202--t7.7 123-t �
2112--t 7.i-6391
.\VORLDBANK INTBAFH.AD �VASIIINGTONDC
httr://www.worlullanK.orW, hooks@ \\orluhan...
27 downloads
1058 Views
40MB Size
Report
This content was uploaded by our users and we assume good faith they have the permission to share this book. If you own the copyright to this book and it is wrongfully on our website, we offer a simple DMCA procedure to remove your content from our site. Start by pressing the button below!
Report copyright / DMCA form
202--t7.7 123-t �
2112--t 7.i-6391
.\VORLDBANK INTBAFH.AD �VASIIINGTONDC
httr://www.worlullanK.orW, hooks@ \\orluhanK.org
60-3-255-9122, 60-3-255-9133
60-3-255-2H 70
fom) s@ unur.org
•
60-3-293-3525
60-3-238-29H
9
A WORLD BANK COUNTRY STUDY
Malaysia Enterprise Training, Technology, and Productivity
The World Bank United Nations Development Programme Government of Malaysia
Washington, D. C.
Copyright© 1997 The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/THE WORLD BANK 1818 H Street, N.W. Washington, D.C. 20433, U.S.A. All rights reserved Manufactured in the United States of America First printing September 1997 World Bank Country Studies are among the many reports originally prepared for internal use as part of the continuing analysis by the Bank of the economic and related conditions of its developing member countries and of its dialogues with the governments. Some of the reports are published in this series with the least possible delay for the use of governments and the academic, business and financial, and d e v e lopment communities. The typescript of this paper therefore has not been prepared in accordance with the procedures appropriate to formal printed texts, and the World Bank accepts no responsibility for errors. Some sources cited in this paper may be informal documents that are not readily available. The World Bank does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this publication and accepts no responsibility whatsoever for any consequence of their use. The boundaries, colors, denominations, and other information shown on any map in this volume do not imply on the part of the World Bank Group any judgment on the legal status of any territory or the endorsement or acceptance of such boundaries. The material in this publication is copyrighted. Requests for permission to reproduce portions of it should be sent to the Office of the Publisher at the address shown in the copyright notice above. The World Bank encourages dissemination of its work and will normally give permission promptly and, when the reproduction is for noncommercial purposes, without asking a fee. Permission to copy portions for classroom use is granted through the Copyright Clearance Center, Inc., Suite 910, 222 Rosewood Drive, Danvers, Massachusetts 01923, U.S.A. Cover photos: Photos used by permission of the Malaysian Government. ISBN: 0-8213-4059-X ISSN: 0253-2123
TABLE OF CONTENTS FOREWORD FROM ECONOMIC PLANNING UNIT, GoVERNMENT OF MALAYSIA
vii
ABsTRACT
Viii
AcKNo�MENTs
oc
AcRoNYMs/ABBREVIATIONs
x
CHAPIER ONE: INTRODUCTION
1 1
The MITP Survey Analytic Approach
4
Overview of Report
6
CHAPTER Two: OvERVIEW OF TRAINING
10
Incidence of Training
10
Sources of Enterprise Training
12
Workers Getting Training by Source
14
Factors Shaping Training Decisions of Firms
17
Findings and Policy Implications
21
CHAPIER THREE: PRODUCTIVITY AND WAGE OUTCOMES
24
Estimating the Productivity Impact of Training
24
Productivity Effects of Training for Different Firms
25
Productivity Outcomes by Skill Group and Training Source
30
Firm-Level Wage Outcomes of Training
35
Compensation Policy and Labor Turnover
38
Findings and Policy Implications
43
CHAPTER FoUR: TRAINING PoLICIEs
46
Constraints on Training: An Employer Perspective
46
The Double Deduction Incentive for Training Scheme
48
Human Resource Development Fund
52
Findings and Policy Implications
61
CHAPIER FivE: TECHNOLOGY, QUALITY AND SKILLS
63
Technological Characteristics of Firms
63
IS0-9000 and Quality Assurance
70
IS0-9000 and Export Orientation
73
New Technology and Changing Skill Needs
77
Findings and Policy Implications
81
iii
CHAPTER SIX: FIRM EFFICIENCY AND ITS DISTRIBUTION
86
Measuring Technical Efficiency
87
Distribution of Efficiency by Firm Size
90
A Profile of Efficient Firms by Size
92
Ownership, Efficiency Difference and FDI Spillovers Findings and Policy Implications
99 105
CHAPTER SEVEN: CoNCLUSIONS AND REcoMMENDATioNs
108
Summary of Main Findings
108
Policy Recommendations
112
ANNExEs 2.1
Probit Estimates of the Likelihood of Formal Training
23
5.1
Introduction of New Technology and Training
83
5.2
Introduction of New Technology and Firm-Level Productivity
85
6.1
Stochastic Frontier Production Functions
107
NOTES
121
REFERENcES
125
TABLES 1.1
Key Variables in the MITP Survey
4
1.2
The MITP Sample and Response rates
5
2.1
Incidence of Training in Manufacturing and by Firm Size
11
2.2
Incidence of Training by Industry
11
2.3
Internal and External Sources of Training
12
2.4
Sources of Training by Firm Size
13
2.5
Workers Trained: Overall and by Firm Size
14
2.6
Number of Workers Trained by Industrial Sector
15
2.7
Workers Getting Formal In-House Training by Skill Group
16
2.8
Workers Trained from External Sources by Occupation
17
2.9
Marginal Effects of the Likelihood of Formal Training
18
3.1
Production Function Estimates by Firm Size
25
3.2
Production Function Estimates by Technology Level
28
3.3
Production Function Estimates by Export Orientation
30
and Ownership
3.4
Production Function Estimates with Predicted Training by Worker Groups
32
3.5
Production Function Estimates: In-house vs. External Training
33
3.6
Production Function Estimates: Training from External Sources
34
3.7
Productivity Effects oflncreased Training Intensity
35
iv
3.8
Wage Model Estimates with Training Indicator and Predicted Values 37
3.9
Wage Effects of Training by Technology, Exports
3.10
Occupation-Specific Wage Effects on Training
38
3.11
Summary Statistics on Quits and Compensation Policies
41
3.12
Compensation and Overall Quit Rates by Training Status
42
3.13
Compensation and Quit Rates by Occupation and
4.1
Reasons for Little or No Training: Overall and by Firm Size
48
4.2
Participation in DDIT by Industrial Sector
50
and Ownership
37
Training Status
43
4.3
Reason Given by Firms for Not Using DDIT
51
4.4
Reason for Not Using DDIT by Firm Size
52
4.5
Use of HRDF by MITP Firms , 1994
53
4.6
Eligible Firms Not Registered with HRDF by Size and Industry
54
4.7
Probit Estimates of Non-Compliance with HRDF
55
4.8
Registerd Firms Not Claiming from HRDF by Training Status
56
4.9
Probit Estimates of Not Claiming from HRDF
57 58
4.10
Training Centers and Training Plans in MITP by Firm Size
4.11
Joint Training Programs in MITP by Firm Size
58
4.12
Pro bit Estimates of Increased Training Under HRDF
60
4.13
Changes in Training Levels Over Past Three Years: Frims Registered with HRDF and Unregisterd Firms
60
5.1
Technology Characteristics by Firm Size and Ownership
64
5.2
Technology Characteristics by Industry
66
5.3
Quality Control and Precision in Production
67
5.4
IS0-9000 Status and Quality Control Systems
71
5.5
IS0-9000 by Firm Size and Ownership
72
5.6
IS0-9000 and Export Orientation
73
5.7
IS0-9000 and Export Propensity by Principal Markets
75
5.8
Introduction of New Technology since 1992
76
5.9
Effects of New Technology on Skill Needs and Employment
76
5.10
New Technology and Changes in Training since 1992
77
5.11
Impact of New Technology on Training
78
5.12
Impact of New Technology on Productivity by Firm Size
80
6.1
Stochastic Frontier Production Function Estimates
89
6.2
Distribution of Efficiency by Firm Size and Economy
90
6.3
Stachastic Frontier Production Function Estimates
6.4
Stochastic Frontier Production Function Estimates with
by Ownership
101
FDI Spillovers
104
v
FIGURES 3.1
Quit rates and Wage Policies: Training and Non-Training Firms
39
5.1
Quality Control Systems by Firm Size and Ownership
68
5.2
IS0-9000 and Exports
74
6.1
Distribution of Efficiency by Economy
91
6.2
Malaysia- Distribution of Efficiency by Firm Size
92
6.3
Technology Attributes of Efficient and Inefficient Firms
93
6.4
Training Attributes of Efficient and Inefficient Firms
94
6.5
Quality Control in Efficient and Inefficient Firms
95
6.6
Quits and Compensation in Efficient and Inefficient Firms
96
6.7
Technology and Training in Past Three Years
97
1.1
Cross-National Enterprise Training Study
BoXES 3.1
Enterprise Training and Productivity in Developing Countries
3.2
Technology Raises the Productivity of Training in Taiwan, China
2 25 27
5.1
Use of External Sources of Technical Support by Firms
69
5.2
Diffusion and Impact ofiS0-9000 in Brazil
70
6.1
Mexico's Proactive Approach to SMI Support
100
6.2
Promoting SMI Networks in Chile
103
vi
FoREWORD FRoM THE EcoNOMIC PLANNING UNIT, GOVERNMENT OF MALAYSIA
The quality of a nation's workforce is the key ingredient to economic growth. Increasing labor productivity and upgrading the skills and flexibility of workers through training and retraining are essential strategies for developing a quality labor force to support sustained growth and economic development of the country. To achieve the status of a fully developed industrialized country by the year 2020, Malaysia has made human resource development one of its major development strategies. The govern ment has, and will continue to, play a strong role in strengthening the educational and workforce skills of the population. But the government cannot do it on its own. Most technological innovations now enter Malaysia through industries; furthermore, learning is a lifelong pro cess, and relevant skills are best acquired in the workplace. This means that employers who have the expertise and technical know-how to train-will have to assume greater re sponsibility for training and upgrading the existing skill levels of their employees to meet the skill requirements of new technology. For its part, the government has introduced the Human Resource Development Fund, to encourage and promote enterprise training in industry, as well as complementary research and development (R&D) incentives and policies to assist small and medium industries (SMis). This report, which is based on a large survey of enterprise training, technology and produc tivity in the manufacturing sector, is written for policy makers and company executives who have to make critical decisions and design training policies. It provides the first broad based look at the existing level and incidence of private sector-led training in Malaysia, and it relates training efforts to corporate strategies on R&D, technology licensing, and quality control, as well as the effects of training on productivity and wages in companies. The analyses reported here can be used to support formulation of more effective public policies and corporate strategies for strengthening industrial training to meet the challenges of sus tained economic growth and globalization. It is hoped that this report will encourage the private sector to play a greater role in developing the country's skill abilities to support Malaysia's strategic vision of attaining our Vision 2020. Tan Sri Dato' Seri Ali Abul Hassan b. Sulaiman Director General Economic Planning Unit Prime Minister's Department Government of Malaysia
vii
ABsTRAcT This report presents the findings of a study of enterprise-based training in Malaysia's manufacturing sector which was jointly sponsored by the World Bank, the United Nations Development Programme, and the Economic Planning Unit, Prime Minister's Department. Using data from a survey of 2,200 companies, the study investigates the incidence and productivity outcomes of employer-sponsored training in in-house com pany programs and from external training providers, and the role of government poli cies and incentives in encouraging private sector training. The study also looks more broadly at technology in firms, their use of quality control systems, and the skill re quirements associated with the use of new technology and organizational change . The report concludes that while some firms, especially the larger, more technologically progressive ones and the multi-national companies do provide training, in general, most Malaysian firms underinvest in employee training. It documents the primacy of the private sector as the most important source of in-service training, and suggests that existing public sector training institutions need to become more demand responsive. It demonstrates that training firms are also making complementary investments in new technology, and that the productivity of local firms lags behind that of foreign-owned firms, in large part because local firms invest relatively less in training and new tech nology. The report also offers recommendations on improving collection and dissemi nation of training information, making training and technology policies more effective, and developing better coordinated, proactive policies to support small and medium industries.
viii
AcKNOWLEDGMENTS This report was prepared as part of the Malaysian Industrial Training and Productiv ity (MITP) Study, a joint project of the World Bank, the United Nations Develop ment Programme (UNDP), and the Economic Planning Unit (EPU), Prime Minister's Department. The project, directed by Hong Tan, was conducted by several teams -- a World Bank team, including Hong Tan and Geeta Batra; a local team including Professors Rajah Rasiah, Osman Rani, and Anwar Ali from Universiti Kebangsaan Malaysia; and staff from the Human Resource Section of EPU, especially Puan Faizah Mohd. Tahir (Director), Dato Zainol Abidin Rashid (former Director), Yap
Kim Lian, Asri Hamidon, Mohd. Hanafi Sakri and Muhd. Fikri Nawawi. The MITP survey was fielded by Survey Research Malaysia (SRM) under the able direction of Eugene Wong, Cheah Swee Kit and Christine Kwan. The MITP survey relied on a sampling frame provided by the Department of Statistics (DOS), and used a survey instrument developed by the World Bank and adapted for the MITP Study by the project team and SRM. This report was written by Hong Tan and Geeta Batra of the Private Sector Development Department. This MITP Study would not have been possible without the financial support of UNDP, the World Bank Research Committee (RPO
678-39), and EPU. We thank
Ameerah Haq, Neil Buhne, and Selva Ramachandran of UNDP for their support. We gratefully acknowledge the active support of Dato Annuar Ma'aruf, Deputy Director General ofEPU, and the many insightful comments provided by members of the project's Steering Committee, including representatives from EPU (Human Resources, Industry and Social Sections), the Ministry of Human Resources, Minis try ofintemational Trade and Industry, Malaysian Industrial Development Author ity, Human Resources Development Council, Ministry of Science, Technology and theEnvironment, and the Federation of Malaysian Manufacturers. We benefited from interactions with numerous individuals and both public and pri vate sector groups. In particular, we acknowledge the staff of DOS, especially Dorothy Robert, Mat Noh b. Russin, Lok Chung Lee and Tan Hoe Seng for their invaluable assistance with surveys and data; and Mr. Yau De Piyau and his staff at HRDC for data and insights into the operation of the Human Resource Develop ment Fund. We gained many insights from interviews with the Penang Develop ment Corporation, the Penang Skills Development Center, Standards and Industrial Research Institute of Malaysia, National Productivity Center, and the National Vo cational Training Council. Finally, we acknowledge the many companies that con tributed their time generously to participate in the MITP Survey; we trust that you will find the research and policy recommendations in the Report useful in formulat ing your skills and technology development strategies.
ix
AcRoNYMs/ABBREVIATIONS APITD
Action Plan for Industrial Technology Development
ClAST
Center for Industrial and Advanced Skills Training
DDIT
Double Deduction Incentive for Training
DOS
Department of Statistics
EPU
Economic Planning Unit
FDI
Foreign Direct Investment
GMI
German-Malaysia Institute
GTS
Group Training Scheme
HRDC
Human Resource Development Council
HRDF
Human Resource Development Fund
IKM
Institute Kemahiran Mara
IMP
Industrial Master Plan
ITI
Industrial Training Institute
JMI
Japan-Malaysia Institute
JTS
Joint Training Scheme
MASTIC
Malaysian Science and Technology Information Center
MFI
Malaysia-France Institute
MIDA
Malaysia Industrial Development Authority
Mill
Ministry of International Trade and Industry
MITP
Malaysia Industrial Training and Productivity Survey
MLFS
Malaysia Labor Flexibility Survey
�
Multi-national Corporation
NPC
National Productivity Corporation
NVTC
National Vocational Training Council
OJT
On the Job Training
Q:C
Quality Control Circles
QIP
Quality Improvement Practices
soc
Skill Development Center
SIRIM
Standards and Industrial Research Institute of Malaysia
SMI
Small and Medium Scale Industry
SMIDEC
Small and Medium Industrial Development Corporation
SPC
Statistical Process Control
SRM
Survey Research Malaysia
1NA
Training Needs Analyses
UNDP
United Nations Development Programme
VEf
Vocational Education and Training
VIE
Vocational and Technical Education
YIC
Youth Training Center
X
CHAPTER ONE: INTRODUCTION This report seeks to inform policy discussions on
employers' technology- whether they invest in re
private sector-led training through a survey offinns
search and development (R&D) or purchase their
and rigorous analyses of their responses.
technology through licensing agreements, whether
The Malaysia Industrial Training and Productivity
relate to training strategies. It characterizes the dis
they have quality control systems- and how these (hereafter MITP) survey, was fielded to 2,200 manu
tribution of employers' technical efficiency levels
facturing firms in 1994 and 1995. The MITP sur
relative to the best-practice frontier, and identifies
vey elicited infonnation on firm-sponsored training,
the key training and technological factors associated
and on a wide range of firms' attributes including
with high efficiency levels.
size, industry, local or foreign ownership, equip ment, technology, quality control systems, markets and exports, work force characteristics, wages and
The MITP Survey
other compensation and production. The firm-level data needed to study private sector These data allow us to document, for the first time,
training do not currently exist in Malaysia. A primary
the incidence and characteristics of training in Ma
data collection effort was deemed necessary to
laysian industry, throughout finns of different sizes,
develop the requisite data from a statistically
ownership, and industrial sector. The data also pro
repre s e n t a tive s a m p l e of m a n u f a c t u ri n g
vide unique insights into where firms get their train
enterprises. The MITP project team adapted, to
ing- from in-house training programs, from private
Malaysian conditions, a survey instrument
sector providers, and from different government
developed by the World Bank as part of its cross
training institutions; which groups of workers get
national study of Enterprise Training and
training and how much; and what are the outcomes
Productivity (see Box 1.1).
of training on firm-level productivity and wages.
Survey Questions This report addresses the issue of whether firms in
Table l.llists the main types of questions asked in
Malaysia under-invest in training. It asks employ
the MITP survey. It elicits a variety of information
ers about why they do little or no training, and in
about the attributes of the enterprise; its market and
vestigates the factors which shape employers'
technology, including research and development,
training decisions. It evaluates the efficacy of dif
technology licensing, equipment, and quality con
ferent training incentives in promoting in-service
trol systems; its work force structure, skills and
training, and suggests ways of overcoming their limi
compensation system; its training facilities and
tations.
worker training by source and type; and produc tion inputs and outputs.
It investigates the links between training and firm level productivity, a critical issue not only for firms
The MITP survey asked detailed questions about
but also for policymakers. It addresses this issue by
employer-sponsored training. The multifaceted
estimating the productivity and wage outcomes of
nature of training makes it notoriously difficult
different kinds of training provided to different
to quantify. It can either be provided informally
groups of workers.
on-the-job through instruction from co-workers and supervisors, or formally through structured
Finally, the report studies the role of new tech
courses of classroom instruction combined with
nology in raising skill requirements. It looks at
on-the-job training.
2
ENTERPRISE TRAINING, TECHNOLOGY AND PRODUCTIVITY
Training can take place in company training centers
Employer responses can be used to characterize,
or be provided by a variety of external sources in
for the first time, the incidence and intensity of
cluding public and private training institutes, in
in-service training in Malaysia: how much in
dustry associations, foreign joint-venture partners,
service training goes on in Malaysia; where are
and buyers and suppliers.
employers training their workers, in company training programs or through external training
The content of training can vary, from machinery
providers; which external training sources are
operation to statistical process control to production
most in demand - public training institutions such
management. Training provided to different occupa
as ITis or IKMs, skil l development centers
tional groups can differ, both in the numbers trained
(SDCs) or advanced training institutes, or other
and in the types and sources of training provided.
private sector providers? They will also allow us
Other dimensions of training- duration, intensity,
to identify which of the firms train and which
cost, and the quality of instruction- are also impor
do not, and which groups of workers are being
tant, but are poorly measured in the MITP survey.
trained.
Box 1.1 Cross-National Enterprise Training Study
This study was based on five developing economies. Three countries-- Columbia, Indonesia, and Malaysia -- fielded surveys of manufacturing firms based on a World Bank survey instrument. A fourth country, Mexico, used a survey instrument developed jointly by the Secretariat of Labor and Social Welfare and the International Labor Organization (ILO), with input from the World Bank to ensure its comparability with the other surveys. Tawain, China was included in this sample because key training, technology and production information was elicted in its 1986 Census of Manufacturing. It was also attractive both for its large sample size and as a benchmark for the other developing economies. Table 1.2 presents some summary statistics on these economies. The five economies in the sample represent considerable diversity in the level of per capita income, stage of industrialization, and export performance. The World Development Report (1995) classifies Indonesia and Columbia as lower middle income economies. In1986, the year for which we have data, Taiwan, China would have been ranked as being higher-middle income by this classification system. These economies experienced strikingly different growth patterns over the 1980s and early 1990s, with stagnant or low groth of per capita GNP and manufacturing output in Mexico and Columbia, and rapid growth in Indonesia, Malaysia and Taiwan, China. Characteristics of Economies in the Enterprise Training Study
Developing Economy
GNP per Capita US$ 1993
GNP Growth 1980-93
Manufactures 1980-93
Export 1980-93
Indonesia
$740
4.2
11.8
6.7
Columbia
$1,400
1.5
3.5
11.0
Malaysia
$3,140
3.5
10.3
12.6
Mexico
$3,610
-0.5
2.1
5.4
Taiwain, China
$3,6878
7.6b
12.7b
6.2b
Notes: For Taiwan, China, a refers to 1986 and b refers to the 1980-86 period. Sources: World Development Report, 1995; Taiwan Statistical Yearbook, 1988. See Tan and Batra, Enterprise Training in Developing Countries, World Bank (1995)
INTRODUCTION
3
The survey included a comprehensive set of ques
vey, this information provides an unprecedented
tions about the attributes of the enterprise. These
opportunity to explore the critical inter-dependen
variables- total employment size, research and de
cies that exist between key strategic variables, and
velopment spending, licensing of technology, for
that ultimately determine the productivity levels
eign capital participation, exports, use of automatic
and competitiveness of firms in the economy.
equipment, quality control system, education and sex composition of the work force, and labor tum
The Sampling Frame
over- are critical for understanding why firms train.
The design of the MITP sampling frame reflected several considerations. First, we wanted a large, na
They allow us to address questions of how skill and
tionally representative sample of manufacturing en
training requirements are influenced by firm size,
terprises.
by the technology and quality control system used,
representative of the composition of the manufac
While the overall sample would be
by foreign capital participation either as joint ven
turing sector, it would be stratified by three firm
tures or as wholly foreign-owned firms, and by the
sizes with larger firms being over-sampled relative
characteristics of its workforce. The survey elicited information on production and compensation, data critical to understanding the eco nomic motive for why firms train and how these
to their true weight in the population. A sample size of approximately 2,200 was thought to be ad equate for ensuring adequate representation in each industry-firm size cell.
investments in training affect firm-level productiv
Second, we wanted to build in the potential for link
ity and the wages paid to employees. Information
ing the MITP
survey
to the 1988 Malaysia
on production inputs and outputs allow us to esti
LaborFlexibility Survey (MLFS). While its fo
mate production functions and, after accounting for
cus was on labor market adjustment, the MLFS also
differences in capital, labor and other firm attributes,
elicited relevant information, such as skill com
to relate investments in training to improvements
position of employees, and adoption of new tech
in firm-level productivity. This ability to relate training to productivity out comes is important since different types and sources of training may have different effects on productiv ity, with implications for where and how policymakers and enterprises should allocate their
nology. To this end, two samples of firms were created- respondents of the 1988 MLFS still pre sumed to be in existence in 1994, the "survivors" sample; and firms not in the MLFS that began op eration between 1989 and 1994, the "new entrants" sample.
training resources. Similarly, the ability to relate
The MITP survey was carried out by Survey Re
training to wages will allow us to address the issues
search Malaysia (SRM), using a sampling frame pro
of how the productivity benefits of training are
vided by the Department of Statistics (DOS), and
shared with workers, and if the factors that shape
with participation of the local research team, the Eco
training changes, (such as adoption of new technol
nomic Planning Unit (EPU), and the World Bank.
ogy) what are the consequences for income distri
The fieldwork involved several activities: track
bution and inequality?
Finally, many variables elicited in the survey are also important in their own right. They represent key elements of private sector firms' innovation,
ing down firms in the DOS list, verifying the de mise or continued existence of firms and conducting pilot interviews to field-test and refine the MITP survey instrument.
human resource, organization, and marketing strat
The survey enumeration was carried out over a pe
egies as well as important areas of government
riod of four and a half months between December
policymaking. When brought together in one sur-
1994 and May 1995. Questionnaires were mailed to
4
ENTERPRISE TRAINING, TECHNOLOGY AND PRODUCTIVITY
Table 1.1 Key Variables in the MITP Survey
Firm attributes Firm characteristics
Types of questions asked Single or multi-plant firm, age of enterprise Foreign capital by country of origin Principal product and exports by destination market
Markets and Technology
Prior growth and future growth expectations Capital stock-automation, vintage,
investment plans
R&D as% of sales, any technology licenses Quality control system, IS0-9000 certification Workforce and Compensation
Education and worker attributes by broad occupation Wages, fringe and statutory benefits by occupation Recruitment and labor turnover by occupation
Training system
Training facilities and training specialists Informal OJT vs formal, structured training Numbers trained in-house and mode by occupation Numbers trained by detailed external source Reasons for low investments in worker training
Production and Inputs
Value of output, capacity utilization rate Cost of intermediate inputs and energy
each firm that could be located, accompanied by a
sponse rates being in the Wilayah Persekutuan area.
letter from the EPU explaining the purpose of the
All the analyses in this report are based on a sample
survey, assuring them of confidentiality, and arrang
of the first 2,200 firms that returned completed ques
ing for a face-to-face interview after respondents had
tionnaires. In the analyses, no distinction is made
an opportunity to assemble all relevant data. A sec
between the survivors and new entrants samples. 2
ond letter from the Human Resource Development Council was also sent out to emphasize the impor
Analytic Approach
tance of responding to the MITP survey. Our analytic approach is motivated by an economic Table 12 . shows the fmal composition of the MITP
model in which firms develop technological capa
sample and survey response rates by state. Out of
bilities through conscious investments in knowledge
the 4,583 names provided by DOS, SRM verified
generating activities.
and mailed out or delivered questionnaires to a to tal of3,373 firms; of these, a total of2,318 firms
Our definition of technological capability follows
returned completed and usable questionnaires.
Bell and Pavitt (1992), who distinguish between "production capacity" and "technological capability."
The overall response rate-68 percent-is extremely
The former concept measures the capacity of firms
high, especially given the length and complexity of
to produce output at given levels of efficiency, with
the MITP questionnaire. Response rates were some
existing inputs of capital, labor, and technology; the
what lower for the new entrant sample (66 percent)
latter incorporates the additional and distinct re
as compared to the survivor sample (71percent), and
sources needed to generate and manage technologi
varied considerably across states, with the lowest re-
cal change, including specialized managerial and
INTRODUCTION
5
technical skills, knowledge and experience, and in
firms operating in the local markets \Westphal
ter-firm linkages. Employers with these technologi
et al, 1984; Pack, 1992).
cal capabilities have a productivity advantage over
•
less capable firms.
ees. Whether importing foreign technology, or using, adapting and redesigning technol
Technological capabilities can be developed in
ogy through deliberate investments in R&D,
several ways. •
firms can build technological capacity by in vesting in the skills and training of the
Firms can invest in their own R&D or pur
workforce.
chase technology and know-how through li censing agreements with foreign firms. The
Several factors are at the heart of why education
evidence from developing countries suggests
and training are so critical to developing a firm's
that reverse engineering, imitation, and modi
technological capabilities. First, we know that the
fication of foreign technology are often more
productivity advantage of new technology is only
critical to developing technological capabili
attained through an intensive learning process. There
ties than investments in basic research and
is evidence from technology literature that much of
innovation (Pack, 1992). •
Firms can invest in the skills of their employ
the productivity gains from introducing a new in novation comes from making cumulative small
Firms can acquire relevant and best-practice technology through their links with foreign buy
modifications in it, essentially through an inten
ers of exported products as well as from foreign
sive learning-by-doing process (Bell and Pavitt,
Table 1.2 The MITP Sample and Response Rates DOS Sample
Number Surveyed
Response Rate %
State
NE
s
Johor
340
331
247
276
84
79
90
93
83
88
Kelantan
34
45
26
90 45
Malacca
69 38
70
51
50
88 76
91 78
57
37
53
95
91 100
Kedah
Negri Sembi ian
NE
s
NE
s
80
Pahang
38
65
29
60
86
Penang
218
284
186
265
70
76
Perak
150
272
91
224
91
94
Perlis
5
4
4
3
100
100
S elangor
346
517
263
418
63
56
Wilayah Per.
601
358
327
249
14
37
23
37
19
34
100
94
251
249
143
110
71
91
2,450
2,133
1,615
1,757
66
71
Trengganu Sabah/Sarawak
TOTAL
Note: NE = new entrant sample, S =survivor sample. Source: 1995 MITP Survey
ENTERPRISE TRAINING, TECHNOLOGY AND PRODUCTIVITY
6
1992; Enos, 1962). The challenge for employers
which its graduates bring to the employer - will
is to motivate and provide workers with incen
determine how cost effective it is for enterprises to
tives to learn about the new technology.
rely on outside training institutions rather than pro viding these skills in-house.
Second, innovative firms are more likely to use highly educated and skilled workers because they
The technology discussion suggests another set of
are more adept at critically evaluating new infor
determining factors. If the productivity advantage
mation, and thus learn more. Being more efficient
of technology is revealed only through learning by
learners, they are more productive when exposed to
doing, then innovative firms have an incentive to
new and unfamiliar information.
train in-house to internalize the new technology in the skills of its workforce.
Microeconomic case srudies have identified the criti cal role of educated workers in the innovation pro cess (Setzer,
1974; Pack, 1992). There is a large body
of substantiating evidence for these views.
In contrast, outside training providers are typically not well-prepared to impart skills associated with the most recent, and still evolving, technologies. They play an increasingly important role (and their
Human capital studies, have shown that educated
training services are utilized more intensively by
farmers and workers are more productive in a rap
firms), when technologies become standardized and
idly changing environment, and thus earn higher
their productive characteristics become well-under
incomes (Welch,
1970; Tan, 1980; Mincer, 1989).
stood.
There is evidence from industrialized and devel oping countries that industries experiencing rapid
These perspectives-on the relative importance of
technological change are more likely to train their
in-house company training when firms are en
workers, and that these training investments give rise to higher wages (Carnoy,
1990; Lillard and
gaged in innovation-are supported by the research of Lillard and
Tan(1992) and Tan et al (1992). In
1992; Tan et al, 1992). Finally, using frrm
their study of the sources of worker training in
level data from Taiwan, Aw and Tan (1994) show
high- and low-technology industries in the U.S., they
that worker training has a large positive impact
find that in-house training programs are empha
on firm-level productivity, and that this effect is
sized when employers are engaged in developing
larger when worker training is accompanied by
new technology.
Tan,
complementary investments in both R&D and for eign technology licenses.
These trends may be less pronounced in developing countries, such as Malaysia, where older, and more
To date, however, the literature has been relatively
standardized, technologies are in common use and
silent about the types of training that are most perti
frrms have limited in-house training capabilities.
nent to technological change. Employers must make decisions not only about whether to train, but also what kinds of training to provide. They may pro vide training in-house, or rely on outside training providers, depending upon their in-house training capabilities, and the vocational education and train ing (VET) system in the country. The VET system- its ability to meet the skill re quirements of enterprises, the quality of technical training provided, and the job relevance of skills
Overview of the Report The report is divided into two broad sections. The
first section, which comprises Chapters Two through Four, focuses on the incidence and productivity out comes of employer-sponsored training and on gov ernment policies and incentives designed to encourage training by employers. The second sec tion, Chapters Five and Six, looks more broadly at
INTRODUCTrON
7
technology in firms, the use of quality control sys
training are larger for small and medium size firms,
tems and IS0-9000 certification, and the skill re
who do relatively little training; for firms investing
quirements associated with the use of new
in new technology, especially through technology
technologies and organizational change. The report
licensing; and for export-oriented firms and firms
concludes in Chapter Seven with a summary of
with some foreign capital participation.
findings and policy recommendations. The production function analyses also revealed Chapter Two uses the MITP survey to paint a
marked differences in the productivity effects of
broad brush picture of enterprise training in the
training provided to different groups of workers and
manufacturing sector of Malaysia. It reports sum
training from different sources. The results show
mary statistics on the incidence of training across
that while skilled worker training leads to gains in
firms of different sizes and industries, and from in
productivity, training provided to unskilled work
ternal and external sources. The latter include
ers has no measurable productivity effects.
polytechnics, vocational schools, skill develop ment centers (SDCs), advanced training institutes
Among training sources, in-house company training
(ClAST), training institutions sponsored by dif
is most strongly associated with productivity gains
ferent government ministries (ITis, IKMs, and
except in local firms where training capabilities are
YTCs), and various private training institutes, buy
weak. The productivity effects of external training
ers and suppliers, joint venture partners, and train
varies by source for different firms, with SDCs and ClAST being most important for local firms and
ing overseas.
other private training providers for foreign firms. The key finding is that most firms either meet their skill needs in-house or through largely private sec
This chapter also analyzes the effects of training on
tor providers. With the exception of SDCs and
the average monthly wages of employees. The re
ClAST, other public training institutions play a rela
sults show that training leads to higher monthly
tively minor role in meeting the in-service training
wages. However, wage effects are smaller than pro
needs of private sector firms Though they currently
ductivity effects, suggesting that employers share
.
play a greater role in providing pre-employment
part of the productivity gains from training with
training, in future they will need to become more
their employees. The pattern of wage effects from
demand driven and work closely with the private
training parallels the productivity results, namely, that the wage effects of training are larger in firms
sector.
that make complementary investments in new tech Analyses of the determinants of firm training also
nology, in foreign-owned firms, and to a lesser ex
yielded other findings. They show that firms train
tent in firms that export. Like the productivity
ing decisions are shaped primarily by firm size, by
results, training provided to skilled workers results
the educational, skill and sex mix of employees, by
in wage gains but not training to unskilled workers.
'
its technology level, whether it exports, foreign own
Finally, it provides some evidence that firms can
ership, the type of equipment used and whether or
lower job turnover by the employees through high
not employers emphasize quality control. Chapter 1hree analyzes the productivity impacts of formal, structured training provided by employers. Using a production function framework, it shows
wage policies. Productivity gains from increased training that comes from greater job retention of trained workers can offset higher wage costs. Chapter Four motivates the discussion of training
that training has a positive impact on raising the pro
policies by reporting employer perspectives on why
ductivity levels of firms. Furthermore, it demon
they do little or no training. This reveals that while
strates that the beneficial productivity impacts of
most firms do not train because of the low skill re-
ENTERPRISE TRAINING, TECHNOLOGY AND PRODUCTIVITY
8
quirements of relatively simple, standardized tech
to invest in R&D and technology licenses than
nologies used, a large number of firms, small and
wholly foreign-owned firms of comparable size,
medium size employers in particular, also cited high
which may reflect the greater reliance of wholly
labor turnover, lack of knowledge about how to train,
owned subsidiaries on the technology stock and
and limited resources, as reasons for not training.
R&D of the parent MNC.
These latter responses, coupled with evidence from
This chapter also touches on IS0-9000, a voluntary
previous chapters about the low incidence of train
standard of the International Standards Organiza
ing and high potential returns, suggest that many
tion that Malaysia has adopted. Over ten percent
Malaysian firms under-invest in training, and that
of firms in the MITP survey had some level of
several market failures pose important constraints
IS0-9000 certification, and 33 percent expected
on training. The chapter then presents the results of
to be certified within the next three years. How
detailed analyses of two training policies designed
ever, IS0-9000 adoption will still be relatively
to encourage employers to train-the Double Deduc
low in micro, small and medium firms, and should
tion Incentive for Training (DDIT) and the Human
be an important area of focus-both in terms of dis
Resource Development Fund (HRDF).
semination a n d technical assista n c e - f o r policymakers. The analyses indicate that firms
It describes the limited use of the DDIT by firms
with IS0-9000 certification, or those actively
and the reasons why many firms did not use this
seeking it, are more successful in exporting to in
training incentive. It reports some teething problems
dustrialized country markets.
with the HRDF, including what appears to be seri ous noncompliance to register and contribute to the
Chapter Six draws together the analyses of training
HRDF, and failure to take advantage of training re
and technology by investigating firm-level tech
imbursements. It is too early to judge the efficacy of
nical efficiency and its distribution. Using a fron
HRDF, but there is some evidence that it has indeed
tier production function framework, it estimates
promoted training and skill upgrading among the
of how far each firm is from "best practice" tech
sample of firms that have registered with the Hu
nology, and what factors determine its level of
man Resource
Development Council.
efficiency. The overall results echo many of the main findings reported in previous chapters
Chapter Five shifts the focus to use of new technol
younger, export-oriented firms, firms that employ
ogy, quality control systems, and IS0-9000 certifi
a more educated workforce, and those that pro
cation in Malaysian firms, and their implications
vide training, skilled worker training in particu
for changing skill requirements. It provides a broad
lar, are more efficient.
overview of research and development, technology licensing, use of testing equipment, automation, and
The efficiency estimates are used to characterize
equipment age among furns by size, local and foreign
the size distribution of efficiency in the MITP
ownership, and industry.
sample. The results show that SMis are not nec
While the MITP survey reveals more private sector
efficient than many larger firms. Their low aver
R&D than the 1992 MASTIC survey, its R&D esti
age efficiency level, compared to larger firms, is
mates are still relatively low compared to other coun
due to the fact that a high proportion of SMis have
essarily inefficient -some SMis actually are more
It shows marked differences in these
low efficiency and a high proportion of larger
technology indicators across firms, withjoint ven
firms have high efficiency. If SMis are not in
tries.
tures and wholly foreign-owned firms being more
herently inefficient, then it follows that their ef
technologically advanced as compared to local furns.
ficiency levels can be improved through policy
It finds, however, that joint ventures are more likely
interventions.
INTRODUCTION
9
Potentially important areas for policy are sug
Finally, Chapter Six reports some preliminary analy
gested by the profile of efficient firms by size.
ses of efficiency spillovers to local firms from linkages
Highly efficient firms tend to have technology li
with joint ventures and foreign firms. The results in
censes but not necessarily R&D; they export and/
dicate that a higher foreign presence is associated with
or; have some foreign capital equity; they pro
efficiency improvements for local firms and that part
vide formal structured training to both skilled
of these gains come from the R&D done by joint ven
and unskilled workers, and do not rely only on
tures, and part comes from the training that wholly for
informal OJT. Efficient firms emphasize qual
eign-owned firms give their employees.
,
ity, especially statistical process control; they use precision measuring instruments and do not rely
The report concludes with Chapter Seven. It sum
on visual inspection and are more likely to be
marizes the main findings and draws out their policy
seeking IS0-9000 certification. Highly efficient
implications in five areas: (i) collection and dissemi
firms have formed work organizations that seek
nation of training information; (ii) expanded role
to reduce job turnover, using high-wage policies
of education and training institutions; (iii) more ef
and compensation that includes severance pay,
fective training policies; (iv) technology diffusion
profit-sharing and bonuses to attract and retain
and promotion; and (v) better coordinated and pro
workers.
active SMI policies.
CHAPTER Two: OVERVIEW oF TRAINING In this chapter, the MITP Survey is used to paint a
training nor formal training; those that rely exclu
broad picture of enterprise training in the manufac
sively on informal on-the-job training from co-work
turing sector. We describe the incidence of training
ers and supervisors; and those that provide formal
by firm size and industry. We present estimates on
training, either in-house or from external sources.
training provided by employers and by a variety of external training institutions, both in terms of the
The figures on training are adjusted using sampling
proportions of employers using each training source
weights constructed from the 1988 industrial survey
and in terms of the number of workers trained. We
whenever aggregate figures are reported for the
use employer responses to gain insights into why a
manufacturing sector as a whole or by industry .1 The
substantial proportion of firms provide little or no
data are not weighted when figures are reported by
formal training to their employees. Finally, we esti
size since the MITP survey is already stratified by
mate regression models to identify the important fac
size. For the purposes of this report, we define four
tors which shape company decisions to train
firm size categories-micro firms (with 15 or fewer
different groups of workers and to rely on in-house
workers), small finns (with 16-100 workers), medium
versus external training providers.
firms (101-250 workers) and large firms (with more than 250 workers).
Incidence of Training
Table 2.1 shows the incidence of enterprise-spon sored formal training for the manufacturing sector as
The MITP Survey elicited a wealth of information
a whole and by firm size. Two points stand out. First,
on training. It asked a limited number of questions
a very high fraction of firms either provide their
about informal on-the-job training provided by co
workers with no training (32 percent), or they rely
workers and supervisors, and detailed questions
exclusively on informal, on-the-job training (48 per
about formal, structured training-the number of work
cent). Only 2 1 percent of all employers provide
ers getting formal training over the past year, by
their workers with any formal, structured training.
broad occupational group and by source of training.
Secondly, there are very marked differences in the
It distinguished between formal training provided
incidence of training by firm size. The proportion
in-house by the employer, and formal training ob
of firms that do not provide any training is highest
tained from a variety of external training institutions,
among the micro finns (34 percent) and lowest among
both public and private. The public training institu
the largest size firms (four percent). Conversely,
tions included polytechnics, vocational and techni
formal training is most common among the large finns
cal schools, advanced skills training institutes
(71 percent) and lowest among the smallest firms (10
(ClAST), Industrial Training Institutes (ITI), Insti
percent). Most firms which provide formal training
tute Kemahiran Mara (IKM), Youth Training Cen
also have informal on-the-job training, a point that is
ters (YTC), Skill Development Centers (SDC), and
apparent from a comparison of the last two rows of
other government institutes. The private training
Table2.1.
sources include buyers and material suppliers, joint venture partners, and private sector training institutes.
Table 2.2 presents the corresponding estimates of
We can broadly characterize training incidence by
reveal considerable cross-industry variation in the
classifying firms into three groups: thosethat provide
proportion of firms that do no training and those that
no training of any kind, neither informal on-the-job
provide formal training.
training incidence by 16 industrial sectors. They
OVERVIEW OF TRAINING
11
First, consider the industries where large numbers
electrical machinery, iron and basic metals, trans
of firms do no training. These include such tradi
port equipment, textiles, apparel, and rubber indus
tional domestic-oriented industries as wood and fur
tries are relatively training-intensive, with over 35
niture, paper and printing, glass and pottery,
percent reporting formal training.
fabricated metals, machinery, and food products where only 10-25 percent of firms provide formal
The high proportion of firms providing formal
training to their employees. On the other hand, the
training in electrical machinery, transport equip-
Table 2.1 Incidence of Training in Manufacturing and by Firm Size Mean Characteristics
Overall
Micro
Small
2,200
247
959
%Firms not training
31.8
33.6
14.8
5.2
3.7
% Firms with only informal training
47.6
56.3
58.7
43.6
25.6
% Firms doing formal training
20.7
10.1
26.5
51.2
70.7
% Firms formal & informal training
17.0
6.9
24.5
48.4
66.5
Number of firms with training data
Notes:
Medium
Large
535
454
Overall estimates are weighted; estimates by firm size are not weighted micro
=
15 or fewer workers;
small= 16-100 workers; medium = 101-250 workers;
large= over 250 workers. Source: 1995 MITP Survey
Table 2.2 Incidence of Training by Industry Industry
All Industries
#Firms
%Firms
with Training
not
only Informal
Data
Training
Training
%Firms
%Firms with Formal Training
2,195
31.8
47.6
20.7
265
34.2
40.4
25.4
Beverages & tobacco
152
30.0
68.5
1.5
Textiles
107
23.6
17.7
58.7
Food
Apparel
116
13.8
49.2
37.0
Wood & Furniture
306
58.1
31.1
10.7
Paper & Printing
126
55.5
26.8
17.6
90
16.9
57.5
25.6 35.1
Chemicals Rubber
131
32.1
32.8
Plastics
133
10.4
77.5
12.1
Glass & Pottery
143
36.4
42.2
21.4
Basic Metals Fabricated Metals Machinery
71
6.1
30.9
63.0
110
43.3
38.8
86
38.8
45.9
17.9 15.3
213
1.8
50.2
Transport equipment
78
9.8
41.1
48.0 49.1
Other Industries
73
23.9
68.1
7.9
Electric Machinery
Note: Estimates by industry are weighted using 1988 Industrial Survey weights. Source: 1995 MITP Survey
12
ENTERPRISE TRAINING, TECHNOLOGY AND PRODUCTIVITY
ment, iron and basic metals is not surprising since these capital-intensive industries tend to be quite technology-intensive.2 Electrical machinery, along with rubber and apparel are also major export oriented industries, and we speculate that export ers have greater incentives to train so as to produce high-quality products for international markets.3 In summary, these data appear to substantiate con
ventional beliefs about training in Malaysia, namely, that the larger firms are more likely to train their employees than smaller employers, and that enter prise training is related to capital intensity, technol ogy and export-orientation of industries. However, what is especially striking is the presence of large numbers of firms without any system of worker train ing at all, formal or informal. This shouldbe of con cern to Malaysian policymakers, given the critical role that skills play in technology acquisition and de velopment, and their presumed beneficial effects on productivity and wages. (These links are quantified in Chapters Three and Five.) Also worrisome is the high proportion of employers (48 percent) that rely exclusively on informal on the-job training (OIT). Informal OJT, while an inte gral part of the skill acquisition process, typically involves fairly basic skills such as familiarizing new hires with the firm's equipment and operating pro cedures-the "how to" -rather than the "why. " It excludes the higher-level problem-solving skills that can come from structured training courses grounded in theory. Both kinds of skills are needed; indeed, as noted earlier, most firms that provide formal training also train informally. What is of concern is that firms which rely only on informal training develop few of the critical problem-solving skills needed to acquire and master new technologies and improve productiv ity. This fact, coupled with evidence indicating that informal OJT has no measurable impact on wages or fum-level productivity,4leads us to focus on formal structured training in the remainder of this report.
Sources of Enterprise Training
Table 2.3 shows the different ways in which firms provide formal in-service training. It distinguishes between formal in-house company training and external sources of training, both public and pri vate. Of the 21 percent of employers that train formally, about an equal proportion of them ( 13 percent) use in-house resources as external train ing providers. The bottom panel of Table 2.3 shows the relative importance of each external training source as re ported by enterprises. Conditional on the employer providing external training, the most commonly cited external sources are private training insti tutes (34.9 percent), followed by Skills Develop ment Centers (25. 8 percent), A dvanced Skills Training Institutes (21.3 percent), and their buy ers and material suppliers (11 percent).
Table 2.3 Internal and External Sources of Training Percentage of Firms
Source of Training• %Any Formal Training
b
20.7
% Internal Formal Training
12.6
% External Formal Training
13.0
External Sources of Training c Polytechnics Vocationalffechnical Schools
4.0
Advanced Skills Training Institutes
3.2 21.3
Skills Development Centers (SDC)
25.8
Institute Kemahiran Mara (IKM)
1.2
Industrial Training Institute (ITI)
5.3
Youth Training Centers (YTC)
0.5
Other Government Institutes
8.2
Joint Venture Partners Buyers/Material Suppliers Private Training Institutes Overseas Training
3.6 11.0 34.9 4.6
The numbers are weighted using 1988 Industrial Survey weights. Includes firms that train formally either inside the firm or from external sources. Conditional on doing external training. Source: 1995 MITP Survey
OvERVIEW oF TRAINING
13
It is plausible that these are external providers with
skills, not for the intermediate or advanced-level skills
capabilities to flexibly provide higher-level skills
that are needed after entering employment.
training to firms. The high proportion of firms that report using skill development centers (SDCs) is strik
For policymakers, the issue is whether these public
ing, especially since most of them (other than the
institutions should continue to limit their training ac
Penang SDC) were only established in the past three
tivities to pre-employment training, or whether they
years. The least commonly cited external sources
also have a role to play in post-employment skills
of training are government-run training institu
upgrading. One aspect of this issue-the limited in
tions-theYouth Training Centers (0.5 percent), IKM
service training provided by these institutions-can
institutes
be studied (see C hapter Three); however, the
(1.2 percent), vocational and technical schools (3.2 percent), and other government insti tutes (8.2 percent).
broader issue can only be addressed by a different study and is beyond the scope of this report.
The relatively small role of government training in
Table 2.4 disaggregates the different sources of train
stitutes reflec� their focus on pre-employment train
ing by firm size. The top panel shows the propor
ing, not in-service training that is the subject of the
tions of firms that provide formal training in-house
survey. The exceptions are the public agencies in
and externally. In general, the use of both training
the "other" category, such as SIRIM and NPC which
sources rises with firm size, with a higher proportion
provide a variety of training and other services di
of small and medium firms training in-house than us
rectly to the private sector. 5 This orientation towards
ing external training providers.
pre-employment training is borne out by data on National Vocational Training Council (NVTC) ad
The bottom panel shows, for the firms that train ex
ministered trade tests taken by graduates from dif
ternally, the proportion of employers citing each
ferent public training institutes. Most YTC, m, and
external source of training. (Note that figures for the
IKM graduates are tested for competencies in basic
micro firm size group are not reliable since less than
Table 2.4 Sources of Training by Firm Size Source of Training
Micro
Small
9.1 5.2 5.2
18.2 13.5 7.6
% Firms training formally % Firms training in-house % Firms training externally
Medium
Large
44.7 31.7 27.0
70.6 53.6 51.4
5.1 3.1 6.3
9.3 4.2 19.9
14.9
28.8
2.3 11.0 1.2* 22.7 9.8 25.1 44.3 12.9
5.1 18.2 2.1 27.1 11.9 25.0 53.0 21.2
External Sources of Training•
Advanced Skills Training Institutes
12.5* 12.5* 12.5*
Skills Development Centers
25.0*
Polytechnics Vocationai!Technical Schools
2.0* 0.0 8.2* 10.2
Institute Kemahiran Mara (IKM)
0.0
4.1*
Industrial Training Institute (ITI)
12.5* 0.0 0.0 0.0 25.0* 25.0* 0.0
0.0 2.0* 20.4 10.2 24.5 28.6 8.2
Youth Training Centers Other Government Institutes Joint Venture Partners Buyers/Material Suppliers Private Training Institutes Overseas Training Conditional on doing external training. *
very small sample sizes (3 or less observations).
Source: 1995 MITP Survey
14
ENTERPRISE TRAJNJNG, TECHNOLOGY AND PRODUCTIVITY
Table 2.5 Workers Trained, Overall and by Firm Size SourceofTraining
NumberofWorkers Trained Overall
Micro•
Small
Medium
Large
Any formal training
195,8 94
35,08 4
13,917
34,5 4 9
112,343
Internal formal training
167,6 14
28,716
12,396
27,286
99,2 14
28,279
6,367
1,52 0
7,262
13,128
External formal training
% workers with formal training
21.7
8.9
10.4
13.2
29.5
% workers with internal training
18.6
7.2
9.2
10.5
26.1
% workers with external training
3.1
1.7
1.1
2.8
3.4
External Training Sources Polytechnics
647
154
24
121
Vocational schools
477
154
0
92
230
Advanced Skills Training Institutes
2,197
1,255
39
198
703
Skill Development Centers
347
7,611
3,844
278
488
3,000
ITIs
833
154
0
232
446
IKMs
275
0
84
113
77
96
0
18
34
43
Other government institutes
1,605
0
160
697
747
Buyers & suppliers
1,792
22
312
548
909
Joint venture partner firms
1,508
0
213
355
938
10,359
782
321
3,972
5,283
872
0
67
405
399
YTCs
Private training institutes Overseas training
Estimates not reliable because of small sample size. Note:
Estimates of numbers trained are weighted using 19881ndustrial Survey weights.
Source: 1995 MITP Survey
five percent of them rely on external training pro
We estimate there figures by using the firm's responses
viders.) The table clearly shows variation in the use
about the numbers of workers trained from each
of different external sources by firms of different
source, and inflating them using size-based weights
size. Training provided by private institutes contin
constructed from the
1988 Industrial Survey. 6
ues to be the single most commonly cited external train ing source.
We caution that these are rough estimates, given changes since 1988 not only in the number of firms
Among the other sources, both small and medium
but also their composition. The estimates for micro
firms are most likely to cite training from buyers
enterprises are likely to be quite imprecise, given
materials suppliers and from other government insti
their small numbers in our sample (153 firms) and
tutes. Large firms are most likely to cite SDCs, other
correspondingly large weights assigned to them.
government institutes, buyers and suppliers, ad
We are much more confident of the estimates for
vanced skills training institutes, and to a growing ex
the small, medium, and large firms where our
tent, ms as well.
sample sizes are larger. We note that this proce dure yields an estimate of the manufacturing workforce of just under one million
Workers Getting Training by Source
which is to be expected since
(900,493), 1988 sample weights
are used. The number of workers trained provides another perspective on the relative importance of the differ
Table 2.5 presents estimates of the number of work
ent in-house and external sources of formal training.
ers receiving formal training by source in the manu-
OVERVIEW OF TRAINING
15
facturing sector, and separately by four firm size
firms or on numbers of workers trained. Both mea
categories.
sures point to the dominant role of private training
First, consider the overall estimates. They suggest
that 196,<XX> workers received fonnal training in 1993, of which 168,000 were trained in-house and just
28,CXX> were trained by external providers. As a share of the total workforce, these represent 21.7 percent for any formal training, 18.6 percent for in-house training, and 3 .1 percent for external training.
institutes, SDCs, and advanced skills training insti tutes which provided training for 10,359 workers, 7,611 workers, and 2,197 workers, respectively. The numbers of workers trained by buyers and materials suppliers and partner firms are as large as the numbers trained by "other government training institutes," and considerably larger than the indi vidual contributions of lTis, IKMs, YTCs, polytech
The overall results are comparable to those based on the proportion of finns that train, but the mix of in house and external training differs widely. While an equal proportion of firms report using in-house and external training sources (13 percent), the. esti mates based on workers trained suggest that fums are giving in-house training to a significantly larger number of employees than they are sending outside for training.
nics, and public vocational and technical institutes. Table 2.5 also presents separate estimates of the num ber of workers trained by fum size. The estimates for micro fums are likely to be unreliable, and will not be emphasized in the following discussion. For the other firm sizes, these worker-based estimates reinforce the points made earlier using utilization rates of finns . For small firms, training provided by private training institutes, buyers and materials sup
The relative importance of each external training source is broadly comparable irrespective of whether estimates are based on utilization rates of
pliers, and SDCs are of roughly equal importance. For medium and large firms private training insti ,
tutes have by far the most significant role in external
Table 2.6 Number of Workers Trained by Industrial Sector Number of Workers Trained Industry
Percent of Workforce
Any
Internal
External
Any
Internal
Formal
Formal
Formal
Formal
Formal
Formal
Training
Training
Training
Training
Training
Training
External
Food
6,331
4,348
1,982
2.9
2.0
0.9
Beverages & tobacco
1,661
1,307
1.0
11,807
11 '180
353 626
0.7 9.9
0.2 0.5 0.1
Textiles
10.4
Apparel
8,549
8,395
153
3.8
3.8
Wood & Furniture
9,773
8,809
964
22.8
20.6
2.2
Paper & Printing
4,139
3,259
880
1.9
0.5
1.5
0.8
3.0
1.2
Chemicals Rubber
4,157
2,705
1,451
2.4 2.3
10,055
7,251
2,803
4.2
7,779
5,871
1,907
8.0
6.0
2.0
Glass & Pottery
10,653
9,358
1,294
33.2
29.2
4.0
Iron & Basic Metals
32,082
25,683
6,399
73.4
58.8
14.6
6,694
6,020
673
3.2
2.9
0.3
Machinery
11 '129
10,193
936
6.8
6.2
0.6
Electric Machinery
Plastics
Fabricated Metals
58,730
52,701
6028
38.8
34.8
4.0
Transportation
5,301
4,319
982
4.7
3.8
0.9
Other industries
7,046
6,207
839
3.5
3.1
0.4
Note: Estimates are weighted using 1988 Industrial Survey weights. Source: 1995 MITP Survey
16
ENTERPRISE TRAINING, TECHNOLOGY AND PRODUCTIVITY
Table 2. 7 Workers Getting Formalin-House Training by Skill Group Occupational Group
Number
Total Number
Percentage
Trained
of employees
Trained
Supervisors
17,109
67,713
25.3
Technicians
15,105
47,396
31.9
Skilled Production Workers
76,074
462,855
16.4
Unskilled Production Workers
59,327
443,051
13.4
Note: Estimates weighted using 19881ndustrial Survey weights Source: 1995 MITP Survey
training, though SDCs, buyers and suppliers, part
They suggest that, on average, a higher proportion of
ner firms, and other government institutes are also
technicians (32 percent) and supervisors (25 percent)
responsible for training a sizeable number of work
are trained as compared to production workers (13-16
ers. Particularly striking is the heavy use of SDCs
percent); however, skilled production workers are
by the largest furns which sent about 3,000 workers
more likely to be trained (16 percent) than unskilled
for training in SDCs and 5,283 workers for training
production workers (13 percent).
in private training institutes. Though not reported in Table 2.7, the data indicate that In Table 2.6, we report more aggregated statistics on
production workers are also less likely to get external
the number of workers trained by industrial sector,
training (14 percent) as compared to non-production
as well as their share of the workforce in each indus
workers (28 percent).
try. The latter measure is particularly significant given the recommendation of the Industrial Master Plan
In Table 2.8, we report the numbers trained by ex
(IMP) that employers provide training to 10 percent of their work force (Mill, Review ofthe IMP, 1994)_7
production workers, as well as the proportion getting
ternal source of training for production and non training in each occupation. The figures show that
By this yardstick, it appears that the target of 10 per
private training institutes and SDCs are the most im
cent training has only been achieved in five out of
portant external sources of training for both groups.
the 16 industrial sectors under consideration-iron and
However a higher proportion of non-production
basic metals (73 percent), electric machinery (39 per
workers get training from private training institutes
cent), glass and pottery (33 percent), wood and fur
(52 percent) than from SDCs (18 percent), while pro
niture (23 percent), and textiles (lOpercent). In the
duction workers are more likely to get training at
other industrial sectors, the proportion of the work force
SDCs (31 percent) than at private training institutes
getting training is considerably lower. The indus
(26 percent).
tries with the lowest figures (less than three percent
trained) include food products, beverages and tobacco, paper and printing, and chemicals.
Other key external sources for both groups of work ers are buyers and suppliers-who provide the train ing to meet their product requirements or to use
Which workers are getting training? Table 2.7 pre
their equipment-and advanced skills training insti
sents estimates of the numbers trained in four
tutes. As before, few workers get training at ITis,
broad occupational groups-supervisors, techni
IKMs, youth training centers and vocational schools,
cians, and skilled and unskilled production work
reflecting the primary orientation of these public
ers-as a proportion of the total number of employees
training institutions to pre-employment training in
in the relevant occupation.
basic skills.
OvERVIEW OF TRAINING
17
labor, and whether the firm is unionized. Two-digit
Factors Shaping Training Decisions of Firms
industry dummy variables control for other industry differences.
With this overview of training as background, we
In the discussion that follows, we summarize the ef
now turn to a more formal analysis of the factors that shape firms' decisions to provide their employees
fects of the most important regressors on the likeli
with formal structured training, and whether the de
hood of the employer providing any formal training,
terminants of training differ by skill group and by
by skill group, and by training source. The coeffi
training source. To address these issues, we esti
cients estimated by the probit model (these are re
mate separate probit regression models for any for
ported in Annex Table 2.1) provide insights into the
mal training, training for production workers and
statistical significance of each variable and the direc
non-production workers, and in-house versus ex
tion of its effects on training. However, they cannot
ternal training.
be interpreted as marginal effects because of the non-linear nature of the probit model.
The likelihood of an employer providing each type of training is hypothesized to depend on the relative
To facilitate interpretation, we report instead the
costs and benefits. It equals one if the present value
marginal effects of the probit model evaluated at the
of training exceeds its cost, and equals zero other
sample means of each variable. The marginal ef
wise. The net benefits of training (benefits minus
fects from different probit models are presented to
costs) are not directly observed, but are thought to
gether in Table
be related to a set of observable attributes of the
regressors across the different training measures.
2.9 to facilitate comparisons of
employer. These firm attributes include firm size; worker characteristics such as educational attainment
Firm Size
and skill mix; its level of technology as reflected in
Table 2. 9 confirms that training probability is strongly
its R&D expenditures and its purchases of know
related to firm size. Relative to micro firms (the omit
how; exporting, and foreign capital participation; or
ted size category), small, medium and large firms are
ganizational factors such as the degree of automation,
14, 35 and 53 percent more likely to provide any
use of quality control methods, employment of female
formal training. The importance of firm size, con-
Table 2.8 Workers Trained from External Sources by Occupation Production Workers External Source of Training
Polytechnics Vocational/Technical Schools Advanced Skills Training Institutes Skills Development Centers Institute Kemahiran Mara (IKM) Industrial Training Institute (ITI) Youth Training Centers Other Government Institutes Joint Venture Partners Buyers/Material Suppliers Private Training Institutes Overseas training Note: Source:
Estimates weighted using
1995 MITP Survey
Non-Production Workers
Number
Proportion
Number
Proportion
Trained
Trained
Trained
Trained
2.4 2.1 9.6 31.3 1.2 3.4 0.5 4.1 6.9 10.0 25.7 2.6
219 99 503 2,065 56 228 2 876 294 644 5,810 406
1.9 0.9 4.5 18.4 0.5 2.0 3.6 7.8 2.6 5.7 51.8 3.6
429 379 1,649 5,546 219 605 95 726 1,214 1,767 4,550 466
1988 Industrial Survey weights
18
ENTERPRISE TRAINING, TECHNOLOGY AND PRODUCTIVITY
trolling for the other correlates of training (includ-
The effects of firm size on training probability dif-
ing level of technology), may reflect scale econo-
fer by skill group: compared to micro firms, the
mies in training provision, the greater access of large
likelihood of training for skilled workers in large
firms to resources for training, and unobserved em-
firms rises to 61 percent as compared to only 43 per-
player attributes associated with improved manage-
cent for unskilled workers, a trend evident in the
ment and training capabilities.
simple tabulations reported earlier. Larger firms are Table2.9 Marginal Effects on the Likelihood of
Formal Training Estimated from a Probit Model
Independent Variable
Any
In-house
External
Skilled
Formal
Formal
Training
Worker
Worker
Training
Training
Training
Training
0.138 IJI
Small Firm Size (16-100 workers)
(0.067) 0.348�1
Medium Firm Size
(0.065)
(1 01-250 workers)
0.529�
Large Firm Size (over 250 workers)
(0.070)
Mean education
0.024�
of the workforce
(0.007) 0.006 �
Percent of skilled workers
(0.001) 0.140al
Invests in R&D
(0.030) 0.071 a!
Foreign capital participation Exports
Proportion of female
0.026 a! (0.006)
0.002 �
0.005 a!
0.003 a!
0.006 �
(0.0008)
(0.0007)
(0.0008)
(0.0008)
0.135-'!1 (0.026) 0.080 a!
0.095 � (0.023)
0.112 � (0.026)
-0.007
0.019
(0.020)
(0.023)
0.151 a! (0.027) 0.080 �
0.008
0.031
0.001
(0.024)
(0.022)
(0.024)
(0.026)
(0.025)
0.001
0.001 �
0.001 �
0.004
(0.001)
(0.0002)
(0.0003)
(0.003)
0.101 a! (0.023)
0.0431J/
0.128 a!
(0.020)
(0.023)
0.084 a! (0.024)
0.024
0.008
0.013
-0.051
0.005
(0.047)
(0.041)
(0.037)
(0.042)
(0.043)
(0.031) -1133.40
Log (likelihood)
0.025 a! (0.081)
0.430 � (0.071)
-0.004
0.060..£1
Unionization
0.016 a! (0.005)
0.606 � (0.094)
0.224 � (0.060)
0.010
(0.026)
workers
0.028 � (0.006)
0.488 � (0.080)
0.395 � (0.081)
0.085 (0.061)
(0.027)
0.103 a!
Use of quality control methods
0.426 � (0.074)
0.253 � (0.062)
0.168 cJ (0.086)
(0.024)
(0.0003)
automatic machinery
0.261 � (0.063)
0.059 (0.063)
(0.027)
0.001
%Value of
0.129 IJI (0.065)
Unskilled
0.027 (0.026) -1090.86
0.059 � (0.024) -918.23
0.0661Ji
0.020
(0.027)
(0.028)
-970.59
-1102.68
a= Significant at 1% b=
Significant at 5%
c =Significant
Note:
at 10% level
Numbers in parantheses are standard errors. Omitted firm size is micro enterprises with 15 or fewer workers. Age of firm and multi-plant status included but were not statistically significant.
Source: Annex Table 2.1.
OvERVIEW
OF
TRAINING
19
also more likely to use both in-house and external
both skill groups. Thus, unskilled workers enjoy an
training sources than their smaller counterparts.
externality by working in a workplace with a high proportion of skilled workers.
Education and Skill Mix The training effects of education stand out. The
The Firm's Technology
results indicate that employers are more likely to
The results provide strong evidence that skill and
provide formal training for all groups and from all
training requirements are shaped by the firm's tech
sources the more educated are their workers. A
nology. Firms that invest in research and develop
one year increase in the education of the workforce
ment (R&D) are about 10-15 percent more likely to
(the mean in the MITP sample is 8. 7 years of school
train formally than firms without R&D.
ing) is associated with a two to three percent higher probability of training. The significant positive rela
The results, by skill group, suggest that while R&D
tionship is strong evidence that the two kinds of hu
firms are more likely to train both production and
man capital-education and training-are highly
non-production workers than firms not doing R&D,
complementary. Educated workers are better
the likelihood of their training production workers is
learners and thus benefit more than less educated
actually higher.
workers from training. A higher level of work force education also raises the probability that the firm will train in-house relative to sending workers for external training, a result evident from the rela tively larger estimated effects of education for in house training.
Workers typically require little formal instruction, beyond some informal OJT by co-workers, to oper ate mature well-established technologies. When new technologies are being introduced, however, pro duction is no longer routinized. Under these new and challenging circumstances, formal structured
Firms with a more skilled workforce are more likely
training for all workers-both production and non
to train. Skill mix is measured as the percentage
production-becomes critical if unanticipated prob
share of managers, engineers, technicians, supervi
lems are to be detected and fixed, and the
sors, and skilled production workers in the total work
productivity advantage of using new technologies
force of the firm. Controlling for education (and
over mature technologies are to be realized.8
other factors), a one percent increase in the skill mix is associated with roughly half a percent increase in the probability of training.
Doing R&D has different effects on where employ ers train their workers. The marginal effects of do ing R&D on training probability are larger for
The results also indicate that skill mix of the work
in-house programs (13.5 percent) than for training
force is a more important determinant of external
from external sources (9.5 percent).
training than of in-house training. To the extent that skilled worker training tends to be highly technical and specialized, employers may fmd it more eco nomical to send non-production workers to external training providers than to develop these programs
These results-that R&D finns are more likely to train their workers in-house-are consistent with the hy pothesis that the use of advanced technologies is associated with a greater reliance on training in
in-house.
house than on external. 9 In part, this is because
There is also evidence that a more highly skilled
train in new technologies when extant knowledge is
external training providers are not well-equipped to
workforce is associated with a greater probability
so limited; and in part, because in-house experience
of training for both skilled workers and unskilled
working with, and adapting, new technology devel
workers. The skill mix variable is positive for
ops the firm's technological capabilities.
20
ENTERPRISE TRAINING, TECHNOLOGY AND PRODUCTIVITY
Exports and Foreign Ownership
technology. These results suggest that automation
We hypothesize that finns can acquire relevant and
will require greater efforts on the part of employers
best-practice technology through their links with
to tram non-production workers and to send them
foreign buyers and foreign firms operatirig locally,
for external training.
and are therefore more likely to trairi their employ ees. However, the results suggest that exportirig is
On average, employers that emphasize quality con
not associated with trainirig. The weak result may
trol methods are between four and
be reflecting the high correlation between exports
likely to train than those frrrns without quality con
and other firm attributes, such as foreign capital
13 percent more
trol. This result is significant for training provided to
participation, which are already included in the
all groups of workers and for trairiiri g from both ill
regression.
house and external sources.
Foreign firms are in general about seven to eight
A second result is suggested by comparing the rela
percent more likely to provide trairiirig for their em ployees as compared to local firms. Note that this
tive size of the estimated margirial effects on trairiirig for each skill group and for each training source.
marginal effect persists even after controlling for
These comparisons iridicate that employers using
other factors, many beirig characteristics of multina
quality control methods are more likely to trairi skilled
tionals such as R&D, exports, and firm size.
workers (13 percent) than unskilled workers (eight
Foreign firms are eight percent more likely to tram
opposed to sending them offsite for trairiirig (four
ill-house than local firms, but not when it comes to
percent).
percent), and to tram them ill-house
(10 percent) as
external trairiirig. This may reflect well-developed ill-house trairiirig capabilities, sirice many are large
Use of Female Labor and Unionization
multinationals irivolved iri technology intensive semi
We iriclude two other variables to characterize work
conductor and electronics production and assem
organization in the firm-the use of female labor and
bly. Finally, while foreign firms are no more likely to
unions. Use of large numbers of female workers
train skilled workers than local firms, they are signifi
may reflect forms of organization built around simple
cantly more likely to trairi their unskilled employees.
assembly, manual dexterity, seasonal work, and rela
Automation and Quality Control
support for this hypothesis in Malaysia.
tively low skills. However, there appears to be little The model included two variables-the degree of equipment automation and use of quality control
Controlling for mean education and skill composi
methods-to irivestigate the trairiirig effects of mod
tion, a workforce with a higher proportion of female
em modes of production organization. Automation
workers is not associated with a lower likelihood of
can either lead to the "dumbirig down" of skills, as
training. This is important in the context of tight labor
some have argued, or to iricreased skill requirements
markets in Malaysia for it suggests that iricreased use
to operate and maintairi iricreasirigly sophisticated
of female workers to meet iridustry's labor needs is
equipment. The results suggest that the probability
unlikely to have deleterious effects on firm-level
of formal training is higher the greater is the per
productivity, provided women are similarly educated
centage share of the firm's machinery and equip
and given the same formal trairiing as their male coun
ment that is semi- or fully automatic.
terparts.
Malaysian policymakers have stressed the need for
In theory, unions are thought to reduce the likeli
iridustry to become more automated, both to con
hood of training by negotiating higher levels of
serve on increasingly scarce labor and to deepen
wages and reducirig the ability of employers to lower
OVERVIEW OF TRAINING
wages to finance firm-specific training through a
21
With the exception of SDCs and ClAST, two in
training wage. However, when statistically signifi
stitutions that are either demand-driven or that cater
cant union effects on training are found, they are
to higher-level skills training, the other public
invariably positive and about six to seven percent
training institutions-IDs, IKMs, YTCs, polytech
higher as compared to non-unionized firms. Simi
nics, and vocational and technical schools-play a
lar results have been reported in several industri
very minor role in meeting the in-service training
alized countries (see Lillard and Tan, 1992, Tan et
needs of the manufacturing sector. Their primary
al, 1992).
focus thus far has been on pre-employment train ing in basic and intermediate-level technical skills.
The union effect is strongest in increasing training
Given their limited role in in-service training, it is
from external sources (six percent) and training for
clear is that the private sector will have to take on
skilled workers (seven percent). Unions may have
greater responsibilities for meeting its growing skill
this beneficial effect on training by giving workers
requirements.
an alternative to job turnover. By establishing griev ance and arbitration procedures, unions promote
The Government can, and is, helping facilitate in
greaterjob stability and increase incentives for finns
creased private sector-led training through the Hu
to invest in training.
man Resource Development Fund, through seed-grants to set up private sector-managed SDCs in the different states, and through subsidized credit,
Findings and Policy Implications
training, and technical assistance for the population of small and medium-scale firms that are most likely
Manufacturingfirms in Malaysia under-invest in
not to train or to tely on informal on-the-job training
the training of their employees. This is based on
(these policies are assessed subsequently).
our estimates that about 80 percent of all firms ei ther do no training or rely exclusively on infor
However, the design and implementation of these
mal training from co-workers and supervisors, and
training and related policies are rarely accompanied
that only 21 percent of firms provide formal training.
by adequate monitoring of their take-up, or by pro gram impact analyses, both of which require a sys
This conclusion is bolstered by the responses of
tematic data collection effort.
employers (reported later in Chapter Four) about why they provide little or no training. Most cite
The Government's existing system for training data
the use of mature technology as the principal rea
collection and analysis isfragmented and should be
son for doing little training. While this is not a
strengthened. Data on public training institutions
market failure per se, a sizeable number of other
are typically maintained by each responsible minis
employers, smaller firms in particular, cite other
try but seldom reported, on a systematic basis to
training constraints that are-free ridership from
gether with detailed cost data, to a central coordinating
high labor turnover, lack of knowledge about train
agency for planning and policy analysis.
ing methods, and limited resources for training. Likewise, information on private-sector training in
Finns that train meet their skill needs in-house or
stitutions is only collected on an ad hoc basis. Few
through a variety of external training sources. Of
evaluation studies of training programs-based on
the external training sources, firms rely most
tracer surveys of graduates, comparisons with a con
heavily on private providers-private training in
trol group, and cost-benefit calculations-have been
stitutes, buyers and equipment suppliers, joint
conducted; evaluations comparing different public
venture partners, a n d overseas training
training institutions are even rarer. The National
institutions.
Vocational Training Council (NVTC) was designated
22
ENTERPRISE TRAINING, TECHNOLOGY AND PRODUCTIVITY
as the institution to coordinate both public and pri
provide DOS with the necessary resources and in
vate vocational training programs, and the Govern
centives to implement and speedily process the aug
ment should give NVTC the necessary legal standing,
mented surveys on a periodic basis.
resources, and capabilities to play this role more ef fectively.
Several determinants of enterprise training stand out. First, smaller firms are much less likely to train than
Least well developed is in formation on in-service
larger firms suggesting that this groups will require
training. Existing industrial and household surveys
special attention from policymakers. Second, em
fielded by the Department of Statistics (DOS) are
ployers are more likely to train when its workforce
,
potentially potent, but currently under-exploited,
is better educated and more technically skilled since
vehicles for developing these training data bases.
they benefit more from training. As such, firm incen tives to train should increase as education policies to
A great deal of demographic and employer infonna
promote higher school retention rates and more tech
tion is already elicited in these surveys. The addi
nical education are implemented.
tion of a short training module to each survey thus provides nationally representative estimates of train
Investments in new technology, automated equip
ing at the level of the enterprise and at the level of
ment, and quality control are associated with in
the individual. Once institutionalized, these aug
creased training, a fact that reinforces the need for
mented firm- and worker-level surveys will yield
continuous skills upgrading if firms are to adopt
time-series data needed for policymakers to monitor
more technology-intensive production. Finally,
and analyze training trends. The Government
local firms are in general much less likely to train
should set up a committee to design, fund, and coor
relative to foreign firms, reflecting both their weak
dinate analyses using these training modules, and
training capabilities and lack of a training culture.
OVERVIEW OF TRAINING
23
Annex 2.1 The following table reports the parameter estimates of probit models for different training measures, where the dependent variable is one if an employer invests in that source or type of training, and zero otherwise.
While these estimates provide insights into the significance of explanatory variables and the
direction of their impact on the training outcome, they are not readily interpreted because of the non-linear nature of the dependent variable which is constrained to lie between 0 and 1.
However, the marginal
effects of explanatory variables can be calculated and they are reported in the text.
Pro bit Estimates of the Likelihood of Formal Training Independent Variable
Any Formal Training
Small Firm Size
0.362 �/
(16-100 workers)
(0.176)
Medium Firm Size
0.939 �
(101-250 workers)
(0.176)
Large Firm Size
1.446 �
(over 250 workers)
(0.193)
Mean education of
0.064 �
the workforce
(0.019)
Percent skilled
0.0174 �
workers
(0.0023)
Invests in R&D
0.365 � (0.078)
Foreign capital
0.188 �
participation Exports
%Value of automatic machinery Use of quality
Proportion of
Unionization
Log (likelihood) •
Note:
0.801 � (0.192) 1.182 � (0.207) 0.088 � (0.019) 0.0063 � (0.003) 0.395-£1 (0.076) 0.243 �
Unskilled
0.221 (0.232) 0.924 � (0.228) 1.477 � (0.084) 0.062 � (0.021) 0.0194 � (0.003) 0.334 � (0.080)
0.518'"' (0.264) 1.265 � (0.259) 1.748 � (0.271) 0.081� (0.020) 0.0110 � (0.003) 0.344 � (0.079)
-0.029 �
0.064
(0.079)
(0.075)
0.246 (0.177) 0.657 � (0.176) 1.172 � (0.192) 0.076 � (0.019) 0.0167 � (0.002) 0.424 � (0.076) 0.233 �
0.027
-0.012
0.030
0.101
0.002
(0.074)
(0.077)
(0.084)
(0.081)
(0.076)
0.002
0.001
(0.001)
(0.001) 0.309 � (0.071)
0.004 � (0.001) 0.160 �/
0.004 � (0.001) 0.403 �
(0.076)
(0.073)
(0.073)
0.001 (0.001) 0.245 � (0.071)
0.065
0.025
0.048
-0.167
0.016
(0.127)
(0.128)
(0.141)
(0.137)
(0.128)
0.158.l0'
Constant term
0.385 � (0.193)
Skilled
Worker Training Worker Training
(0.073)
(0.070)
female workers
External
(0.072)
0.272 �
control methods
In-house
Formal Training Training
0.082
0.215 �
0.207 �/
0.059
(0.083)
(0.083)
(0.086)
(0.085)
(0.083)
-1.808 �
-2.305 �
-2.331 �
-2.514 �
-2.214 �
(0.326)
(0.336)
(0.374)
(0.387)
(0.329)
-1090.86
-918.23
-970.59
-1102.68
-1133.40
= Significant at 1%
b
= Significant at 5%
c
=Significant at 10% level.
Numbers in parantheses are standard errors. Omitted firm size is micro enterprises with 15 or fewer workers. Age of firm and multi-plant status were also included but were not statistically significant
Source: 1995 MITP Survey
CHAPTER THREE: PRODUCTIVITY
AND
wAGE OUTCOMES
In this chapter, we tum to an empirical analysis of the
rizes the complex engineering relationships be
outcomes of enterprise training-both on firm-level
tween the firm's output and the inputs used to pro
productivity and on the wages of workers. We are
duce that output- plant and equipment, labor,
interested in finding out whether employer investments
intermediate inputs and energy.
in formal training are associated with higher firm-level productivity. Other issues of interest are whether
It can be specified in many ways, but the specifi
there are productivity differences in the training pro
cation that we will use is the Cobb-Douglas pro
vided to different groups of employees, for example,
duction function.1 The firm's output is measured
skilled or unskilled workers, and which source of
as the natural logarithm of value-added, that is
training-in-plant training programs or training pro
gross output less the value of intermediate inputs
vided by external institutions--has the largest im
and energy used, and this is related to the firm's
pact on firm-level productivity.
use of the two major factors of production - capital
We also examine the relationship between training
labor (total employment), both-also expressed in
and monthly wages paid by employers. The issue is
logarithms.
(book value of physical plant and equipment) and
whether the productivity gains from training are shared with workers in the form of higher pay and, if
In this Cobb-Douglas functional form, the coeffi
so, what kinds of training have the largest wage ef
cients of capital and labor represent their relative
fects and which groups of workers benefit most. 1his
contribution to output, and they typically sum to
analysis of the productivity and wage outcomes of train
one, or roughly constant returns to scale. The pro
ing has ramifications for employers, workers and
duction function that we estimate is augmented to
policymakers. Insights into the effects of training on
include different training measures and a set of con
firm-level productivity are important for employers
trol variables.
who must make decisions about whether to train, who to train, and what kinds of training to sponsor.
The training measures range from simple indicator
For workers, these wage gains, if any, represent an
training-to more complex ones, such as training pro
incentive for them to undertake training and a moti
vided to different groups of workers, training by
vation for them to develop long-term job attachment
source (in-house versus external training), and type
to the firm. This is important since high job turnover
of external training providers. These training mea
variables-whether employers provide any formal
reduces employer incentive to invest in workers'
sures allow us to ask whether training investments
skills. The training outcomes are also of interest to
are associated with higher firm-level productivity,
policymakers concerned with issues of economic
controlling for inputs of capital and labor, and for the
performance, resource allocation, design of training
influences of other contemporaneous variables that
policies, and income distribution.
also affect productivity. The latter include the average educational attain ment of the firm's workforce, indicator variables for
Estimating the Productivity Impact of Training
firm characteristics such as whether it exports or in
We analyze the productivity outcomes of employer
licensing agreements), and two-digit industiy dummy
investments in fonnal training within a production func
variables to control for productivity differences
tion framework. The production function summa-
across industries.
vests in technology (measured by R&D or technology
PRODUCTIVITY AND WAGE OUTCOMES
25
Our production function approach takes into account
function. Using the predicted, rather than the actual
the possibility of" selectivity bias" in estimating train
value of the training variable in the production func
ing outcomes. Tills bias may arise if firms have very
tion allows us to get unbiased estimates of the pro
different underlying productivity endowments, and
ductivity effects of training.
the firms that choose to train differ systematically from non-training firms in both their observed and unob served productivity attributes. To the extent that we
Productivity Effects of Training for
cannot fully control for these unmeasured differ
Different Firms
ences, the production function may over or under state (bias) our estimates of the productivity impact of
We begin by presenting estimates of the productiv
training. We use an instrumental variable approach
ity effects of formal training provided by different
to correct for this potential "selectivity bias."
groups of employers. In defining these different groups, we rely on the findings in Chapter Two,
In Chapter Two, we report the results of estimating
namely, that the likelihood of training is greater in
probit models for the firm's decision to train. Here,
larger firms in firms using new technology, in ex
we use those probit results to construct a predicted
porting firms, and in foreign-owned firms. If the
value for the training variable that, by its construc
higher incidence of training in these firms is indica
,
tion, is uncorrelated with the unmeasured produc
tive of the relative profitability of investments in
tivity attributes (the error term) in the production
worker training, we should also expect to find rela-
Table 3.1 Production Function Estimates by Firm Size Independent Variable
Overall
Small
Medium
Large
Log (labor)
0.576• (0.039)
0.583• (0.065)
0.401• (0.201)
0.578• (0.090)
0.267• (0.019)
0.256• (0.026)
0.274• (0.042)
0.304• (0.039)
Invests in technology
-0.104 (0.071)
-0.107 (0.118)
-0.139 (0.115)
0.024 (0.113)
Exports
0.034 (0.069)
0.187b (0.091)
-0.138 (0.124)
-0.387 (0.170)
Age of firm
0.007• (0.002)
0.006b (0.003)
0.002 (0.004)
0.009• (0.003)
Education of workers
0.029 (0.020)
0.025 (0.029)
0.019 (0.034)
0.053 (0.039)
Predicted Training
0.325• (0.080)
0.323• (0.104)
0.297b (0.144)
0.125 (0.151)
Constant
7.614" (0.403)
8.130" (0.505)
8.905" (1.131)
7.179" (0.767)
Log
(capital)
a=
b Note:
=
Significant at 1%.
Significant at 5%.
Numbers in parentheses are standard errors. Industry dummy variables included but their estimates are not reported here.
26
ENTERPRISE TRAINING, TECHNOLOGY AND PRODUCTIVITY
tively high productivity outcomes from training
The firm's age is positive, suggesting that the older firms tend on average to be more productive, re
among these groups of firms.
flecting their accumulation of production experience. In interpreting the training results, note that output
The other explanatory variables-the mean educa
or value-added is expressed in natural logarithms.
tional attainment of the workforce, technology, and
This allows us to interpret the coefficient of the train
exports-never attain statistical significance in the pro
ing indicator variable (or its predicted value) as the
duction function estimates though, as seen in Chap
percentage change in output ofbeing a training firm
ter Two, they are very important determinants of the
rather than a non-training firm, controlling for the
firm's decision to train.
productivity effects of other variables. For the MITP sample as a whole, Table 3.1 indicates Productivity Effects by Firm Size
that training has a positive and statistically signifi
Table 3.1 reports the production function estimates
cant impact on firm-level productivity. The esti
for the MITP sample as a whole and separately by
mated training coefficient is 0.325, suggesting that
three firm sizes. Before turning to the training esti
training firms are, on average, about 32 percent more
mates, we note that both labor and capital coefficients
productive than firms that do not train, controlling
are positive and significant, and that their magnitudes
for all other factors that also influence productivity
of approximately two-thirds and one-third, respec
in firms. Training effects of this magnitude are not
tively, are broadly consistent with the shares of la
unusual and, in fact, are broadly similar to those esti
bor and capital in the economy.
mated for other developing countries (see Box 3 .1).
Box 3.1 Enterprise Training and Productivity in Developing Countries
Tan and Batra (1995) used a common production function model to estimate the firm-level produc tivity effects of training in the manufacturing sector of Indonesia, Colombia, Malaysia, and Mexico. In all four countries, they found evidence that enterprise training is associated with higher firm-level productivity. Their findings also indicated that the productivity effects of training, especially training provided skilled workers, are larger in lower-income economies (Colombia and Indonesia) as compared to the higher-income countries in their sample (Malaysia and Mexico), possibly reflecting the relative scarcity of skills in these lower income countries. The implication is that economic development is strongly tied to workforce skills development, and that policies to encourage increased enterprise training will have large productivity gains for the economy. Country (year of survey) Indonesia (1992) Colombia (1992) Malaysia (1994) Mexico (1992)
GNP per capita US$ $ 670 $1,330 $3,140 $3,470
Productivity Effects Any Training 0.711 0.266 0.282 0.444
Productivity Effects Skilled Training 1.430 0.386 0.252 0.204
Source: Tan and Batra, Enterprise Training in Developing Countries, Private Sector Development Department, World Bank, 1995.
PRODUCTIVITY AND WAGE OUTCOMES
Do the productivity effects of training vary by firm
firms, the productivity effects of training are much
size? To address this question, separate production
smaller-12 percent-and these effects are not statis
functions are estimated for three firm size groups
tically significant.
27
small firms (up to 100 employees), medium-size finns (101-250 employees), and large firms (over 250 em
The fact (shown in Chapter Two) that relatively
ployees)-and the results reported in columns two
few smaller firms train despite this evidence of
through four ofTable 3 1
large potential gains in productivity from doing
.
.
so, leads us to conclude that small and medium The estimated training coefficients are 0.32, 0.29 and
firms under-invest in training. Such wide discrep
0.12 in small, medium and large firms. These results
ancies in returns could not persist in a perfectly
indicate that worker training has large productivity
competitive market since firms would train (in
benefits among small and medium-size firms-32 and
crease the supply of trained workers) to equalize
29 percent-productivity increases that are statisti
the returns to training across markets. The fact
cally significant at the five percent level. For large
that they do not suggests that market failures are
Box 3.2 Technology Raises the Productivity of Training in Taiwan, China. Using microdata from the 1986 Taiwan Census of Manufactures, Aw and Tan (1994) investigated the effects of training on firm-level productivity in seven industries. They were interested in whether the productivity effects of training varied with the firm's technology level, as measured by in-house
R&D or purchases of technology.
For each industry, they estimated separate production functions
for firms that invested in technology, termed "high-tech," and for firms that made no such technology investments, or "low-tech," correcting for potential selectivity bias in firms' technology decisions. They found clear evidence that technology had an impact on the productivity outcomes of training. First, within each industry, training provision was associated with a larger impact on firm-level productivity when training was accompanied by firm investments in R&D or purchased technology. Second, looking across industries, the differential impact of training in high-tech and low-tech firms is more pronounced in the technology-intensive industries such as electronics, chemicals, and plastics than in the more traditional industries like textiles and apparel. Thus, both within and across industries, the evidence indicates that the returns to training rises with technological change.
--- -
---- ----�-
P 1
ro d
.
B
0
6
0
4
0
--------
ctivity
Effe
-
---
cts
of
Tra in
in
g
·-
T aiw
a n
1986
2
I' 1 0
u
em H ig h - T e c h
-Lo w -Te ch L-.--------�
2 0
-�--------
---�-
- -
---
----
__j
28
ENTERPRISE TRAINING, TECHNOLOGY AND PRODUCTIVITY
present, especially among small and medium firms
Productivity Effects by Technology
(SMis).
The level of technology used in firms may also af fect the productivity outcomes of worker training
This conclusion is bolstered by employer responses
(Lillard and Tan, 1992). The characteristics of new
about why they provide employees with little or no
technologies are often poorly understood, and their
training. The evidence, which will be presented in
productivity advantages over the older technolo
Chapter Four, suggests that several market failures
gies that they replace are seldom manifested without
from lack of information about how to develop and
significant employer investments in learning-by-do
manage their training programs, high job turnover
ing and training. In this environment, the productiv
which makes it difficult for firms to recoup their train
ity gains from worker training can be quite
ing investments, and limited access to fmance for
substantial.
training-are important reasons for why some employ ers invest very little in training. More significantly,
In contrast, older and more established technologies
their responses also suggest that these factors pose
require less training since their specific characteris
particularly severe constraints for mar�y SMis.
tics are well-known; consequently, the productiv-
Table 3.2 Production Function Estimates by Technology Level DoTec=O Log (labor)
Log (capital)
DoTec=1
Age of Firm
Education of workforce
Predicted Training
Constant
R square
0.604"
0.531"
0.624"
0.391"
(0.058)
(0.041)
(0.084)
0.259"
0.294"
0.261"
0.287"
(0.022)
(0.038)
(0.020)
(0.062)
-0.139
-0.218
(0.083)
(0.155)
0.093
-0.132
0.063
-0.084
(0.079)
(0.126)
(0.070)
(0.213)
0.005b
0.009"
0.006"
0.019"
(0.002)
(0.003)
(0.002)
(0.007)
0.028
0.032
0.029
0.004
(0.024)
(0.034)
(0.021)
(0.055)
0.281"
0.282"
0.233"
0.554"
(0.095)
(0.120)
(0.082)
(0.181)
7.954"
7.768"
7.813"
8.798"
(0.421)
(0.643)
(0.375)
(1.035)
0.619
0.635
0.636
0.626
a= Significant at 1%. b = Significant at 5%. Note:
Numbers in parentheses are standard errors. Industry dummy variables included but their estimates are not reported here.
Do Tee= invest in R&D or has technology license. HasTL =has technology licensing agreement(s). Source: 1995 MITP Survey
HasTL=1
(0.047)
Conducts R&D
Exports
HasTL=O
PRODUCTIVITY AND WAGE OUTCOMES
ity gains from training to use older technologies are
29
To summarize, these production function estimates
also likely to be limited. In Chapter Two, we found
show that firms can make potentially large produc
strong evidence that firms were more likely to train
tivity gains of over 55 percent when new technolo
their workers if they were also investing in R&D.
gies acquired through licensing agreements are
These perspectives lead us to formulate the follow
complemented with investments in training. In con
ing tests of the link between the firm's technology
trast, R&D has limited impact either on overall pro
level and the productivity outcomes of training. We
ductivity levels, or on productivity of worker
split the MITP sample into two groups of firms by
training. We interpret this limited impact of R&D
level of technology, and compare the productivity
as reflecting the relatively weak R&D capabilities
effects of training in the high and low technology
of Malaysian firms; MNCs are widely believed to
groups. Such an analysis can also be done for indi
have greater capabilities in conducting R&D but they
vidual industries when data on large samples of
do little in Malaysia.
firms are available (see Box 3.2). Productivity Effects by Export Orientation Two defmitions of teclmology are used. First, we
and Ownership
define an indicator variable, DOTEC, which takes
Two other attributes of firms-export orientation and
on a value of one if the firms invests in R&D or has
foreign ownership-may affect the productivity out
technology licensing agreements with other firms,
comes of training through the mediating role of tech
and zero otherwise. Second, we define an indicator
nology and links with external markets.
variable, HASTL, to distinguish between firms with and without technology licenses.
The level of teclmology in exporting firms may be higher for two reasons: (a) a firm's export-orienta
This second definition recognizes that when in
tion may simply reflect its underlying teclmological
house R&D capabilities are weak, as is true in many
capabilities and international competitiveness; (b) ex
Malaysian firms, licensing agreements can be an im
porting may also raise technological capabilities by
portant means of accessing relatively sophisticated
giving firms access to technologies and know-how
technologies from abroad, even if the firm does no
from abroad and, through interactions with foreign
in-house R&D. The production function estimates
buyers, information about new markets and product
corresponding to these two teclmology measures
specifications as well.
are reported in Table 3.2. When the broad defini tion of technology, DOTEC, is used, the productiv
Foreign firms-defmed here as firms with over 50
ity effects of training-about 28 percent increase in
percent foreign capital participation-are thought to
value-added-are virtually indistinguishable in the
embody relatively high levels of teclmology, know
high teclmology and low technology firm samples.
how, and managerial expertise as compared to do
To see this, note that almost similar training coeffi
mestic firms. Their level of technological capabilities
cients of0.28 are reported in columns one and two.
is not well reflected by indicators such as local R&D spending or technology licenses, since they are able
The second defmition, HASTL, which is based on
to draw on the MNC parent's stock of technology
whether firms have technology licensing agree
and R&D.2 These are not typically located in de
ments, does a better job of discriminating between
veloping countries where there is often a short sup
the high and low teclmology firms, controlling for
ply of experienced R&D scientists and engineers.
their R&D investments. Not only are average pro ductivity levels (reflected in the constant term) much
Table 3.3 reports production function estimates for
higher in firms with teclmology licenses, the pro
groups of firms differing in their export-orientation
ductivity effects of training in these firms are over
and ownership. Columns one and two indicate that
twice as big as those for firms without technology
the productivity effects of training are higher in firms
licenses-55 versus about 23 percent.
30
ENTERPRISE TRAINING, TECHNOLOGY AND PRODUCTIVITY
Table 3.3 Production Function Estimates by Export Orientation and Ownership
Exports=O
Exports>O
Foreign=O
Log {labor)
0.678• (0.068)
0.515• (0.046)
0.571• (0.048)
0.578• (0.069)
Log (capital)
0.251• (0.029)
0.266• (0.027)
0.285• (0.022)
0.207• (0.044)
Invest in Technology
0.071 (0.151)
-0.135 (0.075)
-0.096 (0.087)
-0.099 (0.119)
0.041 (0.078)
-0.419 (0.215)
Exports
Foreign=1
Age of Firm
0.004 (0.003)
0.01oa (0.003)
0.007" (0.002)
0.018" (0.006)
Education of workforce
0.036 (0.034)
0.022 (0.023)
0.025 (0.024)
0.099b (0.042)
Predic ted Training
0.270b (0.133)
0.333• (0.095)
0.283• (0.098)
0.327b (0.158)
Constant
7.751• (0.579)
7.784• (0.506)
7.319• (0.487)
7.843• (0.776)
R square
0.583
0.608
0.625
0.673
a= Significant at b
Note:
= Significant at
1%. 5%.
Numbers in parentheses are standard errors. Industry dummy variables included but their estimates are not reported here.
Source:
1995 MITP Survey
that export-about 33 percent-as compared with those that do not-about 27 percent. Columns three and four show a similar result, that the productivity outcomes of training are higher in foreign-owned firms (33 percent) than in domestic firms (28 per cent). It is also noteworthy that overall levels of productivity (as reflected in the constant term) are much higher in the sample of foreign-owned firms (7 .84) than in the domestic firm sample (7 .32).
of domestic firms. As shown in Chapter Two, firms with these characteristics are more likely to invest in the training of their workers. The pro duction function results reported here confirm that the productivity effects of this increased training are significantly higher among firms that export, have technology licensing agreements, and some foreign capital participation.
Taken together, these results and the findings re ported in Table 3.2 provide support for the view that employer investments in technology and train� ing are complementary in that investments in one enhance the productivity of the other. Given cur rent weak local R&D capabilities, the results sug gest that export-orientation, foreign technology licensing and joint-ventures may offer the great est potential for improving the technology levels
Productivity Outcomes by Skill Group and Training Source
Thus far, we have treated all forms of training as if they had the same productivity outcomes. We now consider several potential variations in the produc tivity outcomes of training across different worker groups and sources of training. As before, we con trol for selectivity bias by including the predicted
PRODUCTIVITY AND WAGE OUTCOMES
values of training from pro bit models of training
pervisors, engineers, technicians and skilled produc
for different skill groups and for different training
tion workers; and unskilled production workers.
sources.
For each skill group, we begin by estimating sepa
We also test a specification where training is pre dicted using a tobit model. The tobit specification is a mix of a probit model and a regression model in that it incorporates information both on the prob ability of an event and, conditional on that event taking place, the distribution of a continuous vari
31
rate probit models of whether employers provide in-house or external training, including the group specific measures of skill mix and female workers as the identifying variables. The estimated parameters are then used to calculate predicted training mea sures for each group in the production function.
able. This tobit specification allows us to estimate
A corresponding set of tobit training models is also
the productivity effects of "training intensity," that
estimated to predict training intensity of in-house and
is, the proportion of workers in a specific group
external training. Production function estimates us
getting training, while taking into account the de
ing these alternative probit and tobit training mea
cisions of some firms not to train.
sures are reported in Table 3 .4. Both the probit and
Estimating the separate effects of each type and source of training is complicated by the high correlation that exists between different training measures. The correlation arises in large part because firms that provide training tend to rely on all sources of training while employers that do little training rarely use more than one source. This means that our probit or tobit predicted train ing measures will be correlated, unless identify ing variables can be found to explain why employers might choose one training source over another. Given the paucity of identifying vari ables for each source, we can only address this identification issue in a limited way. For training by skill groups, we rely on variations in the proportion of skilled occupations and un skilled workers to identify what types of training are provided. For training by source, we include the presence of a training center and training staff to identify decisions to provide in-house training, and the use of joint training programs with other firms for external training. The limited number of identifying variables precludes a more disaggre gated analysis of training for each detailed occu pational group or every training source.
tobit measures are consistent in showing that training of skilled workers has a positive and statistically sig nificant impact on firm-level productivity while the training of unskilled workers does not. The training estimates for the latter group never attain statistical significance, and are thus interpreted as having zero impact on productivity. What about training skilled workers? Using the probit measure, the estimated coefficient of0.38 in dicates that provision of skilled worker training is associated, on average, with a 38 percent increase in productivity. A reasonable way of interpreting the tobit measure is to evaluate its coefficient-1.22-at the sample mean of the training variable. The propor tion of skilled workers trained was0.175 or 17.5 per cent. This implies that a 10 percent increase in the proportion of skilled workers trained (i.e. 0.017 5) is associated with a 2 .1 percent increase (1.22 x 0.0175 x 100) in productivity. The differential impact of training by skill group is not surprising once it is recognized that education is the foundation of subsequent learning, and to the extent that skilled workers are more efficient learn ers, they benefit more from training. Employers ap pear to recognize these differences in the learning capabilities of different worker groups. In Chapter
Productivity Effects by Skill Group
Two, the analyses indicated that firms were more
We consider the productivity effects of training for
likely to provide all kinds of training to their skilled
two worker groups: skilled workers, including su-
employees than to their unskilled workers.
32
ENTERPRISE TRAINING, TECHNOLOGY AND PRODUCTIVITY
We note that these results are not unique to Malay
ing from all outside sources combined. As before,
sia. Similar patterns of training outcomes, not only
the probability and intensity of in-house and exter
on the productivity but also the wages of skilled and
nal training measures are predicted using probit and
unskilled workers, are found in other developing
tobit
countries such as Mexico, Colombia and Indonesia
tify the employer's choice of each training mode by
(Tan and Batra, 1995). If the experiences of these
the occupational and sex mix of its workforce.
models, respectively. In these models, we iden
countries are any guide, the differential productiv ity impact of training is likely to result in growing
The production function results with the alternative
wage differentials between skilled and unskilled
training measures are reported in Table 3.5, sepa
workers in the absence of training policies to up
rately for local firms (columns one and two) and for
grade unskilled workers to skilled status.
foreign firms (columns three and four). Table 3.5 clearly shows that productivity outcomes by training
Productivity Effects by Training Source
source are quite different depending upon owner
Next, we compare the productivity effects of in
ship status of the firm. 3
house company training programs and external trainTable 3.4 Production Function Estimates with Predicted Training by Worker Groups
Independent Variable Log (labor)
Log (capital)
Invests in Technology
Exports
Age of Firm
Probit
Tobit
Prediction
Prediction
0.5773
0.558•
(0.040)
(0.042)
0.2793
0.266•
(0.019)
(0.019)
-0.102
-0.107
(0.065)
(0.071)
0.010
0.021
(0.064)
(0.069)
0.0063
0.0063
(0.002)
(0.002)
First, consider the productivity effects of internal and external training when training measures are pre dicted by a probit model (columns one and three). For the sample of domestic firms, only externally provided training has a positive and significant im pact on productivity, averaging about 26 percent; no statistically significant impact of in-house training is evident. In the case of foreign firms, the results indicate that both in-house and external training have a positive and significant effect on firm productivity13 percent for in-house training and 33 percent for external. These results are striking-on one hand, they point to the strong in-house training capabilities of foreign firms; on the other hand, they highlight the weak in house training capabilities of local firms and the po
0.035
0.029
(0.023)
(0.022)
0.383b
1.220b
Worker Training
(0.165)
(0.571)
Predicted Unskilled
-0.151
-0.680
Worker Training
(0.248)
(0.723)
7. 5333
7.7323
ence is that external training intensity for foreign
(0.448)
(0.425)
firms is no longer statistically significant.
Education of workforce
Predicted Skilled
Constant
a=
providers can play in meeting their training needs. The qualitative results using the tobit training mea sures are broadly similar in showing the importance of external training sources for local firms and in house training for foreign firms. The only differ
Significant at 5%. Numbers in parentheses are standard
What are the effects of training more intensely, at
errors. Industry dummy variables included but
are statistically significant? For local firms, the
b
Note:
Significant at 1%
tentially important role that external training
=
their estimates are not reported here. Source: 1995 MITP Survey
least for those external sources of training that proportion of workers getting in-house and ex ternal training is 0.094 and 0.026, respectively.
PRODUCTIVITY AND WAGE OUTCOMES
33
Table 3.5 Production Function Estimates: In-house versus External Training
Local Firms
Independent Variable
Probit prediction
prediction
Foreign Firms Probit prediction
Tobit prediction
0.627"
0.589"
0.559"
0.637"
(0.049)
(0.042)
(0.077)
(0.058)
Log (labor)
0.273 a
0.290"
0.201"
0.209"
(0.022)
(0.022)
(0.044)
(0.042)
-0.083
-0.029
-0.120
-0.144
(0.088)
(0.088)
(0.118)
(0.116)
0.101
0.051
-0.442b
-0.331
(0.079)
(0.076)
(0.213)
(0.206)
Log (capital)
Invests in Technology
Tobit
Exports
0.005b
0.005b
0.017"
0.015"
(0.002)
(0.002)
(0.006)
(0.006)
Age of Firm
0.026
0.015
0.089b
0.092b
workforce
(0.023)
(0.025)
(0.042)
(0.042)
Predicted Internal
-0.038
-0.063
Training
(0.050)
(0.169)
Education of
0.400b (0.214)
0.256a
1.751a
0.329b
1.297
(0.096)
(0.691)
(0.151)
(1.021)
Predicted External Training
0.13b (0.068)
Constant
7.555a
7.735a
8.494a
8.364a
(0.512)
(0.437)
(0.847)
(0.747)
a= Significant at 1% Note:
b = Significant at 5% Numbers in parentheses are standard errors. Industry dummy variables included but their estimates are not reported here.
Source: 1995 MITP Survey
Evaluated at these means, the coefficient of 1. 754
eral external sources-poly technics, vocational
on external training suggests that a 10 percent in
training institutes,
crease in the proportion of workers getting external
Skills Training Institutes (e.g. ClAST and GMI),
IKM, ITI, SDCs, Advanced
training (0.0026) will lead to a 0.5 percent increase
buyers and suppliers, other private firms, and over
in productivity. For foreign firms, the correspond
seas (presumably by foreign partners). The pre
ing proportions are 0.191 for in-house training and 0.032 for external training. Using the in-house train ing coefficient of0.40, a 10 percent increase in train ing (0.019) is associated with a produc tivity improvement of about 0. 8 percent. 4
likely to be most important for improving produc
Productivity Effects of Different External
fective for domestic firms as for foreign firms?
vious findings raise the following questions: Which of these external training providers are tivity and, given differences in in-house training capabilities by ownership status, are the same ex ternal training providers likely to be equally ef
Sources of Training The MITP survey elicited information from firms
We begin to address these questions by combin
about the number of employees trained in sev-
ing the different external training providers into
34
ENTERPRISE TRAINING, TECHNOLOGY AND PRODUCTIVITY
Table 3.6:
Production Function Estimates: Training from External Sources
Independent Variable
Domestic Firms Tobit
Probit prediction Log {labor )
Log (capital)
Invests in Technology
Exports
Age of Firm
Education of workforce
Predicted Internal Training
prediction 0.588"
0.546"
0.589"
(0.049)
(0.078)
(0.076)
0.269"
0.284"
0.220"
0.208"
(0.022)
(0.022)
(0.043)
(0.043)
-0.077
-0.083
-0.109
-0.095
(0.088)
(0.089)
(0.118)
(0.117)
0.158C
0.002
-0.427c
-0.457b
(0.088)
(0.085)
(0.223)
(0.236)
0.002
0.008"
0.024"
0.015b
(0.003)
(0.003)
(0.007)
(0.006)
0.011
0.005
0.077c
0.105b
(0.026)
(0.029)
(0.046)
(0.051)
-0.031
-0.132
0.147b
0.515b
(0.050)
(0.172)
(0.069)
(0.232)
-12.516b
1.466b
24.396"
(5.376)
(0.602)
(9.129)
-0.339 (0.350) 0.632b
39.099b
(0.258)
(16.767)
Predicted Training in
0.019
11.346
Government Institutes
(0.262)
Constant
a=
b Note:
=
Tobit prediction
0.65 "
Predicted Training in
SDCs & Adv. Train. Ins.
prediction
(0.057)
Private Institutes Predicted Training by
Foreign Firms Probit
(8.341)
-0.741
-31.238
(0.456)
(38.148)
-0.406
-33.619
(0.441)
(17.425)
8.508"
8.158"
7.325"
7.557"
(0.712)
(0.700)
(1.196)
(1.343)
Significant at 1% Significant at 5%
Numbers in parentheses are standard errors. Industry dummy variables included but their estimates are not reported here.
Source: 1995 MITP Survey
three groups5: (1) government-run training in
of external training. The production function re
stitutions, including ITis, IKMs, YTCs, voca
sults with predicted training measures are re
tional and technical institutes, and polytechnics;
ported in Table 3. 6. These results should be
(2) advanced skills training centers and SDCs
treated with caution since we do not have sepa
providing high-level skills training with input from
rate identifying variables for each external train
the private sector; and (3) all other private sec
ing source.
tor training providers, including private training institutes, foreign partners, buyers and sellers,
Table 3. 6 shows that external training providers have
and overseas training sponsored by employers.
very different productivity effects depending upon
We are motivated to aggregate training into
ownership. For local firms, in-house training contin
three broad categories because of the high de
ues to be statistically insignificant. Among external
gree of correlation among the different sources
training sources, the results indicate that only the
PRODUCTIVITY AND WAGE OUTCOMES
35
training provided by SDCs and advanced skills
vanced skills training centers is associated with a
training centers to local firms has a positive and sta
1.2 percent gain in productivity. For foreign firms
tistically significant productivity impact, irrespec
the corresponding productivity gains from increas
,
tive of whether probit or tobit training measures are
ing the intensity of in-house training is one percent,
used. The probit measure indicates that this pro
that from private training institutes and overseas
ductivity impact is large, averaging about 63 per
training is 5. 6 percent.
cent. Tr aining provided by other private providers is actually associated with lower pro
The different patterns of training outcomes in for
ductivity in domestic firms.
eign and domestic firms suggest the following in terpretation. Foreign firms have well developed
For foreign firms, two sources of training are as
in-house training capabilities, and therefore may
sociated with significant productivity gains-in
need to rely less on SDCs and advanced skills
house training, and training from private training
training centers for training their workers. We
institutes-these include local providers as well as
speculate, but cannot confirm, that the relative im
overseas training. However, the latter source of
portance of training from other private providers
training has an implausibly large productivity im
may reflect their ability to send their workers
pact of 146 percent, based on the probit measure.
abroad to the parent company for training. In
In both groups of firms, there are no significant
contrast, domestic firms have relatively weak in
productivity gains from training in government
house training capabilities so that SDCs and ad
institutes.
vanced skills training centers are important
The productivity effects of increased training in
sources of higher-level skills training for them.
tensity are reported in Table 3. 7 for statistically
Firm-Level Wages Outcomes of Training
significant sources of training. For each group of firms, the table reports the sample means of train ing intensity, and the gains in productivity from
We now tum to a second outcome of training-its ef
increasing training intensity by 10 percent.
fects on the monthly wages of employees. Several
For local firms, a 10 percent increase in the propor
tivity gains from training passed on to workers in the
tion of workers getting training in SDCs and ad-
form of higher pay? In which types of firms are the
issues are of interest: to what extent are the produc
Table 3.7: Productivity Effects of Increased Training Intensity Local Firms Training source
Foreign Firms
Fraction
Productivity
Fraction
getting
impact of
getting
impact of
training
10% change
training
10% change
Productivity
In-house training
0.094
not sig.
0.191
1.0
Private training institutes
0.017
not sig.
0.023
5.6
SDCs & Adv. train. ins.
0.003
0.004
not sig.
Government training institutes
0.005
0.005
not sig.
Note:
1.2 not sig.
The productivity impact is calculated for a 10 percent change in mean training intensity; statistically insignificant impacts denoted as "not sig."
Source: Coefficients of tobit training measures taken from Table 3.6, means of training intensity variables calculated from the MITP data.
36
ENTERPRISE TRAINING, TECHNOLOGY AND PRODUCTIVITY
wage payoffs to training highest? And, which groups
experience (age), and in firms that invest in new
of workers benefit most from training?
technology. Firms with a workforce that is more highly educated also tend to pay higher wages, while
We are interested in these issues for several rea
those that rely heavily on female workers pay lower
sons. First, how the productivity gains from training
wages.
are shared has implications not only for worker in centives to undertake training, but also for employer
Both training measures indicate a positive and sig
incentives to sponsor and pay for training which may
nificant effect on monthly wages. In column one,
not be able to be recouped because of job turnover.
the training indicator variable has an estimated
Second, to the extent that higher wage payments are
wage effect of 0.04 (four percent); in column two,
feasible only when justified by productivity gains
the estimated wage effect of the predicted train
from training, these wage analyses-by firm charac
ing variable is0.06 (six percent). Even given this
teristics and by worker groups-provide a way of in
range of estimates, what is striking is that the wage
dependently verifying the productivity outcomes of
effects of training are smaller than the productiv
training identified earlier.
ity gains from training of0.32 (32 percent) esti mated in a production function model (see Table
To get estimates of the wage effects of training, we
3.1, column one).
regressed the logarithm of monthly wages on a mea sure of worker training and other control variables.
A comparison of these estimates suggests that roughly
The other explanatory variables are similar to those
one-eighth to one-fifth of the productivity gains from
used in the production function model, and include a
training are passed on to workers in the form of
quadratic measure of firm size (logarithm of employ
higher wages. By implication, the remaining seven
ment), age of the firm indicator variables for whether
eights to four-fifths of the productivity gains accrue
the firm exports or invests in technology, mean
to the employer as the returns to his (share of) in
schooling of the workforce, the proportions of non
vestments in training.
,
production and female workers, and a set of two digit industry dummy variables. We also estimated
This evidence of firm-worker sharing of productiv
separate wage models for four occupational groups
ity gains from training is of some policy interest, given
to determine if the wage effects of training differ for
proposed guidelines on linking wages to productiv
skilled and unskilled workers.
ity growth currently being drafted in Malaysia by a tripartite group representing employers, unions and
Overall Wage Effects of Training
the government. However, we caution that this evi
In Table 3. 8, we report the results of two wage model
dence is cross-sectional, when what is required to
specifications, one where training is measured by an
inform the deliberations of this tripartite groups is
indicator variable (column one), a second where we
evidence on how gains in productivity over time are
include the predicted value of training obtained from
passed through to wages increases. This will re
a pro bit model to account for potential selectivity
quire rigorous time-series analyses of productivity
bias (column two). As noted in previous sections, the
and wage growth, which is beyond the scope of this
wage effects of training may be biased (either up or
report.
down) if the firms that train differ systematically from those that do not.
Do the wage effects of training vary systematically across different groups of firms? The previous pro
Before presenting the training results, we note that
duction function results revealed a pattern of pro
mean pay levels tend to rise with firm size (employ
ductivity gains from training that was higher in firms
ment) up to a point, but decline in the very large
that invested in technology, that exported, or had
firms; they are higher in firms with more production
foreign capital participation. To determine if the wage
PRODUCTIVITY AND WAGE OUTCOMES
Table 3.8 Wage Model Estimates with Training Indicator and Predicted Values
Independent Variable
Training Indicator Predicted Training Specification Specification
Log (labor)
0.0988
0. 0738
cant impact on wages in firms that do not invest in technology, or in domestic firms . These weak wage effects may reflect, in part, the much smaller produc tivity gains from training in these latter groups of
firms . Thus, we conclude that the training-wage re sults by firm characteristics are broadly consistent
(0.027)
(0.029)
Log
-0.0138
-0.0128
with the patterns of productivity gains from training
(labor squared)
(0.003)
(0.003)
found earlier.
Invest in Technology Exports
0.032°
0.031°
(0.018)
(0.019)
Wage Effects of Training by Occupation
-0.023
-0.023
The wage effects of training can also be analyzed
(0.018)
(0.018)
for four occupational groups-supervisors, tech
nicians, skilled production workers, and unskilled
0.0048
0.004a
(0.001)
(0.001)
0.023a
0.0188
(0.004)
(0.005)
0.038b
0.062b
Training
(0.017)
(0.027)
Proportion
-0.034a
-0.046a
tion received in-house or external training, and
Female Workers
(0.013)
(0.014)
then using their corresponding training intensity
Age of Firm
Education of Workforce Any Formal
Proportion of Nonproduction Labor Constant
1.039a
0.943a
(0.060)
(0.079)
production workers. The MITP survey elicited detailed occupation-specific information on wages as well as numbers getting training by source. We exploit this rich detail by estimating separate wage models for each occupation, first using indicator vari ables for whether workers in that specific occupa
measures.
5.779a
5.9538
Table 3.9 Wage Effects ofTraining by Level of
(0.089)
(0.119)
Technology, Exports, and Ownership
a= Significant at 1%
Estimated Training Coefficient
b = Significant at 5% c
Note:
= Significant at 10%
Numbers in parentheses are standard
No investment in technology
errors.
Invest in technology
0.023
0.073b
(0.022)
(0.030)
Industry dummy variables included but Source: 1995 MITP Survey
effects of training also exhibited this pattern of variation, we estimated separate wage models for dif
technology license(s) 0.026
0.106b (0.049)
Does not export
Exports
The training effects for each group of firms are sum
Like the productivity results, they show positive and
0.064a
(0.033)
(0.020) Foreign-owned Firm
0.022
0.070b
(0.022)
(0.028)
a= Significant at 1%
statistically significant wage effects of training in the
b = Significant at 5%
firms that invest in technology, that have technology contrast, there is little evidence (except in non-ex
0.061°
Domestic firm
marized in Table 3.9.
porting firms) that training has a statistically signifi-
technology license(s)
(0.019)
ferent groups of firms defined in an analogous way.
licenses, that export, and that are foreign-owned. In
Has
No
not reported here.
c
Note:
= Significant at 10% level
Numbers in parentheses are standard errors.
Source: 1995 MITP Survey
37
38
ENTERPRISE TRAINING, TECHNOLOGY AND PRODUCTIVITY
Table 3.10 Occupation-Specific Wage Effects of Training Training Measures
Supervisors
Technicians
Skilled
Unskilled
Production
Production
Workers
Workers
Training Indicators Internal Training Indicator
External Training Indicator
0.063•
0.014
0.072•
0.029
(0.024)
(0.024)
(0.024)
(0.020)
0.001
-0.019
o.osoc
(0.025)
(0.025)
(0.026)
(0.022)
-0.001
Training lntensi!Y Proportion trained internally
Proportion trained externally
Note:
a=
Significant at 1%
b=
Significant at 5%
c=
Significant at 10%.
0.095•
0.019
0.079•
-0.007
(0.030)
(0.031)
(0.034)
(0.027)
-0.052
0.005
0.110
250workers)
454
145
60
41.4
Tobacco
52
27
51.9
Textiles
74 97
14 25
18.9
food, beverages and tobacco, wood and furniture,
25.8
glass and pottery industries (one-third to one-half of firms), than the electrical machinery, chemicals,
Small (50-100workers) Medium
the MITP sample is not completely representative.
Industry Food Other Food, Beverages,
Apparel Wood & Furniture
208
104
50.0
Paper & Printing
89
22
24.7
Chemicals
62
7
11.3
21
18.6
to be in non-compliance (49 percent) than large
firms (eight percent). Across industries, non-compliance is higher in the
and textile industries where rates of non-compliance rates are lower (10 to 20 percent). As such, it ap
Rubber
113
Plastics
87
23
26.4
pears that non-compliance is concentrated among
Glass & Pottery
80
27
33.8
Iron & Basic Metals
42
9
21.4
small firms and firms operating in the traditional,
Fabricated Metals 71
16
22.5
domestic-oriented industries.
Machinery
39
8
20.5
Electrical Machinery
198
21
10.6
48
10
20.8
probit model to identify the factors associated with
8
17.8
non-compliance. Underlying this analysis is an eco
Transport Other Industries
45
Source: 1995 MITP Survey
To look at this issue in greater depth, we estimate a
nomic model in which firms make cost-benefit cal culations, weighing the probability and cost of being
Wedefine "eligible fume:;" asthoo:::employing50ormore
caught in non-compliance against the benefits of not
workers, broadly following the 1995 Guidelines from
registering with the HRDF.
HRDF, Human Resource Developrrent Couocil.10 On the basis of this rough definition, 402 firms (about 27.7
We hypothesize that the probability of appre
percent) out of the total of 1,450 eligible reported that
hension is lower for smaller firms, who are less
they were not registered with the HRDF.
visible, and for firms that are located in more re mote areas. Benefits of non-compliance are two
Of those that were registered with the HRDF, 45
fold: the firm avoids payment of payroll levies,
percent claimed reimbursements under ATP, 47 per
and the potentially high fixed cost of setting up a
cent under SBL, and less than 10 percent under the
formal training program if one does not already
PLTscheme. However, 34.5 percent of registered
exist.
firms reported that they did not claim reimburse ments under any of the three schemes.
The results of the pro bit analysis are reported in
Non-Compliance with HRDF
First, compared to small :finns, medium size and large
Table 4. 7, and they suggest the following points.
The Human Resource Development Act of 1992
firms are less likely to be in non-compliance, possi
made it mandatory for eligible firms to register with
bly because they believe that the probability of their
the HRDC. The 27 percent non-compliance with
being caught is high, given their higher profile.
TRAINING
Table 4.7 Probit Estimates of Non
PouciES
The HRDC is aware of the non-compliance issue but it has few resources to devote to enforcement.
Compliance with HRDF
55
It
currently has a skeleton team-an administrative of Independent Variable
Estimate
Standard error
Medium size firms (1 01-250 workers)
0.086
-i .323a
0.114
It has established a panel of lawyers but their au
0.254a
0.083
0.759a
0.148
ment of levies by registered firms, not prosecution
-0.767a
0.141
Only internal informal training No training Region: Western
corridor states Trengganu, Kelantan
0.254
0.184
Region: Perlis and Kedah
-0.421 a
0.187
-0.241 a
0.081
Increased production Constant Log likelihood
thority is limited to civil cases regarding non-pay of non-registered firms. Only legal officers can pursue the latter cases, and the HRDC is seeking to fill several of these positions. Until such time
Region: Pahang,
over the last 3 years
underlying population of firms that are eligible but not registered with the HRDC.
-0.532a
Large size firms (>250 workers)
ficer and a clerk-working on developing lists of the
0.420a -684.46
0.153
as the HRDC develops the capability to identify and prosecute non-registered firms, the threat of prosecution will not be credible and the non-com pliance problem will persist.
-684.46
The following steps should be taken to address this a= Statistically significant at 1% level. The omitted re gion is Sabah and Sarawak; the omitted size is small firms with 50-100 workers; the omitted train ing group is firms providing formal training. Source: 1995 MITP Survey
Second, firms that do not train or that rely only on informal training, are significantly more likely to be in non-compliance as compared to those provid ing formal training. This is consistent with the pres ence of high-fixed costs of developing and setting up training programs, and incorporating the new skills into existing production. Third, there are systematic regional variations, with non-compliance being much higher in the eastern states of Pahang, Kelantan and Trengganu, and in East Malaysia as compared to the west coast states. Finally, we attempted to control for the firm's growth experience in the past three years, on the grounds that firms that are not growing are more likely to fail and thus have little incentive to reg
issue. First, the Government should expeditiously provide HRDC with the necessary manpower and legal resources to identify and prosecute firms in non-compliance, and to recover back levies and other penalties. Second, with additional resources in hand, the
HRDC should also mount an information campaign, on television and in newspapers, to encourage eli gible firms to register with HRDC. It should an nounce its intention to vigorously enforce compliance with the HRDF Law and, to ensure that this threat is credible, it should publicize its in creased enforcement capabilities as well as its pros ecutions of selected firms. Finally, this campaign should be accompanied by a time-limited amnesty program for firms to come for ward, register with the HRDC, and pay their back levies without civil or criminal penalties. Similar amnesty programs have been effectively used in the United States.
Claims under HRDF
ister with the HRDF. The estimated results-that
A second issue is that a sizable number (362) of reg
firms with stagnant or declining sales are less
istered firms do not claim reimbursements for train
likely to register-is consistent with this hypothesis.
ing expenditures despite contributions of payroll
56
ENTERPRISE TRAINING, TECHNOLOGY AND PRODUCTIVITY
levies to the HRDF. Their claims for training under
line-to June 1995-granted by the HRDC.12 This is
any of the schemes are a crude indicator of how ef
supported by HRDC data showing an increase in
fective HRD F has been in encouraging firms to be
the ratio of funds approved to levy collected, from
gin or increase training.
64.7 percent in 1994 (the time period covered by the MITP survey) to 88.9 percent in 1995.
Tabulations suggest that small firms are less likely to claim as compared to their larger counterparts-
We estimate probit models to get insights into why
50.2 percent for small firms with 50-100 employ
these registered firms did not implement training
ees, 41.3 percent for medium size finns with 101-250
program s and claim reimbu r sements. The depen
employees, and 19.4 percent for large firms with over
dent variable is an indicator variable with a value
250 workers. This is a key issue since firms paying
of one if the firm does not claim, and zero other
into the system, but not claiming reimbursements,
wise.
in effect pay a tax of one percent of payroll without getting any tangible benefits from doing so.
Two models specifications are considered. In the
first model, we include several measures of firm size, Who are these non-claimant firms and why are they
reported training status, an indicator variable for
not training? Table 4.8 reports the distribution of
whether they have a training plan, and industry
registered firms that do not claim according to
dummy variables. In the second specification, we
theirtraining status-no training for workers, only
replace the actual training variables with the fmns'
informal training on-the-job, and training formally.
own responses about why they provided little or no training. Table 4.9 reports the estimated probit re
Table 4.8 Registered Firms Not Claiming from HRDF by Training Status Training Status
Registered
Distribution
firms not claiming
by training status
22
6.1
Firms training informally only
196
54.1
Firms training formally
144
39.8
Firms not training
Source: 1995 MITP Survey
sults for these two models. The results of the first model indicates that the firms least likely to claim from HRD F are small firms, and firms providing no training or only informal train ing. This result was already evident in the simple tabulations. Having a training plan, however, is as
sociated with a greater likelihood of a claim to HRDF, though not necessarily through the PLT (annual training plan) scheme.13 This is not surprising. A training plan is indicative
Interestingly, only about six percent of these non
of an awareness, on thepartoftheemployer, of its
claimants do no training. The majority of firms (54
skill needs, as well as a commitment to a strategy of
percent) are those that only provide informal OJT
systematically training employees to meet these skill
from co-workers and supervisors.11 Thus, about 60
needs either in-house or through services of exter
percent of these firms are not eligible for reimburse
nal training providers.
ments because they either provide no training or are only training informally. The remaining 40 percent report providing formal training yet do not claim reimbursements for these expenditures.
The results of the second model provide insights into why firms contribute but do not claim. The statisti cally significant responses are that employers have limited resources for trainin g, they use mature tech
It is possible that some (unknown) fraction of these
nology with low skill requirements which are
latter firms submitted claims subsequent to the
readily met by school graduates, and skilled work
MITP survey, based upon an extension of the dead-
ers are readily hired from other firms .
TRAINING PoLICIEs
57
Table 4.9 Probit Estimates of Not Claiming from HRDF Independent Variable
Model1
Standard
Model2
Estimates
Errors
Estimates
Standard Errors
Medium firms (101-250 workers)
-0.123
0.107
-0.196
0.105
Large firms (>250 workers)
-0.630 a
0.114
-0.836•
0.110
Limited resources for training
0.242b
0.115
No knowledge about training
0.067
0.099
Mature technology
0.147°
0.084
Get skilled workers from others
0.285b
0.119
Skeptical about training benefits
0.097
0.139
0.283b
0.124
Skills from schools are adequate 0.463•
0.091
Firm does not train
0.511•
0.216
Firm has a training plan
-0.493•
0.089
Firm only trains informally
-0.248b
Constant
-623.06
Log Likelihood a=
0.104 -623.06
Significant at1%
b = Significant at 5% c=
Significant at 10% level Note: The omitted size category is small firms with 51-100 workers; and the omitted training category in model1 is firms that provide formal training. Industry dummy variables included but are not statistically significant.
Source: 1995 MITP Survey
These responses are consistent with the weak
In the JTS scheme, groups of small firms reap
training and technological capabilities of small
scale economies by banding together to engage
and local firms shown in Chapter Two, as well as
training providers who run specific training pro
the financial constraint on funding training iden
grams for them on a joint basis. In addition to
tified in earlier sections of this chapter. They
lower per trainee cost, the ITS provides an added
explain why most of them do little or no formal
incentive for the firm that organizes the joint
training on their own despite the financial incen
training.
tive of the HRDF levy, relying instead on the edu cational system or on trained workers hired from
In the GTS scheme, now being implemented on a
other firms.
pilot basis, 14 employer associations are encour aged to take the initiative in providing training
Recent HRDF Initiatives
to members, with HRDF providing funds to set
The HRDC recognizes the funding and training
up training facilities, and paying the salary of a
difficulties faced by small local firms, and it has
training coordinator for three years. The coordi
introduced several schemes and initiatives to ad
nator conducts a skill needs survey, and organizes
dress these constraints. One set of initiatives seeks
training program for its members.
to assist both large and small firms, in develop ing a training infrastructure-the JURUPLAN for
In this section, we provide insights into these ini
developing a training plan, and a scheme to pur
tiatives using data reported in the MITP survey.
chase training aids and set up training rooms. The
We report the incidence among firms of in-house
second set of initiatives-the Joint Training Scheme
training centers, training plans and how they were
(JTS) and Group Training Scheme (GTS)-is de
developed, and the different types of joint train
signed to encourage group training for smaller
ing programs, focusing in particular on differences
fums.
in these measures by firm size.
58
ENTERPRISE TRAINING, TECHNOLOGY AND PRODUCTIVITY
Table 4.10 Training Centers and Training Plans in MITP by Firm Size
Conditional on Having a Training Plan
Training System Firm Size
% firms
% firms
with
% firms with
Training Plan
Training Plan
Training
Training
developed at
developed by
funded by
Centers
Plans
own cost
consultants
JURUPLAN 7.6
% firms
% firms Training Plan
Small
3.1
10.9
83.2
23.7
Medium
9.7
42.4
76.7
33.5
7.1
19.2
69.2
79.3
35.7
8.6
Large
Source: 1995 MITP Survey Table 4.11 Joint Training Programs in MITP by Firm Size
Firm Size
Source of Joint Training Programs Small % Firms with joint training programs
3.9
Medium 9.9
Large 18.9
Conditional on ajoint training program: Through Industry associations
23.4
30.2
37.2
Organized by government institutions
27.7
24.5
30.2
Ad hoc programs with other firms
34.0
49.1
52.3
Through specialized companies
21.3
35.9
40.7
Organized by suppliers
31.9
34.0
17.0
Organized by buyers
14.9
17.0
27.9
Source: 1995 MITP Survey
Table 4.10 reports the distribution of firms with
How were these training plans fmanced? Columns
training centers and training plans by three firm sizes.
three through five report the sources of their fund
Small, medium and large sizes are defined as em
ing to develop training plans, conditional on having
ployers with less than 100 employees, 101-250 em
one. Multiple responses are permitted so that the
ployees, and over 250 employees, respectively.
numbers do not sum to 100.
Column one shows that firm size is an important
Two points emerge. First, there do not appear to be
determinant of whether an employer has a training
major differences by size in how employers develop
center-only three percent of small firms have train
training plans. Second, the figures reveal that most
ing facilities as compared to 19 percent of large firms.
training plans (over 70 percent) are developed by
As such, considerable potential exists for HRDC to
employers at their own cost, followed next by train
extend the training aids scheme to small firms.
ing plans developed with the assistance of consult ants. The proportion of training plans funded by
Column two shows the proportion of firms with a
the JURUPLAN scheme is low, about seven to
training plan. As before, the presence of a training
eightpercent. HRDC should ascertain the reasons
plan is highly correlated with size, though a much
for why employers prefer to fund their own train
higher number of firms of all sizes report having a
ing plans when an alternative source of fmance is
training plan as compared to training facilities. To
available through the JURUPLAN scheme.
the extent that employers can send workers outside for training, it reduces the necessity for them to have
Table 4.11 shows the incidence and types of joint
a training facility in-house.
training reported by employers in the MITP survey.
TRAINING POLICIES
59
Firms were asked whether they had joint
Such ad hoc arrangements arise when firms,
trainingprograms with other firms to provide work
which otherwise compete with each other, see
ers with training, and if so, how these training pro
acollective interest in jointly investing in a com
grams were organized. Finns indicated one or more
mon good, in this case, worker training. The im
of six types of programs organized through:
portance of other types of joint programs varies markedly by firm size.
•
industry or professional associations
•
government or public institutions
For small firms, programs organized by suppliers
•
ad hoc arrangements with other firms
and government agencies are cited most often after
•
specialized training companies
ad hoc arrangements. Unfortunately, the govern
•
programs organized by suppliers
ment and public agencies involved are not identi
•
programs organized by buyers
fied. For medium size firms, suppliers are also important as are specialized training companies. For
The first row of Table 4.11 indicates that joint train
large firms, most commonly cited after ad hoc joint
ing programs are relatively rare in Malaysian indus
programs are specialized training companies and
try. When they occur, these programs are most
employer or professional associations. The latter's
commonly found among large firms (19 percent)
focus on large employers would be reoriented to
rather than among smaller firms (four percent) who,
wards supporting smaller firms under theHRDF's
it may be argued, need them most. Unlike larger
new GTS scheme.
firms, individual small employers are often unable to assemble a large enough group of employees to
Has HRDF Increased Training by Firms?
warrant the fixed costs of hiring an outside provider
It is too early to make judgments about the efficacy
to deliver a t ailored training program. Joint train
ofHRDF in promoting training and skill upgrad
ing programs, such as those envisaged by the
ing. Additional years of accumulated information
JTSscheme, would allow groups of small firms to
(panel data) will be needed to do that. However, a
reap the economies of scale.
crude test is possible using retrospective responses
Given the obvious benefits of such programs, espe
has changed-iocreared, stayed the sarre, ordecreased
cially for smaller firms, it is unclear why more joint
over the past three years, a period spanning the year
from employers about how their level of training
programs are not found among them. Is it due sim
prior to the introduction ofHRDF in 1993, to the
ply to the low skill requirements of small firms,
present (1995). We will do this by comparing the
or are there collective failures-no tradition of col
training experiences of two groups of firms: those
laboration among small firms, or absence of em
registered with theHRDF, and those who were eli
ployer associations to represent the collective
gible but did not register. In principle, the regis
interests of small business-which prevent them from
tered group would have increased incentives to train
working together? This issue should be studied by
so as to recover their payroll levy contributions. In
HRDC to determine if incentives alone are suffi
contrast, the non-registered group would not face
cient to encourage joint training.
these same incentives since they do not contribute toHRDF. We recognize that these two groups of
The remaining columns ofTable 4.10 show how ex
firms are different, not only in terms of their mea
isting joint training programs are organized. When
sured characteristics but also in terms of their unob
firms have one, the single most important type of
served (to us) productivity attributes.
joint training program for all firm sizes is through ad hoc arrangements with other firms-the fractions citing this range from 34 percent for small firms to 52 percent for large firms.
Table 4.12 compares the training experiences of these two groups of firms. Of those registered with the HRDF, about 50 percent said that they had increased
ENTERPRISE TRAINING, TECHNOLOGY AND PRODUCTIVITY
60
Table 4.12: Probit Estimates of Increased Training Under HRDF Independent Variable
Combined
Purely
Firms with
Interactions Between Size
Sample of
Domestic
Foreign
Firms
and HRDF Small Firm HRDF
0.160 (0.122)
Medium Firm HRDF
Firms
capital
.141
0.179
(0.151)
(0.215)
0.312"
0.171
0.435•
(0.101)
(0.129)
(0.179)
Large Firm HRDF
0.788"
0.839"
0.753"
(0.102)
(0.147)
(0.175)
Introduced new technology
0.428"
0.499"
0.365"
in last 3 years
(0.076)
(0.103)
(0.114)
Constant
-0.574"
-0.616"
-0.516"
(0.083)
(0.099)
(0.160)
•=
Significant at 1% level
Note:
Industry dummies were included but were not statistically significant.
Source: 1995 MITP Survey
Table 4.13 Changes in Training Levels Over the Past Three Years: Firms Registered with HRDF and Unregistered Firms Registration Status Eligible Registered Firms
Eligible Unregistered Firms
Increased TrainingTraining is the Same
Decreased Training
522
412
12
(49.8)
(39.3)
(1.2)
109 (27.1)
190 (47.3)
21 (5.2)
Note: The percentages do not sum to 100. Close to 10 percent of registered firms and 20 percent of unregistered firms said they did not know. Source: 1995 MITP Survey
training over the last three years , 39 percent firms
creased training over the past three years in regis
said that their training had remained the same, and
tered HRDF firms versus non-registered firms. The
only one percent said that their training had de
effects of HRDF are allowed to vary by firm size
creased. In contrast, of the eligible firms not regis
using a set of interaction terms between firm size
tered with the HRDF, 27 percent said that their
dummies and an indicator variable for being regis
training had increased, 47 percent firms said that
tered with HRDF.
their training had remained unchanged, and five percent said that their training had decreased over
The model includes a set of industry dummy vari
the last three years. Thus, it appears thatHRDFmay have played a role in increasing training provision among registered firms.
ables to control for possible differences in industrycomposition of registered and non-regis tered firms. We include a measure of whether the
firm introduced new technologies over the past three We test this hypothesis formally using a probit
years. The intent was to net out the confounding
model. This model compares the likelihood of in-
effects of increased training due to new technology
TRAINING POLICIES
61
that is independent of HRD F. Finally, separate
sponding increase in demand for training among
models are estimated for pure domestic firms and
such firms.
firms with foreign capital to see if the training ef fects of HRDF varies by foreign ownership. Table 4.13 reports the results of this exercise. They demonstrate that HRDF has had a significant role in increasing training among medium and large firms registered with the HRDF, but not small firms. This result continues to hold for the sample of firms with some foreign capital participation. Among purely domestic firms, HRDF has only been effective in increasing the training of large firms with over 250 employees; the HRDF incentive was not effective in increasing training among small and medium-size local firms. These results were not affected by dif ferences in industrial composition of the two groups, which we control for using industry dummies. However, whether or not firms had introduced new technology in the recent past made a difference. In creases in training and introduction of. new technol ogy over the past three years are significantly correlated, a result consistent with that fmdings in Chapter Two that technological change is accompa nied by higher skill requirements.
Findings and Policy Implications
The DDJI' incentive scheme has generally not proved effective in inducingfirms to train. It has been used primarily by MNCs,joint-ventures,and larger firms who, arguably, were training already. For these firms, the DDIT scheme has meant sizable wind fall gains; for the firms that provided little or no training, the DDIT scheme has failed to induce them to begin, or to increase provision of train ing. Lack of awareness about DDIT, and its re quirements, has been the principal reason for its limited use. A second factor was the heavy re quirements of applying for DDIT, and the corre sponding high rates of rejection, both of which reduced interest in using the incentive. The key lesson for policymakers is that any policy or in centive, whether in training or in other areas, is unlikely to be fully effective if targeted benefi ciaries are unaware of or inadequately familiar ized with the program. Another lesson is that,where feasible, filing requirements should be streamlined to improve take-up of incentives.
The DDJI' incentive is currently restricted to small firms with less than 50 employees; all other firms are covered by HRDF. The Government should eliminate the remaining DDIT coverage entirely
Markets are generally well functioning in Malay
on several grounds. First, it is likely that few
sia, but there is evidence that marketfailures pose
small firms are using the incentive today. Sec
important constraints on trainingfor many employ ers, especially the small and medium-size compa
ond, bringing all firms under the HRDF umbrella greatly simplifies administration, since universal
nies. These include high labor turnover, which
coverage of all firms would searnlessly accommo
prevent employers from recouping investments in
date the growth or shrinkage of firms above or
training; poor information on training methods,
below the 50 employee cutoff. Finally, HRDF is
especipecially how to train or what kinds of training
developing new schemes to support the training
to provide; and inadequate finance for training, es
activities of SMis, and the 50 employee cutoff
pecially among SMis. These market failures justify
would arbitrarily restrict access of small firms to
government intervention. While not a market failure
these programs. The issue of payroll contributions
per se, the use of mature technologies with low skill
for these smaller firms needs to be resolved. The
needs was the principal reason for little or no training
government might consider a waiver of the payroll
both among local firms and SMis. Increased take-up
levy for small firms, and provide HRDF with a block
of incentives to adopt new technology or improve qual
grant from general revenues to cover their use of
ity, such as ITAF schemes, should lead to a corre-
training services.
62
ENTERPRISE TRAINING, TECHNOLOGY AND PRODUCTIVITY
Non-compliance in HRDF appears to be significant.
deadline granted by HRDC, it is likely that the un
The MITP survey indicates that as many as 27 per
derlying problem remains, especially for smaller
cent of eligible firms with 50 or more employees are
firms. About 60 percent of them provide no train
not registered with, and contributing to, the HRDF.
ing or only unstructured, informal, on-the-job train
I t is concentrated among smaller firms, firms in tra
ing that is not eligible for reimbursement under the
ditional and domestic-oriented industries, firms in
HRDF. Some of their constraints-poor knowledge
the states on the east coast and in East Malaysia, and
about training, not having a training plan, or inad
among firms providing little or no structured train
equate training facilities-are being addressed through
ing. While there may be good reasons to downplay
HRDF'sTNA workshops, theJURUPLANscheme
enforcement in the early gestation period, policymak
to develop training plans, and schemes to fund pur
ers will eventually have to make a strong effort to
chase of training aids. Other factors which limit
address the issue of non-compliance. HRDC cur
demand for training, such as use of mature technol
rently has few personnel or legal officers to devote
ogy, are under the purview of other government
to enforcement. The Government should expedi
agencies, and policies to address them are discussed
tiously provide HRDC with the necessary man
in Chapters Five and Six.
power and legal resources to identify and prosecute HRDC has introduced two new schemes-ITS and
eligible but non-registered firms .
GTS-to encourage group trainingfor smaller em The HRDC should also llWUnt an infonnation cam
ployers, either initiated by groups of small firms
paign, on television and in newspapers, to encour
themselves, or organized by employer associations.
age eligiblefirms to register with HRDC. It should
The MITP survey indicates that such joint training
announce its intention to vigorously enforce com
programs between firms are rare in Malaysia. They
pliance with the HRDF Law and, to ensure that this
are commonly found not among SMis, but among
threat is credible, it should publicize its increased
large firms. When they occur, most are ad hoc ar
enforcement capabilities as well as its prosecutions
rangements. Joint training programs organized by
of selected firms . This campaign should be accom
suppliers and by government agencies are more im
panied by a time-limited amnesty program for firms
portant for small fim1s; joint programs organized
to come forward, register with the HRDC, and pay
by specialized companies are cited by many medium
their back levies without civil or criminal penal
and large fimls; industry associations are also cited,
ties. Similar time-limited amnesty programs have
but primarily by large firms. These industry as
been used effectively in several states in the U.S. to
sociations will have the responsibility, under the
improve compliance.
pilot GTS scheme, for organizing training for SMis. These group-oriented approaches are po
As ofyear-end 1994, over one-third of registered
tentially potent policy instruments for fostering
}inns had not claimed any reimbursementsfor train
training among SMis. Variants of both policies
ing through the HRDF. This figure was especially
have been used, with some success, in a number
pronounced for small and medium size firms about
of developing countries (see Chapter Six) and the
,
half of whom did not claim. While claims have risen
progress of these initiatives in Malaysia should
since them, in large part due to an extension of the
be carefully monitored.
CHAPTER FivE: TEcHNOLOGY, QuALITY
AND
SKILLS
Malaysian policymakers have identified low levels
past three years, and its consequences for changing
of technology and product quality as a bottleneck to
skill needs and employment.
sustained growth and competitiveness. They are actively encouraging firms-through fiscal incentives
This wealth of firm-level data, from such a large
and the activities of technology support institutions:
sample of firms, provides an unprecedented oppor tunity to analyze enterprise decisions to invest in
•
to increase firms ' spending on research and de
technology, to examine the quality control efforts of
velopment,
firms, to identify the effects of introducing new tech
•
to accelerate technology transfer from the MNCs
nology on future skill requirements and productiv
to domestic firms, to invest in automated pro
ity, and to draw out their implications for
duction technologies to economize on scarce
policymakers.
labor, •
•
to modernize small and medium-scale industries
(SMis), to adopt quality control systems and raise prod uct quality to meet exacting international stan dards for exports (MID, IMP Review, 1994).
The 1992 National Survey ofResearch and Devel opment provides some information on industrial train
Technological Characteristics of Firms We begin by using the MITP survey to character ize the technology level of firms in Malaysia, then their efforts to improve quality. Employers can develop their technological capabili ties in several different ways. First, they can de
ing in Malaysia. 1 It indicates that overall the research
velop technology in-house through investments in
and development efforts in Malaysia-about 0.37 per
research and development. Since few local enter
cent of GDP-are lower than projected in the 1990
prises have the requisite scientific, engineering and
Action Plan for Industrial Technology Development
technical capabilities to conduct cutting-edgeR&D,
(APITD), while private sectorR&D spending---0.17
much of this expenditure may reflect relatively mod
percent ofGDP-is higher than projected. However,
est engineering and productR&D activities.
the scale of private sector industrial R&D is Malay sia is relatively modest by international standards
Second, when in-house R&D capabilities are lim
(WorldBank, 19%).2 Much ofR&D is concentrated
ited, technology transfer is an alternative way for
in the electrical and electronics industry and among
local firms to acquire new technology, either through
MNCs, and private R&D spending in Malaysia total
licensing and know-how agreements with other
RM 125.4 million spread over just 97 firms.
firms, or through joint-ventures with foreign firms . Finally, firms can acquire new production technol
In this chapter, we use the MITP survey to provide
ogy embodied in new vintages of capital, through
additional insights on the technology level, quality
investments in automatic machinery, computer-as
control systems, and associated skill needs of enter
sisted production, and testing and quality control
prises. The survey elicited detailed firm-level infor
equipment.
mation on R&D expenditures as a percentage of sales; technology and know-how licensing agree
Table 5.1 begins by providing a broad overview of
ments; investments in automation and quality control
the incidence of these technology indicators by four
equipment, as well as the vintage (age) of machin
firm size categories aiXi by ownership--domestic firms,
ery; quality control methods; IS0-9000 certification;
joint-ventures, and wholly foreign-owned firms.
whether new technology was introduced over the
Three broad sets of indicators are considered:
64
ENTERPRISE TRAINING, TECHNOLOGY AND PRODUCTIVITY
•
Research and development -- whether the
most half of this R&D (RM 4.812 million) is concen
firm does R&D, and R&D expenditures as a
trated in the electronics industry.
percentage of sales •
•
Technology transfer -- does the firm have
When these sample estimates are multiplied by the
any technology or know-how licensing agree
population weights, total R&D spending almost
ments, from foreign or domestic sources
doubles--toRM 1,908 million in 1994. Thus, com
Sophistication of machinery and equip
pared to the 1992 R&D survey, the 1994 MITP sur
ment-- percent of equipment that is fully auto
vey finds four times as many firms reporting R&D
matic, whether the firm has quality control or
expendirures, higher per firm R&D spending, and if
testing equipment, and percent of equipment
the weighted estimates are to be believed, almost 15
that is more than 10 years old.
times as much private sector R&D spending as re ported in the 1992 R&D. Some part of this gap is
First, consider the R&D expenditures reported by
undoubtedly due to differences between surveys in
firms in the MITP survey. Out of a sample of2,200
the definition of R&D, and to the two years separat
firms 435 firms or 19.8 percent had positive R&D
ing the surveys. The important point to note is that
expenditures in 1994. Based on reported R&D to
even with this more expansive R&D measure, lev
sales figures, we estimate that these firms spent a
els of private R&D in Malaysian industry are still
total ofRM 1,030 million on research and develop
relatively low in comparison to other Asian NICs
ment, or approximatelyRM 2.4 million per firm. AI-
and industrialized countries.
,
Table 5.1 Technology Characteristics by Firm Size and Ownership Mean Values
Percent of Firms Ownership Type and Firm Size
Do R&D
HaveQC
R&D
Equipment
Automatic
Technology
& Testing
%of
over 10 yrs
equipment
license(s)
Equipment
sales
Have
%
%
Domestic Firms Micro
4.4
1.5
4.4
1.31
39.7
3.1
Small
9.2
2.8
17.1
0.08
34.2
11.6 20.6 27.3
Medium
23.9
5.6
38.4
1.40
25.1
Large
31.4
12.8
50.0
0.38
22.0
Joint-Ventures Small
16.7
10.0
36.7
0.27
28.2
17.4
Medium
23.4
22.5
44.0
0.93
20.9
22.3
Large
38.8
33.8
60.4
1.64
19.3
32.9
100% Foreign Small
15.4
7.7
46.2
0.49
11.4
23.4
Medium
20.7
15.7
47.9
0.43
25.9
Large
26.9
23.1
67.5
2.09
7.2 7.5
Notes:
Micro= less than 16 workers, Small= 16-100 workers,
38.3
Medium= 101-250 workers
Large= over 250 workers. Micro firms not reported for joint-ventures or 100% foreign firms because of small sample sizes. Source: 1995 MITPSurvey
TECHNOLOGY, QUALITY AND SKILLS
65
Table 5.1 shows a striking positive relationship be
Finally, Table 5.1 reveals striking differences in the
tween firm size and the likelihood of R&D. Among
types and vintage of capital equipment by firm size
local firms just over four percent of micro firms re
and ownership. Compared to larger firms, micro,
,
port R&D spending; this figure rises to 24 percent
small and medium size firms are less likely to have
for medium firms and to over30 percent for large
quality control and testing equipment, a smaller frac
finns . A similar size-R&D trend is found amongjoint
tion of their equipment is made up of numerically
ventures and wholly foreign-owned firms. Except
controlled automatic machinery, and a higher frac
for local firms, R&D spending as a ratio of sales gen
tion of their capital equipment is over 10years old.
erally rises with firm size especially among large
Furthermore, for any given finn size, the table shows
firms with foreign capital.
that a progression to more intensive use of testing
A second, intriguing result are the differences by
tages of equipment as the fraction of foreign equity
ownership status. For any givenfirm size, medium
increases in the firm.
equipment, greater automation, and younger vin
and large local firms and joint-ventures are more likely to report R&D spending than wholly foreign
Table 5.2 reports these technology indicators by two
owned firms For example, among large firms with
digit industrial sector. The figures reveal consider
over 1,000employees, over31 and39percent of
able cross-industry variation by foreign equity, by
local firms andjoint-ventures reported R&D spend
capital intensity, and by export orientation. Indus
ing, respectively, as compared to just 27 percent of
tries with high levels of foreign direct investment
wholly foreign-owned finns . Plausibly, the latter firms
(FDI) and joint ventures, such as electrical machin
have few incentives to conduct R&D locally since
ery and chemicals, are more likely to have high pro
.
they can draw on the parent MNC's stock of tech
portions of finns with R&D and technology licenses,
nology and R&D laboratories; these typically are
using quality control and testing equipment in pro
not located in developing economies.
duction. Capital intensive industries with heavy do mestic ownership, such as iron and basic metals and
A similar pattern of technology licenses by firm size
transport equipment, are also relatively technology
and ownership is also apparent. In general, small
intensive. A high proportion of firms in iron and
firms irrespective of their ownership are less likely
basic metals have technology licenses and quality
to report technology licenses than larger firms, re
control equipment, while many finns in the transport
flecting lower levels of technological capabilities in
sector (primarily Proton) report R&D spending. Elec
SMis. Joint ventures are more likely to report tech
trical machinery, along with plastics, rubber and ap
nology licenses than comparably-sized wholly for
parel are also export-oriented industries, and a high
eign firms For example, among small firms, lOpercent
proportion of these firms have quality control and
of joint ventures have technology licenses versus
testing equipment to produce for export markets.
.
eight percent of foreign firms; the differential wid
The remaining industries -- food products, bever
ens among large firms with34 percent of joint ven
ages and tobacco, textiles and apparel, and general
,
tures and 27 percent of foreign firms reporting
machinery -- generally show low overall levels of
technology licenses.
the technology indicators.
This pattern of licensing by ownership status may
Quality Control and Precision in
reflect a conscious strategy by MNCs to recover the
Production
costs of developing new technologies from its joint
To become competitive in world markets, Malaysian
ventures. This incentive to license its technology is
firms will need to produce more and better products
diminished when the enterprise in question is a
that meet international standards for price and qual
wholly-owned subsidiary.
ity. It is not adequate merely to introduce new tech-
ENTERPRISE TRAINING, TECHNOLOGY AND PRODUCTIVITY
66
Table 5.2 Technology Characteristics by Industry Percent of Firms Industrial Sector
R&D
Mean Values
Have
HaveQC
R&D
Equipment
Automatic
Technology
& Testing
%of
over10
equipment
equipment
sales
years%
Do
license(s)
%
Food
3.7
1.2
7.9
0.99
19.2
7.0
Beverages & tobacco
1.9
0.3
2.3
0.09
46.3
2.2
Textiles
5.3
0.6
10.2
0.15
12.5
5.9
Apparel
8.1
0.5
11.2
0.51
23.2
4.8
Wood & furniture
4.6
1.4
5.6
0.74
20.3
3.6
Paper & Publishing
4.8
0.7
6.5
0.45
66.9
10.0
Chemicals
30.4
27.0
42.4
1.11
23.1
6.5
Rubber
11.8
5.1
33.0
0.79
29.6
16.0
Plastics Glass & Pottery Iron & Basic Metals Fabricated Metals Machinery
8.3
11.4
14.4
0.08
15.2
16.5
11.1
4.8
17.7
0.30
28.2
7.5
3.8
59.5
66.3
0.02
56.4
5.1
11.6
3.3
19.4
0.90
18.7
5.7
3.7
3.4
18.7
0.80
51.4
6.3
Electrical Machinery
18.9
11.8
76.1
3.23
19.6
27.1
Transport
50.7
2.9
11.9
1.24
82.7
2.2
Other
52.8
2.5
3 .0
0.77
11.3
2.5
Source: 1995 MITP Survey
nologies to reduce production costs. Enterprises will
process control, quality control circles and precision
also need to introduce new fonns of work organiza
testing instruments in production, and only 16 per
tion that emphasize product quality, precision in
cent rely on visual inspection to verify accuracy in
production, consistency of quality, and continuous
production. These figures stand in sharp contrast to
quality improvement. Such organizational features
those for SMis. Less than a quarter of micro and
include the introduction of quality control circles
small firms report using either statistical process con
(QCC), the use of statistical process control (SPC),
trol or quality control circles. Less than one-fifth of
and reliance on quality control and testing equip
them use precision measuring equipment to verify
ment rather than visual inspection to meet the high
accuracy in production; in fact, 64 percent of micro
levels of quality demanded by increasing sophisti
finns and 43 percent of small finns rely exclusively
cated users and consumers.
on visual inspection to verify accuracy. This sharp size differential in quality highlights an area of pri
Table 5.3 reports the incidence, by firm size and
ority for policymakers. There is a clear need for
ownership, of several variables that reflect firms' em
policies to instill quality consciousness among SMis
phasis on product and process quality:
through information dissemination, subsidized QC training, and incentives to use precision measuring
•
whether it relies on statistical process control
•
whether it has quality control circles
•
how it verifies accuracy in production
•
whether it provides training in quality control.
and testing equipment. Second, local finns are less likely than joint ventures and wholly foreign-owned firms to have a quality control system. Between 20 and 25 percent of local
First, firm size is an important determinant of whether
firms use SPC or QCC techniques, and about five
an enterprise has a quality control system in place.
percent provide QC training. The comparable fig
Among large finns , about 50 percent use statistical
ures for joint ventures are 31-46 percent for use of
TECHNOLOGY, QUALITY AND SKILLS
67
Table 5.3 Quality Control and Precision in Production Quality Control System Firm Size and
Statistical Quality
Ownership Type
Process Control
Control Circles
Verifying Accuracy in Production
Quality
Precision
Control
Measuring
Measuring
Training
Equipment
Devices
Simple
Visual Inspection
Firm Size
8.1
4.1
1.6
8.1
23.7
63.8
Small
16.5
25.1
4.7
19.9
31.6
42.8
Medium
30.8
41.7
9.2
34.8
29.9
26.4
Large
49.6
53.5
13.7
52.9
24.5
16.3
Micro
Ownership
20.0
25. 4
5.5
20. 5
30.0
42.9
Joint-Ventures
31.5
46.0
9.9
43.0
28.9
22.3
1 00% Foreign
44.7
47.9
12.3
49.2
25.6
19.4
Domestic
Source: 1995 MITP Survey
these QC techniques and 10 percent of Ns provide
control training variable was constructed from in
QC training. The incidence of QC and QC training
formation provided by employers on the main types
is highest among wholly foreign-owned firms
of training provided to different occupational
.
groups-technicians, supervisors, skilled production While part of this result reflects differences in size
workers and unskilled production workers. A firm
composition by ownership, it is also consistent with
was coded as providing QC training if any one of
the notion that the use of new technology requires
these four occupational groups reported QC training
new fonns of work organization and quality control.
as being the most important training type provided. 3
Are local firms less likely to have quality control systems than joint ventures or foreign firms, once
It very likely understates the incidence of quality
account is taken of size? The answer appears to
control training, since it excludes QC training from
be yes.
external sources and QC training that was a second
Figure 5 .1 graphically shows the incidence of these
provided QC training to one or more occupational
quality control indicators by firm size and foreign
groups. Not surprising, the industries with high pro
ownership. The vertical bars represent the percent
portions of finns providing training in quality con
ary area of training. By this defmition, 160 firms
of local firms, joint ventures (Ns), and wholly for
trol-electrical machinery, plastics and chemicals-were
eign owned firms reporting each QC indicator. The
also the industries where QC methods are common.
four panels clearly show that controlling for firm size, a higher proportion of joint ventures and wholly for
To summarize , the MITP data show that the scope of
eign firms use statistical process control, quality con
private R&D in Malaysia is relatively low by interna
trol circles and precision measuring instruments to
tional standards. Furthermore, there are large dif
verify accuracy in production as compared with do
ferences in technological capabilities-as measured
mestic firms. Across all size categories, a much higher
by R&D, technology licensing, sophistication of ma
proportion of domestic firms rely on visual inspec
chinery, and quality control systems-between local
tion to verify accuracy in production as compared
and foreign-owned firms, and between SMis and
with foreign firms.
large finns. These size and ownership differences in technological capabilities mirror those involving
Finally, the table confinns that the introduction of
training, which is not surprising, given the strong
quality control systems increases the requirement for
linkages between training and technology revealed
training in quality control techniques. This quality
by the analyses in previous chapters.
ENTERPRISE TRAINING, TECHNOLOGY AND PRODUCTIVITY
68
Figure 5.1 Quality Control Systems by Firm Size and Ownership
A. Statistical Process Control
B. Quality Control Circles
70 60
50
50
40
40
30
30
20
20
10
10
0 +-"""'"'---+ro E
70
60
60
50
50
40
40
30
30
20
20
10
10
u
.E
12' .!!!
E
D. Visual Inspection Only
70
0 +-'-----t-
QJ
::J
�
Ul
C. Precision Measuring Equipmt.
e
E
ro E
Ul
�------....,
0 ro E Ul
E
::J 15 QJ
E
QJ
1111 Local
If finns with weak technological capabilities are also
E ::J 15 QJ E
ro E Ul
12'
.!!!
0
QJ
12' .!!!
Foreign
First, the overwhelming demand from firms is for
the same ones with weak training capabilities, it im
diffusion services for known technologies rather
plies that policies should be designed to address both
than support to develop wholly new technologies.
sets of finn-level weaknesses and constraints since
For Malaysia, this means focusing support on tech
the target population is the same. A recent study of
nology transfer, licensing agreements, dissemi
technology-support institutions in six countries sug
nation of information, standards and testing, and
gests some broad directions for the design of tech
skills training rather then public R&D or R&D
nology policies to address these firm size and
ince n t i v e s f o r f i r m s .
ownership differences in capabilities (see Box 5 .1).
prioritization o f technology diffusion, rather than
Su p p o r t f o r t h e
TECHNOLOGY, QUALITY AND SKILLS
69
Box 5.1 Use of External Sources of Technical Support by Firms A recent World Bank study looked at six economies--Japan, Korea, China, India, Mexico and Taiwan--to examine the key characteristics of technology support institutions (Tis) and their use by industrial firms (Goldman, 1 995). Tis were broadly defined to include all public and private sources of technology and training support used by firms, including (i) national technology and standards institutes, industry associations, and productivity cen ters; (ii) private sources such as foreign technology licensors and contract laboratories; and (iii) technical assistance from suppliers and buyers.
Over two thousand firms were
interviewed, including both small and large firms and covering six sectors. Several of the principal findings and conclusions are summarized below. The overwhelming demand by firms, both large and small, is for services related to technology diffusion, i.e. the transfer and application of known technology.
Firms most
commonly use basic services related to acquisition of information, standards and test ing, trouble shooting, and technology-related training. And when firms use R&D services of public Tis, they tend to contract for answers to specific technology questions, rather than for development of new technologies. While larger firms tend to use Tis more intensively than smaller firms, use is also shaped by whether firms have in-house laboratories or technical departments. This is especially pronounced among small firms, where those with in-house resources use Tis at nearly twice the rate of other small firms. This highlights the difficulty of reaching and serving small firms, particularly those without internal technological capabilities. Large firms are also three times more likely than the overall sample to have received grants, tax incen tives or soft loans for technology; only assistance directed at technology diffusion--such as help in developing standards, or subsidies for training--seem to be taken up by small as well as by larger firms. A high proportion of firms reported using a public Tl at least once, though long-term customers, followed by suppliers, were the most commonly used external sources of technology.
The survey found that small firms require special Tis dedicated to them;
otherwise, they obtain little or no support. Tis focusing on small firms need to work proactively to expose them to the benefits of change if demand is to be generated for technology improvement and assistance. The Japanese approach--support directed at industry clusters in a region and focusing on technology diffusion--is quite effective in reaching a large number of small firms. The Taiwanese approach--productivity centers which develop generic expertise with applicability to small firms in a wide range of indus tries--is also effective, but reaches a lower fraction of the target population.
development, was provided in Chapter Three
ized support institutions working actively to de
which showed licensing to have greater produc
liver technology support services to hard-to-reach
tivity effects than R&D.
SMis, especially those with limited in-house ca pabilities, to expose them to the benefits of change
Second, larger firms use support services more in
and create demand for technology improvement
tensively, and their take-up of technology incen
and assistance. For Malaysia, this means restruc
tives is more common, than smaller firms. SMis
turing the way public institutions deliver support
have special needs, and these are seldom met by
to firms, SMis in particular-from one that relies
broad-based institutions. They require special-
on firms to take-up incentives, to one in which
70
ENTERPRISE TRAINING, TECHNOLOGY AND PRODUCTIVITY
technology support services are delivered
systems and the structured training programs needed
proactively to firms. These policies are discussed
to attain those standards.4 The Brazilian experience
in greater length in Chapter Six.
indicates that adoption ofiS0-9000 certification and total quality management standards (TQM) in pro
150-9000 and Quality Assurance It is increasingly recognized that standards and me
duction has led to productivity and quality gains (see Box 5.2). IS0-9000 certification also provides a strong signal to clients that a firm is prepared to
trology can be an important policy instrument for
attain and maintain high and exacting quality stan
improving and diffusing modem production meth
dards (Frischtak, 1995). As such, it has become the
ods and quality control systems (Dahlman, 1992), and
prerequisite for doing business in many sectors of
upgrading product quality to meet the exacting in
the European Community (EC) and, increasingly,
ternational standards for export markets. One such
is being extended to the East Asian Trade area around
voluntary standard, the IS0-9000 series introduced
Japan.
in 1987 by the International Standards Organization, represents the international consensus on how best
The MITP survey provides insights into the adop
to operate and assess quality management systems.
tion of IS0-9000 standards in Malaysia. There is
The publication of IS0-9000 standards provides
Malaysian firms. The Standards and Industrial Re
growing interest in implementing IS0-9000 among firms with a benchmark of what constitutes best
search Institute of Malaysia (SIRIM), which is re
practice in their specific area, and thus incentives to
sponsible for metrology and standards, is the
put in place both the quality control and assurance
registration body for IS0-9000. It has awarded 700
Box 5.2 Diffusion and Impact of IS0-9000 in Brazil Many observers attribute the recent productivity and quality gains in Brazilian industry to producers' commitment to total quality management (TQM) and adherence to international quality standards of the International Standards Organization (ISO) 9000 series.
The diffusion of IS0-9000 among in
dustrial firms has been rapid--between 1990 and 1994, the number of certified firms increased from 18 to 577, an average annual growth rate of 138 percent. The industries with the greatest number of certified firms are electrical equipment and instruments, chemicals, basic metals and fabricated products, and general machinery.
A number of factors were responsible for the rapid diffusion of TQM and IS0-9000 certification- industrial restructuring during the 1990-92 recession, major trade reforms beginning in 1990, and growing awareness of the increasing importance of quality control to meet client needs, reduce costs, and improve competitiveness viz. a viz. international producers. The Government has played an active diffusion role through the Brazilian Program for Quality and Productivity (PBQP). The PBQP provides (1) analysis of the market environment, (2) assessments of systemic and internal con straints to competitive behavior and the diffusion of TQM (3) establishment of sectoral and global benchmarks in terms of productivity and quality indicators, (4) dissemination of information on TQM and provision of TQM training, and (5) subsidizing adoption of TQM practices.
A recent survey of 93 major Brazilian enterprises indicates that adoption of new managerial methods for quality control, IS0-9000 certification in particular, has had beneficial effects on the firm--55 percent cited increases in productivity, 35 percent improved standardization of processes, 31 per cent increased employee participation in quality control, 25 percent in product quality improvement, and over 20 percent cited increases in client satisfaction (Frischtak, 1995).
TECHNOLOGY, QUALITY AND SKILLS
71
Table 5.4 IS0-9000 Status and Quality Control Systems Systems of Quality Control and Verification of Accuracy
With IS0-9000
Seeking IS0-9000
Certification
Certification
No IS0-9000 plans
Firms
%
Firms
%
Firms
%
229
10.4
731
33.2
1,240
56.4
Statistical Process Control
130
56.8
268
36.7
171
13.8
Quality Control Circles
123
53.7
329
45.0
268
21.6
141
61.6
299
41.0
198
16.0
47
20.5
216
29.6
370
29.9
22
9.6
154
21.1
609
49.1
Total Sample of Firms Quality Control System
Verifying Accuracy in Production Precision Instruments Simple measuring devices Visual Inspection Source: 1995 MITP Survey
foreign and local finns with some level ofiS0-9000
and implemented systems of quality control and
certification, and is reportedly in the process of as
quality assurance. A much higher proportion of
sessing another 600 firms.
IS0-9000 certified firms use QCC and SPC to en sure quality in production and precision instruments
The survey elicited information from firms about
to ensure accuracy in production, followed by finns
whether they had any IS0-9000 series certification,
seeking certification within the next three years.
and if they did not, whether they expected to gain
Firms with no plans for IS0-9000 certification are
IS0-9000 certification within the next three years.
much less likely to report use of QCC or SPC, and
This second question was designed to identify finns
are significantly more likely to rely on visual in
that were preparing for certification, a process that
spection to verify accuracy in production.
can take as long as three years. Firms that did not currently have IS0-9000 certification, or were not
Table 5.5 reports the distribution ofiS0-9000 sta
expecting it within three years, were classified as
tus by firm size and ownership. It indicates that
having no plans for IS0-9000 certification.
while the number of IS0-9000 certified firms is small, interest is growing. Currently, over 30 per
Table 5.4 reports the number of firms with IS0-
cent of large finns are certified, but the proportion
9000 certification, those seeking certification and
of micro, small and medium firms with IS0-9000
those without certification. Out of 2,200 firms in
certification is relatively low-less than one percent
the MITP survey, 229 firms (10.4 percent) had
among micro firms four percent among small firms
IS0-9000 certification; 731 firms (33.2 percent) ex
and eight percent among medium-size firms. The
,
,
pected IS0-9000 certification within the next three
trend in the number of firms expecting certification
years, and 1,240 firms (56.4 percent) did not have
is more optimistic, with 27 percent of small firms
certification and did not have any plans to become
and 48 percent of medium firms expecting IS0-9000
certified. Industries with the highest fraction of firms
certification within the next three years. This trend
with IS0-9000 included the most technology-inten
implies that within three years, over three-quarters
sive industries such as electrical machinery and
of large firms will have IS0-9000 certification.
chemicals as well as the export-oriented industries such as rubber and plastics.
Nonetheless, the total coverage ofiS0-9000 among micro firms will still be below seven percent at the
The bottom panel of Table 5.4 show the distribu
lowest end of the size spectrum. This highlights a
tion of quality control systems by firms' IS0-9000
potentially important area of focus for Malaysian
status. IS0-9000 certifies firms to have documented
policymakers. Another important area of policy fo-
72
ENTERPRISE TRAINING, TECHNOLOGY AND PRODUCTIVITY
Table 5.5 150-9000 by Firm Size and Ownership Firm Size and Ownership Type
%Firms With
%Firms Seeking
%Firms With No
IS0-9000
IS0-9000
IS0-9000
Certification
Certification
Plans
Firm Size Micro
0.8
6.5
92.7
Small
4.2
26.9
68.9
8.2
48.2
43.5
31.3
43.6
25.1
Medium Large Ownership Type
5.6
29.6
64.8
Joint-Ventures
14.3
43.9
41.8
100%Foreign
27.8
35.3
36.9
Domestic
Source: 1995 MITP Survey
cus should be local firms. Compared to joint ven tures (14 percent) and foreign-owned firms (28 per cent), only about five percent of local fums currently haveIS0-9000 certification. H owever, this appears to be changing. A growing number of local fmns appear to realize the importance of total quality man agement and quality standards for improving com petitiveness and meeting the increasingly high standards demanded in international markets--thirty percent of them expect to get IS0-9000 certification within the next three years.
IS0-9000. According toSIRIM, the SMI section has provided QIP consultancies to a cumulative to tal of 162SMis by the end of 1995.
SIRIM can play a greater role in disseminating international best practices in production and qual ity control to employers and, through their adop tion of IS0-9000 standards, improve the competitiveness of local firms. The recent corporatization ofSIRIM in 1996, and the reorga nization of the institution that is now in progress, should allow it to respond more flexibly to the dramatic growth in private sector demand forIS09000 certification. 5
QIPs developedjointly bySIRIM and leadingMNCs in specific sub-sectors, are a potentially powerful policy instrument for assisting groups ofSMis to upgrade their quality and to foster increased link ages withMNCs and other larger firms. For many MNCs, a major obstacle to developing supplier rela tions with localSMis is the low and uneven quality of their products(Fong, 1991).SMis may notknow what quality standards are required to become part sup pliers, so that few are willing to invest the necessary resources to upgrade quality practices on the chance ofbecoming a subcontractor. To the extent that QIPs can establish clear, and certifiable, quality standards acceptable to leading firms in a given sub-sector, they provide tangible incentives not only forSMis to improve and upgrade their quality control prac tices, but also forMNCs and other larger employers to accept QIP-certified SMis as part suppliers.
Not all firms,SMis in particular, can afford the high cost and time required (about three years on aver age) to meet IS0-9000 standards.SIRIM can play an expanded role in helpingSMis to improve quality control by building on its existing, but thus far lim ited, consultancies on Quality I mprovement Prac tices (QIP), which are less expensive to attain than
S ub-sectoral QIPs, when developed, are amenable to group provision of assistance toSMis in terms of consultancies, training, finance, as well as technical assistance from leading firms in the industry. SIRIM should pursue this program in collaboration with other goveriUIY;!nt agencies-such as the National Productivity Corporation (NPC), HRDC, and
TECHNOLOGY, QUALITY AND SKILLS
MID's SMI agency-and with leading private sector
73
countries, Australia, and New Zealand. All other countries, primarily those in ASEAN and the
finns.
Middle East, are included in the developing mar ket category.
150-9000 and Export Orientation Table 5. 6 shows the proportion of firms exporting There is considerable anecdotal evidence linking
to different markets by their I S0-9000 status.
quality certification to producers' efforts to penetrate
They suggest two points. First, among firms with
developed markets in the US, the EEC, and Japan
out plans for IS0-9000 certification, a lower pro
(see Frischtak, 1995). In Malaysia, we also observe a
portion export to industrialized markets (20
strong correlation between IS0-9000 certification
percent) as compared to developing country mar
and the export status of firms. About 82 percent of
kets (24 percent). Second, firms with IS0-9000,
IS0-9000 certified firms currently export, while
or in the process of certification, are more likely
export-orientation is 69 percent among firms seek
to export to industrialized country markets-47 and
ing certification within the next three years, and
36 percent, respectively-than to developing coun
just 44 percent among those without certification
try markets, where the corresponding fractions
and not planning to do so in the near future. While
of exporting firms is 36 and 33 percent. The third
it is difficult to establish a causal relationship be
column, which is conditioned on exporting, rein
t ween getting IS0-9000 certification and in
forces these points, namely, that the relative impor
creased exports, these figures suggest that the
tance of exports to industrialized markets increases
firms which already have IS0-9000 certification
with firms' efforts to get IS0-9000 certification.
.•
or those in the process of being certified, are bet Figure 5. 2 shows the proportion of firms exporting
ter able to compete in export markets.
to each market type in each of 16 industries where Exporting is clearly not precluded for firms without
industries are sorted in ascending order (from left to
certification. However, it may be more difficult with
right) by the share of firms with IS0-9000 certifica
out IS0-9000 certification to break into industrial
tion. The percentage share of certified firms in each
ized country markets, where quality requirements
industry is represented by the heights of bars. The
tend to be higher, than it is to export to developing
dark shaded area shows the percent of firms export
countries. To determine ifiS0-9000 certification
ing to industrialized country markets, the light shaded
makes a difference, we distinguished between in
area the corresponding figure for exports to devel
dustrialized country markets and developing
oping country markets.
country markets on the basis of firms reported
primary export market. The industrialized mar
In all industries, a higher proportion of firms ex
kets include the United States, Japan, the EEC
port to developing country markets than to indus trialized markets, as is evident by the light shaded
Table 5.6 IS0-9000 and Export Orientation
% Firms that Export IS0-9000 Status
To
To
Exporting Firms % exporting to
industrialized
developing
industrialized
countries
countries
countries
No certification plans
20.3
23.5
46.6
Seeking IS0-9000 certification
36.0
33.3
51.8
With IS0-9000 certification
46.5
36.0
56.3
Source: 1995 MITP Survey
74
ENTERPRISE TRAINING, TECHNOLOGY AND PRODUCTIVITY
Figure 5.2
150-9000 and
Exports
90 80 70 60 50 40 30
1
20 1 o 0
-e "'
(l_
(l_