transaction provided the feared event occurred. A modern economist would simply say that the three risk-sharing rule. Viewed from Genoese businessmen had come up with a non-linear risk-sharing option rule is convex: he was long an to default. Zaccaria's standpoint, the with rule reconciled risk-sharing this 1298, be ingenious Although dating back to can Zaccaria risk-bearing. Indeed, faced of optimal theory two results of the recent some risk types of risk, namely a businessman risk and an idiosyncratic risk. The idiosyncratic the time, of risk. At the businessman is due to the sea hazards and is usually independent this risk was not easily hedgeable. In such a setting and with some additional restrictions, Franke, Stapleton and Subrahmanyam (1995)and Briys and Viala (1996)have shown that The Genoese contract also fits well in rule is indeed non-linear. the optimal risk-sharing marketplace. More and more investment the current developments that affect the fmancial loss the whose directly by pattern of natural hazards returns are determined instruments specifically, or some other contingencies are either traded or privately placed. More natural hazards risks and various insurance risks are securitized in order to place them with investors on the marketplace in the form of securities. Other things being equal, this is exactly what Zaccaria's loan was all about. Grilli and Suppa extended a natural hazardlinked loan through which the risk of sea perils was securitized. Nowadays, more sophisticated versions of Zaccaria's loan are issued by investment banks such as J.P. Morgan, Salomon Brothers, AIG Combined Risks, Swiss Re Financial Products or Merrill Lynch. For instance, Nationwide Mutual Insurance Company issued $400 million in 30-year secured bonds at 2% above long-term Treasury bond rates. Using the proceeds, the company bought Treasury bonds to use as collateral. If a catastrophe occurs in the next 10 years, Nationwide will substitute company surplus notes and use the Treasury securities to pay losses. The risk for investors is the possibility that Nationwide Other bonds where the would default on the surplus notes following a major catastrophe. risk principal is itself partially or totally at are also structured. These are usually zerocandidates potential for securitization cover quite a large coupon bonds. Hazards that are airline crashes, and so on. According earthquakes, hurricanes, including floods, spectrum advantages': 'In addition offer investors such bonds Re Sigma Swiss (1996b), to to providing an above-average yield potential, such instruments are attractive since their performance is not correlated with any other financial risks. They therefore promise an outstanding diversification effect.' To the reader familiar with the CAPM theory, this is a free lunch'. Indeed, if insurance linked bonds have argument may sound like no systematic risk, their return should equal the risk-free return. It is interesting to observe that insurance linked bonds (also called insurance linked assets) are often compared to corporate bonds. Indeed, investment banks use credit implied by the spreads on corporate bonds as a benchmark to evaluate the richness is that insurancespreads on insurance-linked bonds. The output of such comparisons conclusion, characteristics. The common linked bonds offer outstanding risk-return based upon historical analysis, is that an investment in an insurance linked bond, after adjusting for risk, tends to outperform an investment in, say, Treasury bonds. For instance, according to AlG Combined Risks, if an investment in natural catastrophe linked bonds with principal fully at risk had been available over the last 25 years, its return would have been four times that of Treasury bonds with a lower volatility. The same kind of argument was applied in the 1980s to investment in junk bonds: see Altman (1987) and Blume and 'decisive
'there
OPTIONS,
228
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
performance fact and the lack of correlation risks led Swiss Re Sigma (1996b)and many possibility shifts the so-called additional efScient frontiers upward, within both national and international modeling frameworks'. The same shift was documented with the introduction of emerging market assets. Finally, it should be emphasized that insurance linked securities make it possible for investors to play the insurance game without having to carry the other risks associated with an investment in shares of an insurance company.
Keim (1987, 1989). This risk-adjusted between natural hazards and financial investment houses to conclude that 'this
10.2
THE STRUCTURE BONDS
.
OF INSURANCE
.
.
LINKED
PRICING
INSURANCE
LINKED BONDS
229
reinsurance markets. Indeed, according to Swiss Re Sigma, the potential losses from catastrophe risks worldwide exceed the cover capacity ofthe insurance industry. The capital reinsurance), as the argument goes, no and the surplus of the insurance industry (including longer offer a sufficient cushion to absorb the losses caused by natural hazards. The same kind of concern was expressed by Kleindorfer and Kunreuther (1996)and Cummins et al. (1996).In a nutshell, the insurance industry feels that it can no longer provide coverage against natural hazards without facing the risk of insolvencies or significant equity losses. Compared to the daily fluctuations on the financial markets worldwide, these potential Seventy basis points of fluctuations on the US financial losses seem less worrying. markets is equivalent to a fiuctuation of $US 133 billion on average (Swiss Re Sigma, 1996a). This a lot more than the size of the Kobe losses. Still, a 70 basis point daily fluctuation is something which is the common rule rather than the exception on financial markets. Canter, Cole and Sandor (1996)noted that a $50 billion catastrophe were to occur in the U.S., approximately 20% of the capital of the primary and reinsurance industries would be wiped out'. The same point was made by Cutler and Zeckhauser $10 billion is large relative to insurance (1996).They argue, for instance, that markets, it is tiny relative to asset markets as a whole'. This prosaic comparison has recently revived the idea that insurance risks can also be priced and exchanged outside the traditional insurance and reinsurance markets, namely on the financial markets. The first proposal emanated from the Chicago Board of Trade where insurance futures contracts and options are now traded. The next step is now towards securitization and private placements. Numerous institutions including investcompanies and direct insurers are currently developing new ment banks, reinsurance classes of assets, the so-called insurance linked assets. These assets are very close in spirit and in action to the 1298 Genoese loan described in the introduction. The most common ones are insurance linked bonds. A typical private placement can be disentangled as follows (see Lehman Brothers (1997)).Suppose there is a corporation that wants to be insured against some nature risk in some geographical area for two years. This corporation cannot find suitable insurance coverage. It turns to an investment bank which suggests the following sequence of transactions. The corporation pays an insurance premium at the same time that some investors bring cash to a so-called Special Purpose Vehiclei (SPV). The insurance premium and the cash payment are bundled together to purchase some Treasury bonds or strips. For the sake of simplicity, we assume that the Treasury instruments purchased are zero-coupon bonds. After the purchase of the strips, the SPV issues two-year naturelinked zero-coupon bonds yielding a spread over Treasury. These bonds are delivered to the investors in exchange for their initial cash payment. As a result, investors hold a nature-linked investment. They accept to lose part of the principal of the bond if some event (saytoo much wind or too much hail) occurs in the designated geographical area during the first two years. The two-year period is called the exposure period. If the event occurs during the first two years, the corporation receives its indemnity from the SPV The SPV is able to cash out this indemnity because it keeps the fraction of the principal of the nature-linked bond that the investors have agreed to give up on the event Cash flows are occurrence. The risk has been passed on to the financial market. 'if
In his masterly piece on the history of climate since the year 1000, Le Roy Ladurie that 1316 had been very wet, with some rather unexpected consequences. Inhabitants of Tournai, a wealthy town of Belgium, were forced to drink their execrable local wine because French vineyards had been ruined by heavy rainfall! On a more of nature's and weather's serious note, it is clear that the financial consequences misbehavior can be very significant. For instance, strong hailstorms have caused heavy damage to vehicles, mobile homes, windows, and so on. Hailstones can be surprisingly heavy (morethan a kilogram) and hence dangerous. In 1986, a violent hailstorm killed 100 people and devastated more than 80 000 real estate properties in central China, In Bangladesh, a sudden hailstorm on 14 April 1986 killed 92 people (seeGauthier (1995)). The spectrum of hazards generated by Mother Nature is wide. In the United States, in 10 major populaaccording to Simpson (1997),over 1983-88 temperature vanations tion centers caused the cost of energy consumed in space heating and cooling to vary by variation was $9 billion over the whole an average of S3.6 billion per year. The total market of the for heating and cooling energy. $75 billion US country. This represents 12% northeast the United States can have weatheroil in and distributors heating Natural gas driven sales that exceed 90% of their sales during the winter season (see Simpson (1997)).In the United Kingdom, subsidence risk came second only to gales and storms in terms of costs to insurers over the last decade. Although buildings are constructed to receive support from the ground, shrinkage of clays caused by prolonged drought presents a significant subsidence peril to these buildings. According to Swiss Re Sigma (1996a),the insurance industry has been significantly hit in the 1990s by a record number of natural catastrophes. In 1995, they caused insured losses of $US 12.4 billion, more than half of which were accounted for by four single hazards costing some billion dollars each: the Kobe earthquake, hurricane Opal, a hailstorm in Texas and winter storms combined with floods in Northern Europe. The Kobe earthquake was by far the most severe disaster: total damages were estimated at $US 82.4 billion and insured losses at SUS 2.5 billion. Losses in excess of $US 1 billion are much $US more frequent. Since 1988, every year has seen at least one disaster costing more than also 1988. on encountered often Storms this less size were before 1 billion. Disasters of are the rise. They are the most costly cause of damages for the insurance industry. Over the period 1989 -95, they entailed losses amounting to nearly $US 10 billion. topped by the significant number of manThese record numbers of natural catastrophes capacity m the insurance and made catastrophes have raised concern about the available
(1983)reported
'while
'bankruptey-remote'.
SPV is necess to make the nature-Unked bond designated event only. This is our assumption in what follows.
Indeed, the bond has to be contingent
on the
FUTURES
OPTIONS,
230
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
RICING INSURANCE
to the state of nature where they are the most badly needed. Howeve f occurs during the exposure period, the investors receive the Treasury yield topped by the proceeds from the insurance premium. bond looks like a junk bond. A junk bond offers To put it in a nutshell, a nature-linked an interesting spread over Treasury investments because its holder grants the shareholders of the issuing company an option to walk away (which is usually deep in-the-money). A nature-linked bond is a junk' bond where the investor is short an option to insure the corporation in case things go wrong. As should be obvious by now, the whole problem is to make sure that the level of the insurance premium is high enough to warrant an attractive spread over Treasury.
reallocated nothing
'natural
10.3
A SIMPLE PRICING MODEL OF INSURANCE/ NATURE LINKED BONDS
10.3.1
The Valuation
Model
model for valuing nature-linked In this section we develop a simple continuous-time non-catastrophic. risks words, we restricted other that In nature is to bonds. The scope are rather than the Poisson type of uncertainty. focus on the Wiener type of uncertainty Although a more realistic pricing setting would incorporate at the same time both interest rate risk and natural hazards or insurance risk, we concentrate in the following on the simpler case of constant interest rates.2 In other words, the only source of uncertainty stems from natural hazards or some other insurance risk. This uncertainty is usually index. captured by a suitable index. The return on the nature-linked bond is pegged to this index like published those official such institutions either by This index as an can be industry statistical agent, Sigma, Property Claims Services (PCS hereafter), an insurance 3 index or a customized index a service of Swiss Reinsurance Company, a meteorological covered Simpson reficcting (orcausing) the contingency to be (1997)). (see,for instance, period. If this A trigger level is defined which remains active during the exposure of the bond is allowed to default. trigger is hit by the index the issuer Hereafter, the index and the trigger level are labeled I(t) and K(as oftime t) respectively. index. The bond is a zero-coupon The bond payoff is contingent upon the value taken by the is characterized by E It maturity Tand value of face bond an exposure period maturing at time T' s T. If the index does not exceed4 the trigger level K during the exposure period, .
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
-
.
.
.
.
.
the investor is sure to receive the face value E If, however, nature decides otherwise (thesocalled event'), the investor loses part of the face value of the bond and receives coef6cient applied to the bond. In practice, only (1 a)F where a denotes the write-down the period between the end of the exposure period and the maturity of the bond is used for , accurately assessing the value taken by the mdex during the exposure period. 'qualifying
.
.
.
.
.
of 2This assumption is less drastic than it appears at first glance. Indeed, as can be seen from Appendix 10.A, even in the case the stochastic interest rates (i.e. a Vasicek term structurek we maintain a zero correlation assumption between the process for interest rate and that for the loss index. To avoid moral hazard problems, it is clear that the index shall not be subject to manipulations 4We assume that the index may bit the trigger from below We could have looked at the sciated case where the trigger is hit from above. A typical case would be a rain index tracking the risk of a low rainfall level. "This is easily done for a weather-related index. 11 is more dif6cult for a loss-related index.
LINKED BONDS
231
stochastic process. In the We assume that the index is governed by a continuous-time data is reasonable. Indeed, one of case of meteorological data, the assumption of the primary tasks of meteorological offices is to release reliable on-line data on temperature (such as degree-days measured by the National Weather Service in the USA), windspeed (the famous Beaufort scale6), river water level or rainfall. As far as insurance loss-related indices are concerned, the assurnption of an instantaneous claim process is quite common in the literature (see, for instance, Shimko (1991, 1992), Cummins and Geman (1995)).The index I(t) is assumed to be driven by a geometric Brownian motion: 'on-line'
dl -I
=
µ dt + o dz
(1)
where µ denotes the instantaneous expected change in the index and a its instantaneous standard deviation. The uncertainty of nature is captured by the increments of a standard Wiener process z(t). The drift µ is an interesting quantity in itself. It is usually the object of intense discussion in scientific circles. If one assumes that the index I(t) is a weatherlinked index, µ can be related to the famous El Niño or the global warming effect' currently under discussion at the Kyoto Conference. We denote by T,,, the first passage time of I(t) through the constant trigger level K: II,K
=
{inf(t >
T; I(t)
0; 0 < ts
=
K)}
(2)
.
by a payoff that is pegged to aggregate bonds are characterized Some nature-linked This is the case, for instance, for hurricane bonds whose return is linked to aggregate damage caused by the occurrence of hurricanes. A new stochastic process has thus to be defined. If I(s) denotes the instantaneous claim level, aggregate claims are I(s) ds. The first passage time is then defined with respect to A(t). We given by A(t) could also consider an event in the spirit of Parisian options. In this case, the event is described as one where the index is above the trigger and stays there for a given amount of time. For example, if the index measures the temperature level the corporation issuing the bond will try to hedge a persistent drought. To keep things simplc and tractable, this chapter is based on a parsimonious frarnework. . imprecise) Indeed, a proxy (admittedly for the two previous definitions is to choose a high value for K, whatever If the index reaches that level (say,temperature or means. windspeed), significant losses are to be expected. In January 1943, Spearfish, Dakota, was hit by the chinook ('snow-eater'),a Rocky Mountains foehnwind whose blow can have devastating effects if it is too strong. The chinook blew so strongly that the temperature rose from -20° to +7°C in less than two minutes! House, building and shop windows were blown out in a wide area, causing significant damage to individuals and local businesses. As stated above, the interest rate r is assumed to be constant over the lifetime of the option. Financial markets are assurned to be complete and frictionless. Trading takes place continuously. Under this hypothesis, Harrison and Kreps (1979)have shown that there is a unique probability measure Q-the risk-neutral probability-under which the continuously values.
.
.
.
=
.
.
.
'high'
.
.
.
6The Beaufort scale ranges from 0 to 17. A value between 0 and I corresponds to a windspeed weather vane. For values between 12 and 17, the wind speed is above l 18 km/h. Severe damage for values of 10 and above 'Scientists may even disagree on the true magnitude of µ. [n the case of an insurable risk, this Company bond quite fat (compared may find the spread over Treasury implied by a nature-linked as a direct reinsurer) and decide to invest in it
to 5 km h, namely a still constructions usually occurs
of0 to
may explain why an insurance to what it would have charged
OPTIONS,
232
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
The fact that markets are considered complete is discounted loss index is a Q-martingale. not such an heroic assumption as it sounds. Indeed, the Chicago Board of Trade has introduced derivative assets, including options and futures, based on natural catastrophe implies that fmancial assets loss indices: see, for instance, D'Arcy and France (1993).This perfectly correlated to the changes m the mdex I(t)." exist whose returns are (almost) To clarify the valuation procedure, we first look at the cash flows which bondholders are entitled to under the various scenarios. They have a claim on the following potential cash flows: .
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
•
No trigger during the exposure period: Under this scenario, bondholders receive the linked zero-coupon bond, namely F.1 , where full face value of the insurance la is function for the event B. the indicator Under this second scenario, bondholders Trigger hit during the exposure period: .
.
•
receive
an amount equal to a)F.1rer,
0 of the insurance linked zero-coupon bond is thus given by The price as of time t value of future expected cash flows under the risk-neutral probability Q: =
the discounted
=
LINKED BONDS
EU[exp(-rT)(F.1,
=
e +
(1 -
a)F.17,
s,)]
exp(-rT)F
-
EU[exp(-rT)aF.1,
(4)
is easy to interpret. It simply says that holding an insurance linked bond investing in a portfolio which is long a default-free zero-coupon bond of face short a conditional binary option to default. formulation, the probability distribution of the first passage time of I(t) through barrier K appears explicitly as the key factor driving the pricing process: Do= exp(-rT)F(l
-
aQr,
c)
(5)
Qr, is the one-sided risk-neutral first passage time distribution of the index f(t) through the barrier K. of the risk-neutral The explicit computation first passage time distribution (see Appendix 10.B) yields the following closed-form solution for the insurance linked bond:
where
,
Do
=
Fexp (-rT)
1- a
N(di)
nhenomenn
lo2)T'
In(Io K)+(r-
di=
naturnt
(r - ja2)F
In this pricing formula, N(.) denotes the normal distribution function. The term withm coefficient a, is simply the one-sided risk-neutral first the brackets, after the write-down Ice" K. passage time distribution. This closed-form solution depends on the ratio E, vulnerability' reminiscent is of It This ratio can be viewed as a measure. the quasi-leverage ratio of Merton (1974).Indeed, the underlymg stochastic process (the nature index here or the corporate assets in Merton's case) is redefmed through the change of numeraire (i.e. under the new probability measure) and compared to the trigger level (K here or the face value of the corporate debt in Merton's case). In what follows, it will be shown that this ratio plays a sigmficant role. When a is equal to zero, the price of the insurance linked bond collapses to that of an otherwise equivalent default-free zero-coupon bond, P(0, T). The same holds true when the exposure period is nil, namely when T' is equal to zero. For an mfinite trigger point K, the insurance linked bond tends to its default-free value. Some other properties of the pricing formula are also noteworthy. The first yields the obvious result that the price ofthe insurance linked bond tends to P(0, T)(1 - a) when lo tends to K. As a result, when the principal ofthe 1, the bond price tends to zero, other things being equal. The bond is fully at risk, i.e. a second interesting property deals with the impact of the index volatility on the price of the insurance linked bond. When the index volatility goes to infinity, the bond value tends to .
.
.
=
'pseudo-nature
·
-
-
=
Do
2
(7)
of
such
as
the Re:nifort
scale
are not tra
(33)
lo
Using standard methods for the price of a European call, the solution is found to be
C(S, T)
=
N(di)
Se
-
Ee
'
""N(d2)
(34)
with
ln(S/E) b'y
I 1.6.2
Empirical
di
=
+
(r
Ü2
+ L)T ,
d2
=
di - o
v/Ï
'at-the-money'
(35)
Tests
The model presented above is simulated here with reference to the B-S model and tested with regard to stock options traded on the MONEP, the Marché des Options Négociables de la Bourse de Paris. The focus of this section is to calibrate the model to the observed prices in the option market. For the specificities of this market, see for example Bellalah and Prigent (1997a,1997b). Stocks and options prices were given by the database of AFFI, Association Française de Finance, and missing data were collected from the journals La Tríbune and Les Echos· We have selected closing prices for stocks and the mid-quoted bid-ask spread for options Options are quoted for different strike prices and maturities. Most options are traded for the nearest maturities of three and six months. Options with nine months to maturity are rarely traded. The database englobes in-the-
C,,,
=
as, +ß,,,M,,,
+
E¡¡,
(36)
where
l'
S,, - Xe X,,e
"
"
(37)
In the above regression as, is an implied weighted average cost for each option j on asset i on day t. Some results are reported in Tables I 1.4-11.6, from Bellalah and Jacquillat
(1995). To get an idea of the amount of mispricing, and using the weighted average cost of incomplete information and the historical volatility, we calculate each day the difference
254
OPTIONS,
TABLE I I.4 Estimates age Costs of Incomplete Peugeot
AND EXOTIC
of Implied Weighted Averfor Options on Information
Dote
N Options
a'
2-01-88 2-02-88 2-03-88 2-04-88 2-05-88 2-08-88 2-09-88 2-10-88 2-I I-88 2-12-88
63 53 32
0.03 0.03 0.01
20 26 24 2I 25
0.03
R
ß
0.52
0.50 0.10
0.83
-0.88
0.97 -i.08
56 64
TABLE I l.5 Estimates Costs of incomplete Paribas
age
Date
N Options
2-0 1-88 2-02-88 2-03-88 2-04-88 2-05-88 2-08-88 2-09-88 2- I0-88 2- I I 2-12-88
45 I4 IS 15 I2 5I 27 i5 48
-88
FUTURES
74
-0.89
0.01 0.02 0.09 0.\0 0.09 0.08
0.58 0.42 0.71
0.70 0.62
0.93 0.82 0.52 0.89 0.78 0.69 0.75
of Implied Weighted AverInformation for Options on a'
0.72 0.42
0.07 0.08 0.\7 0.09 0.2I 0. I2 0.13 0. I l 0. I 3 0.l8
R2
ß'
-0.88
.08
- I -0.89 0.89 0.72 0.7 I 0.80 0.62
0.80 0.83 0.97 0.93 0.82 0.72
0.69 0.78 0.69 0.74
DERililATIVES
jUMP PROCESSES,
of Implied
Averfor Options on
Weighted
Information
Date
N Options
a'
ß'
R2
2-01-88 2-02-88 2-03-88 2-04-88 2-05-88 2-08-88 2-09-88 2-10-88 2-Il-88 2- I2-88
43 46 21 33 29 40 53 IS 52 29
0.\3 0.03 0.0 I 0.07 0.0 I 0.08 0.13 0.05 0.06 0.04
0.52 0.56 -0.88 0.73 -0.69 0.48 0.62 0.76 0.60 0.62
0.67 0.54 0.87 0.90 0.72 0.49 0.84 0.78 0.7\ 0.40
VOLATILITIES,
SMILE EFFECT
255
between theoretical or model prices (TP) and market prices (MP), expressed in French Francs. The difference is designated YCI. Also, a ratio RCI is calculated by dividing YCI by TP. When the difference is positive, the model price is greater than the market price and vice versa. expressed by RCl lies between 0.01 and 0.2 Results show that the relative mispricing 0.06 for Peugeot, 0.02 and 0.14 for Saint 0.01 Elf Aquitaine, and and Michelin for Gobain, 0.029 and 0.13 for Paribas and Compagnie du Midi, 0.01 and 0.11 for Thomson, and 0.03 and 0.15 for Lafarge (exceptfor some extreme values around 0.2). To quantify the magnitude of mispricing (under-or overevaluation of the option price with respect to the market price), the means and standard deviations of YCI, RCI and Ml were calculated. Results are reported in Tables 11.7 and 11.8, from Bellalah and .
Jacquillat (1995). Subscript l means that options are out-of-the-money.
Subscript 2 refers to at- and inthe-money options. It seems that the model values correctly at- and in-the-money options and misprices out-of-the-inoney. This result is interesting since the B-S model often overvalues out-ofthe-money calls and undervalues in-the-money calls. If information costs are correctly estimated, then calculations of implied volatilities from our model would not show different volatilities for different strike prices. This
TABLE
I I.7
Magnitude
of Mispricing
for Out-of-the-Money
Options
Options
MOY YCII
STD YCII
MOYRCl|
STD RClI
MOY MI\
STD MI i
Paribas Thomson
2.746 40 -0.284 98 5.746 20 5.905 60 1.78063 4. IO9 42 5.\4294 4.46758
3.595 42 2.824 63 8.0 18 44 6.842 65 2.28472 2.52 103 4.81947 3.58582
8.88 I 26 0. I l 6 30 0.66 I 80 0.042 20 0.23979 0.540 35 0.27562 0.67030
4.679 05 0.690 67 0.790 37 0.072 32 0.28931 0.434 13 0.30343 1.52086
-0.200 78 -0. I52 43 -0. I98 57 -0.094 62 -0.08478 -0.102 33 -0.0547\ -0.22227
0.109 2 I 0.|38 I0 0. i08 62 0.04 I 63 0.05334 0.078 80 0.02257 0.13122
Lafarge
Midi Michelin Elf Gobain
TABLE I I.6 Estimates age Costs of incomplete Lafarge
STOCHASTIC
Peugeot
TABLE
I I.8
Magnitude
of Mispricing
for At- and In-the-Money
Options
Options
MOY YCl2
STD YCl2
MOYRCl2
STD RCl2
MOY M/2
STD MI2
Paribas Thomson Lafarge Midi Michelin
3.4 18 70 -0.64 I 22 3.128 59 -0.569 63 2.74482 2.I l842 5.23294 6.577 58
4.095 72 3.464 43 |2.072 844 9.094 69 2.48362 2.155213 5.18147 |4.556 92
0. I3 I 26 -0.020 40 -0.005 02 0.006 94 0.I25 13 0.140 IS 0.14562 0.084 30
0. I83 68 0.|5 I 85 0.222 88 0.035 92 0.I2654 0.10949 0.14937 0. I 59 I l
0.09| 57 0.089 42 0.064 8 i 0.233 02 0.09768 0.l5494 0.02984 0.061 24
0.074 57 0.069 I 3 0.060 02 0. I62 63 0.07422 0.080 23 0.03235 0.050 32
Elf
Gobain Peugeot
256
OPTIONS,
FUTURES
would
AND EXOTIC
mean that an appropriate choice of information costs appearance of the U-shaped curve, known as the smile of volatilitics.
I l.7
VOLATILITY
SMILES: EMPIRICAL
could
STOCHASTIC
257
jUMP PROCESSES,
eliminate
biases. These biases are shown to be more pronounced for foreign exchange options than for stock options. The extensions of the B-S model include constant elasticity of variance processes and jump-diffusion processes to explain some of the option biases. The extension of this model to incomplete markets takes into account the stochastic character of volatilities. strike price bias. However, the This allows in part the explanation of the well-known major drawback of these models is the need to estimate several non-observable parameters which limit their implementation. On top of this, they lose the convenient
the
EVIDENCE
volatility The expected of an underlying asset can be inferred from the option price. Implied volatilities can be taken for different times to maturity and different exercise with rows ordered by prices. Hence, using option prices, a matrix of implied volatilities the exercise price and columns ordered by time to maturity can be constructed. The rows of the implied volatility matrix may provide information about the term structure of expected future volatility. Stein (1989) and Franks and Schwartz (1988) studied the term structure of implied volatilities using only two times to maturity. The time-series studies done by Day and Lewis (in press) used one implied volatility per day and ignored the term structure effects, since time to maturity varies from day to
day Stein (1989)used two daily time series on implied volatilities for the S&Pl00 index options over the period 1983-87. Based on the assumption that the volatility is meanreverting, he concluded that long-maturity options tend to overreact to changes in the implied volatility of short-maturity options. This conclusion has been disputed by other authors who showed that overreaction depends on the model used to represent changes in the volatility. Xu and Taylor (1994)presented and illustrated methods for estimating this term matrix corresponding structure from one row of the implied volatility to nearest-theand its time-series money options. They modeled the term structure of expected volatility properties. They used spot currency options on the British pound, Deutschmark, Japanese yen and Swiss Franc quoted against the US dollar in their empirical work. The study concerned the period from January 1985 to November 1989. The main results appeared in Xu and Taylor (1994). When examining the relation between short- and long-term implied volatilities for the European option exchange index and Philips stock, the principal result in Heynen, Kemma and Vorst's study is that the major determinant for the specification of the term structure of implied volatility relations is the level of the unconditional volatility. This latter seems correctly specified in the case of the EGARCH(l, 1) stock return volatility model. Xu and Taylor's study presented the following results. First, implied volatilities vary significantly across maturities. Second, the direction of the term structure of implied volatilities changes (up or down) nearly once every two or three months. Third, the variations m expectations regarding long-term volatility are significant, although the process of adjustment of expectations is slower than that regarding short-term volatility
uniqueness of pricing of complete markets. This chapter presents recent developments along these lines, especially the models of Merton (1976),Cox and Ross (1976),Hull and White (1988),Stein and Stein (1991), Heston (1993a,1993b) and Hoffman, Platen and Schweizer (1992).From a theoretical point of view, these models are rather interesting. They point out the difficulty of pricing assets in an incomplete market. From a practical point of view, the use of these models is very limited given the burden of parameter estimation to implement them. effect' is reviewed and some of the findings The recent evidence regarding the volatility models. Finally it is noteworthy to are explained with respect to stochastic mention that other models have the potential to explain the smile effect without the use of stochastic volatilities. 'smile
POINTS • • • • • • • • •
FOR DISCUSSION
What are the specificities of the jump-diffusion model? What are the specificities of the constant elasticity of variance model? What are the deficiencies of Hull and White's model? How can we proceed to price options in a stochastic volatility economy? What are the basic assumptions behind Stein and Stein's model? What are the basic assumptions behind Heston's model? What are the basic assumptions behind HPS's model? What are the theoretical reasons for the existence of volatility smiles? What is the empirical evidence regarding volatility smiles?
If (N,),x
is a Poisson process with an intensity 1, then for all t > 0 the random variable N, satisfies: P(N,
=
n)
SUMMARY Also, when s Many authors, well-known
'
e
=
(38)
(At)"
In particular Var(N,)
its
PROCESS
\ I.A: THE POISSON
APPENDIX
E(N,)
The B-S model is the simplest model in the theory of option pnemg however, have tried to relax some of its assumptions in order to explain
SMILE EFFECT
VOLATILITIES,
DERIVATIVES
>
0,
E(sN,
s
O
=
E(N))
=
-
li (E(N,))2
=
At
(39) (40)
l2 The Lattice Approach and the Binomial Model
CHAPTER
OUTLINE
This chapter is organized as follows: 1. In section 12.1, a short survey of numerical techniques in derivative asset valuation is presented and the lattice approach is applied to the valuation of European and American equity and futures options. The treatment of discrete and continuous dividends within the lattice approach is presented. Simulation results are provided. The approach is also extended and applied to the valuation of options in the French market by taking into account the specificities of the Paris Bourse, and in particular, the mechanism. 2. Section 12.2 deals with the pricing of interest rate derivative assets in the context of lattice approaches, First, the Ho and Lee interest rate model is presented and applied to the valuation of derivative assets whose values depend on interest rates. Some of its deficiencies are analyzed. Second, Hull and White's interest rate model is presented. 'report'
INTRODUCTION with the valuation of derivative assets using the binomial or the lattice approach. The valuation of options in a discrete-time setting is more pedagogical than in a continuous time setting. Ironically enough, however, the more complex approach, namely the Black and Scholes one, was discovered before the simple binomial approach. efficient, Even if the discrete-time approach is not always computationally option valuation with the lattice approach is very flexible. It can handle many situations where for the valuation of no analytical solutions are possible. This is the case, for example, stock options and index options when there are several discrete cash payouts made by the underlying asset, such as cash dividends on a stock. The model proposed by Cox, Ross and Rubinstein (1979), hereafter CRR, is one of the It is framed in the context most successful models dealing with derivative asset valuation. of a lattice approach. The model was first proposed for the valuation of stock options. It
This chapter deals
OPTIONS,
260
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
valuation of several derivative assets with complex pay-offs and was then extended to the different underlying assets. The lattice approach has also been used by several authors to model the dynamics of the term structure of interest rates and to value bonds and bond options. There have been using a one-factor many attempts and approaches to describe yield curve movements model. The approach presented by Ho and Lee (1986), in the form of a binomial tree for discount bonds, provides an exact fit to the current term structure of interest rates. Their model is convenient since it takes market data such as the current term structure of interest rates as given. In that respect, it is close to a binomial stock option pricing approach where the current stock price is taken as an input to the model. Unlike most interest rate contingent claims models, this model uses full information on the current term structure. In fact, using an ingenious discrete-time approach for pricing bonds and interest rate contingent claims, Ho and Lee succeeded in incorporating all information about the yield curve in their model. An alternative to the Ho and Lee model was proposed by Black, Derman and Toy (1990)and Hull and White (1993)among others. Black, Derman and Toy (1990) used a binomial tree to construct a one-factor model of of all discount bond yields as well as the the short rate that fits the current volatilities Hull and White (1993)presented a general rates. of interest structure current term numerical procedure involving the use of trinomial trees for constructing one-factor models where the short rate is Markovian and the models are consistent with initial snarket data. Their procedure is efficient and provides a convenient way of implementing models already suggested in the literature. In that respect, their contribution is more a numerical one than a financial theoretical one. This chapter covers binomial and more general lattice approaches for the pricing of equity and interest rate dependent claims.
12.1
LATTICE APPROACHES
12.1.1
A Survey
THE LATTICE
AND THE BINOMIAL
MODEL
26 I
Since then, the CRR approach has been extended and extensively used for the valuation of many contingent claims and options. Rendleman and Barter (1980)applied the CRR methodology to the pricing of options on debt instruments. Trigeorgis (1993) applied the methodology to the valuation of investments with multiple real options and to the pricing of managerial flexibility implicit in investment opportunities. Hull and White (1988, 1993) provided a modified binomial lattice model for the valuation of stock options and interest rate options. Boyle (1986)proposed a trinomial option pricing model in which the stock price can at a given time period. In another move either upwards or downwards or stay unchanged paper, Boyle (1988)showed how a five-jump, three-dimensional lattice can be used for the valuation of options on two underlying assets. Omberg (1988)studied a family of discrete-time jump processes and applied a GaussHermite quadrature technique to derive prices of options on options or compound options. Yisong (1993)modified Boyle's approach by presenting a general methodology that lattice approach. He proposed a modified can be applied to any multi-dimensional approach to the selection of lattice parameters including probabilities and jumps using additional restrictions. Sandmann (1993)developed a model for the pricing of European options under the assumption of a stochastic interest rate in a discrete-time setting. He used a combination of the binomial model for a stock with a binomial model for the spot interest rate. Rubinstein (1994)developed a new method for inferring risk-neutral probabilities or option prices from observed market prices. These probabilities were used to infer a binomial tree by implementing a simple backward recursive procedure. However, the approach is restricted to European options, and future research remains to be done regarding the pricing of American options.
12.1.2
for the pricing of Various numerical procedures have been proposed by many researchers derivative securities. These procedures include the lattice approach, finite difference schemes and the Monte-Carlo method, among others. When pricing European options, equivalent to these procedures are, under certain specific conditions, asymptotically closed-form solutions à la Black and Scholes. However, they may be more practical for the pricing of American options and complex derivative securities. In fact, these approaches can handle more complex situations such as cash dividend payouts. this chapter, In we are interested in the lattice approach pioneered by CRR (1979)· These authors proposed a binomial model in a discrete-time setting for the valuation of framework, their approach was based on the construction options. Using the risk-neutral argument, of a binomial lattice for stock prices. They applied the risk-neutral valuation pioneered by B-S, which simply means that one can value the option at hand as if With an appropriate choice of the binomial parameters, they investors were risk-neutral. result established of their model to that of B-S. a convergence
APPROACH
The Model for Options
on a Spot Asset without
any
Payouts
The lattice approach can be introduced by first looking at a stock option whose underlying asset does not pay any dividend. Let T be the option's maturity date which is divided into N reasonably small intervals of length At, so that T NAt. During each time interval, the stock price moves either upwards from S to uS or downwards from S to dS. This movement in the stock price is binomial with a probability p attached to an upward jump and a probability (1 p) to a downward movement. The binomial process can be represented as shown in Figure 12.1. The parameters u, d and p are functions of the mean and variance of the rates of return on S during the interval At. Indeed, intuition has it that the larger the spread between u and d, the greater is the variance of the return on S. world, it is possible to show that model parameters must satisfy the In a risk-neutral following relations: =
u
=
e
(1)
OPTIONS,
262
FUTUftEGdilMIN
1|Il Ti AIMllM¥ATIVES
THE LATTICE
Su
AND THE BINOMIAL
APPROACH
At time T, the call's value
P
is given by the
MODEL
263
maximum
between its intrinsic
value
and
zero: C,
=
max
[0, S, -
K]
2
-
or 1-p
Sd
gg.t
=max[0,SudN-j
C,
At the same date, the put's pay-off is given by
Price
gefetmAsset
d
p
e-c,m
=
=
a
Pr
(2)
e'*'
(3) (4)
=
u - d
The stock value at each node is given by Su d' for the value of S is observed, at instant t + At it takes takes on three values, and at instant t + iAt it takes stock price dynamics over three periods. The value of a call option, C,_, (or a put, P(i, j)), starting from date T, where the option terminal backward through the tree.
j
on two values, at instant t + 2At it i values. Figure 12.2 represents the
-
.
at time /
iAt can be calculated by pay-off is known, and proceeding
=
[0, K
- Sr]
max
[0, K
SuddN-j
-
Since in a risk-neutral world, the option's value is given by its expected pay-off discounted at an appropriate risk-free interest rate for the length of time considered, it is possible to calculate the option value at each node using the following equation: Cy for 0
=
'
'[pC,
e
+
(1 -
p)C,
,]
(7)
i GN - 1 and 0 sje also for a put. i. This relationship If the option is of the American type, then its price must at least be equal to its intrinsic value. For an American call, the condition applies
r, we do not discount the dividends: 9* 10*
S(4. 4) - S*(u'd°) S(4, 3)
=
S*(u'd')
14*
P(5, 0)
=
15*
P(4, 0)
=
max
[0, K
- S(5, 0)]
[pP(5, l) + qP(5, 0)]
The European put price with dividends is equal to 5.8190.
a
OFTIONS,
268
FUTURES
XOT1C
AND
DERIVATIVES
THE LAT I gbAPPRO
10144
ID HE BINOMIAI.. MODEL
0
0.0000 0
.0.0248
0.0000
0.0248
0.0508
1.1294
269
1.2186
0.0508 16*
0.1040
2.2861
3.1876
4.6266
5,3610
58190
5.633Ï
6.0633 9.3621
8.6183
8.6274
5.0000 17*
8.9441
13.2485
12.5047 16.7111
15.9673
19.7961
22.5446 14*
12.6
Put Price with
European
The American
22;5446
Figure
Dimitiends
Put Price with Dividends
a
-
-
For the put price, P(i, j)
=
max
{[pP(i
For example, the values 16*
17
P(4, 4)
P(4, 3)
+ 1, j + 1) + qP(i + 1, j)] a; max
at nodes
- S(i, j)]}
16* and 17* (Figure 12.7) are calculated
=
max
max [0; 45 {0.0508;
=
max
(0.0508;0)
max
max [0; 45 {4.6266;
=
[0, K
=
-
(20)
as follows:
50.3914]}
0.0508 -
40]}
=
max
(4.6266; 5)
=
5
The price of the American put when there are dividends is 6.0633. The difference between the American price and the European price corresponds to the early exercise premium.
12.7
American Put Price
The Model for American
Options
in the French
with
Dividends
distributions. This model is fully developed in Bellalah (1995b). The stocks are traded in the RM market, the Marché à Règlement Mensuel, and present 13 cash payments per year in the form of report, déport and dividends. When there is a déport, the stock price is reduced by the amount of déport in the same way as for dividends. Therefore, it can be handled as a dividend. When there is a report, the stock price rises by the amount of report. These cash distributions can induce early exercise of American options. Since 10 September 1987 American options on stocks and stock indices have been negotiated on the Paris options market, called the MONEP, Marché des Options Négociables de la Bourse de Paris. The market is organized under the authority of the Conseil des Bourses des Valeurs. In April 1992, 27 classes of stock options were traded. and Eurotunnel Each option contract implies 100 stocks except for Euro-Disneyland where lots of 500 shares are used. The underlying RM market quoted 240 stocks in 1992. Since 1991, long-term options have been traded on the CAC40 index. .
The RM Market 12.1.6
1$.7111
16.ËW7
19.4226 15*
Figure
9.3621
8.9887
12.8Ì51
12.1375
0.1040
2.4685
3.3657
and the Report
Mechanism
Market
The RM
of the basic lattice approach to the valuation of This subsection provides an extension American options traded in the Paris Bourse when there are many discrete cash
market can be regarded as a forward market since the buyer (the seller) of a stock at an instant t pays (receives)and takes delivery of (delivers)the asset at a specified date t,, known as the liquidation. The liquidation day corresponds to the sixth day
OPTIONS,
270
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
preceding the last trading day of the month. The buyer assumes a long position and agrees to buy the stock at a specified future date for a specified price, which is the stock price at instant t. The seller assumes a short position and agrees to sell the stock on the same date for a specified quoted price at t. On the liquidation day, the buyer pays and takes delivery of the stock and the seller receives the payment and delivers the stock. If the buyer (seller)decides to maintain his long (short)position, he can defer the maturity of the initial transaction to the next liquidation date, and so on. The Franc amount of the long net position often exceeds the short net position (nearly 10 times). Hence, if the short investor has no difnculty in obtaining the stocks from the long one, the long investor may not have enough money to defer his or her position for the next month. There is another group of investors who accept delay on the long positions by buying the stocks for one month from the long positions and selling them the next month. This operation is realized at a price called the report. For some stocks, it may happen that the short position exceeds the long position. In this case, there is a shortage of capital to defer the long net position and stocks are necessary for the delay of short positions. In this case, there is a déport. Each stock traded in the RM market gives the right to the long or short investor to pay or receive at liquidation a cash amount called the report and sometimes the déport. Also, each stock provides unknown cash incomes 13 times per year corresponding to 12 reports or déports and a dividend. For the CAC40 stock index, there are 520 unknown cash income distributions a year. The Modified
Lattice
Options traded in the Paris Bourse can be priced by an extension ofthe basic lattice approach pioneered by CRR and extended by Hull and White. In fact, if we suppose the existence of only an ex-report date t', the following condition must be added in the lattice approach: '^6
S(t) - R, e S(t)
if ts t' if t > T'
(21)
kAt < t' s (k + l)At, where R, stands for the amount of report or déport. This amount is positive for a report and negative for a déport. asset values can Hence, at each day of liquidation, at an instant t + iAt, the underlying be written as with
(S*(t)uíd'i-Roe
S'(t)uid'
i
'^6
ifAt0
(28)
THE LATTICE
Example
APPROACH
AND THE BINOMIAL
MODEL
275
2
and "(T l)]P"'(l) (29) - l)+ (1 -X)P value bond discounted by This equation shows that the bond price equals the the prevailing one-period rate. Hence, x may be interpreted as the implied risk-neutral probability. Assuming that the discount function evolves from one state to another dependmg only assuming that a on the number of upward and downward movements is equivalent to downward movement followed by an upward movement is equivalent to an upward movement followed by a downward movement, This is the path independence condition which gives rise to the following values of h and h*: P)"'(T)
"(T
[xP
=
'expected'
.
.
h(T)
1/[x + (I - x)ör]
=
for T
>
0
(30)
Consider the following parameters the Ho and Lee model:
The current
x +
Poo(3)
TABLE
(l
-
x)ö r
=
=
=
funtion: Poo(3)
=
TABLE
The Term
12.7
T Poo(K) Pio(K) Pii(K) P20(K) P2,(K) P22(K) Pao(K) P3|(K) P,,(K) Ps3(K) P4o(K) P4 (K)
I | 1 I I I | 1 I I I i
1
=
Poo(4)
0.98260 0.97923 0.98514 0.97570 0.98|64 0.98756 0.97235 0.97822 0.984\2 0.99006 0.969I5 0.97500 0 98 0.99276
Poo(2)
0.9826, =
0.9651
=
Poo(5)
0.9296,
=
0.9119
e (g)
in the Ho and Lee Model, Example
Structure
/
0
( P (K)
Poo(l)
0.9474,
12.8
Poo(K) Rio(K) Po(K) P2o(K) P2i(K) Pa(K) Pao(K) P3;(K) P32(K) Ps(K) P4e(K) P4,(K) P42(K) P43(K)
.
1,
0.5, t
=
365 days.
(Table 12.8) is specified
term structure Poo(0)
Consider the following parameters for the determination of discount functions in 0.5, t 365 days. 4, ó 0.994, Jr the Ho and Lee model: n The current term structure (Table 12.7) is specified by the following discount =
=
by the following discount
.
f
Poo(0)
0.994, x
=
function:
This model is convenient since it uses all information available in the current term structure of interest rates. Besides, only two parameters need to be estimated.
=
4, ö
=
=
1,
Poo(l)
0.941,
The Term
=
Poo(4)
Structure
Poo(2)
0.982, =
0.921,
=
Poo(5)
0.961 =
0.911
in the Ho and Lee Model,
Example
2
T0/2345
h*(T)=
Example
=
n
for the determination of discount functions in
2 6 0.95837 0.96997 0.95l64 0.963I6 0.97482 0.94520 0.95664 0.96823 0.97995
3 0.94740
0.93752 0.95460 0.92780 0.94477 0.96198
4 0.929 0.91687 0.9392\
I 1 I
I I 1 I I i I i I I I i
0.98200 0.97567 0.98155 0.97320 0.97917 0.98508 0.9699 I 0.97576 0.98165 0.98758 0.97720 0.983 I 3
0.96 l00 0.95248 0.96604 0.94680 0.95832 0.96992 0.95069 0.96220 0.97385 0.98564
0.94 l00
0.92941 0.94634
0.92100 0.91653 0.93886
0.9 I 100
0.93090 0.94786 0.96513
0.98907 0.99504 i
I
5
12.2.2
The Ho and Lee Model for Contingent
Consider the valuation of
a contingent
Claims
claim C, with a maturity date Tand pay-off
such that C(T, i)
=
f(i)
for 0
6
i GT
f(i) (31)
Let C(n, i) stand for the contingent claim value at time n and state i. The contingent claim has a minimal value L and a maximum value U such that at time n and state i, L(n, i), C(n, i) and U(n, i) satisfy the following relationship: L(n, i)
The holder of this
contingent
=
'
(29)
a
e"f(y)dy
p2B
f(y|x) dy N(-xi
and K, it is convenient
x
+U2
-x2
,
=
In(Sid
KR
')+(a
e"f(x) dx
,
p)
ln(S2d
KR
')
(37)
y
times the expected
fmal
value
of Sr, under the conditions
times the expected
final
value
of
=
to
Sr,
> K and
Sr,
> K and
ln(S d '/S2d
')
ln(S2d '/Sid
')
=
S R
'
R
'
ST,
under the conditions
Ï
Sg>S •
f(x y)dx
(28)
2
Since the option value depends on the positions of Sr,, S, break the pay-off into three components: Ii
yi, pi)]
S2d [N(y2) - N(-x2, y2, KR
e' f(x) dx
(34)
'
=
dy
with
with
•
f( y|x)
_
13
y) is the bivariate density function given by
-x
"
S2R
In(Sr /S2)
y=
ln(K/Si)
'""2/
=
with x
*
Sid '[N(yi) - N(-xi,
=
where
*
'
Si R
=
that K > Sr, and K >
times the probability
(x) (y)
1
'72"!
e
=
e
1/2"!
and the followmg conditional
x-µit
with
v
=
with
v
=
(3l )
(x y)
(y|x)
~1/2
2x(1
p2)a
-
e
e-w2/2
=
2x(1
-
¯ wa
With
p2)o2t
Using these densities li, I2 and 13 can be written
«2
p(y _ y ¿p2
1 - p2)t
w2
=
[(y -
#21)
a,
P(I
"1
agl as
+
jÏ
(39)
+
jÏv
(40)
-2paia2
(41) pa, - a
The value of the option delivering the best of two assets and cash Cb2ac
i
Options
on the Minimum
2
3
(42) is
(43)
of Several Assets
(Ma×imum)
Johnson (1987)extended the results of Stulz to the pricing of options on the maximum or the minimum of several risky assets. His model is based on some results that appeared in the B-S model, the Cox and Ross approach, Margrabe's model and Merton's model. Remember that in the B-S model, the stock price and the strike price are multiplied by N(di) and N(d2). In the Cox and Ross approach, N(d2) is considered as the probability that the stock price at expiration, ST, will be greater than the strike price K, given that the stock price is S today. If a trick based on a device introduced in Margrabe is used, then the N(di) term can be written down immediately without laborious calculation. In fact, a call option can be regarded as an option to exchange cash (thestrike price) for the common stock. Hence, it .
a_I
1
(a
(30)
densities:
=
a
po2 - a
ST,.
This decomposition allows us to write the option value as the sum of the three compo¯ nents li + 12 13 with the following densities: =
=o
+
- p2)t
-
#i t)]
(32)
,
(33)
.
.
OPTIONS,
320
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
RAINBOW
DERIV
121
OPTIONS
The call price can be valued as in Margrabe by taking the stock price as a numeracy. measured in units of the stock price can be regarded as a European put on a risky asset with unit strike price and zero interest rate. with current price x (K/S)e price' is just the risk free In this context, the stock price measured in units of the asset. Using Itõ's lemma for dx and replacing the drift term with zero in the Cox and Ross approach, Johnson showed that N(d,) N(-dí) where '
=
,
'stock
=
d'= This procedure
Si, S2, S3, For n
=
is applied
to value
calls on the maximum
(minimum) of
n assets '
So, with a strike price K and a maturity date T 2, the formula presented by Johnson reduces to that of Stulz.
.
.
(d, D)
(d, C ) FIGURE 15.1
The First Move
.,
From the return (u, B), the second return which gives a total return of 15.1.2
The Discrete
Approach
(u, B){(u,
In this section, we present briefly the discrete time approach proposed by Rubinstein (1994)for the valuation of European and American rainbow options. These options can be valued by constructing a square binomial pyramid. We show first how to construct the binomial pyramid and then apply the approach to the valuation of an American call option on a spread. The following additional notations are used: R:
bi: ö2: K:
the annualized the annualized the annualized a fixed arnount
discrete interest return, discrete pay-out return for asset 1, discrete pay-out return for asset 2, of cash potentially received at expiration.
A),
(u, B), (d,
C),
(d, D)}
=
can again be
A),
(u, B), (d, C), (d, D)}
=
A),
(u, B), (d, C), (d,
D)}
=
(u, A), (u, B), (d, C)
(ud, AC), (ud, BC), (d2, C2), (d',
From the return (d, D), the second return can agam be which gives a total return of
(d, D){(u,
2
The First Move As in standard binomial trees, we assume the returns to the first asset to be either u or d with the same probability. When the first asset moves to u, the second asset has returns A or B with equal probability. When the first assset moves to d, the second asset has returns C or D with equal probability. Hence, starting at (1, 1), the four pairs (u, A), (u, B), attained with an equal probability of I /4. The first move can be represented as shown in Figure 15.1.
(d,
The Second Move From the first return (u, A), the second (u, A), (u, B), (d, C) or (d, D) which gives a total return of
return
C),
(d,
D)}
=
C) and
(d, D)
(u2, A2), (u2, AB), (ud, AC), (ud,
again
B
,
)
(u, B )
(ud, BD)
are
(44)
(d, D)
(ud, BC)
|
be
(d AD)
(u
AB )
(ud, AC)
(d, C) can
,
(ud AD )
(u, A )
assets.
2
2
2
(u
)
RGURE
15.2
,
(d
C )
The Second
Move
(d, D)
or
(d,
D)
(46) (d, D)
(ud, AD), (ud, BD), (d2, CD), (d2,D2) (47)
2
A
,
For the sake of simplicity, we standardize the returns of the two underlying assets to the pair (1, 1) and consider what happens in the first and second moves of the two underlying
(u, B), (d,
CD)
Note that a probability of l 16 is attributed to each of these 16 pairs. These different pairs can be represented as shown in Figure 15.2.
(u
A),
or
(u, A), (u, B), (d, C)
The Binomial Pyramid
(u, A){(u,
or
(u2,AB), (u2, B2), (ud, BC), (ud, BD) (45)
From the return (d, C), the second return can again be which gives a total return of
(d, C){(u,
(u, A), (u, B), (d, C)
,
CD
)
(d
2 ,
D
2
)
322
OPTIONS,
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
Constructionof the Pyramid
Let a horizontal slice of the square pyramid represent total returns after each move. When we set (1, 1) at the apex and the last move at the bottom of the square pyramid, then several paths through the pyramid lead to the same node. Since by assumption, AD BC, four paths reach the central node. When there are n moves, the total number of distinct nodes at the bottom is (1 + n)2. Now, to construct the appropriate move sizes in a square binomial pyramid, the following values of (u, d), A, B, C and D are used:
RAINBOW
OPTIONS
value
Finally, the option Csee
=
323
at the initial time is given by
max [(S2 - Si) - K,
C(u, B) + C(d, C) + C(d, D)]}/Rh
A)
({C(u,
(55)
=
"I
e" A
=
D
',
eu"""2
=
d
,
=
B
a
=
e""
"
C
=
""
e'""""
15.2
SIMULATIONS
(48)
15.2.1
Calls on the Minimum
(49)
Tables 15.1 and 15.3 show the effect of a change in the correlation coefficient for 10%, r 1700, k 1700, V 1700, r 0.25, as 0.3 and av 0.3 for Call H 122.75 and for Call H 122.75 and 35.62 respectively. For example, using Table V 29.64. Table 15.2 shows the effect of a change in the volatility 15.1, when p 0.7, c.;, 0.15. for the same parameter values except av =
where
=
=
=
=
µi
of,
In(rföi)
=
ö2) -
µ2 - M
h
=
(¤
t/n
(50) (51)
Using the above expressions, it is possible to proceed as in the standard bmomial model by starting at the end and discounting each four nodes into one at each move with the same probability
at each node
=
=
=
=
Coefficient: TABLE 15.1 Effect of a Change in the Correlation 10%, r 0.3, Call on H 1700, K 1700, r 0.25, oH 0.3, av Y= 122.75 =
=
(1/4).
=
=
=
=
=
=
H 1700, Y 122.75, Call on =
=
=
.0
p
of the Model
Application
Call H
of an American call option on a spread. At the expiration date, the pay-off of the option on a spread is
Consider the
valuation
Cs, When n
=
=
max
2, the move tree at expiration
C(u2, A2) C(u2, AB)
=
=
C(u2, B2)
=
C(ud, A C)
=
C(ud, BC)
=
C(ud, AD)
=
C(ud,
=
BD)
C(d2, C2)
=
C(d2, D2)
=
Sr
[0, (Sr,2 -
K]
)-
callV
0.4
0,5
0.6
0.7
0.8
0.9
l 22.75 I22.75
I22.75 I22.75 3.3 I
)22.75 I22.75 I5.64
| 22.75 I22.75 29.64
122.75 I22.75 46.64
l 22.75 I22.75 68.82
O
cas,
I
(52)
shows the following call option values:
2) - K, 0] max [(S2A2 _ S u2) max [(S2AB - S - K, 0] 2) [(S2B2 - K, 0] max - S ud) [(S2A S C max - K, 0]
-
max [(S2BC - S ud) - K, 0] max [(S2AD - S ud) - K, 0] max [(S2BD - Siud) - K, 0] max [(S2
2
Triax[(S2D2
-
-
Sid2) Sid2)
-
K, 0]
- K, 0]
When we go back one move, we get the following values:
TABLE I 5.2 Effect of a Change in the Volatility: 10%, r 0.25, «H 1700, r 1700, V 1700, K I22.75, Call on V 73.97 0.15, Call on H av ro
p Call H Call V com
H 0.3, =
=
=
=
=
.
=
=
=
=
0.6
0.7
0.8
0.9
122.75 73.97 0
122.75 73.97 5.67
122.75 73.97 |4.02
122.75 73.97 22.6 I
in the Correlation TABLE 15.3 Effect of a Change 1700, V 1700, K 1700, r 10%, Coefficient: H 35.62, Call on 0.3, av 0.3, Call on H 0.25, as r V 122.75 =
=
=
=
=
=
=
=
=
C(u, A)
=
C(u, B)
=
C(d, C)
=
C(d, D)
=
AD)]} R max [(S2A - Siu) - K,¼{ C(u2, A2) + C(u2, AB) + C(ud, AC) + C(ud, R^ max [(S2B - Siu) - K,¼{C(u2, ßA) + C(u2, ß2) + C(ud, BC) + C(ud, BD)]} max [(SaC - Sid) - K, max [(S2D -
({C(du,
CA)
C(du, Cß) + C(d2, C2) + C(d2, CD)]} R
Sid) - K,¼{ C(du, DA) + C(du, DB) + C(d2, DC) + C(d2, U
p Call H Call V c
0.5
0.6
0.7
0.8
0.9
0.99
35.62 122.75 0
35.62 122.75 5.06
35.62 122.75 13.f4
35.62 122.75 22.32
35.62 122.75 3I.91
35.62 122.75 35.6i
I22.75 I22.75 122.70
324
OPTIONS,
I 5.2.2
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
RAINBOW
Calls on the Maximum
TABLE I 5.7 Effect of a Change in the Correlation 0.3 0.25, ÜH 0.3, av I0%, r I700, r |700, K =
Tables 15.4-15.6 show similar data to Tables 15.1-15.3 for calls on the maximum. For example, using Table 15.4, when p 198.86. 0.8, ca,,x c c
TABLE 15.4 Effect of a Change in the Correlation Coefficient: I 0%, r 0.3, Call on H 0.25, «H 0.3, av I 700, K 1700, r V I 22.75 =
=
=
=
H 1700, V I 22.75, Call on =
=
=
=
p
=
=
=
325
OPTIONS
0.4
0.5
0.6
0
3.3 I I598.36 62.97
I 5.64 I609.07 64.58
I588.68 69.341
po
Coefficient:
H
=
I 700, Y
=
=
=
0.7 29.64 I62|.24 66.42
0.8
0.9
46.64 I635.68 68.983
68.82 i654.54 72.336
I.0 I22.70 1699.99 8.73
--
=
TABLE I 5.8 Effect of a Change in the Volatility: 10%, r 0.25, 1700, K 1700, V 1700, r H 0.I5 0.3, av as
-----
p Call H Call V casa,
0.4
0.5
0.6
0.7
0.8
0.9
I22.75 I22.75 245.50
I22.75 I22.75 242.I8
I22.75 I22.75 229.86
I22.75 I22.75 2I5.75
I22.75 |22.75 198.86
I22.75 I22.75 I76.68
.0
I
=
=
I22.75 122.75 I22.75
Poun
=
=
=
=
=
=
p Call H Call V c
0.7
0.8
0.9
122.75 73.97 196.73
122.75 73.97 191.05
122.75 73.97 182.7
122.75 73.97 174.12
15.3 15.3.1
=
=
=
=
r*:
S:
=
Call H Calli V cas,
0.5
35.62 122.75 158.38
0.6
0.7
0.8
0.9
0.99
APPLICATIONS Pricing
Currency
the the the the
Bonds
firm's value in domestic currency, bond's face value in foreign currency, riskless rate of interest in foreign currency, spot exchange rate.
35.62 |22.75 l53.3l
35.62 122.75 145.24
35.62 |22.75 |36.05
35.62 122.75 126.46
35.62 |22.75 122.75
B*(V
Tables 15.7 and 15.8 show similar data to Tables 15.4 and 15.5 for puts on the minimum K For example, using Table 15.7, when p 0.8, the discounting factor e 1658.026, cas, 46.64, c 1635.68 and p.,, 68.983. =
=
22.6 I 1639.83 40.8
=
=
S, K*, r)
(l/S)cssas(V,
=
H, 0, r)
(56)
In fact, Stulz showed that casos(V, H, 0, r) corresponds to a standard call with K 1, r 0, and underlying asset price V H. Since c,sise(V, H, 0, r) is a decreasing function of o2, the bond's value is also a decreasing function of the volatility of the firm's value and the exchange rate value. Using the interest rate parity theorem
Puts on the Minimum
=
I4.02 \631.78 40.26
At maturity, the bond's pay-off is given by min ( V, SK*) where SK* is uncertain. K* be the price of a zero-coupon Let H(t) bond at t paying SK* at T Let S(t)e B*(V/S, K*, r) be the value of the foreign currency bond (in foreign currency). It is possible to show that this bond's value is also equal to the product of a standard European call option and the inverse of the exchange rate, i.e.
=
15.2.3
5.67 1624.59 39.103
0.9
=
=
>
0 1618.032 39.99
0.8
A currency bond is a bond denominated in a different currency from that prevailing in the country in which the common stock of the firm is traded. To price this simple form of currency bonds, we use the following notation:
TABLE I 5.6 Effect of a Change in the Correlation Coefficient: H I 0%, I 700, V I 700, K I 700, r 0.25, as 0.3, Call on H 35.62, Call on 0.3, av Y V I 22.75 =
0.7
H 0.3,
V: K*: =
=
=
=
=
0.6
=
0.6
p cm c
TABLE I 5.5 Effect of a Change in the Volatility: 1700, K 10%, r 0.25, «H 1700, Y 1700, r 0.15, Call on H 122.75, Call on V 73.97 av
=
=
=
=
=
(t,
T)
=
S(t)e"
'
"
(57)
OPTIONS,
326
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
f(t, T) stands for the forward exchange rate at t for a delivery at T, it is possible to show that H depends on f(t, T). Using this relationship, H can also be written as
where
RAINBOW
OPTIONS
327
When V > SK* > K, the option on the minimum pays SK* - K, and when V > K > SK* it pays nothing. If SK* > V > K, the bond value is V and the portfolio K} value is K + {min(V, H) V. =
H
=
f(t,
T)e "K*
(58)
It follows that the higher the forward exchange rate and the higher the expected future spot exchange rate, the higher the bond's price. This result is immediate when changes in exchange rate are certain. In fact, in this context, the bond is assimilated to a bond in a domestic currency with a fixed strike price f(t, T)K*. Hence, an increase in the forward rate increases the bond's face value in domestic currency.
I 5.3.2
Bonds
Multi-Currency
g*) be the Let S4(Ss) be the current price of one unit of currency of counti) A (B) and rA riskLless inSt est rSateKinc' r) st nd fr the discount bond's price, giving the option to the KA* units of currency of maturity, either K units of domestic currency, or at get bearer, to * country A, or Ka units of currency of country B. A portfolio comprising a domestic * * discount bond, two options on SAK, and SaKa, with the same strike price K, and an * * and exactly the same pay-off as this option SaKa, gives the of minimum S,K, option on bond. If we define the values of two assets H and Vas ·
H
=
V then the bond's
value
exp
4
exp(-rat)SaKb
(59) 4
(60)
is
B(SAKi, where
=
(-r,*r)S,Ki
SaK,*, K, r)
=
cniax(V, H, K, r)+
Ke
"
(61)
cmax(V, H, K, r) stands for the price of a European option on the maximum of V date r.
and H, with a strike price K and a maturity
15.3.4
Spread
Options
A standard spread option entitles its holder the right to call or put the spread value against and corresponds in general to the difference between two a predetermined strike price prices. Examples of spread option include spreads in futures markets, bond markets and energy markets. Spread options in futures markets refer, for example, to the spread or the basis between Nebraska's corn and Chicago's corn. This spread may be due to location or grade, among other things. Spread options in bond markets may be due to the differences issued in different countries. Spread options in energy in yield spreads between bonds markets result from the differences between, for example, refmed and unrefined products, such as crack spreads. Spread options can be defined by using two underlying assets, contracts or commodities which are closely related. This correlation between the assets or commodities results from demand substitution or the potential for transformation. Spread options have the following pay-off: .
.
.
cspa
=
max
{0,¢(Se
-
S
)-
¢K}
(63)
-1
the binary variable ¢ takes the value l for a call and for a put. Even though the models proposed above allow the valuation of spread options, there are pros and cons to these approaches, since, as shown by Garman (1992),the valuation of these options is rather complex. Besides, they present the paradox of negative where
vegas.
15.3.5
Portfolio
Options
Portfolio options have the followmg pay-off 15.3.3
Corporate
Option
Bonds
=
c,
Let B(V, SK*, K, t) stand for the price of an option bond issued by a corporation. The issuer gives the bearer the option at maturity to choose between payments of K* units of the foreign currency and K units of the domestic currency. The bond's pay-off is equivalent to that of a portfolio comprising a discount bond with K*, with Se face value K, an option on the minimum of Vand H a strike price K and a sale of a standard European put on Kwith the same strike price. In this context, the bond's price is given by
where
15.3.6
max
{0,¢(niS,
+
n2ST,)
¢K}
-
(64)
to the number of units of the two assets
ni and n2 correspond
in the
portfolio.
Dual-Strike Options
=
Dual-strike options have the following pay-off: cm
B(V, K, SK*, r) At maturity, the currency
=
Ke
" -
option is worthless
P(V, K, r) + cos(V, when
H, K, r)
the firm's value is smaller than K-
(62)
=
max
{0,¢(Sc
- Ki),
¢(ST,
-
K2)}
where the binary variables ¢i and ¢2 take the values 1 or -1. For the valuation of these options, see the numerical techniques
(65) in Boyle et aL (1989).
FUTURi!BAlglþEKOTICOERIVATIVES
OPTIONS,
328
I 5.3.7
Options
Delivery
OPTIONS
329
computations involving integrations over n - 1 dimensional multivariate normal integrals. His simulations show that the impact of the quality option increases as the number of deliverable assets increases. For example, for 10 deliverable assets, the impact is nearly twice as large as in the case when there are just four assets.
Options
and Wildcard Assets
with N Deliverable
QualityOptions
RAINBOW
Consider a futures contract allowing the seller to choose at maturity between n assets for delivery. The seller will choose among these underlying assets and deliver the cheapest. When there is just one deliverable asset, a long forward contract to purchase that asset is equivalent to a portfolio containing a long European call and a short European put on one unit of the asset for which the strike price is the equilibrium forward price. When there are two deliverable assets, the forward contract value is equivalent to a long call on the minimum of the two assets and a short put on the minimum of these assets. These relations can be generalized for n assets. Following Boyle (1988),we use the following notations: '
-
in Futures Contracts
The Timing Option
Timing options are embedded in many futures contracts, offering the seller some flexibility concerning the timing of the actual delivery. In fact, delivery may take place on any business day within the delivery month. Following Boyle (1989),let the short position deliver the underlying asset at any time during the interval (t + Ti, t + T3) where t + T3 is the maturity date of the futures contract. Suppose delivery occurs at time t + T2 and Ti < T2 3Let F[t, (Ai), t+ Ti)] Fi be the futures price at time t of a futures contract on an asset with a current price Ai and having a maturity date of t + Ti. In a similar way, let F[t, (A2), t + T2] F2 be the futures price at time t of a futures contract on an asset with with price A2 current a a maturity date t + T2. Using arbitrage arguments, it can be shown that F2 must be equal to Fi. In this case, the timing option is nil and the short position should optimally deliver the asset at the first permitted opportunity. The value of Fi is obtained from the cost of carry model, so that =
t: t + T: A;(t): f[t, (Ai, A2,
the current time, the delivery date, the current asset price for i 1 to n, the forward price at t giving to the short side the t + B: choice among the n assets, A,), K, t TJ:a European call price on the minimum of n deliverable assets As), K, t + T]: a European put price on the minimum of n assets. =
n), ·
·
->
C
[t, (Ai,
A2,
P
[t, (A i, A2,
...,
=
'
...,
Since the interest rate r is constant, the futures price is equal to the corresponding forward price. In the case of two or more assets, the value of the forward contract can be expressed in terms of a long call and a short put as C
is,,[t,
(Ai, A2,
A,,), K, t+
•••,
T]-
Pass,,[t, (Ai, A2,
As), K, t+
...,
T]
(66)
At inception, the value of the forward contract is zero and the strike price K is equal to As), t+ T]. the forward price: f[t, (Ai, A2, By analogy with the simple case of two assets and using the extended put-call parity theorem m Stulz, expression (66)can be written as ...,
.
Coss,,[t, (Ai, A2,
A,), 0, t+
...,
T] - Ke
'
(67)
A,), 0, t + T) stands for the European call on the minimum where C (t, (Ai, A2, of n assets having a zero strike price. Since the forward's contract value at inception is zero, it is possible to write ...,
[t, (Ai,
A2,
...,
A,), t + T]
' =
e
C
,,[t,
(Ai, A2,
...,
An), 0, t+
T]
(68)
Hence, the forward price is given by the discounted value of the European call option on the minimum of the n assets with a time to maturity T + t and a zero strike price. For 2, it is possible to use the Stulz formula. For n a 2, the Johnson formula can be n =
used. To compute the value of the quality option, Boyle (1989) assumed that all assets have the and are equi-correlated, the same current price and volatility so he simplified
Fi
=
Ai(t)e'
Since the seller is committed to deliver during the delivery window, and there are no gains from waiting, F2 iS also equal to Fi. This result holds when there is no distribution to the underlying asset. However, if there is more than one deliverable asset, it is no longer true that the futures price when there is a timing option is equal to the futures price assuming earliest delivery. regarding In fact, when there is an uncertainty the asset to deliver, it could happen that the first asset is the cheapest to deliver under the futures contract without the timing option, whereas the second asset is the cheaper at time t + A2. Hence, there may be an interaction between the timing option and the quality option in the presence of at least two deliverable assets. Boyle (1989) developed a bmomial lattice framework to value the timing option where at each node, delivery is assumed to occur if it minimizes the contract value. He concluded that the impact of the timing option on the futures price is rather small. However, it is convenient to note that his model does not apply to Treasury bond futures contracts since it ignores coupon payments and it may be more appropriate to commodity .
.
.
.
.
futures. Analysis and Valuation
of Wildcard
Options
Anolysis of Wildcard Options Fleming and Whaley (1994)analyzed and priced wildcard options embedded in the S&Pl00 index option contract, OEX. The OEX wildcard options arise because the settlement price is given with reference to the S&Pl00 index level at 3:00 pm Central Standard Time (CST), at the close of the New York Stock Exchange, while the option holder may postpone the exercise decision until 3:20 pm. If the market rises (falls) during this wildcard period of 20 minutes, the holder of a
OPTIONS,
330
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
slightly in-the-money put option (or call) may find it optimal to exercise his option. Since the wildcard option is linked to the exercise procedure, it appears each day between 3:00 and 3:20 pm until the option's maturity date. Hence, there is a wildcard option sequence which must be taken into account when pricing S&Pl00 index option contracts. that builds upon the standard Fleming and Whaley (1994)provided a methodology CRR (1979)binomial model for valuing American-style options to price the embedded early exercise premium, which is options. They applied their model to the wildcard value with embedded wildcard American option the difference between defined as an options and an American option without this privilege. Their results show that the wildcard premium is an important component of an OEX option value. It accounts, for example, for about 12 cents of the value of slightly in-the-money call and put options. Also, wildcard premiums are approximately the same for calls and puts with the same and time to expiration. They show that the wildcard value increases with time moneyness and that it accounts for more than 2% of an at-the-money to expiration and moneyness option value. Their analysis suggests that the wildcard privilege is even more valuable for derivative securities for which the wildcard period is hours or sometimes days. proposed by Fleming and Whaley (1994) Valuation o¶Wildcard Options The methodology for the valuation of American S&Pl00 index options uses simultaneously the lattice approach proposed by CRR (1979)and a modified version of the B-S model. First, the number of time steps m in the lattice is selected in such a way that the end of each time step coincides with the end of each wildcard period. Hence, when valuing an OEX call which has an end-of-day wildcard option, the number m is set equal to the number of days to the option expiration. option is Second, at each node j in each time step m, the value of the wildcard calculated and added to the present value of the expected future's option value. When proceeding backward from the end of the tree to a node just before, an American call value is calculated using the following formula:
C
"'a
=
i
max [Su'd'"
'(pC,,,
K, e
-
(1 - p)C,,,
)]
=
max
RAINBOW
'"
-
K, A)]
A
At the node defined by
(m,j), W
'[pC,,,
e
(1 -
the value of the wildcard =
Se
"'N(di)
p)C,,, µ]
.
POINTS • • • • •
•
(70)
•
•
(71)
• •
with
•
di
=
In (S /(K + A)) -
t is the wildcard period. Now, the value of an American option
(r -
(Ü2y ,
•
d2
=
d,
-
pf
(72)
where
with embedded
wildcard
qasons ss calculated at
each node using the formula
C,,
=
max [S,, - K, A + W),,]
(73)
+
(1 - p)C,4, ]
to the pricing
of American options
(74) with
FOR DISCUSSION
What is a rainbow option? What is the pay-off for a call on the minimum of two assets? What is the pay-off for a put on the minimum of two assets? What is the pay-off for a call on the maximum of two assets? What is the pay-off for a put on the maximum of two assets? What is the pay-off for an option delivering the best of two assets and cash? options? Are there put-call parity relationships for extremum (maximum/minimum) of options on the extremum of two assets be extended to N How can the valuation assets? How can we identify extremum options in currency bonds? How can we identify extremum options in multi-currency bonds? How can we identify extremum options in corporate option bonds? What is the pay-off of a spread option? What is the pay-offof a portfolio option? What is the pay-off of a dual-strike option? What is the pay-off of a delivery option? What is the pay-off of a wildcard option? .
•
•
- (K + A)N(d2)
i
In this chapter, several forms of rainbow options and options on the minimum or the maximum of many assets are analyzed and valued in a continuous and a discrete time setting. First, using the approach in Stulz, options on the minimum or the maximum of two assets are studied and valued. Then options delivering the best of two assets and cash of several assets or the minimum are analyzed and valued. Also, options on the maximum are analyzed. Some simulations of option values are run. Finally, some applications to currency bonds, multi-currency bonds, corporate option bonds, spread options, portfolio options and dual-strike options, quality options with N options are deliverable assets, the timing option in futures contracts and wildcard provided.
(69)
option is
[pCoi
e
SUMMARY
• =
=
This simple methodology can be applied embedded wildcard options.
where
A
331
where
•
[SI
OPTIONS
.
I6 Extendible
CHAPTER
Options
OUTLINE
This chapter is organized
as follows:
1. In section 16.1, extendible options are identified, analyzed and valued. 2. In section 16.2, simple writer extendible options are analyzed and priced. 3. Finally, in section 16.3, extendible options are applied in the analysis of extendible bonds and extendible warrants. Simulations of option values are provided.
INTRODUCTION There are many
types of financial contracts
or contingent
claims allowing the issuer or
the contract's holder to extend the maturity date of the initial contract. For example, corporate warrants give the issuer the right to extend the maturity date of the contract unilaterally. Also, bonds with embedded options give the right to the issuer to extend the initial maturity date. More generally, in any financial contract with provisions of terms can imply the existence of payments, a renegotiation concerning a rescheduling of options with extendible maturities. These options can be extended by either the option holder or the option writer. When this option allows the holder to extend the initial maturity date T, to another date T2, he must pay an additional premium A to the option writer. Note that when pricing these options, the strike price is often adjusted from Ki to K2.
16.1
PRICING
16.I.I
The Valuation
Context
The valuation of these options is realized in the B-S context. In fact, following Longstaff (1990),the dynamics of the underlying asset are described by dS/S=adt+odW where a and a are constants.
(!)
334
OPTIONS,
The valuation
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
DE
ATIVES
EXTENDELE
OPTIONS
equation that must be satisfied by the option price, V(S, t), is 'Û2X2Vss + rXVs - rV + V,
,
0
=
(2)
where subscripts refer to partial derivatives. Let CE(S, Ki, Ti, K2, T2, A) be the current value of an extendible call as a function of the two strike prices Ki and K2, times to maturity Ti and Ta, the underlying asset S and the premium A. At date Ti, the call's pay-off is
(3) {0,C(S, K2, T2 - Ti) - A, S - Ki} i.e. the option holder can choose between three pay-offs: the intrinsic value S Ki, zero, with a strike price or the difference between the premium A and a standard European call K2 and a maturity date T2 - Ti. This may also be written as CE(S, Ki, Ti, K2, T2, Á)
=
335
m3X
a2/2)T2
yi
=
(ln(S/I2)
+
Q+
y,
=
(ln(S/li)
+
(r +Ü2/2)T,)/
y
=
ya
=
(ln(S/K2) + (ln(S/Ki) + p
(10)
(r
+ o 2/2)T2)/
(1l)
(r
+ Ki, the extension privilege When A 0, li A sufficient condition for I, to be less than Ki is =
At Ti, the value of I2
iS
Extendible
worthless
is
'O A < K2 - K2e given by the solution to the equation
C(I2, K2, T2
16.1.2
-
(6)
=
The extendible call has some interesting properties. It is worth at least as much as an equivalent standard call without the extension privilege. It is greater than or equal to the maximum of a standard call, C(S, Ki, Ti) and a compound option on C(S, K2, T2 Tip when S Note that the call is worthless 0. When li is nil and I2 iS infinite, the extendible call is worth C(S, K2, T2). The extendible call price is an increasing function of S, r and o, and a decreasing function of Ki. The examples in Tables 16.1-16.4 simulate values of extendible call prices for different parameter values. Also, the effect of change in the parameter values on option prices is examined. =
TABLE 16.1 I 5%, Ti r =
Effect of a Change 0.25, T2 0.25, Ti =
=
,
T,)
CE
SN(yi, y4) - Ae
'T
N(y,
Ke
-
,
y2, -oo,
N(yi
,
y2
Premium 0.3
A: S
=
40, K,
=
43, K2
0.5
I.0
4l.I I 43.52 I.79 I-8I
43.44 42.84 I.79 I.79
TABLE 16.2 K, 43, K2 =
,
)
I
=
45.04 42.20 1.79 f.84
2.0
2.5
3.0
46.32 41.58 1.79 f.94
47.38 40.99 l.79 2.08
48.38 40.39 1.79 2.27
(2)subject to
y3, p)
-
-
=
.5
li 12 C(S, K
SN(y
in the 0.5, «
(7)
T,) -- 12 - Ki + A
C(S, Ki, Ti)
=
-----
Calls
Cs(S, K,, Ti, K2, T2, A)
•
N2(a, b, c, d, p) defined as the cumulative probability of the standard bivariate normal density with correlation coefficient p for the region [a, b] × [c, d] N(a, b) defined as the cumulative probability of the standard normal density in the region [a, b] C(S, Ki, Ti) a standard call option.
Premium A
The value of the extendible call given by Longstaff as a solution to equation condition (3) is
where
•
[0, C(S, {max
C(I,,
=
•
y4 ¯
(8)
Il I2 C(5, K CE
,
T;)
=
Effect of a Change in the Strike Price: S 45, r 0.25, T2 0.5, a= 0.3 15%, T, =
=
39.45 46.68 I.79 2.05
=
=
40.94 45.13 1.79 l.89
44.08 41.88 1.79 l.82
40,
50,
336
FUTURES
OPTIONS,
TABLE 16.3 Effect of a Change in the Volatility 0.25, T2 0.5, A I 15%, Ti K2 45, r =
=
=
=
AND EXOTIC
Parameter:
S
EXTENDIBLE
DERIVATIVES
40, Ki
=
OPTIONS
337
43
=
+ SN(y49
¯
Kie
"l
N(y4 ¯
2
N(yi O y2 ) Note that when li K the option is not extendible and its value reduces to P(S, Ki, Ti). When A 0 and li 0, the Pa option value is P(S, K2, T2L When A is positive and li 0, the Ps value is equal to that of a call on P(S, K2, T2 ¯ l The Pa option value is an increasing function of Ki, Ti, K2, T2 and o, and decreasing a function of S, r and A. =
0.ls
0.30
0.20
'
- Ae
Volatilitya 0.l0
2
=
0.35
0.40
-
,
,
=
0.50
=
=
I, I, C(5,
KI,
43.59 42.49 0.29 0.3 i
Ti)
CE
42.72 43.24 0.63 0.64
41.70 44.21 !.067 i I
39.45 46.68 2.04 1.79
.06
TABLE 16.4 Effect of a Change in Interest 0.3, A Ti 0.25, T2 0.5, « 1 =
=
=
Rates:
38.28 48.I4 2.57 2. I 8
S
=
37.10 49.76 3.10
2.58
40, K,
=
34.00 53.00 4.l8 3.37
43, K2
=
.
=
Interest Rote r
li I, C(5, K,, T;)
.
CE
10%
I2%
16%
IB%
39.90 45.64 \.60 (.77
30.72 46.0 I i.67 f.88
39.36 46.94 \.82 2.l0
39.l8
39.00
47.56 l.9I 2.33
48.33 1.99 2.36
16.2
SIMPLE WRITER
16.2.1
Simple
EXTENDIBtÆ OP1%ONS
45,
Writer
Extendible
Calls
Let Cw(S, Ki, Ti, K2, T2) be the value of a simple writer extendible call for which T, is the initial maturity date and T2 is the extended maturity date. If the call is extended by the writer, its strike price is adjusted from Ki to K2, and A is zero. The Cw payoff at Ti is
20%
Cw(S, K,, T,, K2, The use of equation
O ¯
(8) under
C(S, K2, T2 S - Ki
the restrictions
A
-
=
Ti)
if S Ki at Ti
0, I,
0 and 12
=
=
Ki gives the
followíng price: 16.1.3
Extendible
Cw(S, Ki, Ti, K2, T2)
Puts
Let Py(S, Ki, Ti, K2, T2, A) be the value of an extendible price of a B-S put. At maturity date, Ti, the pay-off of Ps is Po which
=
max
{0,P(S,
Ka, Ta
-
Ti) - A, Ki - S}
(14)
Ka, T, - T;) A], max (0, K, - S)] (15) This analysis is very similar to that of an extendible call and implies the existence of two values of the underlying asset in the interval (I,, I2) that must be determined from the following equations: =
max
[max[0, P(S,
P(Ii,
Ki - 11 A P(I2, K2, Ta - Ti) K2, T2 - Ti)
=
Ps(S, Ki, Ti, Ka, T
,
A)
=
for equation
(2)
subject
P(S, Ki, T;) SN(yi, y2, -oo, -
K2e
"
N(yi
,
y2 -
N(y3
-
-y4
,
,
(20)
p)
It is convenient to note that the price Cw is not always a monotone increasing function of the underlying asset price. The intuition is that if the call is near-the-money at Ti, the option buyer has a second chance to exercise the option at T2. This option may be both convex and concave with respect to the underlying asset. The examples in Tables 16.5-16.9 simulate values of simple writer extendible call prices for different parameter values. For example (Table 16.6), when S 100, Ki 100, K2 120, r 0.1, Ti 0.25, T2 0.6 and Cw 9.24, the bivariate normal l is nbl 0.1357, and the bivariate normal 2 is nb2 0.11156. Reducing T2 from 0.6 to 0.5, Cw falls from 9.24 to 9.09. =
=
=
=
=
=
=
=
=
(16)
A
(17)
=
The solution given by Longstaff extendible put pnce s
- K2e
put and P(S, K, T) be the
can also be written as Py
C(S, Ki, Ti) + SN(ys, -y49
=
to conditior(14)
for the
16.2.2
Simple
Writer
Extendible
Let P,(S, Ki, Ti, K2, T2) be the date, its pay-off is given by
value
y3, p) ,
-oo,
73 -
'
A
Pw(S, Ki, Ti, K2, T2)
=
Puts of a simple write extendible P(S, K2, T2 Ti) Ki - S
put. At the maturity
if S > Ki at T if S< Ki at Ti
(21)
TABLE
100
100
I10
0.25
100
100
95
0.25
o
nb'
nb2
10%
0.4
0.1964\
0.1813
9.16 9.69
10%
0.4
0.3225
0.3212
12.64
T2
r
0.60 0.50 0.60 0.50
T
K
K
S
OPTIONS
339
TABLE I 6.9 Effect of a Change in interest tol0%:S=IIO,K,=90,K2=50,r=IO%,T,=0.5,T2=1
Price and Maturity
in the Strike
Effect of a Change
16.5
EXTENDIBLE
AND EXOTIC DERIVATIVES
FUTURES
OPTIONS,
338
C .
Volatility Cw
.
0.10 25.33
0.20 32.54
0.15 28.79
Rates from
0.25 35.72
0.35
20%
0.40 42.8\
38.39
12.17
This pay-off corresponds to two components: a standard put and the value of the extension feature. Substituting A 0, li K, and 12 oo in equation (18)gives the Pw
----
=
=
=
value: TABLE
of a Change
Effect
16.6
Strike
in the
Price,
Date
=
K
K2
12
Ti
nb2
r
a
ad 0.2016
0.1685
K2e The examples
4.33 6.\3
100
\00
I20
0.25
0.60 0.50
10%
100
100
I20
0.25
0 00
10%
0.3
0.t357
0.II156
\00
90
100
0.25
10%
0.3
0.1109
0.I 195
100
95
100
0.25
0.60 0.50 0.60
IO%
0.3
0.\930
0.\990
100
110
130
0.25
0.90 0.50
IO%
0.3
0.2023
0.1591
13.54 I3.7 \ 10.75 10.58 4.54
100
90
80
0.50 0.25
1.50 0.50
10%
0,3
0.3426
0.4050
3.29 23.38
S
K
K
95
60
90
50
110
90
50
Price,
Maturity
16.3
APPLICATIONS
16.3.1
Extendible
16.10
5
Effect of a Change
in the Strike Price and Maturity
Ki
K2
Ti
T2 0.75 0.50 0.75 0.50 0.75 0.50 0.75 0.50 0.75 0.50
nb
nb2
Cw
100
\00
100
0.25
0.50
l.00 0.50 l.00 0.50 l.00 0.50
IO%
0.3
0.3570
0.4667
100
90
100
0.25
10%
0.3
0.2720
0.3780
35.62 26.56 38.39 28.70
100
80
100
0.25
20%
0.5
0.4442
0.6107
56.07
100
I l0
120
0.25
100
120
140
0.25
0.\0 33.59
=
r
o
obi
ob2
IO%
0.4
0.2997
0.2732
4.l8 4.|6
10%
0.4
0.445
0.446
5.58
IO%
0.4
0.565
0.613
9.07 8.49
IO%
0.4
0.265
0.204
10%
0.4
0.\88
0.l25
16.63 I7.86 33.20 36.23
Pw
-
40.48
=
=
=
T2=I Volatilit Cw
=
Bonds
a
=
puts
=
As shown in the analysis and valuation of compound options, the stockholder's claim on the assets of a levered firm may be assimilated to a call on the value of the firm with a
Date, Volatility
TABLE 16.8 Effect of a Change in Volatility: 0.5, 20%, Ti S I 10, K, 90, K2 50, r =
=
=
r
0.25
y4 ¯
,
16.12 simulate values of simple writer extendible
=
=
=
T
0.50 0.25 0.50
+
=
T
0.15 110
Asset
(22)
N(-y3
=0.2732.
16.32
in the
in Tables 16.10
SN(-y3, y49
-
100, Ki 100, for different parameter values. For example (Table 16,10), when S 0.10, Ti 0.25, T2 0.75, o 0.4 and Pw 4.18, nbi K2 100, r 0.2997 and nb2 Reducing the time to maturity from 0.75 to 0.50 year (9 to 6 months) reduces Pw from 4.18 to 4.16.
TABLE TABLE I 6.7 Effect of a Change Rates and interest
'
Cw
0.3
o.so
1)
P(S, K2, T2 ¯
----
S
100
2)
Pw(S, Ki, Ti, K2,
Volatility and Maturity
0.15 39.61
0.20 43.83
0.25 46.82
0.35 51.037
TABLE 16.1 I Effect of a Change r= IO°/o, T, 0.25, T2 0.5,«= 0.3 =
S w
95 25.29
96 25.03
5.46
in the
Asset
Price:
K2
=
120,
K,
=
90,
=
97 24.46
98 23.89
99 22.72
100 22.I I
101
102
21.51
20.90
103 20.27
104 19.64
106 19.07
I10 16.40
OPTIONS,
340
TABLE 16.12 K2
=
100, K,
=
0.I 0.0
o Pw
AND EXOTIC
FUTURES
Effect of a Change in Volatility: S 0.25, T2 0.50 10%, Ti 80, r 0.2 4.09
0.15 \.85
=
100,
=
=
=
DERIYATIVES
0.25 5.78
0.3 6.97
0.35 7.83
strike price equal to the debt's face or nominal value and a maturity date equal to that of the outstandmg debt. Many corporate bonds have embedded options allowing the issuing firm to extend the maturity date of the original debt. By analogy, extending the life of the debt is equivalent extendible call to extending the time to maturity of the call. Hence, stockholders have an additional time gives maturity them time extending the to debt's since the value, firm's on valuable. applications particularly Other this around. privilege is Hence, the firm turn to of extendible option analysis are possible in pricing the firm's capital structure.
I 6.3.2
Extendible
Foreign Currency Options and Hyb rid Securities ,
,
y
a
,
CHAPTER
y
OUTLINE
This chapter is organized as follows:
Warrants
Warrants are often issued by corporations with simple or complex provisions. Some longconsequently be modeled as term warrants stipulate a change in the strike price and can when the strike price changes from extendible calls. In fact, if you denote by Ti the date then warrant, of the at Ti the warrant holder must Ki to K2, and by T2 the maturity date strike price Kr. If the warrant is not the whether exercise his warrant at decide or not to 0). exercised at Ti, it is extended to T2 (A This type of warrant can be valued using the formula for extendible calls. For other applications, see Longstaff (1990).
1. In section 2. In section 3. In section 4. In section results are
17.1 equity-linked Forex options and quantos are analyzed and valued. 17.2, the valuation of hybrid foreign currency options is described. 17.3, several forms of capped options are studied. 17.4 some hybrid instruments are analyzed and valued. Also, simulation provided.
=
UMMARY valuedIn this chapter, options with extendible maturities are identified, analyzed and values their and are First, the general context is provided. Second, options are priced and simulated. Third, some applications are presented. In particular, extendible bonds extendible warrants are analyzed and identified to options with extendible maturities.
POINTS • • • • • • •
What What What What What What What
FOR DISCUSSION
is the pay-off of an extendible call?
is the pay-off of an extendible put? is the pay-off is the pay-off is the pay-off is the pay-off are the main
call? a simple writer extendible writer extendible put? simple a an extendible bond? an extendible warrant? characteristics of options with extendible
of of of of
maturities?
INTRODUCTION For more than 15 years, foreign currency markets have been characterized by wide price changes. The high volatility of exchange rates has exposed treasurers and international investors to a high level of currency risk. Currency options markets have developed to provide new means of dealing with this growing risk. Currency options are traded on several security exchanges throughout the world. A sizeable over-the-counter market has also developed, offering a variety of specialized currency options. Among such specialized options are the so-called quantos, hybrids, ratios, capped options, and so on. It is often interesting for investors to link a strategy in a foreign equity and a currency to create pay-offs corresponding to a foreign equity option struck in foreign currency, a foreign equity option struck in domestic currency, an equity-linked foreign exchange option, a fixed exchange rate foreign equity option, and so on. This last option is known as a quanto option. An example of a quanto option is the dollar-denominated option on the Nikkei 225 allowing its holder to participate in the foreign equity market without exposure to currency risk. Ratio options, capped options and hybrid securities are also traded in different forms in OTC markets. Ratio options are options on the ratio of two asset prices, index levels, commodities, etc. An example of a ratio option is given by the dollar-denominated European option on the ratio of the German DAX stock index to the French CAC index. Also, as a special
OPTIONS,
342
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
option on the ratio of two US or Japanese index levels case, there is a dollar-denominated options may involve more than two assets and several sources of or stock prices. Ratio the different underlying risk from the assets, the exchange rates and the interest rates from couSntrieesfinancial possible pay-offs at maturity. contracts impose a cap or a floor on the reduced. A capped option can be is risk the issuer's By limiting the possible pay-offs, the range forward Examples include option. and call put of combination a analyzed as a a option note. and the index currency bonds collar, indexed the contract, resemble commodity Also, several firms have issued some financial contracts that securities, known as linked exchange principle rate the futures and debt, for example commodity futures and options with those of combining traditional which erls, are notes receive at maturity a pay-off, which is debt instruments. These notes allow the holder to value nommal of the notes. either larger or smaller than the face or based options some use of the put-call parity on are These hybrid foreign currency and simultaneously sells a call buys corporation put exporting a example, relation. For an of a straight put, but then the from the bank so that the overall cost is less than the cost of the foreign currency above the appreciation exporter loses any potential gain from an strike price of the call. compromise between fkxibility, Currency risk management has thus become a delicate tailoring an protection and cost. The achievement of such a trade-off amounts to anticipaconditional his the of on investor, needs instrument that perfectly matches the .
.
17.1.1
OPTIONS
CURRENCY
FOREIGN
Equity Option Struck
The Foreign
C' ,*
EQUITY-LINKED AND QUANTOS
FOREIGN
EXCHANGE
OPTIONS
the B-S formula for stock options also As shown in Garman and Kohlhagen (1983), where the foreign interest rate replaces applies to the valuation of options on currencies in a foreign stock and a the dividend yield. When an investor wants to link a strategy equity option struck of foreign options: different types a currency, he can use at least four struck in domestic currency, fixed exchange in foreign currency, a foreign equity .option options, or an equity-linked foreign rate foreign equity options, known also as quanto valued in this section. options are analyzed and option. These different types of exchange
in Foreign
Currency
X* max [S"
=
-
K', 0]
-
the equity price in the currency of the investor's country and K' is a foreign currency amount. The spot exchange rate expressed in domestic currency of a unit of stands m front of the pay-off to show that the latter must be foreign currency, X converted into domestic currency. The domestic currency value of this call option is given by where S
is
,
Ci
K'Xr*
S'Xd 'N(di)
=
'N(di
my/t)
-
(2)
with In (S'd '/K'r*
di
'
=
(3)
s
.
where os. is the volatility of S'. This option can be easily hedged by an stocks and B' units of foreign cash, with
As B
17.1.2
The Foreign
,
-K'r
=
=
d 'N(di) 'N(di
smaam A
in
(4) (5)
)
- as
Equity Option Struck in Domestic
Currency
When an investor wants to be sure that the future pay-off from the foreign market is meaningful when converted into his own currency, then the foreign equity option struck m foreign currency is appropriate. This option has the following pay-off for a call:
C
=
max [S'*X*
- K, 0]
(6)
where K the domestic currency amount. For the foreign option writer, the pay-off is given by is
Cl*
17.1
343
W h en an mvestor in a foreign equity is not interested m the risk borne from the drop in t¡exnchhangerate,ohe snapyainvest in a foreign equity call struck in foreign currency. This
tions.
marketing these hybrids, although Banks worldwide have been quite successful in traded on organized theoretically they can be replicated by combinations of instruments Citibank the range forward option from cylinder or markets. A typical hybrid like the customize the hedge by selecting the holder to allows its Brothers contract from Salomon available on an organized exchange. appropriate strike and a maturity that might not be mostly European options, which make them Besides, hybrid foreign currency options are potential for a wide variety of The counterparts. American less expensive than their the French hybrid currency specifications has attracted many customers. In that respect, actively competing among thembeen have French banks since market is interesting, in such a way that selves to market several hybrid contracts. These contracts are designed referred and they upfront to as zero-premium cost are the buyer does not have to pay any options. hybrid foreign currency
AND HYBRID SECURITIES
=
max [S''
-
KX'*
'
0]
23
1/X. X' corresponds to the exchange rate quoted as the price of a unit of domestic currency in terms of the foreign currency. It is convenient to note that this payoff corresponds to that of an option to exchange one asset (K units of our currency) for another asset (a share of stock). The value of this option is given by
where X'
=
,70)
C'*
=
S'd 'N(d2) - KX'r
'N(d2 - o
g)
with
da
In(S'd '/K'X'r =
')
9)
OPTIONS,
344
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
FORE1GN CURRENCY
MS
AND HYBRID SECURITIES
OPTIONS
I
oi.+oi,-20s'x-Us
ass-=
(10)
x'
B'
-
C,
=
'N(d2 - Kr -
'N(d2)
S'Xd
)
¤s
vit) - as
exp(-ps'xus-Jxt)N(d3
-
r*
X
ps,,, is the correlation coefficient between the rates of return on S' and X'. If we multiply this formula by the exchange rate and substitute l/X for X', we get the domestic value of this option, i.e. where
'
rd
KS' =
As
(20)
C3/S'X
=
_
(21) (22)
B'X
(11)
with '
ln (S'Xd
d2
Kr
')
+ as
(12)
2pssora
a
=
os
(asx
(13)
This option can again be easily hedged by an amount A in stocks and B' units of foreign
Rate
The Fixed Exchange Options
(7.1.4
are proposed
Two approaches
EquityDptions
Foreign
orquanto
for the pricing of this option:
Reiner's
approach and
Jamshidian's approach.
cash, with
d 'N(d2)
A= B'
'N(d2
-Kr
=
-
os
)
(14)
Reiner's Approach
(15)
When an investor wants to hedge away the exchange risk on his investment in a foreign equity and fixes in advance the exchange rate at which the future pay-off will be converted in the domestic currency, he can invest in a quanto option or a fixed exchange rate foreign equity call with the following pay-off:
This formula is equivalent to that of B-S with S'X replacing S and as x replacing a. It is asset S'K This as if the B-S risk-neutral pricing approach were applied to the underlying allows the derivation of simple rules that can be applied for the valuation and the hedging ofthe two following options
C4*
=
Ïmax {S'* -
K', 0}
=
Xi is the rate at which the conversion will are equivalent even though the strike price for the first is in foreign terms and in the latter in domestic terms. We rewrite the pay-off in reciprocal units:
where
17.1.3
Equity-linked
Foreign
Call
Exchange
When an investor wants to place a floor on the exchange component of his investment in foreign equity, he can use a combination of a currency call and an equity forward to foreign exchange call with the following pay-off: create an equity-linked Cl*
S'*
=
max
[1
KX'*, 0]
=
S'd 'N(d3) - KS'X'
/
C'*
ln(Xr*
'/Kr
)
(-ps
)
xos ax
(17)
pssos.ext
=
ÏX'
=
S'Xd
'
N(d3) - KS'
=
ÏX'e"max
(24)
{S'e" - K', 0}
exp(-psxagoxt)N(d4)
S'
(25)
(18)
(a
K'r
'N(d4
- os
v't)
(26)
with
d4 exp( -ps
-
.
+
The domestic value of this call option is C3
max {S'* - K', 0}
u and v stand for the natural logarithm of 1 plus the returns of S' and X'. Using the joint distribution for u and v, the value of this option in foreign currency given by Rubinstein and Reiner (1991a)is
C' =
ÏX'*
and express it in the following form:
with
da
=
where
rd
exp
C'*
(16)
The foreign value of this call option is given by
C'
(23) {S'*Ï- K, 0} be made. Note that the two pay-offs max
ayaxt)N(d
- a
)
(19)
This option can again be hedged in an unusual form by an amount A in stocks, B' foreign cash and ß in domestic currency, with
'/K'r*
')-Ps'xasoxt S
The domestic value ofthis option is rd
in
ln(S'd
C4
=
XS
-r*
'
exp(-psxoraxt)N(d4)-
K'r 'N(d4 -
s./0
(28)
OPTIONS,
346
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
FOREIOMØdRRENCY
Ï
rd
exp(-pyxoraxt)N(d4)
=
X
\r* B'
-AyS',
=
B
=
(29)
C
(30)
Jamshidian'sApproach
AblD NYERID SECURITIES
347
"
This option can be hedged in an unusual form by an amount A in stocks, B' in foreign cash and Bm domestic currency, where A
OPTIONS
.
dc(t)
c(to) +
hm c(t)
=
=
max (f(T)
0) - K,
'
(36)
Since f(T) Sr, this is exactly the option pay-off and the option price must be equal to C(to). This general result can be applied to options on stocks and zero-coupon bonds as =
wcIl as quanto and ratio options. of quanto and ratio options is based on the following The hedging and valuation theorem: a dynamic trading strategy in (only) international T-maturity forward contracts for which the net dollar result at time T is [f( T) f(to)] replicates the dollardenominated T-maturity forward contract with terminal price f( T) dollars, and the later price is f(to) dollars (seeNelken (1996)). Consider a quanto option having the following pay-off at the maturity date: -
The approach proposed by Jamshidian (1994) needs the stiategy and the application of Itô's lemma to show that lent to that of the call. Accordingly, the option price investment for the strategy. We illustrate this technique with respect to a off in dollars:
construction of a self-financing the strategy's pay-off is equiva is equal to that of the initial
'generic'
Co
=
Coo
option with the following pay-
max [Sr - K, 0] at the maturity date T, referred
(31)
where S, is the underlying variable to as a T-maturity underlymg forward contract The option value can be expressed in terms of the dollar price of this forward contract. forward price, f(t), where by definition, This latter is referred to as the underlying f(T) SrThe question is how to value and hedge this generic option in terms of the underlying forward contract? An answer can be given in a B-S and Merton economy when f(t) is continuous and has dynamically the underlying a deterministic volatility. Therefore, we need to replicate under of other forward the assumption that the contracts in terms forward contract instantaneous covariances between foi,«ard prices are deterministic. Let
where Sr refers to the price S, dollars. To apply the generic of the yen-dominated denote by g(t) the yen
underlying
=
max [Sr - K, 0]
(37)
forward contract denominated in dollars
with terminal
option results, we have to replicate this forward contract in terms with terminal price S, T-maturity forward contract yen. If we forward price of this contract, then
=
c(t)
=
f(t)N(di)
- KN(d2)
(32)
+ v(t)
(33)
with
ln(f(t)/K)
di
=
d2
=
v(t) In(f(t)/K)
v2(t)
-
v(t) =
var,
pg)
-
f(s)
(34)
=
=
g(t) exp
df cov,
(s) dg(s)l
(38)
,
where the covariance between the forward exchange rate and the actual forward price is to be deterministic. We denote by S(T) the exchange rate, and consider an investor who is long n(t) f(t)/(f,(t)g(t)) actual T-maturity forward contracts at any time t, to< t< T. The forward exchange rate contracts at time t + dt at the then investor shorts n(t)dg(t) prevalent forward exchange The net result of this rate, f,(t+dt)=f(t)+df,(t). strategy at time Tis
assumed
=
i
r
S(T)
n(t)dg(t)
-
r
n(t)dg(t)[S(T)
-
f,(t+dt)]=
(35)
consists of holding C(to) Consider at time to a dynamic trading strategy until c(to) and T, T-maturity bonds N(d,) units of the underlying Pr(to)c(to) dollars cash, forward contract. In this expression, P,(t) stands for the dollar price at time t of a US Tmaturity bond. of this position to Applying Itõ's lemma to equation (32) shows that the contribution i result interval time T at the strategy over an (in dollars) [t, + dt] is given by N(d,) d f(t) dc(t). Accordingly, the net pay-off at time Tis which
f'
f(t)
n(t)dg(t)[[s(t)+dfs(t)]
f(T)
-
f(to)
(39)
=
n(t)dg(t)[f,(t) since df(t) + df,(t)]. ST, Using the theorem, and the fact that f(T) it follows that this strategy g(T) replicates underlying entered the forward contract at time la and the later price is f(to) =
=
dollars. The same approach can be applied
to ratio options.
=
OPTIONS,
348
17.2
ANALYSIS AND VALUATION OPTIONS
17.2.1
The Range Forward
FUTURES
AND EXOTI
TIVES
FOREIGN
CURRENCY
OPTIONS
AND HYBRID SECURITIES
sale of a call with a strike price Ki (< f). Hence the contract's value is
OF CAPPED
X(S, T, Ki, K2) In a range forward contract, the buyer and the bank agree on two prices, Si and S2, at the mception of the contract. At the maturity of the forward contract, the buyer will purchase the foreign currency either at Si if the spot price is less than Si, or at S2 if the spot price is greater than S2, or at the spot price if it is between Si and S2. The two prices Si and S2 are set such that no money changes hands at the inception of the contract. Like a range forward contract, a participating forward contract guarantees a minimum exchange rate for a forward sale and a maximum exchange rate for a forward purchase. Besides, the seller (buyer)gets a participation in the foreign currency appreciation (depreciation).Obviously, there is a cost to this participation. Since the contract is structured with no upfront payment, the cost of the seller's upside participation is that the minimum exchange rate guaranteed through a participating forward sale will necessarily be greater than the outright forward price. Analogously, the maximum exchange rate guaranteed through a participating purchase will necessarily be greater than the outright
forward price.
and a purchase of a put with a strike price K2
(> f)
V(S, T,
=
Contract
349
f) - c(S,
T, Ki) + p(S, T, K2)
(42)
By construction, the initial premium for the range forward contract is zero. When the buyer takes a strike price, the bank picks the other, so that the contract's value is zero: X(S, T, Ki, K2) Hence, the value of a
range currency option pnces, where
=
p(S, T, K2) - c(S, T, Ki)
forward contract
c(S, T, Ki)
=
(43)
is given by the difference
Se '"N(di)
'N(d2)
- Kie
between two
(44)
and
p(S, T, K2)
=
"N(-d2)
Ke
-
Se
'
N(-ds)
(45)
.
with d where i
=
r*+¾a2)T
ln(S/K,)+(r =
,
d
=
d - a
5
(46)
1, 2.
A conditional forward purchase contract is similar to an outright forward purchase, except that the long side of the contract has the right to pull out of the forward purchase by paying a fee to the short side of the contract on the maturity date. The contract can also be designed in such a way that there is no cancellation fee simply by guaranteeing a buying price lower than the forward price. Similarly, a conditional forward sale contract is equivalent to an outright forward sale, except that the short side of the forward contract has the right to pull out of the agreement by paying a fee to the long side of the contract. To give an example for the use and valuation of a range forward contract, consider a when the spot rate is 1.4 manager of a US firm intending to buy pounds in three months, dollars per pound and the three-month forward rate is 1.38 dollars per pound. He can buy value a range forward contract, taking two rates 1.32 and 1.45, so that the initial contract is nil. At maturity, if the spot exchange rate is below 1.32, the buyer pays 1.32. If it is above 1.45, he pays 1.45. If the spot exchange rate is in the interval (1,32, 1.45), he pays
Take, for example, a firm issuing a bond for one year where interest rates are adjusted semi-annually with reference to the LIBOR. If in six months, the LlBOR is above (below) 9%, the firm pays (receives)the difference to the bank. Hence, the cost of financing in variable rate ranges between 6% and 9%. The collar can be regarded as a difference between two European option prices. Its value is given by
the spot rate. At the maturity date, T, the contract's value is assimilated and a short put, p. Hence, the contract's value is
Ki K2
V(S, T, K)
=
17.2.2
X(r,
T, Ki, K2)
=
p(r, T, Kr) - c(r, T, Kz)
(47)
where r
to a position in a long call, c,
The Collar
is the six-month LIBOR, is the price of a discount bond yielding 9%, is the price of a discount bond yielding 6%.
(40)
c(S, T, K) - p(S, T, K)
where
17.2.3
fstands for the forward exchange rate. A range forward contract can also be regarded as a combination of two portfolios. The first portfolio corresponds to a long position in a call and a short position in a put. The second portfolio comprises a cap which is placed on the range of possible pay-offs, by the
Standard Oil issued notes in June 1986 with a nominal value of 1000 and a maturity date of 1990. These notes have an implicit capped option. The additional amount of the mdexed note is given by 170 times the amount (if any) by which the price of a barrel of petrol exceeds 25 dollars at the maturity date. Hence, if the barrel's price at that date is 20 dollars, the option is worthless. However, if the barrel's price lies between 25 and 40 dollars, the option pay-off is (40 25) × 170. This indexed note is regarded as a sale of a call and a cap on the possible pay-oíTs at
S stands for the spot rate. At the contract's initiation, the strike price is given in a way such that the contract's value is nil, or V(S, T, K) where
,
=
c(S, T,
f) -
p(S, T,
f)
=
0
(41)
Indexed
Notes
-
OPTIONS,
350
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
FOREIGN
DERIVATIVES
maturity. The embedded option is analyzed as a purchase of a European call with a strike value of the mdexed price of 25 and a sale of another call with a strike price of 40. The note is given by
X(S, T, Ki, K2)
c(S, T, Ki) - c(S, T, K2)
=
(48)
Table 17.1 lists the values of the indexed note X(S, T, K,, K2) for
various
[l69/S - l]l000
-
B(T) - [c(S, T, K) - c(Y, S, 2K)]I000/K
(49)
where
B( T)
the option,
value without
is the note's market
is the spot exchange rate (dollar/yen), K is the strike price (dollar/yen) 1/169, T is the maturity date of the ICON, c(S, T, K) is the European currency call (in dollars)
S
=
TABLE I 7.1 Values 3 years, 45, T K2 =
=
Petrol Price
16 18 20 22 24 30 35 40 45
of r
=
Notes: Indexed 40% 9%, «
PRIClNG HYBRID FOREIGN OPTIONS
K,
=
17.3.1
Hybrid
Tailoring Approach
Foreign
Implicit Option Value X(S, T, Ki, K2)
\.68 2.47 3.40 4.46 5.64 6.9 1 il 15.23
0.67
l.OI l.4l l.84 2.28 2.75 3.20 4.52 5.51 6.39 7.\2
19.51
2.89 3.7 \ 6.70 9.72 13.\2
23.96
16.84
CURRENCY
Currency
firm) aims at the
Options:
the Briys-Crouhy
On the one hand, corporate treasurers claim that plain vanilla put on call options are expensive. On the other hand, standard zero-premium hybrid foreign currency options cost nothing to the buyer to initiate, but he or she has to give up some capture'. There are at least three ways of dealing with this issue. The first way to lower the cost of the put is to slightly reduce the level of protection, as in the put with proportional coverage in Figure 17.1. If the contract expires in-the-money, the pay-off is limited to a percentage beta of what it would be for an ordinary put: P
=
ß(K
- S),
0
K Pean S, - A else =
Note that the pay-off of a gap put an asset-or-nothing
(0
to the difference between the Hence, its value is given by
corresponds
put and a cash-or-nothing.
pg,=-Sd
'N(-x)+KR
sometimes
[2A]=
Following underlying underlying expiration
pay-offsof
[4A]
'N(-x+av'i)
(14)
Rubinstein and Reiner (1991a,b), let f(u) be the density of the risk-neutral asset return u. Let g(u) stand for the density of the natural logarithm of the asset return when it hits the barrier but ends up below the knock-out level at that the underlying asset starts at S above the barrier H). Let h(r) be the
(given
(u)
=
e
72
where v
=
[3AJ Sd =
Binary Barrier Options
density for the first time r when the underlying functions f(u), g(u) and h(r) are given by
=
=
In(R d)
a2
(15)
[4C]
KR 'N(¢xi
=
=
=
binary
KR 'N(¢x -
=
[2CJ
[3C]
Sd '(H S)2*N(ty yi),
-
'N(qyi
are
¢o v'i) ¢a i) (22)
KR '(H/S)2(1 I)N(yy KR '(H/S)26
options
-
-
ga
t)
77a
t)
Using the above notations, Tables 18.1-18.4 give the binary barrier call and put value formulae for in-cash or nothing (Tables 18.1 and 18.2) and in-asset or nothing binary barrier call and put value (18.3, 18.4), and Tables 18.5-18.8 give the formulae for out-cash or nothing (18.5, 18.6) and out-asset or nothing (18.7,18.8). 'in'
'out'
TABLE Nothing
18,1 Call
Down
(or
condition Down
Up
µ
[I C]
Sd 'N(¢xi),
'(H/S)"N(gy),
asset crosses the barrier. These density
,
Sd 'N(¢x),
(21)
Ü2
As in Rubinstein and Reiner (1991b),28 types of path-dependent valued with 44 different formulas. We define the following notations =
2
µ2 + 2 ln (R)o
b=
,
'
«2
(13)
replacing the strike price.
Path-dependent
a=
'
«2
[ l A]
This formula is like that of a standard put except for the cash amount sometimes
18.2.2
A=l+-
.
Up)-and-in-Cash
callValue
or
¢
y
HH
[3CJ
K S
H H
[IC]
K
H
[2C]
-
-
l I
[3C] + [4C]
[4CJ
-I
I
i
371
OPTIONS,
TABLE Nothing
18.2
Down
Up
TABLE Nothing
Up
TABLE Nothing
Up
DERIVATIVES
BINARIES AND BARRIERS
Put Value
S K KH 5 K K
18.3 Call
H H
[lC]-[2C]+[4C] [3C)
Down
S K K 5 K K
I - I -I -l
-1
Up
- I
Up)-and-in-Asset
(or
Down
Up
S K K S K K
¢
y
Nothing
,
[lA]-
[3A] [2A]+[4A]
I I
[lA] [3A]+
I
Down
I
,
H H H H H H
Down
H H H H H H
Put Value
H H
[lA]-
(or
[4A]
[2A]
-I
K S K K
H H H H
[4A]
[lA] -[2A] [3A]
[3A]
(or
[2C] - [4C] [lC) - [3C]
TABLE Nothing
1 - I - I
0 [lC] - [2C] [4C]
Down
Down
Up)-and-out-Asset
(or
or
Colf Volue
H H
[lA] - [3A] [2A] - [4A]
H H H H
=
[ \A]
-
¢
y
0 [2A] + [3A] [4A]
I I
I I
- I
I
18.8 Put
Down
S K
H H
K
H H H H
5
(or
Up)-and-out-Asset Put Value
[lA] - [2A] [4A] 0
[3A]
y
or
¢ 1 -1
-
[2A] - [4A] [lA]-[3A]
-l -I
-l -I
¢
y
I I
-I
S K K 5 K K
K K
or
I I
18.3 [3C] -
- I - I -I -I
Call
Cond tion
-I
-i -l
[I C] [3C] [2C] - [4C]
- I
¢
Up)-and-out-Cash
CollVolue
\
or
y
- [3A] [\A]
Up
I
Up)-and-in-Asset
Put Value
or
¢
y
[I C] - [2C] + [3C] [4C] 0
Condition
Down
Condition
(or Up)-and-out-Cash
or
Up
TABLE 18.5 NothingCall
S K
TABLE 18.7 Call Value
Down
Put Condition
Down [2C] - [3C] + [4C] [IC]
H H H
S> H K> H K H K< H
18.4 Put
¢
9
373
TABLE 18.6
or
Nothing
Condition Down
Up)-and-in-Cash
(or
Condition Down
AND EXOTIC
Put Condition
Down
FUTURES
I
VALUATION
OF BARRIER OPTIONS
In the following analysis, a distinction is made options. We define the following notations:
between
'in'
barrier and
'out'
barrier
'N(¢x - ¢KR
'N(¢x)
[1] ¢Sd =
=
[3]
=
¢Sd '(H/S)"N(77y)
-
'N(¢xi
¢KR
[2] ¢Sd 'N(¢xi) -
DEglyATIVES
)
¢a
glgetARIES AND BARRIERS
TABLE 18.9
"N(yy
'(H/S)
[5] [6] wherex, xi,
=
=
KR '[N(yxi R[(H
-
S)""N(yz)
-
+ (H/S)"
"N(r¡yi
y, yi, z, 1, a and b are defined as in equations
callVolue pay-off
max (0, S* - K) R(at expiry)
=
K H
I i
-i
Put Value
S> H
pay-off
S*) max (0, K R (at expiry)
=
H Up
if Br if Vr
[2]pay-off
S< H
.
4
t, S(r) GH t, S(r) > H i
[5]
5*) max (0, K R (at expiry)
=
i
if Br a t, S(r) > H Vr a t, S(r) < H
If
-1 -l
[t]-[2]+[4]+[5] [3]-[5]
K>H K 4
K, pay-off K, pay-off
=
=
S, - K. 0.
asset price can end up above the call, when K < H, the underlying For an up-and-in barrier having first hit the barrier. This gives the holder a positive pay-off. Also, it can The end up below the barrier but above the strike price. This gives the holder nothing. asset price ends up above the barrier holder receives the rebate when the underlying without touching it before expiration. The difference between the down-and-in call and the up-and-in call is that in the latter case the underlying asset starts out below the barrier. and Using notations [1]-[6] Tables 18.9 and 18.10 give the down (or up)-and-in call put value formulae.
18.3.2
'Out'
Barrier
Options
> H and K < H.
Given this pay-off, we must distinguish between two cases: K asset price can end up above the For a down-and-in call, when K > H, the underlying strike price having first reached the barrier. This gives the holder a positive pay-off. Also, it can end up above the barrier without ever having hit the barrier before maturity. This gives the holder a rebate. This may be written as If If
I
a t, S(r) > H if Vr a t, S(r) < H
as pay-off
•
i i
Put
(or Up)-and-in
Options Down
written
i i
(18) (21). Condition
'In' Barrier
¢
if Br < t, S(r) GH if Vr a t, s(r)> H
[l]+[5] [2]- [3]+ [4]+ (5]
K>H K< H
TABLE
18.3.1
y
[3]+ [5] [i]-[2]+[4]+[5] S* max (0, - K) if Br
( R(at
tjov/i)]
-
2r¡bov/Ï)]
N(yz -
Call
(or Up)-and-in
K> H
(23) Up
(H/S)2'
Down
S> H
Down
r¡ovít)
-
"N(yy;-yopli)
[4]=¢Sd'(H/S)"N(tyy)-¢KR'(H/S)2' r¡ap/t)
375
Condition
¢«vít)
-
¢KR
-
AfdD EKOTIC
FUTURES
OPTIONS,
$7ig
each down-and-in and up-and-in option a down-and-out and Tables 18.11 and 18.12). up-and-out option an (see When the rebate 47 is nil, the pay-off from a standard option equals the pay-off from a down-and-out option plus the pay-off from a down-and-in option. This parity relationship holds for both put and call options.
It is possible to associate to
TABLE
18.1 I
Down
(or Up)-and-out
CallValue
Condition Down
S> H
pay-off
=
S< H K> H KH K< H Up
Call
max (0, S - K) R(at hit)
if if
Bi s t, S(r) t, S(r)
vr a
> H «
H
[l]-[3]+[6] [2] [4]+ [6] pay-off
=
ma×(0, S - K) R (at hit)
¢
y
I |
i |
i
i I
if Br a t, S(r)< H E t, S(r) > H
if VI
[6] [l]-[2]+[3]-[4]+[6]
_
-l
376
OPTIONS,
TABLE
18.12
Down
(or Up)-and-out
Condition
S> H
Down
pay-off
=
S< H
pay-off
K> H K< H
=
BINARIES AND BARRIERS
AND EXOTICM1VATIVES
18.3.3
Put Put Value
K> H K H S(r) GH
Outside
377
Barrier
Options: 'mside'
.
an Alternative
.
.
Approach
.
.
In classic barrier options, an barrier is defined with respect to the underlying asset price. Some other barrier options are defined with respect to a second variable, an barrier which determines whether the option is knocked in or out. For example, Bankers Trust International proposed to investors in October 1993 a call on a basket of Belgian stocks where the knock-out level corresponds to an appreciation by more than 3.5% of the Belgian Franc. and its location with respect to the Using the nature of the barrier, or with options, it is possible to structure underlying asset, inside barrier as or four different outside barrier call options and four different outside barrier put options. option plus an option with the same strike price, barrier and Recall that an maturity date have the same pay-off as an otherwise identical standard option. So there is no use in valuing the eight options separately. In fact, it is sufficient to value the or the options to get the prices of the others by the stated relationship. Hence, the value of a down-and-in call is given by the difference between the price of a standard call and that of the corresponding down-and-out call. of options with an outside barrier in a B-S economy is analyzed in The valuation Heynen and Kat (1994a).They consider these options as options on two underlying assets variable', and V S and V where S defmes the actual option pay-off, called the variable', stands for the defining whether the option is knocked or Following Heynen and Kat (1994a),we assume the following dynamics for the two 'outside'
I -i I -I S(r) < H S(r) > H
'in'
-
-I
I - i -i
'out',
'down',
'up'
'out'
'in'
'in'
'out'
The proof of this relationship is as follows. Consider an investor who holds a portfolio comprises an otherwise down-and-out option and a down-and-in option. If the underlying asset price never reaches the barrier, then the portfolio's pay-off is identical to that of a standard option. If the underlying asset reaches the barrier, the down-and-in option gives a standard option and the down-and-out option disappears. The main difference between down-and-in and down-and-out options is that for the former the rebate is received at the maturity date and for the latter it is received when the barrier is hit. Since the time the barrier is hit is unknown, the valuation of down-and-out options also needs the knowledge of the density of the first passage time r for the barrier to be hit by the underlying asset Since we need to value the rebate associated with the down-and-out option, its present value is given by its expected value discounted by the interest rate raised to the power of the first passage of time: which
'pay-off
'barrier
underlying
'in'
assets:
S
dln
=
dln
[6]
=
Rr
h(r)dr
R[(H/S)""N(yz)
=
+ (H
S)""N(yz
- 2pbo
)]
'out'.
=
-
µi dt + oi dWi
(28)
µ2 dt + «2dW2
(29)
(25) We denote by
y equals l if the barrier is hit from above and -1 if it is approached from below It is convenient to note that the value of an up-and-out put is given also in Cox and Rubinstein (1985) and Hudson (1991) and indirectly in Conze and Viswanathan (1991) who present the following formula: where
di
d' P
=
SN(-x) + KR 'N(o
-
x) - [-S(S/H)
"N(-y)
KR '(S/H)
2'"'N(a
-
l =
aid
=
di +
y)]
(26)
1 ei
=
ln . 2p
aiÖ ln
U2
So -K
In
+
(µi +ai)T
/ H \
LVo
H - 0
-
In
H -
,
(µ2
d2
,
d'
=
2p
d2 + ai
Û162
N 62
9
ciÑ
di -
=
In
¯
/ H\
LVo
El
(30)
RÛl
with
2 ei
=
ei
We also denote by ri This formula applies only for a pay-out protected not account for dividends.
European upend-out
put, i.e. it does
pl(u,
ti>
(belowpl(u,
ti
2 =
e2 +
H
In -
of time for V through the barrier H and by of In (Sr/So) and V not hitting the barrier H from above > T)) during the option's life. It can be shown that
T), the
the
e'
nrstpassage
joint density
pl(u,
r,, > T)
µ, T
N
=
2 -
¢
,
ln - µ¡ T - 2p (H
Nx
exp
In (H/ Vo) - µ2 T
(32)
T)du
(33)
outside call and put are given respectively
by the foMowing
So)
'
e
an up-and-out
1 (u, ti
> T) du
ln(K
poco
(See" - K)p
"
7 (u, ri
(See" - K)p
ln(K
So)
in (K
so)
'
(K - Soe")p
e
l (u, r'|>
>
¢ei,
->¡¢p)
-
in
2'
exp
(34)
T)du
(35)
N(17d',
In
C si -with µ
i
-
'AE
[lgs,, x,]
=
r
,
AN
\Kf
µ
v'
¢e',
is
(37)
ln (R) + ¾a2. ln this section, we show how to represent and value standard options, down-and-in and knock-out range options in terms of elementary options, switch options, corridors digital options.
18.4.1
=
Example
I: Standard
Options
of strike prices K, increasing by K an amount Ax, i.e. Ko K + Ax, Ka K + 2Ax, K, K + iAx. If we take this sequence with the _ 3mOunt the following pay-off is Ax and add the corresponding binary conditions, Obtained for an infinite number of strike prices:
Consider a sequence
T) du
Using some transformations and tedious calculations, it can be shown that the values down-and-out and up-and-out calls and puts are given by
r¡So N(7¡ds
379
ANALYSIS AND VALUATION OF STANDARD AND EXOTIC OPTIONS USING BINARY OPTIONS
¢p
Vo)
AND BARRIERS
y
=
=
,
.
=
.,
of
When Ax tends to zero,
i
em
the limit, the above conditiori can be rewntten as Its,
-r¡¢p)
dx
(39)
K)1ts,> x,
(40)
Note that the value ofthis integral is(S, ---7¡¢µ)
-
ye "K
N(17d2,¢e2, -17¢µ)
-
exp
2
in
N(77d',
¢e',
(36)
where v¡ takes the value 1 for the call and -l for the put and ¢ takes the value l for an up-and-out option and -1 for a down-and-out option. The correlation coefficient between the two processes is very important in this formula. When p 0, the formula reduces to a standard B-S call which multiplies a probability factor. For in-options, the probability corresponds to that of knocking the option in. For out-options, the probability corresponds to that of not knocking the option out· When p 1, the formula reduces to that of an inside barrier option. there is a higher When the pay-off and the barrier variables are negatively correlated, pay-off vanable the knocked-out call is that probability moves into the as a down-and-out coefficient yields a higher option price. For a in-the-money area. A higher correlation coefficient, the lower the option price. down-and-in call the higher the correlation
-
where the indicator variable takes the value l if S, > K and 0 if S, < K. This condition is simply the pay-off of a standard call we take several multiplicative and additive combinations of binary options, then it is possible to represent the pay-offs of exotic options in terms of digital options.
=
18.4.2
Example
2: Down-and-out
Call Options
=
The down-and-out by the condition
call with a strike price K and a knock-out
(Sr - K)1,s,,
x,1KL. tends to zero, the small and is area approximating portfolio's pay-off tends to that of the continuous strike option. For more details, see Ross and Hart (1994)and Carr and Bowie (1994). 'near
lix,
Fa(S) --
s
,
(s,,,iss,,Ar
(55)
or in a continuous time form: 1(Ki
H and the initial underlying asset price is 100, we can denne a barrier call. If the lowest underlying down-and-out from asset price to $75 $90 to a range attained has been 90 or above, the option is still alive. If the lowest underlying asset If the lowest underlying price attained has been 75 or less, the option is worthless. asset price attained has been 87, then 20%, i.e. (90 87)/(90 - 75), of the option
S,: the value of the underlying asset at maturity asset, a: the volatility of the natural logarithm of the return of the underlying thheerik-free rate n numeraireccurrency fore netnamoeusm *: ed yield for the sasse H: the barrier for a discrete barrier option, U: the upper limit of the barrier range of a soft barrier option, L: the lower limit of the barrier range of a soft barrier option,
Cso
=
([S'e"
2"
given in Rubinstein and Reiner (199la)between the upper and lower limits of the range option. Recall that the value of a down-and-in call with K > H, in the absence of rebate, is
strike call option is given by ""'N(x
)-
+ o
2KSe "'N(x)
+ K2e "N(x - a
-
disappears.
maturity,
the value of a continuous
given by
)]
(58) "'
with
co,(K > H) l x
=
-
In
385
S
+
-
(r -
r*
jo2
+
(59)
"
N(y) - Ke
Se
=
N(y - a
y __
In
SK
a
la
1
,
r -
=
r*
+
The value of the soft barrier range down-and-in call option for K Continuous
Strike
Range Options
cssao,
The continuous strike range option, Csao, is an option for which there is a lower and an upper limit on the strike price. The pay-off of a continuous strike range option is similar to that of a portfolio with a long position in a Cso with strike price K and a short position in a Cso with strike price Kc. The pay-off of a continuous strike range option is
Csao
=
(max{S, -
KE,
0}2
-¡rnax{S,
0}2 - Ka,
(60)
cssaa;
•
10
=
-
N
Soft Barrier
Options
.
.
A barrier option can be transformed to a continuous barrier option by keeping a single strike price and allowing for proportional knock-in and knock-out of the barrier. This allows the option to get gradually in or out. The value of a barrier range option can be easily obtained by integrating the formula
U - L
Se
(U)] - µ,N[y2(U)]
(63)
'S
2(A +
()
Ai
(64)
A
N[yi(L)]
-
-
+ µsN42(L)]
(65)
Of
csekoic
18.5.4
is givën by
(SK)"i
l -
2
(U2 KL
L
(62)
with Ai
Buy a Cso with a strike price KL and sell a Cso with a strike price Ko. An equally weighted portfolio of European calls with strike prices varying from Ko.
> H
coi(K > H) dH
=
U
¼
or
The pay-off to this option can be easily replicated by one of the following strategies: •
(61)
with
Since the option pay-off involves S2, the above formula can be used to valueanireplicate power options. The Cso does not have an upper limit on the strike price.
18.5.3
)
=
'
Ke "S
i
(SK) ,
A2
(66)
with U2 A2 where
=
N[y3(U)] - µxN[y4(U)]
L2 -
SK
N[y3(L)]+
µgN[y4(Q]
(67)
OPTIONS,
386 l
yi(H)
=
In SK o v/t µs
+(A-
exp {-((1-()(A
=
DERIVATIVES
(H2 In H2
l
ya(H)=
AND EXOTIC
FUTURES
la
,
1)o
,
y2(H) -- yi(H)
y4(H)=
+()o2t},
µ
-
y3(H)
-
G+
(1- )a
exp {-((A -()(A
=
o
(68)
l +()c;2t}
BINARIES
AND BARRIERS
387
struck at H 2 K where the barrier H corresponds to the geometric mean of the strike roes This relationship allows one to hedge a short position in a down-and-in call (strike K< H) by a long position in K/H puts with a strike price equal to H2/K.
Example
the difference between this formula and the European B-S Using call gives the European down-and-out barrier range call formula. the parity relationship,
Consider a call struck at 4 and a put struck at 1. When the underlying asset price is (at the barrier), then how many out-of-the-money puts struck at l should you have in order to get the equivalent value to an out-of-the-money call and to implement the hedge? 2. Note that this mean of 2 The geometric mean of the strike prices is corresponds to the barrier. So the number of purchased puts is K/H 2 4 2 and the put strike price is H'/K, or 22/4 1. Hence, the sale of the down-and-in call with the strike price K can be hedged by the purchase of two puts with strike
2
18.6
OF BARRIER OPTIONS
STATIC HEDGING
=
=
The following analysis concerns the static hedging and valuation
18.6.1
Hedging
At-the-Money
Down-and-in
of down-and-in calls.
Calls
When the strike price K equals the barrier H, the down-and-in call is at-the-money. This is a simple case The sale of a down-and-in call can be hedged by the sale of an otherwise standard put with the same underlying asset, strike price and time to maturity as the down-and-in call. If the underlying asset price remains above the barrier, then the put and the down-andin call are worthless. However, if the underlying asset price is at the barrier or hits it for the first time, then standard puts and calls have the same value. The hedger can sell the standard put and buy a standard call simultaneously since these options have the same value. Hence, the sale of a down-and-in call can be exactly hedged by the purchase of a standard put. If we denote by co(K, H) the value of a down-and-in call with a barrier H and a strike price K, then its value prior to hitting the barrier is simply equal to that of a standard put, P(K) for H K. This can be written as =
cen(K, H)
=
P(K)
for H
=
K
(69)
This relationship applies only when the strike price equals the barrier
18.6.2
Hedging
Out-of-the-Money
Down-and-in
=
=
Cans
When K < H, the strike price is less than the barrier and the down-and-in call is out-ofi.e. selhng . the hedge . the-money. The same hedging strategy as in Section 18.6.1 apphes, as the barrier is hit and doing nothing when the asset price is above the barrier. However, when the barrier is hit, the emergent call is out-of-the-money and the put-call parity does not apply. This is because the call and the put have different strike prices. It is possible m this case to use the results in Carr (1994)concerning the put-call symmetry. The put-call symmetry shows that the pay-off from a call struck at K when the underlying asset price is equal to the barrier H is equivalent to the payoff from K/H puts
price 1. If the underlying asset does not hit the barrier (2), then the call and the two puts worthless. When the barrier is hit, the two puts have the same value as the call are and the hedger can sell the two puts and buy a call at zero cost. Hence, a short position in two standard puts is an exact hedge for the sale of a down-and-in call. The following relationship is verified: coi(K, H)
18.6.3
Hedging
In-the-Money
=
\H)
P
HEK
\ K /
Down-and-in
(70)
Calls
When K > H, the down-and-in call is in-the-money and has a positive intrinsic value at the barrier. We define a down-and-in bond as a security that pays $1 at maturity if the barrier is hit before the maturity date. If we construct a portfolio comprising H K down-and-in bonds, then it presents the same value at the barrier as the emergent call. It is shown in Rubinstein and Reiner (1991a)and in Bowie and Carr (1994)that a down-and-in bond can be synthesized from standard and binary puts. Also, a binary put, Ps(K), struck at K can be expressed as a function of standard puts in the following form: -
.
Ps(K)=
hmn
n
2
P K+-
l n
-P
K--
1 n
(71)
It turns out that the down-and-in bond with barrier H can be synthesized by a long position in two binary puts struck at K and a short position in (1/H) standard puts struck at H. Hence, an investor who is short (1 H) standard puts at the initial time and covers his position when the barrier is hit, ensures a self financing transaction at the barrier. The down-and-in bond value is
388
Boi(H) If P(H) is replaced can be
written
OPTIONS,
FUTURES
2Ps(H)
P[H]
=
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
BINARIES AND BARRIERS
SUMMARY
(72)
by an average of puts struck just above and below H, then Boi(H)
as
Î
i
(PH PH
+ Boi(H) If one substitutes puts:
=
2Ps(H)
(71) in (73), it
-
n
_ _
n
lirn
(73)
2
-
I
4
is clear that the down-and-in bond is only a function of
standard
Ba(H)
=
lim
(7
l
1 + -
PH
n -
/
'i
-
m
l
PH
n
l
(74)
The rebate, Rey, associated with a down-and-in call can be synthesized from a long position in Rey standard bonds paying $1 at expiry and a short position in Rey down-and-
in bonds: Ru(H)
=
Reye
"' -
RevBo,(H)
(75)
As a consequence, the rebate can be expressed solely in terms of standard puts. The above analysis now allows the valuation of a down-and-in call when the strike price is less than the barrierHence, a short position in a down-and-in call (strikeK, barrier H > K) can be hedged by a long position in a standard put (strike price K) and in H K down-and-in bonds.
-
2
This chapter analyzes simple and complex digital options, digital range options and barrier options. In particular, it illustrates by simple examples, elementary digital call and put options, all-or-nothing options and one-touch all-or-nothing options. Then, some examples of complex binary and range options and structured currency products are presented: range binaries, rebate range binaries, mandarin collars, mega-premium options, limit binary options, boundary binary options, wall options, knock-out wall options, mini-premium options, hokey-cokey options, boolean digitals and corridors. Also, differup-and-in, down-andent kinds of barrier options are studied. Examples of up-and-out, out and down-and-in calls and puts are given. Then, examples of synthetic forward structures in currency OTC markets are analyzed. These structures are based on combinations of barrier options. Some characteristics of barrier options are studied. It turns out that binary options are useful in the representation of the pay-offs of simple in Pechil, the chapter analyzes and and complex options. Using the representation provides simple valuation formulas for down-and-out options, switch options, corridors and knock-out range options. Second, analytic formulas for the pricing of binaries and barriers are presented. Also, a framework for the analysis and valuation of continuous strike options, continuous strike range options and soft barrier options is presented. of Finally, we present some static hedging techniques for the analysis and valuation barrier options.
POINTS
Example
• •
An investor selling a down-and-in call with a strike price of 4 and barrier of 7 can hedge his short position by the purchase of a standard put struck at 4, and 7 4 3 down-and-in bonds with barrier 7. If the spot remains above the barrier, the down-and-in call, the down-and-in bonds and the put are worthless at maturity. If the barrier is hit, the two down-and-in bonds and the standard put are used to 4). Since the exact hedge for finance the purchase of a standard call (strikeprice the sale of a down-and-in call is a portfolio with a long position in a standard put (strikeprice 4) and 3 down-and-in bonds with barrier 7, then the value of the downand-in call before the barrier is hit is equal to that of the portfolio. =
=
• • • • • • • • • • • • •
If the hedge involves
just standard
cix(K, H)
=
puts, the following relationship
(H - K)ßoi(H)
+ P(H)
H
applies: >
K
•
(76)
where
Boi(H) is given in (74). Bowie and Carr (1994) show that for n the bid-ask spread of these options
• • •
=
10, the relative
error
in the hedge liestithin
389
• •
FOR DISCUSSION
What is a binary option? What is a barrier option? What is a path-dependent option? What is a path-independent option? What is an all-or-nothing option? What is a range binary option? What is a rebate range binary? What is a mandarin collar option? What is a mega-premium option? What is a limit binary option? What is a boundary binary option? What is a wall option? What is a knock-out wall option? option? What is a mini-premium What What What What What What What
is a hokey-cokey is a corridor? is the pay-offof is the pay-off of is the pay-off of is the pay-offof is the pay-off of
option? cash-or-nothing options? asset-or-nothing options? gap options? the down-and-in cash (at hit) or nothing when S> H? the up-and-in cash (at hit) or nothing when S< H?
390
• • • • • • •
• • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • •
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
the down-and-in asset (athit) or nothing when S> H? the up-and-in asset (at hit) or nothing when S < H? the down-and-in cash (atexpiry) or nothing when S> H? the up-and-in cash (at expiry) or nothing when S< H? is the pay-off of the down-and-in asset (at expiry) or nothing when S> H? is the pay-offofthe up-and-in asset (at expiry) or nothing when S< H? is the pay-off of the down-and-out cash or nothmg when S > H? up-and-out cash or nothing when S< H? is the pay-offofthe is the pay-off of the down-and-out asset or nothing when S > H? is the pay-offof the up-and-out asset or nothing when S< H? What is the pay-off of the down-and-in cash-or-nothing call when S > H? What is the pay-off of the up-and-in cash-or-nothing call when S < H? What is the pay-off of the down-and-in asset-or-nothing call when S > H? What is the pay-off of the up-and-in asset-or-nothing call when S< H? What is the pay-off of the down-and-in cash-or-nothing put when S > H? What is the pay-off of the up-and-in cash-or-nothing put when S< H? What is the pay-off of the down-and-in asset-or-nothing put when S > H? What is the pay-off of the up-and-in asset-or-nothing put when S< H? What is the pay-off of the down-and-out cash-or-nothing call when S > H? What is the pay-off of the up-and-out cash-or-nothing call when S < H? What is the pay-off of the down-and-out asset-or-nothing call when S > H? What is the pay-off of the up-and-out asset-or-nothing call when S< H? What is the pay-off of the down-and-out cash-or-nothing put when S > H? What is the pay-off of the up-and-out cash-or-nothing put when S < H? What is the pay-off of the down-and-out asset-or-nothing put when S > H? What is the pay-off of the up-and-out asset-or-nothing put when S < H? What is the pay-off of a down-and-m call? What is the pay-off of an up-and-in call? What is the pay-off of a down-and-m put? What is the pay-off of an up-and-in put? What is the pay-off of a down-and-out call? What is the pay-off of an up-and-out call? What is the pay-offof a down-and-out put? What is the pay-off of an up-and-out put? What is the link between standard and exotic options and binary options? What is a continuous strike barrier option? What is a continuous strike range option? What is a soft barrier option? How can we implement static hedgmg of barrier options?
What What What What What What What What What What
• •
OPTIONS,
is the pay-off of is the pay-off of is the pay-off of is the pay-offof
?
Look back Optio ns
CHAPTER
OUTLINE
This chapter is organized as follows: 1. Section 19.1 analyzes and gives some examples of lookback options. 2. Section 19.2 presents valuation formulas for European lookback options. In particular, standard lookback options, extreme options, limited risk options and partial lookback options are valued. Also, simulation results are provided. 3. Section 19.3 presents valuation formulas for an exotic timing option, with simulations. 4. Section 19.4 studies the strike bonus option.
NTRODUCTION Some financial contracts allow the holder to receive, at the maturity date, a pay-off dependmg on the maximum or the minimum of the reahzed values of the underlying asset durmg the contract's life. The underlymg asset may be a spot asset, a forward or a futures contract, commodities, indices and so on. These options are negotiated either m organized markets or m the OTC markets and may be embedded in some contracts issued by financial institutions and firms. Hence, a lookback call is defmed as an option whose strike price corresponds to the minimum price recorded by the underlymg asset durmg the option's life. A lookback put is defined as an option whose strike price corresponds to the maximum price recorded by the underlying asset during the option's life. These options are interesting but are more expensive than standard options. Therefore partial lookback options are designed to reduce the costs attached to lookbacks while preserving their main characteristics. This can be easily achieved by reducing the period during which the underlying asset is monitored. Hence, a partial lookback option allows its holder to purchase a fraction of the underlying asset above a certain minimum. .
.
.
.
.
.
.
'full'
.
There are many
reasons
.
.
which
incite investors
.
.
.
to buy and sell lookback
options.
Perhaps the main aim is to gain a lot of money and to avoid transaction costs resulting from the replication of these options by some strategies. Generally, investors who resort knowledge about an asymmetry in the to lookback options think that they have of the dynamics of the underlying asset price, the price paths and the 'superior'
'volatility
volatility',
among
other thines.
OPTIONS,
392
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
When an investor has some prior expectations about future prices and believes that upward and otherwise they will downward, he might have some incentives to purchase and hedge at-the-money lookback calls and to sell and hedge lookback puts. Also, when his prior expectations about future prices let him believe that they will upward and downward, he might be incited to purchase and hedge lookback puts and to sell and hedge lookback calls. This strategy is based on the fact that the market tends to go up slowly and fall suddenly. Goldman, Sosin and Gatto (1979)and Goldman, Sosin and Shepp (1979) analyzed and valued standard lookback options which entitle the holder to buy the underlying asset at its realized minimum value during a certain period Harrison and Kreps (1979)and Harrison and Pliska (1981)showed that in complete markets, it is possible to implement a self-financing strategy to duplicate the pay-off of an option using the underlying asset and riskless discount bonds. The current option value is given by its expected pay-off discounted to the present under the appropriate probability measure. Hence, these options can be priced in a B-S economy using martingale techniques. They can also be valued using lattice approaches and numerical techniques· Whatever approach is used, the specificities of these options are reflected in their terminal and intermediate pay-offs. 'drift'
'gap'
LOOKBACK
393
OPTIONS
When the option was purchased gold was $405, and on the maturity date $395. If the highest price achieved during the option's life is $430 and the option is cash-settled at maturity, then the settlement value is
'drift'
(430-
'gap'
19.1
ANALYSIS
OF LOOKBACK
19.1.1
Examples
of Standard
Lookback
A lookback option gives its holder the right to buy (sell) a fixed amount of an asset at the best price which occurs over the option's life. Hence, a lookback call (put)involves the right to buy (sell)at the lowest (highest)price. The Lookback
Lookback
The holder of a nine-month European lookback call has the right to buy at maturity period. 10 000 ounces of gold at the lowest price which is attained over the nine-month The contract stipulates as well that the holder is entitled to the favorable strike price of $377 whenever the asset price fails to reach this level. Suppose that when the option is purchased gold was $405 and on the maturity date $395. Suppose that the lowest price achieved during the option's life is $380. If the option is cash-settled at maturity then the settlement value is
in-the-Money
Lookback
min
(380,377)]l0 000
Put
European lookback put has the right to sell at maturity The holder of a nine-month period. ounces of gold at the highest price which is attained over the nine-month
14¾
=
$180 000
Puts
The holder of a nine-month European lookback put has the right to sell at maturity 10 000 period. The ounces of gold at the highest price which is attained over the nine-month stipulates as well that the holder is entitled to the favorable strike price of $432 contract whenever the asset price fails to reach this levet Suppose that when the option is purchased gold was $405 and on the maturity date $395. If the highest price achieved during the option's life is $430 and the option is cashsettled at maturity, then the settlement value is
[max(430, 432)
19.1.2
The Floating
Strike
- 395]l0 000 with
=
$370 000
floating strike prices or with fixed strike
Lookback
For a floating strike lookback, the strike price is unknown before the maturity date. For a corresponds price realized by the to the minimum underlying asset durmg the option's life. For a lookback put, the strike price corresponds to the maximum price realized by the underlying asset during the same period. Hence, a A floating strike lookback call gives the right to the holder to buy at the minimum. floating strike lookback put gives the right to the holder to sell at the maximum. When the underlying asset price drops and then rises, the call will pay-off from the lowest price realized. Since the strike price drops with the underlying asset value, these
lookback call, the strike price
(395-380)l0000=$150000
$350000
Calls
There are two types of lookback options: pnces.
Call
The holder of a nine-month European lookback call has the right to buy at maturity 10 000 ounces of gold at the lowest price attained over the nine-month period. Suppose that when the option is purchased gold was $405/ounce and on the maturity date it is $395. Suppose that the lowest price achieved during the option's life is $380.If the option is cash-settled at maturity, then the settlement value is
The Lookback
In-the-Money
OPTIONS
Options
=
If we denote by S,s,, and Sas, the lowest and highest underlying asset price achieved at any instant t between the current time to and the maturity date T, then the lookback call pay-off can be written as Sr The standard lookback put pay-off is Smax Sr. - Sass.
[395-
In this section, we describe some lookback options with respect to their terminal and intermediate pay-offs. These options are often structured in order to offer, for a higher initial premium, some or all of the potential value of the option during its life.
395)l0 000
394
OPTIONS,
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
options offer a suitable solution to the market entry problem and are more expensive than standard options. When the initial underlying asset price corresponds to the minimum value recorded during the option's life, then the floating strike lookback call pay-off is equal to that of a standard call.
19.1.3
Fixed Strike
LOOKBACK
DERIVATIVES
.
|
Lookback
.
ANALYTIC OPTIONS
FORMULAS
FOR LOOKBACK
When the dynamics of the underlying asset are given by the following familiar equation:
=
max
[0, Sr -
K,
f(.) -
K]
dS,
P
=
max
[0, K
- S,, K -
f(.)]
S,
(1) (2)
rS, dt + o S, d W,
=
(3)
then
and in the following form for the put:
value
Long a lookback call.
19.2
Strategies
C
f(.) is the
•
.
.
The value of path-dependent options is a function of the underlying asset, time, the strike price, and a function f(.) specifying the option in question. Most lookback options are defined as calls or puts for which the pay-off can be written in the following form for the call:
where
Short a synthetic forward contract at spot, i.e. selling a European call and buying a European put.
It is convenient to mention the Arcsine law for lookback options. The Arcsine law refers to the distribution which predicts the timing of the minima and the maxima of the underlying asset values during a certain period of time. This means that the underlying asset price attains a minimum or a maximum near the beginning or the endpoints of the lookback penod rather than at some time in the middle of the period. Hence, when an investor sells a lookback call and a lookback put, it is not impossible that one extreme value be attained at that time and the other extreme value at the maturity date. For more details, see Garman (1993).
.
19.l.4
as follows:
•
Â
For fixed strike lookbacks, the strike price is known m advance. The call option pay-off is given by the difference between the highest value of the underlymg asset during the option's life and the fixed strike pnce. The put option pay-off is given by the difference between the fixed strike price and the lowest value of the underlying asset recorded durmg the option's life. When the final underlying asset price is the maximum value recorded during the option's life, then the fixed strike lookback call's pay-off is equal to that of a standard call. .
395
A lookback put strategy is constructed
.
Lookbacks .
OPTIONS
-
1
=
Soexp
[(r
2
a2)t + aW,]
(4)
(seeChapter 2 for more details). Using the following notations for the over the interval [ti, t2þ
maximòm
and the
minimum
M
of the underlying asset, determined in a way defined in the issue of
max {Ss
=
é
[ti, t2D
=
m
min {Ss
é
Di, t2]}
(5)
the financial asset.
Hence, a lookback option is an option for which the function f(.) corresponds to the maximum or the minimum of all values attained by the underlying asset during the option's life. The maximum or the minimum can be calculated in a continuous time .framework as it can be sampled at different times. An average strike lookback call (put) of the underlying asset is defined by the function f(.) giving the minimum (maximum) value over the option's life A lookback call strategy is constructed as follows: •
•
Long a synthetic forward contract at spot, i.e. buying a European call and selling a European put. Long a lookback put.
value of S which can be achieved by The pay-off of this strategy is the maximum exercising the lookback put and by paying the strike price K, which corresponds to the
then X,
Y,
19.2.1
=
In
=
So
Standard
ln
=
max {X|s
Lookback
=
So E
[0, t]}
a2)t+
(r y,
=
ln
a W,
=
So
(6) min {X)s E
[0, t]}
(7)
Options
Since the pay-off of a standard European lookhack call at the matunty date S, - m its current value is
is
given by
FUTU
OPTIONS,
1996
c
SoN(d")
=
- e
"m
N(d"
ES AND EXOT1C
DERIVATIVES
LOOKSACK
OPTIONS
on)
-
e "(M
=
c
397
"M - e
SoN(d') - K) +
N(d'
-
an)
2r/ m. When M°To
)] -
e "K[N(d
)-
- a
N(d,
the call's current value is
Gm
-
on)]
) N
m
e
(Sr -
+e"N(d)
d-
2d, -d-
o
m
(12)
"K - e
N
\m)
2d,,, - d -
-N
d,,-
N
d,, -
-a
(18)
with with
d,, d
When K < M
=
the call's value is
ln
+
¡Û2
(13)
1 =
-
The pay-off at the maturity date of p
ln imited
=
So -
+ rT
a2 T
(19)
sk put is
(K - Sr)*14,
(20)
OPTIONS,
398
when
p
=
m° < m, the put -
is worthless. When
-2d,,
N
- n
m
DERIVATIVES
LOOKBACK
m, the put's current value
is
19.2.5
N(-d,,
)]
Tables 19.1 and 19.2 show the effect of changing maturity date and interest rate on standard lookback options. Tables 19.3 and 19.4 show the effect of changing maturity
e "K[N(-d
So[N(-d) - N(- d,,,)]
AND EXOTIC
FUTURES
)-
a
d
d,
N
-
+ a
Simulations
TABLE 19.1 Effect Maturity Date: m, =
-
N
K
-2d,,
d
-d,,,
N
-
399
+a
(2r/ol)+l
e
OPTIONS
(21)
These options are issued in foreign exchange markets and also in stock index markets.
19.2.4
Partial
Options
Lookback
date their pay-off
These options differ from lookback options smee at matuilty (S, - Am
=
c
with 1
)
is
d"-
-a
-2r/a2
a2 -2r
e
Se
AS
N
-mo,
-d
ln(A)
,,
-
o
2r -vT a
,
I Y 2r
N
d,,
=
0.2, r
in the 0.1
=
(5, T)
0.25
0.5
I
80 85 90 95 100 105 I 10 115 I20
31.77
31.63 22.19 16.37 13.56 13.19 \4.69 17.54 21.29 25.59
32.95 25.41 21.17 19.45 19.64 21.27 23.95 27.38 31.34
TABLE Interest "N
-Am°e
d"-
«
21.02 \3.78 9.85 8.95 10.50 13.74 17.94 22.63
22)
l
The current value of a partial lookback call is c=SoN
of a Change
100,
ln (X)
19.2 Effect Rates: m, =
of
a
100,
«
=
Change in 0.2, T 2 =
(5,r)
/0%
is%
IB%
80 85 90 95 l00 105 110 115 120
37.03
48.59 38.91 34.49
57.07 43.64 37.79 36.25
3\.71 29.16 28.57 29.45 3\.4l 34.17 37.53 41.33
33.34 34.29 36.58 39.77 43.54 47.7\
37.24 39.73 43.14 47.13 51.47
At the rnaturity date, the pay-off of a partial lookback put is p
=
(AM
with 0
- Sr)
A
(24)
l
TABLE 19.3 Effect of a Change 10% 25%, r So 100, « =
The current value of a partial lookback put is p
=
SoN
AM e "N
-d'
2r
S
e-cr 2r/
M
d'
S(t)ez"°
becomes
eg(to-t+H(N+1))
-
(N + 1)(1
-
-
egH
K
(4)
Approaches
ssetnarnost opt onndprcying problems,
it is assumed that the dynamics of the underlying µS(t)dt + US(t)dW
=
+¼a )N -+---
e xp
e
-
o
µ KN
o,
o,
e
C"(S, K, t)
(28)
ln(So) +
=
µ,
o µ
So +
=
a
= "
q2
K
=
2K
a'[ti
'" =
"E[(S,
e
|F,] - K)
(37)
where E is the conditional expectation operator with respect to the transformed riskneutral probability measure Q which replaces P, and K is defined as in equation (35). Two time windows A, A]. In the time window are considered: [0, T - A] and [T prior to T A, applying the iterated conditional expectations (see Duffie, 1988) to (37)
ti +
a
exp
y
µ
(i (n -
(31)
2
i(i - 1) At 2n . 1)(2n - 1) At 6n
(32)
1)
(lnK - µ)
-
gives
(30)
-
(r - d - jo2)
a2
--
=
(29)
(r - d - Ja2)t + (i 1)At]
(33) U
C (S, K, t)
'a =
"E{E[(S,
e
Fr_a] F,}
- K)
(38)
At this level Taylor expansions and a linearization are used. After some computations, the closed-form solution to the pricing of the Asian option over [0, T A] is found to be
v/37v/Ã+
Ai
C(S,K,t)=S,e'^
-N 2
2A -e 6x
2a
^U"'
forts
T-A
(39)
with r
(34) In the time window
is the time of first averaging point and At is n is the number of averaging points, t the time between averaging pomts. It seems that the geometric conditioning method gives better results than the previous methods.
(36)
-
with
where
µ dt + o dz
=
The price of the forward-starting Asian option at time t, C (S, K, t), is given by
ln(K*)
-
-
dS -S
=
r -
2
Ao2
AF
-J2
m
'
=
-
'
2
v
=
-
3
posterior to T - A, the strike price is gradually revealed.and and M, which is equal to x, S,]
(40) investors
know the sequence [S,
.,
S(u)du '
T
^
(41)
FUTURES
OPTIONS,
4 18
S(u)du=
A
,_,
=
"'
e
S(u)du
A
,_,
"E
S,
Using Taylor expansions and the same linearization =
S, e
'"
"
mN
+
\F,
S(u)du
cr
(43)
procedure gives the desired formula: "'726
C(S, K, t)
(42)
S(u)du
a,S
=
, -
K
which is also equal to
M, A
-
419
At the option's maturity date, the basket pay-off is given by
as follows:
The pricing problem can be reformulated
C (S, K, t)
ASIAN AND FLEXIBLE ASIAN OPTIONS
as of time t:
The strike price can be split into components A
AND EXOTICOERWATIYE
for t > T - A
e
b,S
=
cr
K*
-
a,F o
(49)
where
(44)
b
=
(50)
a,F with t)2
(T-
T-1 m=l--+r(T-t)-î
2A
A
2
3
sothatLb
land
-
2
-M=o
(T
t)+
A
3A3
The corresponding
a,F
=
-
rA
1 S, + C(S,, K, t)
for tsT
- A
(46)
At time 0, the basket option value can be obtained by taking its ekted under the appropriate probabihty measure, or
or e_gr
P(S,, K, t)
20.2
=
put formula is given by
P(S,, K, t)
=
K*
Sr
(45)
M, e
ANALYSIS OPTIONS
'
-n +
rA
co
,,
K, t) - 1 S, + C(S,,
AND VALUATION
for t > T - A
e "E
=
b;S
,
K
-
a,Fio
(52)
(47)
OF BASKET
valuation of basket Rubinstein (1994)presented a bivariate binomial lattice for the methodology The can be underlying assets. options where the basket comprises two the However, underlying assets. with valuation options basket of many extended to the of basket book time to manage a method is time-consuming and can not be used in real
Since the distribution of [Lb,S ,] is unknown, average: [G¿S K']. Finally, the basket option formula is given by co
=
e
TE
it is approximated
K'
S
of basket options. His Gentle (1993)presents an alternative method for the pricing used in Vorst (1992)for the pricing of an that similar technique to model is based on a average rate option. by: Following Gentle (1993),we denote respectively
by the geometric
a,Fi.o
(53)
EL b,S$r
(54)
avhere K'
=
K
E
S"
options.
S,,: the spot price of asset i at time t, F,,: the forward price of asset i at time I, of assets, at: the weight of asset i in the basket volatility of asset i, o,: the coefficient between assets i and j. p,,: the correlation
discounted value
Aner some tedious calculations, the basket option co
=
e
"
a,F o[a exp
h *
'
'
a
=
=
(v
value
is given by
)N(vv'Ì- h) -
In
vy exp
(ja
K'N(-A
1
(55) (56)
T)
(57)
410
v2
K'
OPTIONS,
FUTURES
Li
p,,b,bpp
S"
E
ba +
=
K + E
=
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
(58) b,S
(59)
The above formula was simulated by Gentle (1993)for prices of standard sterling and yen call options relative to forward rates as the basket of options. When compared with results of Rubinstein's model, simulations show that the formula is accurate and the basket option is cheaper than the pair of single options.
OF FLEXIBLE
ANALYSIS AND VALUATION ASIAN OPTIONS
20.3
ASIAN AND FLEXIBLE ASIAN OPTIONS
FAA(n)
20.3.1
Flexible
In this section we use the following notation: T:
the option's maturity
t: r:
the current time,
t:
for i
W(n, a, i)P(i)
=
1, 2,
=
.
.
.,
n
(60)
n:
h:
(n 1)h: [r -(A -
i)}hn
ps:
with
W(n, a, i)
for i
=
=
1, 2,
n
...,
(61)
where
The main advantage of the GWA is its flexibility. The flexible geometrië average, which is a simple extension of the standard geometric average, is given by FGA(n)
When j= 0, the averaging period does not start and r>(n When j 0, n, I - l)h. and the option is at its maturity date. When 1 « j< n, the option lies in the averaging period. At the option's maturity date, the pay-off of the option based on the flexible geometric average is given by =
=
max
(K, {graa(n) -
0}
=
(64)
Under the assumption of log-normality, the value of the flexible geometric Asian option is given by its expected pay-off discounted to the present under the appropriate probability. The general formula given in Zhang (1995)is
C
(62)
S'"'
=
date,
the time remaining to maturity, a binary indicator which is 1 (-1) for a call (a put), refer respectively to flexible, geometric and arithmetic, the number of observations specified in the option contract, the observation frequency or the time interval between two consecetive observations, the number of observations already done, the length of the averaging period, the starting time of the averaging period, the correlation coefficient between assets i and j.
P''
a is a weighting positive parameter, P(i) is the ith observation.
(63)
Asian Options
f: GWA(n, a)
w(i)S,
=
where all the parameters are as defined above.
f, g, a Before valuing flexible Asian options, we introduce the flexible weighted average and flexible geometric and arithmetic averages. Following Zhang (1995),the general weighted average (GWA) is given by
421
=
(SA'(j)N($d _
+
) - (Ke
ga
"
N($d
_,)
(65)
)]
(66)
where with w(i)
n
=
W(n, a, i) as given in (61)for i
is thhenumbber co
=
1, 2,
...,
n, where
A'(j)
=
B'(j)exp[-r(r-
T
)
servations,
B'(0) Note that the log of the FGA corresponds underlying asset prices. The flexible arithmetic average, which average, is given by
to a flexible arithmetic is a simple extension
=
1, Bf(j)
average of the log of the of the standard arithmetic
ds
=
ln (S/K) =
S[r -
+
(n
-
i)h]
a2)
(r a
a2(Tr
yr
for I sjsn M [B'U)
(67) (68)
OPTIONS,
422
FUTURES
w2(i)[r
=
i)h] + 2
(n -
-
w(i)w(k)[r i
DERIYATIVES
ASIAN AND FLEXIBLE ASIAN OPTIONS
k)h]
Note that this formula can be obtained directly from the preceding formula by the current asset price by the approximation factor Kr
i-I
«
T
AND EXOTIC
(n
-
-
j+2 k-j+1
(70)
In the above formula (65), the weighted average of the returns of the already passed observations is B'(j). The term T _, is assimilated to the mean function. The term Ts is regarded as the effective variance function. This formula reduces to that in Kemma and Vorst (1990)and Turnbull and Wakeman 1/n for all i 1 to n. {1991)for a 0 and w(i) =
20.3.2
=
=
Approximating
Flexible
Arithmetic
Asian Options
20.3.3
Some
yr
=
{$'"(n)-
max
(K, 0}
(71)
Using the approximations given above and discounting the option pay-off, the flexible arithmetic Asian option price is given bv
C
Af(j)N((di_
(SK
=
ga
(Ke
)-
"
N((d _
)
(72)
replacing
Properties
When compared to standard options and standard Asian options, flexible arithmetic Asian options have some special characteristics with respect to the Greek-letter risk measures: the delta, gamma, vega, theta, rho, charm, etc. For standard Asian options the delta is fixed given the number of observations and the observation frequency. For the flexible arithmetic Asian options, the delta and the other Greeks depend on the weighting scheme used. For example, when the observation numbers 0.5, S 10%, 100, K 100, r 4 and the weight parameters a are v 10% and r « 1 year, and the observation frequency is 1 month, the values of the 10.066 and 10.057 and flexible arithmetic and geometric Asian options are respectively the option's delta is 0.85. The flexible arithmetic Asian option's value is greater than that of the flexible geometric Asian option. prices) are accurate and show a It seems that the formulas presented (approximated small under-valuation bias when compared to prices obtained by the Monte-Carlo method. The approximation formulas provide accurate results and are not time consuming. =
=
At the maturity date, the pay-off of the option based on the flexible arithmetic average is given by
423
=
=
=
=
=
with
SUMMARY In(SKL/K)
d*
(r
.=
where x is approximated
)
a
_,
+WFUM
(73)
by =
1 + (E[¢
]+
¼[(E[¢
])2+
var
(74)
(¢ )]
In this chapter, Asian options are analyzed and valued. First, we propose the different approaches for the valuation of arithmetic and geometric Asian options. Simulation results are given. Second, we present the general context for the analysis and valuation of basket options. Finally, we introduce the concept of flexible arithmetic and geometric mean to the valuation of flexible arithmetic and geometric Asian options.
with
E[¢
]
=
v var
iw(i)[1 - w(i)] - 2
oh
[i|w(i)]+
iw(i)
w(j)
(75)
POINTS •
where E[¢
] is the
mean function
with
flexible
weights w(i) for i
=
1 to n, with
• •
var
[i|w(i)]
=
(i -
M)2w(i),
M
=
(76)
iw(i)
• -a2)
v
=
•
h(r -
(77)
2
• • •
var(¢í)
and
=
2v2 var[i|w(i)]{E[¢
]-
iv'var
[i w(i)]}
+
4Û2hQ-
(E[¢
])2
•
FOR DISCUSSION
What is an average option? What is the pay-off of an average call option? What is the pay-off of an average put option? Describe briefly the different valuation approaches for Asian options. What is a basket option? What is a flexible Asian option? What is a flexible arithmetic Asian option? What is a flexible geometric Asian option? What are the main properties of Asian options?
-
Bibliography
Abramowitz, M. and Stegum, I. (1972)Handbook of Mathematical Functions. Dover, New York. Ahnani, M. (1998)Modèles de valorisation d'options exotique, Doctorate, Université de Paris-Dauphine. Altman, E.I. (1987)The anatomy of the high-yield bond market. Financial Analysts Journal, 43, July-August. Ambarish, R. and Subrahmanyam, M.G. (1989)Default risk and the valuation of highyield bonds: a methodological critique. Working paper, Salomon Brothers Center for the Study of Financial Institutions, New York University, NY. Arak, M. and Goodman, L. (1986)How to calculate better T-bond hedge ratios. Futures, 15-16, 56-7. Arak, M. and Goodman, L. (1987)Treasury bond futures: valuing the delivery options. Journal of Futures Markets, 7 (3),269-86. Arrow, K. (1953)Le röle des valeurs boursières pour la répartition la meilleure des risques. Colloque international CNRS, 41-7. Arrow, K. (1970)Essays in the Theory ofRisk Bearing. North-Holland, Amsterdam. Ayres, H.F. (1963)Risk aversion in the warrants market. Industrial Management Review, 4 (Fall), 497-505. Bachelier, L. (1900)Théorie de la Spéculation. Annales de l'Ecole Normale Supérieure, 17. Barnhill, T. (1988)The delivery option on forward contracts: comment. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 23, 337-49. Barnhill, T. and Seale, W. (1987)Valuation and optimal exercise of the switching option in treasury bond cash versus futures arbitrages. Working Paper 162, Columbia Futures Center. Barnhill, T. and Seale, W. (1988)Optimal exercise of the switching option in treasury bond arbitrages. Journal of Futures Markets, 8, 517-32. Barnhill, T. and Seale, W. (1990)Financing with hybrid securities having commodity Advances in Futures and Options option and forward contract characteristics. Research, 4, 137-51. Barone-Adesi, G. and Whaley, R.E. (1987)Efficient analytic approximation of American option values. Journal of Finance, 42 (June), 301-20. Bellalah, M. (1990a)Essais sur l'évaluation des options et des contrats à terme. Doctorat de l'Université Paris-Dauphine, June.
OPTIONS,
426
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
(1990b)Gestion Quantitativedu Portefouille et Nouveaux Marchés FinanEditions Nathan. Bellalah, M. (1995a)Wildcard options and the valuation of American options on the CAC 40 stock index. Working paper N9507, Université de Paris-Dauphine. of American options in the Bellalah, M. (1995b)A lattice approach for the valuation French market. Working paper N9508, Université de Paris-Dauphine. Bellalah, M. (1998) Les options et les dividendes: revue de la littérature. Revue Canadienne FINECO, No. 2, Summer, forthcoming. of futures and commodity options with information Bellalah, M. (1999)The valuation of Markets, Journal Futures September. costs, Bellalah, M. (1999) Les biais des modèles d'options révisités, Revue Française de
Bellalah, M. ciers.
Gestion, June. Bellalah, M. and Jacquillat, B. (1991a)Effet de la volatilité des taux sur l'évaluation des options. Working paper N9106, Université de Paris-Dauphine. Bellalah, M. and Jacquillat, B. (1991b)Effet d'un détachement de dividendes sur l'évaluation des options. Working paper N9110, Université de Paris-Dauphine. with information costs: theory Bellalah, M. and Jacquillat, B. (1995)Option valuation and empirical tests. Financial Review, 30 (3),617-37. Bellalah, M. and Prigent, J.L. (1997a)A note on the valuation of an exotic timing option. Journal of Futures Markets, 17 (4),483-7. Bellalah, M. and Prigent, J.L. (1997b)La fourchette optimale dans un marché non liquide d'options. Working paper N9701, Université de Paris-Dauphine. La fourchette optimale dans un marché concurrenBellalah, M. and Prigent, J.L.
(1997c)
tiel d'options. Working paper N9702, Université de Paris-Dauphine. Bellalah, M. and Prigent, J.L. (1997d)L'évaluation des options en présence d'une prime de liquidité verticale. Working paper N9703, Université de Paris-Dauphine. Bellalah, M. and Prigent, J.L. (1998)Les options et la liquidité. Revue Canadienne
FÍNECO, forthcoming. Bellalah, M. and Simon, Y. (1997a)Prix au comptant et prix à terme. Encyclopédie des Marchés Financiers, Economia, Paris. Bellalah, M. and Simon, Y. (1997b)Contrats à terme sur indice. Encyclopédie des Marchés Financiers, Economia, Paris. Bellman, R. and Dreyfus, S. (1962)Applied Dynamic Programming. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ. Benson, R. and Daniel, N. (1992)Up, over and out. Risk, 4 (6). Chapter 26 in From Black-Scholes to Black Holes. Risk Magazine Publications, London. The market spread, limit orders and options. Journal of Financial Berkman, H.
(1992)
Services Research, 2, 399-415. Bernstein, P.L. (1992) Are financial markets the problem or the solution? A reply to Michael Porter. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, Summer, 5 (2), 17-22. Bick, A. (1988)Producing derivative assets with forward contracts. Journal ofFinancial Analysis, 23 (2), 153-60. and Quantitative Black, F. (1975a)The Pricing of Complex Options and Corporate Liabilities. Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago, Chicago, IL. Black, E (1975b)Fact and fantasy in the use of options. Financial Analysts Journal, 31, July-August.
.
BIBLIOGRAPHY
427
Black, E (1976)Studies of stock price volatility changes. In Proceedings of the 1976 Meetings ofthe American Statistical Association, August, 177-81. Black, E and Cox, J.C. (1976) Valuing corporate securities: some effects of bond indenture conditions. Journal ofFinance, 31 (May), 351-67. Black, E and Scholes, M. (1972)The valuation of option contracts and a test of market efficiency. JournalofFinance, 27 (May), 399-417. Black, F. and Scholes, M. (1973)The pricing of options and corporate liabilities. Journal of Political Economy, 81 (May- June), 637-54. Black, F., Derman, E. and Toy, W. (1990)A one-factor model of interest rates and its applications to treasury bond options. Financial Analysts Journal, 46, 33-39. Blomeyer, E.C. (1986)An analytic approximation for the American put price for options Analysis, 21 (June), on stocks with dividends. Journal of Financial and Quantitative 229-33. Blume, M.E. and Keim, D.B. (1987) Lower-grade bonds: their risks and returns. Financial Analysts Journal, 43, July-August, 75-83. Blume, M.E. and Keim, D.B. (1989) Volatility patterns of fixed-income securities. Working paper, Salomon Brothers Center for the Study of Financial Institutions, New York University, NY. Boness, A.J. (1964)Elements of a theory of stock option value. Journal of Political Economy, 72 (April), 163-75. Bouaziz, L., Briys, E. and Crouhy, M. (1994)The pricing of forward-starting Asian options. Journal of Banking and Finance, 18 (5), 823-39. Bowie, J. and Carr, P. (1994)Static simplicity. Risk, 7 (9),45-49. Boyle, P. (1976)Rates of return as random variables. Journal of Risk and Insurance, 43 (December), 694-711. using a three jump process. International Options Boyle, P. (1986)Options valuation Journal, 3, 7-12. Boyle, P. (1988)A lattice framework for option pricing with two state variables. Journal ofFinancial and Quantitative Analysis, 23 (March), 1-12. Boyle, P. (1989)The quality option and the timing option in futures contracts. Journal of Finance, 44, 101-13. Boyle, P. and Turnbull, S. (1989)Pricing and hedging capped options. Journal ofFutures Markets, 9 (1),41-51. Boyle, P., Evnine, J. and Gibbs, S. (1989)Numerical evaluation of multivariate contingent claims. Review ofFinancial Studies, 2, 241-50. Brealey, R.A. and Myers, S.C. (1995)Principles of Corporate Finance. McGraw-Hill, New York. Brennan, M.J. and Schwartz, E.S. (1977a)Saving bonds, retractable bonds and callable bonds. Journal ofFinancial Economics, 5, 67-88. Brennan, M.J. and Schwartz, E.S. (1977b)The valuation of American put options. Journal of Finance, 32 (May), 449-63. Brennan, M.J. and Schwartz, E.S. (1977c)Convertible bonds: valuation and optimal strategies for call and conversion. JournalofFinance, 32 (December), 1699- 715. Analyzing convertible bonds. Journal of Schwartz, M.J. and E.S. Brennan, (1980) Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 15 (September), 461-74. Brennan, M.J. and Schwartz, E.S. (1990) Arbitrage in stock index futures. Journal of Business, 63, 7-31.
OPTIONS,
428
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
(1997)From Genoa to Kobe: natural hazards, insurance risks and the pricing of insurance-linked bonds. Working paper, Lehman Brothers. Briys, E. (1998)Taming Mother Nature: a primer on the pricing of nature-linked
Briys, E.
securities. Working paper, Lehman Brothers. Briys, E. and Crouhy, M. (1988)Creating and pricing hybrid foreign currency options. Financial Management, 17, 59-65. financial Briys, E. and Crouhy, M.L. (1993)Playing against (with?) the devil: managing risks for better corporate returns. European Management Journal, 11 (3),304-12. Briys, E. and de Varenne, E (1997)Valuing risky fixed rate debt: an extension. Journal of Analysis, 32 (June), 239-48. Financial and Quantitative Briys, E. and Solnik, B. (1992)Optimal currency hedge ratios and interest rate risk. Journal ofInternational Money and Finance, 11, 431-45. Briys, E. and Viala, P. (1996)One-sided idiosyncratic risk and optimal risk sharing rules: the case of insurance. Working paper, Groupe HEC. Briys, E., Crouhy, M. and Schöbel, R. (1991)The pricing of default-free interest rate cap, floor and collar agreements. Journal ofFinance, 46 (December), 1315-24Brock, W. and Kleidon, A. (1992)Periodic market closure and trading volume. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 16, 451-89. Brown, S.J. and Dybvig, P.H. (1986)The empirical implications of the Cox, Ingersoll, Ross theory of the term structure of interest rates. Journal of Finance, 41 (July),
617-30. Budd, N. (1983)The future of commodity index financing. Harvard Business Review, 61, 44-50. Canter, M.S., Cole, J.B. and Sandor, R.L. (1996)Insurance derivatives: a new asset class for the capital markets and a new hedging tool for the insurance industry. Journal of Derivatives, 4. Carr, P. (1988)Valuing bond futures and the quality option. Working paper, Graduate School of Management, UCLA, Los Angeles, CA. Carr, P. (1994)European put-call symmetry. Working paper, Cornell University, Ithaca, NY. Carr, P. and Bowie, J. (1994)Static simplicity. Risk, 7 (8),45-9. Carr, P., Jarrow, R. and Myneni, R. (1992)Alternative characterisations of American put options. Mathematical Finance, 2, April. Default risk and the duration of zero-coupon bonds. Journal of Chance, D.M.
(1990)
Finance, 45, 265-74. Chang, A. and Lansing, E. (1992) Option pricing when jump risk is systematic· Mathematical Finance, 2, April, 107-123. Chaplin, M. (1987)A formula for bond option values under an Ornstein-Uhlenbeck model for the spot. Actuarial Science Working Paper, 87, 87-115. Chateau, D. (1990)Valuation of capped variable rate loan commitments. Journal of Banking and Finance, 14, 717-28. Chen, A. (1970)A model of warrant pricing in a dynamic market. Journal of Finance, 25, 1041-60. Chen, A. (1991)Pricing stock and bond options when the default free rate is stochastic: a Analysis, 26 (3),433-4comment. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Cheng, S. (1985)Multi-asset contingent claims in a stochastic interest rate environment Working paper, Graduate School of Business, Columbia University, New York.
BIBLIOGRAPHY
429
Chesney, H., Elliott, R. and Gibson, R. (1993)Analytical solutions for the pricing of American bond and yield options. Mathematical Finance, 3, July. Chiang, R. and Okunev, J. (1993)An alternative formulation on the pricing of foreign currency options. Journal ofFutures Markets, 13, 123-141. Chowdry, B. (1986)Pricing of futures with quality option. Working paper, University of Chicago, Chicago, IL. (1963)Fourier Series and Boundary Value Problems, 2nd edn. McGrawHill, New York. Clark, C. (1961)The greatest of a finite set of random variables. Operations Research, 9, 145-62. Constantinides, G. (1984) Warrant exercise and bond conversion in competitive markets. Journal of Financial Economics, 13, 371-98. Conze, A. (1991)Path-dependent options: the case of geometric averages. Finance, 22,
Churchill, R.V.
7-22. Conze, A. and Viswanathan, R. (1991) Path dependent options: the case of lookback options. Journal ofFinance, 46, 1893-907. Courtadon, G. (1982)The pricing of options on default free bonds. Journal ofFinancial and Analysis, 17 (March), 75-100. Quantitative Cox, J.C. and Ross, S.A. (1976)The valuation of options for alternative stochastic 145-66. processes. JournalofFinancialEconomics,3, Englewood Markets. Prentice-Hall, Options Rubinstein, M. and Cox, J.C. (1985)
Cliffs, NJ. Cox, J.C., Ingersoll, J. and Ross, S.A. (1985a)An intertemporal general equilibrium model for asset prices. Econometrica, 53, 363-84. Cox, J.C., Ingersoll, J. and Ross, S.A. (1985b)A theory of the term structure of interest 53, 385-407. rates. Econometrica, Cox, J.C., Ross, S.A. and Rubinstein, M. (1979)Option pricing: a simplified approach. Journal ofFinancial Economics, 7 (September), 229-63. Cummins, J.D., Lewis, C.M. and Phillips, R.D. (1996)Pricing excess-of-loss reinsurance against catastrophic loss. Working paper, The Wharton School. contracts Cummins, J.M. (1977) Incentive contracting for national defense: a problem in optimal risk sharing. Bell Journal of Economics, 8 (1), 168-85. Cummins, J.D. and Geman, H. (1995)Pricing catastrophe insurance futures and call
March 1, 6-57. spreads: An arbitrage approach. JournalofFixedIncome, (1992)Beyond average intelligence. Risk, 5 (10),60-62. Cutland, N. and Kopp, P., Wollinger, W. (1990) A non-standard approach to option pricing. Mathematical Finance, 1 (4), 1-38. and cataclysms. Cutler, D. and Zeckhauser, R. (1996) Reinsurance for catastrophes Working paper, Harvard University, Cambridge, MA. D'Arcy, S.P. and France, VG. (1993)Catastrophic futures: a better hedge for insurers. Journal of Risk and Insurance, 59, 575-601. Day and Lewis (in press) Stock market volatility and the information content of stock index options. Journal of Econometrics. Debreu, G. (1954) Representation of a preference ordering by a numerical function. In R. New York. Thrall, C. Coombs and R. Davis (eds),Decision Processes.Wiley, Decamps, J.P. (1994) Integrating the risk and term structures of interest rates. Working Université de Toulouse, France. paper, GREMAQ,
Curran, M.
430
e
OPTIONS,
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
(1997)The economics of changing numeraire and time. Working paper, FFSA. Duffie, D. (1988)Securities Markets. Academic Press, New YorkDuffie, D. (1992a)From discrete to continuous time finance. Mathematical Finance, 2, January. Duffie, D. (1992b)Dynamic Asset Pricing Theory. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ. of the terrn structures of Duffie, D. and Singleton, K.J. (1995)Econometric modelling defaultable bonds. Working paper, Graduate School of Business, Stanford University, Stanford, CA. and risk Eberhart, A.C. and Senbet, L.W. (1993) Absolute priority rule violations incentives for financially distressed firrns. Financial Management, 22 (Autumn), 101-16. Eberhart, A.C., Moore, W.T. and Roenfeldt, R.L. (1990) Security pricing and deviations from the absolute priority rule in bankruptcy proceedings. Journal of Finance, 45, 1457-69. El Karoui, N. and Geman, H. (1993)A probabilistic approach to the valuation of general floating rate notes with an application to interest swaps. Unpublished working paper. El Karoui, N. and Rochet, J.-C. (1989)A pricing formula for options on coupon bonds. Working Paper 8925, Université Paris 6. Elliott, R., Myneni, R. and Viswanathan, R. (1990)A theorem of El Karoui, Karatzas applied to American options. Working paper, Stanford University, CA. and exercise strategy. Journal of Financial Emanuel, D. (1983) Warrant valuation Economics, 12, 211-35. Evnine, J. and Rudd, A. (1984)Option portfolio risk analysis. Journal of Portfolio Management, 10, 23-7. 40 Evnine, J. and Rudd, A. (1985)Index options: The early evidence. JournalofFinance,
de Varenne, E
(3),743-756.
Favier, J. (1987)De l'Or et des Epices, Naissance de l'Homme d'Affaires au Moyen-AgeFlammarion, Paris. Feiger, G. and Jacquillat, B. (1979) Currency option bonds, puts and calls on claims. Journal of Finance, 34 spot exchange and the hedging of contingent l 129-39. Feiger, G. and Jacquillat, B. (198l) International Finance. Allyn & Bacon, Boston, MAFiglewski, S. and Webb, G. (1993)Options, short sales, and market completeness Journal of Finance, 48, June, 1341-1356. Fisher, S. (1975) The demand for index bonds. Journal of Political Economy, 83, 509-34. Fisher, S. (1978)Call option pricing when the strike price is uncertain and the valuation of index bonds. JournalofFinance, 33, 169-76. Fleming, A. and Whaley, R.E. (1994)The value of wildcard options. JournalofFinance, 40 (1),215-36. Fons, J.S. (1994)Using default rates to model the term structure of credit risk. Financial Analysts Journal, 50 (Sept-Oct), 25-32. M.G. (1995) Idiosyncratic risk and the Franke, G., Stapleton, D.C. and Subrahmanyam, theory of optimal risk bearing. Working paper, EIASM. Franks, J.R. and Schwartz, E. (1988) The stochastic behavior of market variance
implied
BIBLIOGRAPHY
43 I
from the prices of index options. Working paper, University of California at Los Angeles. Franks, J.R. and Torous, W. (1989) An empirical investigation of U.S. firms in reorganiza44, 747-69. tion. JournalofFinance, Franks, J.R. and Torous, W. (1994)A comparison of financial recontracting in distressed exchanges and chapter ll reorganizations. Journal of Financial Economics, 24, 349370. Frenkel, J.A. and Levich, R.M. (1977)Transactions costs and interest arbitrage: tranquil versus turbulent periods. Journal ofPolitical Economy, 85 (6), 1209-26. vol. l. AcaFriedman, A. (1975)Stochastic Digarential Equations and Applications, demic Press, New York. Garbade, K. and Silber, W. (1983) Futures contracts on commodities with multiple varieties: an analysis of premiums and discounts. Journal ofBusiness, 56, 249-72. Garman, M. (1976)A general theory of asset valuation under diffusion state processes. Research Program in Finance, Working Paper 50, Institute of Business and Economic Research, University of California, Berkeley, CA. Garman, M. (1989) Recollection in tranquility. Risk, 2 (March), 16-18. Garman, M. (1992)Charm school. Risk, 5 (7). Garman, M. (1993)'Recollections in tranquility' and 'Semper tempus fugit', in From Black-Scholes to Black Holes. Risk magazine and Finex. Garman, M. and Hawkins, G. (1984)Another look at put call parity. Unpublished paper presented at the American Finance Association Meeting, December. Garman, M.B. and Kohlhagen, S.W. (1983)Foreign currency option values. Journal of International Money and Finance, 2 (December), 231-7. Gauthier, Y. (1995)Catastrophes Naturelles. Explora, Cité des Sciences et de l'Industrie, Pocket Sciences, Paris. Gay, G. and Manaster, S. (1984)The quality option implicit in futures contracts. Journal of Financial Economics, 13, 353-70. Gay, G. and Manaster, S. (1986)Implicit delivery options and optimal delivery strategies for financial futures contracts. Journal ofFinancial Economics, 16, 41-72. Gay, G. and Manaster, S. (1991)Equilibrium treasury bond futures pricing in the presence ofimplicitdeliveryoptions.JournalofFuturesMarkets,ll,623-45. Geman, H. and Yor, M. (1993) Bessel processes, Asian options and perpetuities. Mathematical Finance, 3, October, 349-375. Geman, H., El Karoui, N. and Rochet, J.-C. (1995)Changes of numeraire, changes of probability measure and option pricing. Journal of Applied Probability, 32, 443-458. Gentle, D. (1993)Basket weaving. Risk, 6 (6),5 I -52. Geske, R. (1977)The valuation of corporate liabilities as compound options. Journal of Analysis, 12 (November), 541-52. Financial and Quantitative Geske, R. (1978)The pricing of options with stochastic dividend yield. Journal of Finance, 33, May, 617-625. Geske, R. (1979a) The valuation of compound options. Journal of Financial Economics, 7, 63-81. American call options Geske, R. (1979b) A note on the analytical formula for unprotected with ofFinancial Journal 7, 375-80. Economics, known stocks dividends. on Geske, R. and Johnson, H.E. (1984)The American put option valued analytically. Journal ofFinance, 39 (December), 1511-24.
OPTIONS,
432
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
(1985)Valuation by approximation: a comparison of alternative option valuation techniques. Journal of Financial and QuantitativeAnalysis, 20 (March), 45-71. Goldman, M., Sosin, H. and Gatto, M. (1979) Path dependent options, buy at the low, sell atthehigh.JournalofFinance,34,ll11-28. Goldman, M., Sosin, H. and Shepp, L.A. (1979) Path-dependent options: buy at the low, sell at the high. Journal ofFinance, 34. securities as a new asset Goldman Sachs (1996)Assessing catastrophe-reinsurance-linked class. Goldman Sachs & Co., New York. Grabbe, J.O. (1983)The pricing of call and put options on foreign exchange. Journal of International Money and Finance, 2 (December), 239-53. Grinblatt, M. (1994)An analytic solution for interest rate swap spreads. Working paper, UCLA Anderson Graduate School of Management, Los Angeles, CA. Guy Carpenter (l995) The emerging asset class: insurance risk. Guy Carpenter & Co., New York. Harris, M. and Raviv, A. (1985)A sequential signalling model of convertible debt call
Geske, R. and Shastri, K.
policy. Journal of Finance, 40, 1263-81. Harrison, J.M. (1985) Brownian Motion and Stochastic Flow Systems. Wiley, New York. Harrison, J.M. and Kreps, D. (1978)Martingales and the pricing of contingent claims. Research Paper 444, Stanford University, Stanford, CA, May. securities Harrison, J.M. and Kreps, D. (1979)Martingales and arbitrage in multiperiod markets. Journal of Economic Theory, 20, 381-408. Harrison, J.M. and Pliska, S.R. (1981)Martingales and stochastic integrals in the theory of continuous trading. Stochastic Processes and Their Applications, II, 215-60. Hart, l. and Ross, M. (1994)Striking continuity. Risk, 7 (6),50-51. Hayes, R.H. and Abernathy, W.J. (1980)Managing our way to economic decline. Harvard Business Review, July/August, 67- 77. Hayes, R.H. and Garvin, M. (1982)Managing as if tomorrow matters. Harvard Business Review, May June, 71-9. Heath, D., Jarrow, R. and Morton, A. (1987)Bond pricing and the term structure of Working paper, for contingent claims valuation. interest rates: a new methodology Cornell University, Ithaca, NY. (Revised edition, 1989) Heath, D., Jarrow, R. and Morton, A. (1989)Contingent claims valuation with a random evolution of interest rates. Review ofFutures Markets, 9 (1),54-76. Heath, D., Jarrow, R. and Morton, A. (1992)Bond pricing and the term structure of Econometrica, 60 interest rates: a new methodology for contingent claims valuation. 77-105. (l), with Heston, S. (1993a)A closed form solution for options with stochastic volatility application to bond and currency options. Review ofFinancial Studies, 6, 327-43. Heston, S. (1993b)Invisible parameters in option prices. Journal of Finance, 48 (3),
933-47. Heynen, R. and Kat, H. Heynen, R. and Kat, H. Heynen, R. and Kat, H. 3, 253-274.
(1994a)Crossing barriers. Risk, 7 (6), 45-58. (1994b) Selective memory. Risk, 7 (11), 56-59. (1994c) Partial barrier options. Journal of Financial
Engineering,
BlBLlOGRAPHY
433
Ho, T. and Lee, S. (1986)Term structure movements and pricing interest rate contingent claims.JournalofFinance,41,1011-29. Ho, T. and Lee, S. (1990)Interest rate futures options and interest rate options. Financial Review, 3, 345-70. Ho, T. and Saunders, A. (1983)Fixed rate loan commitments, takedown risk and the Analysis, 18, dynamics of hedging with futures. Journal of Financial and Quantitative 499-516. Hoffman, N., Platen, E. and Schweizer, M. (1992)Option pricing under incompleteness and stochastic volatility. Mathematical Finance, 2, 153-87. Horrigan, J. (1974)Some hypotheses on the valuation of stock warrants. Journal of Business Finance and Accounting. Hudson, M. (1992)The value in going-out. Risk, 4 (3).Chapter 27 in From Black-Scholes to Black Holes. Risk Magazine Publications, London. Hull, J. (1993)Options, Futures and Other Derivative Securities. Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ. Hull, J. and White, A. (1987)The pricing of options on assets with stochastic volatilities. Journal of Finance, 42, 281-300. Hull, J. and White, A. (1988)An analysis of the bias caused by a stochastic volatility in option pricing. Advances in Futures and Options Research, 3, 29-61. Hull, J. and White, A. (1990) Pricing interest-rate derivative securities. Review of Financial Studies, 3, 573-92. Hull, J. and White, A. (1993a)One factor interest rate models and the valuation of interest Analysis, 28, June, rate derivative securities. Journal of Financial and Quantitative 235-254. Hull, J. and White, A. (1993b)Efficient procedures for valuing European and American path-dependent options. Journal ofDerivatives, 1 (Autumn), 21-3. Ingersoll, J. (1977a)A contingent claims valuation of convertible securities. Journal of Financial Economics, 4, 289-322. Ingersoll, J. (1977b)An examination of corporate call policies on convertible securities. Journal of Finance, 32, 463-78. Ingersoll, J. (1983)The pricing of commodity linked bonds: discussion. Journal of Finance, 38. Ingersoll, J. (1987) Theory of Financial Decision Making. Rowman and Littlefield, Totowa, NJ. Jamshidian, E (1989)An exact bond option formula. Journal of Finance, 44 (March) 205-9. Jamshidian, E (1991)Bond and option valuation in the gaussian interest rate model. Research in Finance, 9, 131-70. Jarrow, R.A. and Eisenberg, L.K. (1991) Option pricing with random volatilities in complete markets. Working paper, Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta. Jarrow, R.A. and Rudd, A. (1982)Approximate option valuation for arbitrary stochastic processes. Journal ofFinancial Economics, 10 (November), 346-69. Jarrow, R.A. and Rudd, A. (1983)Option Pricing. Irwin, Homewood, IL. Jarrow, R. and Turnbull, S. (1992) Pricing options on financial securities subject to default risk. Working paper, Graduate School of Management, Cornell University, Ithaca, NY.
434
OPTIONS,
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
Jennings, and
E.H. (1974)An estimate of convertible bond premiums. Journal.of Financial Analysis, 9 (January), 33-56. Quantitative M. and Meckling, W. (1976)Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agene
Jensen, Economics, 3, 305-60. costs and honorship structure. JournalofFinancial Johnson, H.E. (1981)The pricing of complex options. Unpublished manuscript. Johnson, H.E. (1983)An analytic approximation to the American put price. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 18 (March), 141-8. Johnson, H.E. (1987)Options on the maximum or minimum of several assets. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 22, 227-83. Johnson, H.E. and Shanno, D. (1987)Option pricing when the variance is changing. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 22, 143-51. Jones, E.P., Mason, S.R and Rosenfeld, E. (1984)Contingent claim analysis of corporate capital structures: an empirical investigation. Journal of Finance, 39 (July), 611-25. Jorion, R (1995)Big Bets Gone Bad. Academic Press, New York. Kahaner, D.C. and Nash, S. (1989) Numerical Methods and Software. Prentice Hall Series in Computational Mathematics. Kalay, A. and Subrahmanyam, M.G. (1984)The ex-dividend day behaviour of option prices. Journal ofBusiness, 57, 13-28. Kane, A. and Marcus, A.J. (1986)The quality option in the treasury bond futures market: an empirical assessment. Journal of Futures Markets, 6, 231-48. Kassouf, S. (1968)Warrant price behavior 1945 to 1964. Financial Analysts Journal, 24 (Jan-Feb), 123-6. Kemma, A.G.Z. and Vorst, A.C.F. (1990)A pricing method for options based on average assetvalues.JournalofBankingandFinance,14,ll3-29. Kendall, M.G. and Stuart, A. (1969)The Advanced Theory of Statistics, vol. l. Charles Griftin, London. Kim, J., Ramaswamy, K. and Sundaresan, S. (1993)Does default risk in coupons affect the valuation of corporate bonds: a contingent claims model. Financial Management, 22 (Autumn), 117-31. King, R. (1984)The effect of convertible bond equity values on dilution and leverage. Accounting Review, 59 (July), 419-31. Kleindorfer, P. and Kunreuther, H. (1996)Challenges facing the insurance industry in managing catastrophic risks. Working paper, The Wharton School. Knoch (1992)The pricing of foreign currency options with stochastic volatilities. PhD dissertation, Yale School of Organization and Management. Kunitimo, N. and Ikeda, M. (1992)Pricing options with curved boundaries. Mathematical Finance, 2 (4),275-298. toward an Lamoureux, C. and Lastrapes, D. (1993)Forecasting stock return variance: understanding of stochastic implied volatilities. Review of Financial Studies, 6, 293-
326. time markov model of the term structure of credit risk Lando, D. (1993)A continuous spreads. Working paper, Graduate School of Management, Cornell University, Ithaca, NY. Leabo, D. and Rogalski, R. (1975) Warrant price movements and the efficient market model. JournalofFinance, 30, 163-77. Lee, C.J (1981)The pricing of corporate debt: a note. Journal of Finance, 36, l 187-9.
BIBLIOGRAPHY
Lee, J. and Nayar, N. (1993) A transaction data analysis of arbitrage options and index futures. Journal of Futures Markets, 13, 889-902.
435
between index
Securities. New York. Lehman Brothers (1997)Introduction to Catastrophic-Linked Leland, H. (1994a) Corporate debt value, bond covenants, and optimal capital structure. JournalofFinance, 49, September, 1213-1252. Leland, 11. (1994b) Bond prices, yield spreads, and optimal capital structure with default risk. Finance Working Paper 240, University of California at Berkeley, Berkeley, CA. Leland, H. and Pyle, D. (1977) Information asymmetries, financial structure, and financial intermediation.JournalofFinance,32(May),371-87. Le Roy Ladurie, E. (1983)Histoire du Climat depuis l'An Mil. Flammarion, Paris. Levi, M.D. (1983)International Finance, 2nd edn. McGraw-Hill, New York. Levy, E. (1990)Asian arithmetic. Risk, 3 (May), 7-8. Levy, E. and Turnbull, S. (1992)Average intelligence. Risk, 5 (2), 53-59. Litzenberger, R.H. and Rolfo, A. (1984) An international study of tax effects on governmentbonds.JournalofFinance,39(1),March,1-22. Livingston, M. (1987)The delivery option on forward options. Journal of Financial and Analysis, 22, 79-87. Quantitative analysis and applications. Longstaff, F. (1990)Pricing options with extendible maturities, Journal ofFinance, 45, 935-57. Longstaff, E and Schwartz, E. (1994)A simple approach to valuing risky fixed and floating rate debt and determining swap spreads. Working paper, UCLA, Los Angeles, CA. Longstaff, F. and Schwartz, E. (1995)A simple approach to valuing risky fixed and 50, 798-819. floating rate debt and determining swap spreads. JournalofFinance, Madan, D. and Milne, F. (1991) Option pricing with VG Martingale components. Mathematical Finance, 1, 39-55. Madan, D. and Unal, H. (1993) Pricing the risks of default. Working paper, College of Business, University of Maryland. in securities markets. Journal of Finance, 47 Madhavan, A. (1992) Trading mechanics (2), 607-41. and implicaMargrabe, W. (1976) Alternative investment performance fee arrangements ßell Journal of Economics, 7 (Autumn), policy: a comment. tions for SEC regulatory 716-18. Margrabe, W. (1978)The value of an option to exchange one asset for another. Journal of Finance, 33, 177-86. Masulis, R. and Korwar, A. (1986)Seasoned equity offerings: an empirical investigation. Journal of Financial Economics, 15 (January), 91-l 18. McCulloch, J.H. (1975a)An estimate of the liquidity premium. Journal of Political Economy,83,95-ll9. McCulloch, J.H. (1975b)The tax adjusted yield curves. Journal of Finance, 30 (June),
811-30. McKean, H.P. Jr. (1969) Stochastic Integrals. Academic Press, New York. McKinsey (1990)Cash is king. The McKinsey Quarterly, Spring, 82-94. McMillan, L. (1986)Analytic approximation for the American put option. Advances in Futures and Options Research, 1, l 19-39. Mehdi, J. (l982)Stochastic Processes. Wiley Eastern, New Delhi. Melino, A. and Turnbull, S.M. (1987) Estimations of the parameters describing the Libor
436
OPTIONS,
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
interest rate process. Progress report, Department of Economics, University of Toronto. Melino, A. and Turnbull, S.M. (1990)Pricing foreign currency options with stochastic volatility.JournalofEconometrics,45,239-65. Merton, R.C. (1971)Optimum Consumption and Portfolio rules in Continuous-time. Journal ofEconomic Theory, 3, 373-413. Merton, R.C. (1973a)Theory of rational option pricing. Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 4, 141-83. Merton, R.C. (1973b)The relationship between put and call option prices: comment. Journal ofFinance, 28 (March), 183-4. Merton, R.C. (1974)On the pricing of corporate debt: the risk structure of interest rates. JournalofFinance,29,449-70. Merton, R.C. (1976)Option pricing when underlying stock returns are discontinuous. JournalofFinancialEconomics,3,Jan-March,125-144. Merton, R.C. (1987)An equilibrium market model with incomplete information. Journal of Finance, 42, 483-510. Merton, R.C. (1988)On the application of the continuous-time theory of finance to financial intermediation and insurance. Geneva Association Lecture, Centre HEC-ISA, France. Merton, R.C. (1992)Continuous Time Finance. Blackwell, Oxford. Mikkelson, W. (1981) Convertible calls and security returns. Journal of Financial Economics, 9 (September), 237-64. Milgrom, P. and Roberts, J. (1992)Economics, Organization and Management. PrenticeHall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ. Miller, M. (1986)Financial innovation: the last twenty years and the next. Journal of Analysis, 21 (December), 451-71. Financial and Quantitative Miller, M. (1991)Financial Innovations and Market Volatility. Blackwell, Oxford. Miller, M. and Scholes, M. (1980)Executive compensation, taxes and incentives. Working Paper 42, University of Chicago, Chicago, IL. Modigliani, E and Miller, M. (1958)The cost of capital, corporation finance, and the theory of investment. American Economic Review, 48, 261-97. Modigliani, E and Pogue, G.A. (1975)Alternative investment performance fee arrangements and implications for SEC regulatory policy. Bell Journal of Economics, 6, 127-60. Myers, S.C. (1987)Finance theory and financial strategy. Midland Corporate Finance Journal, 5 (Spring), 6-13. Myers, S. and Majluf, N. (1984) Corporate financing and investment decisions when firms have information that investors do not have. Journal ofFinancial Economics, 13, 198-221. Nelken, I. (1993)Square deals. Risk, 6, April, 52-55. Nelken, I. (1996)Handbook of Exotic Options. Irwin, New York. Nielsen, L., Saa-Requejo, J. and Santa-Clara, P. (1993)Default risk and interest rate risk: the terrn structure of default spreads. Working paper, INSEAD. Noddings, T. (1973)The Dow Jones Irwin Guide to Convertible Securities. Dow Jones Irwin, Homewood, IL. Officer, L.H. and Willet, T. (1980) The covered arbitrage schedule: a critical survey of recent developments. Journal ofMoney, Credit and Banking, 2, 247-57.
BIBLtOGRAPHY
437
Ogden, J.P. (1987)Determinants
of the ratings and yields on corporate bonds: tests of the contingent claims model. Journal ofFinancia/ Research, 10 (4),329-39. O'Hara, M. (1994)Market Microstructure Theory. Blackwell, Oxford. Ornberg, E. (1987a)The valuation of American put options with exponential exercise policies. Advances in Futures and Options Research, 2, l 17-42. Omberg, E. (1987b)A note on the convergence of binomial pricing and compound option models. Journal ofFinance, 42 (June), 463-70. Omberg, E. (1988)Efficient discrete time jump process models in option pricing. Journal ofFinancial and Quantitative Analysis, 23 (2), 161-174. Omberg, E. (1991)On the theory of perfect hedging. Advances in Futures and Options Research, 5, l-30. Parkinson, M. (1972) Empirical warrant stock relationships. Journal ofBusiness, 45 (October), 563-9. Parkinson, M. (1977) Option pricing: the American put. Journal ofBusiness, 50 (January), 21-36. Pechil, A. (1994)A synopsis of certain option pricing formulae. Unpublished MS.
Pechil, A. (1995)Classified information. Risk, 8 (6),June, 59-61. Peters, T.J. and Waterman, R.H. Jr. (1982) In Search of Excellence: Lessons fi-om America's Best Run Companies. Harper & Row, New York. Pitts, C.G. and Selby, M.J. (1983)The pricing of corporate debt: a further note. Journal ofFinance, 38 (4), 1311-13. Porter, M.E. (1992a) Capital choices: changing the way America invests in industry. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 5 (2),4-17. Poterba, J.A. and Summers, L.M. (1988)Mean reversion in stock prices: evidence and implications.JournalofFinancialEconomics,22,27-59. Porter, M.E. (1992b)Capital disadvantage: America's failing capital investment system. Harvard Business Review, Septernber October, 65-82. Rabinovitch, R. (1989) Pricing stock and bond options when the default free rate is stochastic. Journal of Financial and QuantitativeAnalysis, 24 (December), 447-57. Ramaswamy, K. and Sundaresan, S. (1985)The valuation of options on futures contracts. Journal ofFinance, 40, 1319-40. Randall Woolridge, J. (1988) Competitive decline and corporate restructuring: is a myopic stock market to blame? Continental Bank Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, Spring, 26-36. Rappaport, A. (1992)CFOs and strategists: forging a common framework. Harvard Business Review, May June, 84-91. Rendleman, R.J. and Barter, B.J. (1980)The pricing of options on debts securities. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 15 (March), ll -24. Resnik, B.G. and Hennigar, E. (1983)The relationship between futures and cash prices for US treasury bonds. Review of Research in Futures Markets, 2, 283-312. Ritchken, P. (1987)Options: Theory, Strategy and Applications. Scott Foresman, Greenview, IL. Ritchken, P. and Boenawen, K. (1990)On arbitrage free pricing of interest rate contingent claims. Journal ofFinance, 55 (1), 259-64. Robbins, E. and Schatzberg, J. (1986) Callable bonds: a risk reducing signalling mechanism. Journal of Finance, 41 (September), 935-49.
438
OPTIONS,
FUTURES
AND EXOTIC
DERIVATIVES
Rodriguez, R.M. and Carter, E. (1979) International Financial Management. Prentice Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ. Roll, R. (1977)An analytic valuation formula for unprotected American call options on Economics, 5, 251-8. stocks with known dividends. JournalofFinancial Ross, S. (1977) The determination of financial structure: the incentive signalling 8 (Spring), 23-40. approach. BellJournalofEconomics, Ross, S. (1989)Financial markets, financial marketing and financial innovation. Journal ofFinance, 44 (3),541-56. Ross, S. and Hart, I. (1994)Striking continuity. Risk, 7 (6), June, 51-5. Rubinstein, M. (1983) Displaced diffusion option pricing. Journal of Finance, 38 (March), 213-17. Rubinstein, M. (1985) Nonparametric tests of alternative option pricing snodels. Journal of Financial Economics, 40, 455-80. Rubinstein, M. (1991a) Pay now, choose later. Risk, 4 (2), February, 44-47. 53-56. Rubinstein, M. (1991b) Double trouble. Risk, 4, December-January, Rubinstein, M. (1991c)Options for the undecided. Risk, 4, April, 70-73. Rubinstein, M. (1991d)Somewhere over the rainbow. Risk, 4 (10),November, 63-6. Rubinstein, M. (1992)Exotic options. Presented at the FORC Conference, Warwick. 49 (3),771-818. Rubinstein, M. (1994)Implied binomial trees. JournalofFinance, Rubinstein, M. and Reiner, E. (1991a)Breaking down the barriers. Risk, 4 (8),28-35. Rubinstein, M. and Reiner, E. (1991b)Unscrambling the binary code. Risk, 4 (8), 75-83. Rubinstein, R.Y. (1981)Simulation and the Monte Carlo Method. Wiley, New York. Runggaldier, W. and Mercumo, E (1993)Option pricing for jump diffusions: approximation and their interpretations. Mathematical Finance, 3, April. Rush, D.E and Melicher, R.W. (1974) An empirical examination of factors which infiuence warrant prices. Journal ofFinance, 29, 1449-66. Samuelson, P. (1965)Rational theory of warrant pricing. Industrial Management Review, 6, 13-31. Samuelson, P. (1972) The Collected Scientific Papers of Paul Samuelson (ed. R.C. Merton). MIT Press, Cambridge,
MA.
model complete of warrant pricing that Industrial Management Review, 10, 17-46. Sandsnann, K. (1993)The pricing of options with an uncertain interest rate: a discrete time approach. Mathematical Finance, 3 (April), 201-16. Sarig, O. and Warga, A. (1989)Some empirical estimates of the term structure of interest rates. Journal ofFinance, 44 (5), 1351-60. Schervish, M. (1985)Algorithm ASl95: multivariate normal probabilities with error bound. Applied Statistics, 34 (January), 103-4. Schwartz, E. (1977)The valuation of warrants: implementing a new approach. Journal o Financial Economics, 4, 79-93. Scott, L.O. (1987) Option pricing when the variance changes randomly. Journal o Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 22, 419-38. Scott, L.O. (1991)Random-variance option pricing: empirical tests of the model and delta-sigma hedging. Advances in Futures and Options Research, 5, 113-35. Security Exchange Commission (1985) Institutional Ownership, Tender Offers and Long Term Investment. Office of the Chief Economist, Washington, D.C. Shapiro, A. and Titman, S. (1986) An integrated approach to corporate risk manage-
Samuelson, E and Merton, R.C. maximises
utility.
(1969) A
BIBLIOGRAPHY
439
ment. In J.M. Stern and D.H. Chew, Jr. (eds), The Revolution in Corporate Finance. Basil Blackwell, Oxford. Shepp, L.A. (1978)The joint density of the maximum and its location for a Wiener process with drift. BTL Memorandum, January. Sigma-Swiss Re (1996a) Natural catastrophes and major losses in 1995: decrease compared to previous year, but continually high level of losses since 1989. Report no. 2, Sigma-Swiss Re. Sigma-Swiss Re (1996b)Insurance derivatives and securitization: new hedging perspectives for the US catastrophe insurance market? Report no. 5, Sigma-Swiss Re. Siinpson, M. (1997)Weather derivatives: shelter from the storm? Energy and Power Risk Management, 1, Dec. 1996-Jan. 1997. Smith, C.W. (1976) Option pricing: a review. Journal of Financial Economics, 3 (Jan-March), 3-52. Smith, C.W. (1977)Alternative methods for raising capital: rights versus underwritten offerings. Journal of Financial Economics, 5, 273-307. Smith, C.W. (1979) Applications of option pricing analysis. In J.L. Bucksler (ed.), Handbook ofFinancial Economics. North-Holland, New York. Smith, C.W. (1986)Investment banking and the capital acquisition process. Journal of Financial Economics, 15 (January), 3-29. Smith, C.W. and Warner, J.B. (1978)On financial contracts and optimal capital structure: an analysis of bonds covenants. Unpublished paper, University of Rochester, Rochester, NY. Smith, C.W. and Warner, J.B.
(1979) Bankruptcy, secured debt, and optimal capital 34, 247-51. structure comment. JournalofFinance, Smith, C.W. and Watts, R.L. (1981)Incentive and tax effects ofUS executive compensation plans. Unpublished MS. Smithson, C. (1991)Wonderful life. Risk, 4 (9)(October), 50-51. Spindel, M. (1992)Easier done than said. Risk, 5 (9),October, 77-80. Sprenkle, C. (1961)Warrant prices as indications of expectations. Yale Economic Essays, 1, 179-232. Sprenkle, C.M. (1964)Warrant prices as indicators of expectations and preferences. In E Cootner (ed.),The Random Character of Stock Market Prices. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, 412-74. Stapleton, R. and Subrahmanyam, H. (1993)The analysis and valuation of interest rate options. Journal ofBanking and Finance, 17, 95-126. Stein, J. (1989)Overreactions in the option markets. Journal ofFinance, 44, 101l-23. Stein, E.M. and Stein, J.C. (1991)Stock price distributions with stochastic volatility: an analytic approach. Review of Financial Studies, 4, l13-35. between put and call option values. Journal of Finance, Stoll, H. (1969)The relationship 24, 802-24. Stoll, H. and Whaley, R.E. (1986) The new option markets. In A.E. Peck (ed.),Futures Markets: Their Economic Role. American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research, Washington, DC. Stulz, R.M. (1981) A model of international asset pricing. Journal of Financial Economics, 9, 383-407. Stulz, R.M. (1982)Options on the minimum or maximum of two risky assets: analysis Journalof Financial Economics, 10, 161-85. and applications.
OPTIONS,
440
S
FUTURES
(1985) The determinants
z, R.M. and Smith, C.W.
AND EXOTIC
of firms' hedging policies. Journal
Analysis, December, 391-405. Quantitative and C.W. R.M. Smith, Stulz, (1992)Trading mechanics in securities Finance, 47 (2),607-41. Sweet, A.L. and Hardin, J.C. (1970)Solution for some diffusion of Financial
DERIVATIVES
and
markets. Journal of processes
with two
Applied Probability, 423-31. Thakor, A. and Udell, G. (1987)An economic rationale for the pricing structure of bank loan commitments. Journal of Banking and Finance, 11. Thorp, E. and Kassouf, S. (1967)Beat the Market. Random House, New York. Tilley, J.A. and Latainer, G.D. (1985)A synthetic option framework for asset allocation. Financial Analysts Journal, 41 (May-June), 32-43. Trigeorgis, L. (1993)The nature of option interactions and the valuation of investments Analysis, 28, 1-20. with multiple real options. Journal ofFinancial and Quantitative barriers. Journal
.
.
.
Turnbull, S. (1987) Option Valuation. Holt, Rinehart and Winston, Toronto· Turnbull, S. (1992)The price is right. Risk, 5 (4), 54-55. Turnbull, S. and Wakeman, L. (1991) A quick algorithm for pricing European average options. Journal of Financial and QuantitativeAnalysis, 26 (September), 377-89 options containing the wildcard of cash-settlement Valerio, T. (1989)The valuation feature. Unpublished MS, University of Pennsylvania. Van Horne, J. (1985)On financial innovations and excesses. Journal of Finance, 40 (July), 621-31. of the term structure. Journal of Vasicek, O. (1977)An equilibrium characterization Financial Economics, 5, 177-88. Vorst, T. (1992)Analytic boundaries of average exchange rate options. Econometric Institute, Erasmus. of claims priority. Journal of Weiss, L.A. (1990) Bankruptcy costs and violation Financial Economics, 20 (May), 239-76 of American call options on stocks with known Whaley, R.E. (1981)On the valuation of Journal Financial Economics, 9, 375-80. dividends. Whaley, R.E. (1982)Valuation of American call options on dividend paying stocks: empirical tests. Journal ofFinancial Economics, 10 (March), 29-58. Whaley, R.E. (1986)Valuation of American futures options: theory and empincal tests Journal ofFinance, 41 (March), 127-50Whaley, R.E. and Harvey, C.R. (1992) Dividends and S&P 100 index option valuation. .
.
.
.
Journal ofFutures Markets, 12 (2), 123-37. Wiggins, J.B. (1987)Option values under stochastic volatility: theory and empirical estimates. Journal of Financial Economics, 19, 351-72 Winkler, R.L., Roodman, G.N. and Britney, R.R. (1972)The determination of partial moments. Management Science, 19, 290-7. implied by foreign Xu Xinzhong and Taylor, S. (1994)The term structure of volatilities Analysis, 29, 57-74. exchange options. Journal ofFinancial and Quantitative lattice approach to option pricing. Journal of Futures Yisong, T. (1993) A modified Markets, 13, 563-77. Zhang, P.G. (1995) Flexible arithmetic Asian options. Journal of Derivatives, 3 (Spring), 53-63.
in d ex
of
Absolute priority rule 213 AFFI252 AlG Combined Risks 227 Alcar Group 6 All-or-nothing option 361 AM International 8-9 American call options on spread 322 valuation175 Arnerican calls early exercise with continuous
distributions 159 early exercise with discrete
distributions 159-61 early exercise without distributions 159 on dividend paying stocks 282-3 with dividends 290-1 American cap options, simulation 178 American cap prices 178, 179 American commodity options 163-5 American futures options 166-8 American options 157-79 applications 176 early exercise 170 m French market 267-72 numerical pricing methods 281-95 pricing 158 pricing models 158 valuation 158-63 with discrete cash distributions 170-6 with dividends 175 American puts early exercise with continuous distributions 162 early exercise with discrete earlyde erreb ni hl -d stributions 161-2 paying stocks 284-5 dividend on price with dividends 266-8 with dividends 291-2 Apple Computer 2-3 Arbitrage arguments 4l4
between futures 101-2
Arbitrage
index
options and
Arbitrage portfolio, and Itõ's differential 42-3 Arrow-Debreu security 50 Asian options 409-20 average price options 411-18 B-B-C approach 417-18 Curran approach 416 C-Vapproach415 K-Vapproach 414 T-W approach 414 valuation 413-18 Asset-liability management (ALM) 219 Asset-or-nothing options 369-70 Asset prices 15, 60 continuous time processes for 28-34 dynamics 27-47, 262, 265 in complete markets 49-71, 73-86 At-maturity trigger forward contract 367 At-the-money down-and-in calls 386 At-the-money option 253 ATT 4-5 Auction markets 14, 15
Bacheller call values 89 Bachelier formula 88-9 Backward difference 57 Bank deposit rates 185-6 Bankruptcy 9, 212, 214 Bankruptcy-tnggermg mechamsm Barrier options 84-6, 359 90 analysis 361-8 categories 360 characteristics 368 bvaal atl edgin373f 3886-8 Basket options 418-20 valuation 418-20 153 BAW model l14-20, Bearish put spread 23 Binary barrier options 359-90
204
441
INDEX
Binary barrier options (cont.) analysis 361-8 valuation of368-71 Binomial model 330 Binomial option pricing model 43 Binomial process 161 Binomial pyramid 320-3 Binomial tree 264 Bivariate cumulative normal density function 175 Black and Scholes. See B-S Black's model 105-7, 152 Bond futures traded on LIFFE, tions on 109-10 Bond options 103-4 Rabinovitch's model 189 Bondholders' final pay-off 200 Boness formula 90 Boolean digitals 364 Boundary binary option 363 Boundary conditions 58, 61, 76-8, 94, 16 Box spread strategy 25-6 Brennen and Schwartz model 284 Briys-de Varenne model 207-24 Brownian bridges l 14 Brownian motion 28-31, 81 -3, 85, 88, 199, 205 and martingale 30-l geometric 40 mathematical definiton 30 p-dimensional 40 standard 31 standard independent 39 see also Wiener process B-S call option 56 B-S economy 76-9, 81, 83 B-S equation 78 B-S hedge portfolio 42 B-S method 39, 50, 5l 151 B-S mode192-l04, applications 99-104 precursors 88-92 B-S partial differential equation 42 B-S pricing of options 53 B-S process 39 B-S solution 83
B-S theory 88 Bullish call spread 22
CAC40 index 268, 314, 402 Calendar spread 16, 17 California Earthquake Authority 227 Call on maximum of two assets 316 Call on minimum Call options 77
of two assets 314
16
Continuous-time model 229 Continuous-time processes for asset
model 92-5 sensitivity parameters for 130-3 Call ratio strategy 23 Call sensitivity parameters 151-3 Call spread 22-3 Call values, with jump-difTusion process 24 Call values function 98 Call's delta 125 Call's elasticity 128-9 Call's gamma 126 Calls on the maximum 324 Calls on the minimum 323 Call's Rho 128 Call's theta 127 Call's vega 127 Capital Asset Pricing Model 43, 106, 302 Capitalization factor 75 over time 75 CAPM theory 227 Capped options 348 50 Capped variable loan commitments 168-70
prices 28-34
Continuous-time stochastic process 46 Contracts 8 Conversions
50
numerical solution 287-8 simulations 288 specificities 285-9 valuation 286-7 Convertible call and put prices 293-5
Convertibles 13 Corporate asset process 199 Corporate Corporate
1
Complex binaries 361-4 Complex chooser options 307 Nelken's approach 309-10 Rubinstein's approach 308-9 Compound digitals 360 Compound option 171-4 generalization
173
Conditional expectation 46 7 Constant elasticity of variance (CEV) difths process 243-4 Constant trigger level 230 Contingent claims 50, 56, 274-5 modeling 198- 202 Continuous auction systems 14 Continuous barrier options 382 3 Continuous quote-driven system 13-14 Continuous strike option 383-4 Continuous strike range options 384
24-5
Convertible bonds 285-8
Cash flow 6 Cash-or-nothing options 369 Charm 123, 124 Chen's correction to Rabinovitch's model 190 Chicago Board Options Exchange 14, 26, 192 Choice date 307 Chooser options 307-10 Chrysler 8 Closed-form pricing formula 233 Collar 349 Color 123 Commodity futures options 120 Commodity movements 10 Commodity options 120 Complete markets 49-71, 74-5, 199 asset pricing in 49 71, 73-86 characterizations
443
INDEX
øn
asset volatility 216
bonds
interest rate elasticity of 219-24 pricing of 197-224 valuation 197-224 Corporate default 203 Corporate option bonds 326-7 Corporate spreads pricing of 202 term structure of 203-5 valuation of 212-18 Corporate zero-coupon bond 212 risky 222 Corridor options 381-2 Corridors 364 Cost-of-carry formula 78, 8l Coupon-paying bonds 104 Cox, Ingersoll and Ross model 193 Cox, Ross and Rubinstein (CRR) model 259, 330 Crank-Nicholson numerical scheme 70 Creditor claims, write-down of 204 Critical stock price 176 Cumulative normal density function 95 Cumulative normal distribution, approximation 68 Cumulative normal distribution function 53 Cumulative standard normal distribution 77 Currency bonds, pricing of 325-6 Currency call formula lll Currency forwards, options on 109 Currency futures, options on 109 Currency options 111, l14, 341-57 Currency put formula 112 Dealer markets 14, 15 Default-free zero-coupon bond 206, 207 Default spreads, term structure of 202 Delivery options 328-31 Delta 124 6 monitoring and managing
134-9
Delta measures 123 Delta-neutral hedging 137 Density function 30 Derivative assets 50 pricing 49-71 Deterministic functions 75, 81, 208 Diagonal spread 16, 17 Diffusion processes 45-6 Dirac measure 44 Discount functions 272, 273 Discrete dividends 264-5 Dividends 264 Dow Jones 6 Down-and-in call 367 Down-and-out call 365-6 Down-and-out call options 379 Dual-strike options 327 Duration as function of time-to maturity 222, 223 Duration of insurance linked bonds 234-1 as function of interest rate 236, 237
Earnings Per Share (EPS) 5-6 Earnings-window dressing 6 Earthquake Risk Bond 227 i Economic level ll Elasticity 123, 128-9 Embedded digitals 359 Equilibrium option pricing theory 43 Equity-linked foreign exchange call 344-5 Equity-linked foreign exchange options 342-7 Equity options 99-100 Rabinovitch's model 186-9 Equivalent probability 63 Error terms 43-4 European call option 76, 79, 82, 83, 88, 201 European call price 94, l15 European calls 59-61, 86 algorithm 70-1 European cap prices 178, 179 European option values 98 European Options Exchange (EOE) 14, 15 European put price l 15 with dividends 266, 267 Exchange offer 301 Exchange options 298-301 Exotic options 360, 379-82 Exotic timing options analytic formula 401-3 characteristics 403 simulations 403 valuation of402 Explicit difference scheme 58-9 Extended Vasicek model 278 Extendible bonds 339-40
†NDEX
444
on security with no income l17 timing option in 329
Extendible calls 334-5 Extendible options 333-40 pricing of 333 -7 simple writer 337-9 valuation of 333-4 Extendible puts 336-7 Extendible warrants 340
margined American options 107, 263 price 105-7 prices l16
Futures Futures Futures Futures
FIFO 6 Filtration 46, 76 Finance level 11- 13 Fmance theory 2, 3 Fmancial engmeermg 11 of 14 Fmancial markets, internationalization Fmancial risk management . implementation 9 13 policies 2 Fmancial stability 8 Finite difference methods 57 First passage time distribution computation 240 Fisher option call values with uncertain exercise 303 Fisher option put values with uncertain exercise 304 Fixed exchange rate foreign equity options Jamshidian's approach 346-7 Reiner's approach 345-6 Fixed strike lookbacks 394 Flexible arithmetic Asian options 422-3 Flexible Asian options 420-3 analysis and valuation 420 -3 Floating strike lookback 393 4 equation 44 Fokker-Planck Foreign currency, futures contracts l18 Foreign currency options. See Currency optums Foreign equity option struck in domestic currency 343-4 struck in foreign currency 343 Foreign exchange 10 Forward contracts 77, 78, 105-6, l 16-19 Forward currency options, pricing of l 13 Forward difference 58 Forward extra contract 367 Forward functions 272 Forward option 78 Forward prices l16 Forward rate contracts l1-12 Forward start options 304 Fractional bonus option 406 Frankfurt Stock Exchange 14 Futures contracts 12 on commodities l16-19 on foreign currencies l l8 on security with discrete income l18-19 on security with known income l17 .
-
Gamma 123, 124, 126
options 109-10
.
and managmg 139-43 nn K7o0hlhagen model 110-11,
l
Gaussian diffusion process 75 Gaussian interest rate uncertainty 75 Gaussian law 54 Gaussian variables, simulation 62 General Electric 6 General weighted average (GWA) 420 .
.
.
-
.
Generalized payoff segment 353 Geske's approach for a call on a call 171-3 GG1sd Shaechr 5C 2330 .
an
Grabbe model 110-11 Greek-letter risk measures 121, 123-4, Grillil5B l
445
Hybrid securities 341-57, 354-6 Hybrids 12
monitoring moa
INDEX
a0n6o 226
Heat transfer equation 66, 69 Heath, Jarrow and Morton (HJM) model 193-5 Hedgeability of lookback options 404 Hedged portfolio 106, 137, 183 Hedged position 138 Hedging 7-9 at-the-money down-and-in calls 386 in-the-money down-and-in calls 387-8 of strike bonus options 407 out-of-the-money down-and-in calls 386-7 relationship between parameters 154-5 Hedging error 43 Hedging ratio of strike bonus option 406 Heston's model 248-9 Ho and Lee model deficiency in 276-7 for contingent claims 274-5 for interest rates and bond prices 272-3 term structure 273-4 Hoffman, Platen and Schweizer (HPS) diffusion model 248 -50 Hokey-Cokey option 363 Hull and White model 244-5, 277-9 Hybrid foreign currency options pricing of 351-4 tailoring 351
Implicit difference scheme 57-8 'In' barrier options 374 Incomplete information 254 Index futures, options on 108-9 onndss100-2 d ed Indexed notes 349-50 Information costs, option valuation with 251-5 Insolvency 200 Instantaneous interest rates under certainty 190-1 under uncertainty 191-2 Instantaneous standard deviation 201 Instantaneous volatility 83 Insurance industry 228 Insurance linked bonds duration of 234-7 pricing of 225-40 structure 228-9 time-series properties of237-9 valuation of 229-39 Insurance linked spreads as function of time-to-maturity 234 valuation of 232-4 Insurance risks 225, 226-8 Integral differentiation, Leibniz's rule for 71 Interest rate derivative assets 272-9 Interest rate elasticity measure 235 Interest rate elasticity of corporate bonds 219-24 Interest rate models 192-5 Interest rate options 190-5 Interest rate risk ll Interest rate theorem 113 Interest rate uncertainty 204 Internationalization of financial markets 14 In-the-money down-and-in calls 387-8 In-the-money lookback calls 393 In-the-money lookback puts 393 Investment banks 227 Iterative procedure 174 Itõ's differential and arbitrage portfolio 42-3 and replication portfolio 41-2 Itõ's formula application 38 example 37 generalized 39 40 mathematical expression 40 mathematical form 36-9 multidimensional 39 Itôs lemma 34-40, 187, 201, 22I, 346
example 36
implementation 43 intuitive form 35 Itô's process 32-3 Jump-diffusion
model 242-3
Kellogg's 8 Knock-out range options 382 Knock-out wall option 363 Known dividend yield 264 Kolmogorov equation backward 44 forward 44
.
Lambda 123, 124 Lattice approach 259-80 for bond prices 275 for put price 276 model for options on spot asset without payouts 161-3 survey 260-1 Lebesgue measure 30 Leibniz's rule for integral differentiation 71 LIBOR 349 LIFFE, options on bond futures traded on 109-10 .
LIFO 6 Limit binary option 363 Limited liability 199-201 Limited risk options 397-8 Linear tax schedule 8 Liquidation date 269 Loan covenants 9 Log-normal distribution 33 Log-normal property 34 London International Stock Exchange Long calls 18-19, 24 Long puts 20 Long straddle 21 Long-term bonds, short-term options on 102-3, 186 Long-term planning 3 Long-term view 6 Longstaff-Schwartz model 205-7 Lookback call 392 Lookback options 391-407 analysis 392-5 analytic formulas 395-400 hedgeability of404 simulations 399-400 standard 392-3, 395-6 Lookback put 392-3
13
446
Lookback Lufthansa
M4DEK
strategies 394-5
Options 12 B-S pricing of 53
9
combinations on on on on
Macaulay duration 222 Mandarin collar 362 Marché à Règlement Mensuel 267 Margin account 300-1 Market imperfection 8 Markov diffusion process 44 Markovian process 277 Martingale, and Brownian motion 30-1 Martingale method 32, 50, 52-6, 74, 81 Mega-premium option 362 Merton's model 153, 157 applications 185-6 derivation 182-6 Mini-premium option 363 Modified lattice 269 Modigliani-Miller theorem 199 MONEP 252, 268 Monte-Carlo method 56, 61-2
of 16
bond futures traded on LIFFE 109-10 currency forwards 109 currency futures 109
extrema on the maximum 396-7 on the minimum 397 on index futures 108-9 with uncertain exercise prices 301-3 Options markets 15 Order-driven system 13-14 Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process 187, 193, 247, 250 'Out' barrier options 375-6 Out-of-the-money 255 Outside barrier options 377-8 Over-the counter (OTC) markets 109, 114, 391, 403 Over-the-counter (OTC) options 99
Multi-currency bonds 326
NASDAQ14 Nationwide Mutual Insurance Company 227 Natural catastrophes 228 Natural hazards 226-8 New York Stock Exchange 14, 15, 329 Non-dividend paying stocks 59-61 Numeraire, change of 78-81 Numerical analysis 56-62, 69-70 Numerical methods for American option pricing 281-95 Numerical solutions 59-61 OEX wildcard options 329 30 One-touch all-or-nothing option 361 Open outcry system 15 Opening Automated Report System (OARS) 15 Option contracts 105-7 trading in 15-26 Option implicit volatility 17 Option markets 14 Option pay-offs 15 Option positions monitoring and management 123-55 in real time 129-49 Option price sensitivities 124-9 simulation and analysis 129-30 Option prices 54, 60, 107, 176 Option pricing models 87-122 Option strategies 15-19 Option valuation with information costs2¾I
5
Pan Am 8 Paribas call values 270 Paribas put values 271 Paris Bourse 14, 267, 269, 314 Partial differential equation 50-3, 57,ß9, 73-4, 76, 81, 82, 94, l15 resolution 64-8 Partial lookback options 398 Path-dependent binary barrier options 370--i Path-independent binary barrier options 369-70 Pay later options 305 -6 Pay later premium values 306 Pay-out ratio 304 PepsiCo 5 Performance incentive fee 300 Perls 354-6 valuation of355-6 Perturbation functions 272 Philadelphia Stock Exchange 114 Poisson process 243, 257 Portfolio options 327 Pricing of bonds 190-5, 192-5 of corporate bonds 197-224 limits of traditional approach 203 5 of corporate debt 200 of corporate spreads 202 of currency bonds 325-6 of extendible options 333-7 of forward currency options l13 of hybrid foreign currency options 351 of insurance linked bonds 225-40
INDEX
447
of options 192-5 Pricing models, American options 158 Private placements 229 Proactive risk management 7 Probabilistic method 74 Probability adjusted ratio 221 Probability measure (Q)74-5 Property Claims Services (PCS) 230 put on minimum (maximum)of two assets 316-17 on the minimum 324 with bound payoff 352 with disappearing deductable 352 with proportional coverage 351 Put-call parity condition 413 Put-call parity relationship 95-6, 107 Put options 19, 86 sensitivity parameters for 134 Put sensitivity parameters 151-3 Put spread 23 Put values function 99 Put's delta 125-6 Put's elasticity 129 Put's gamma 126 Put's Rho 128 Put's theta 127 Put's vega 128
212, 218 Q-economy 75, 79, 231 Q-martingale 240 Q-probability options 380 Qualitative Qualityoptions with Ndeliverable assets 328-9
options 380 Quantitative Quantooptions 342-7
Random variable 46 Range binary 361 Range forward contract 348-9 Range options 361-4 Range structures 359 Rate of return, distribution 34 Ratio spread 16 R&D 6, 9-10
Real-valued random variable 79 Rebate range binary 362 Reflection principle 85 Regular chooser 307 Reinsurance industry 228 Replicating portfolio 77 Replication portfolio, and Itô's differentia141-2 Report mechanism 268- 9 Reversals 24-5 Rho 123, 128 Risk evaluation 73 Risk exposure 8 Risk-free bond 116
bond 201 Risk-neutral economy 233 Risk-neutral probability (Q)75 Risk premium 4 Risk-return relationship 18 Riskless zero-coupon bond 2l3, 221 Risky asset, dynamics 75-6 Risky corporate bond 207 Risky corporate zero-coupon bond 222 Risky discount bond 207 Risky zero-coupon bonds 20l default before maturity 210- 12 no default before maturity 2l0 RM market 268
Risk-free zero-coupon
Jamshidian's approach 346-7 Reiner's approach 345-6 ratio 233 Quasi-debt-to-firm-value
Safety covenant 204 Sallie Mae straight bond 355 Samuelson formula 90-2 Scapegoat hypothesis 6
Rabinovitch call values 189
Securities 50
Schwartz model 282 Rabinovitch's model bond options 189 Chen's correction to 190 equity options 186-9
Radon-Nikodym derivative 79 Rainbow options 313-31 delivering the best of two assets and cash 317-19
discrete approach 320 of several on minimum (maximum) assets 319--20 valuation 314--23
Securities markets, trading mechamsms in 13-15 Securitization 229 Self-financing portfolio 42 Sensitivity parameters for call options 130-3 for put options 134 Share value 2 Shareholder stake 200 Shareholder value 3 Shareholders, final pay-off200 Short calls 18- 19
448
Short puts 20, 24 Short straddle 21 Short strangle 22 Short-term effects 2 Short-term gains 5 Short-term options on long-term bonds 102-3, 186 Short termism vs. long termism 6 Simple chooser option values 308 Simple writer extendible calls 337 Simple writer extendible puts 337-9 Simulation methods 56-62 Simulations 176, 323-5 American cap options 178 convertible bonds 288 exotic timing options 403 lookback options 399-400 Smile effect 250 for bond and currency options 250-1 in stock and index options 250 Soft barrier options 384-6 Solvency 200 S&Pl00 index 314, 329-30 Speed 123, 124 Spread options 327 Spreads 22-3 Sprenkle formula 89-90 Standard binary options 361 Standard options 379 Static hedging of barrier options 386-8 Stein and Stein's model 245-7 Stochastic component 31 Stochastic differential equation 75, 81, 206 Stochastic economy 74 Stochastic interest rates 181-96 extension 240 Stochastic process 45, 73, 230 governing loss index 240 having no memory 46 Stochastic revision strategy 43-4 Stochastic volatiles 247-50 Stock index options 100 Stock prices 5
dynamics 32-3 Stock value 5 Straddles 20-2 buying 20-1
INDEK Strike price bias 250 Structured barrier options 364-8 Structured products 359 Suppa, Enrico 226 Swaps l2 Swiss Option and Financial Futures Exchange (SOFFEX)
14
Switch options 380 Synthetic contracts 16 Synthetic forward contract 17 Synthetic positions 15-16
Taxes 8 Taylor series 35, 47 and Itõ's differential 40-1 Technically default-free bond 232 Technically default-prone bond 232 Term structure of corporate spreads 203-5 of default spreads 202 Theta 123, 124, 127 monitoring and managing 143-5 Time change 81- 3 Time-series properties of insurance linked bonds 237-9 Timing option in futures contracts 329 Tokyo Stock Exchange's Computer Assisted Routing and Execution System (CORES) 14 Toronto Stock Exchange's Computer Assisted Trading System (CATS) 14
Trading in option contracts
15-26 underlying asset 17 Trading calls 18 Trading mechanisms in securities markets 13-15 Trading ratios 23 Treasury bill yields 185-6
Treasury bond futures 329 Treasury bonds 227, 229 Trigger forward contract 367 Trigger point 233
Strategic level 10 Strict priority rule deviations 204
Uncertain exercise price option call values 301-3 Underlying asset, trading 17 Underlying asset price and time to maturity 178 Underlying asset price volatility and time to
hedging of 407 hedging ratio of 406 Strike option 405 Strike price 15-18, 20, 21, 26, 83, 94
Unique associated random variable 46 Up-and-in put 365 Up-and-out call 366 Up-and-out put 365
selling 21-2 Strangles 20-2
INDEX
Valuation exotic timing options 402 of Asian options 413-18 of barrier options 373-8 of basket options 418-20 of binary barrier options 368-71 of convertible bonds 286-7 of corporate spreads 212-18 of extendible options 333-4 of flexible Asian options 420-3 of insurance linked bonds 229 -39 of insurance linked spreads 232-4 of perls 355-6 of rainbow options 314-23 of wildcard options 330 Valuation formula 175 Vasicek formula 221 Vasicek framework 222 Vasicek model 192 Vasicek term structure 230 Vector of variables 46 Vega 123, 124, 127-8 monitoring and managing 146-9 Vertical bulls spread 16 Vertical spread 16 Volatility function 194 Volatility parameter 137 Volatility smiles empirical evidence 256 theory 250-1 Volatility spread 16 characteristics 149
449
Volatility strategies
17
Wall option 363
Warrants 13
au Weighting schemes 100 Westinghouse 6 Wiener process 28-31, 298 example 29 generalized 31 when is very small 30 with drift 240 see also Brownian motion Wildcard options 328-31 analysis 329-30 OEX 329-30 valuation of 330 Write-down of creditor claims 204
ot
Yield spread as function of asset volatility 219, 220 as function of initial quasi-debt ratio 216 as function of time-to-maturity 214, 215, 217, 218
Zaccaria, Benedetto 226 Zero-coupon bonds 104, 192, 198, 201, 206, 210-12 riskless 213, 221 risky corporate 222