EBL
Competitive Electricity Markets: Design, Implementation, Performance
EBL
EBL
This page intentionally left blank
Competitive Electricity Markets: Design, Implementation, Performance Edited by Fereidoon P. Sioshansi Menlo Energy Economics 1925 Nero CT Walnut Creek, CA
EBL
AMSTERDAM • BOSTON • HEIDELBERG • LONDON • NEW YORK • OXFORD PARIS • SAN DIEGO • SAN FRANCISCO • SINGAPORE • SYDNEY • TOKYO
Elsevier The Boulevard, Langford Lane, Kidlington, Oxford OX5 1GB, UK Radarweg 29, PO Box 211, 1000 AE Amsterdam, The Netherlands First edition 2008 Copyright © 2008 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system or transmitted in any form or by any means electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording or otherwise without the prior written permission of the publisher Permissions may be sought directly from Elsevier’s Science & Technology Rights Department in Oxford, UK: phone (+44) (0) 1865 843830; fax (+44) (0) 1865 853333; email:
[email protected]. Alternatively you can submit your request online by visiting the Elsevier web site at http://elsevier.com/locate/permissions, and selecting Obtaining permission to use Elsevier material Notice No responsibility is assumed by the publisher for any injury and/or damage to persons or property as a matter of products liability, negligence or otherwise, or from any use or operation of any methods, products, instructions or ideas contained in the material herein. British Library Cataloguing in Publication Data A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data A catalog record for this book is available from the Library of Congress
EBL
ISBN: 978-0-08-047172-3
For information on all Elsevier publications visit our website at books.elsevier.com Printed and bound in Great Britain 08
09
10
11
12
10
9
8
7
6
5
4
3 2
1
Working together to grow libraries in developing countries www.elsevier.com | www.bookaid.org | www.sabre.org
Contents Contributors
vii
Foreword: Liberalization and Regulation in Electricity Systems – How can We get the Balance Right? Michael Pollitt Preface: Competition and Long-Term Dimensions of Electricity Supply Wolfgang Pfaffenberger Introduction: Electricity Market Reform – Progress and Remaining Challenges Fereidoon P. Sioshansi
2.
3.
xxxv
1
25
PART I: Market Reform Evolution 1.
xvii
Reevaluation of Vertical Integration and Unbundling in Restructured Electricity Markets Hung-Po Chao, Shmuel Oren, and Robert Wilson
EBL
Hybrid Electricity Markets: The Problem of Explaining Different Patterns of Restructuring A.F. Correljé and L.J. De Vries Achieving Electricity Market Integration in Europe Nigel Cornwall
PART II: Market Performance, Monitoring and Demand Participation 4.
Transmission Markets, Congestion Management, and Investment Harry Singh
5.
The Design of US Wholesale Energy and Ancillary Service Auction Markets: Theory and Practice Udi Helman, Benjamin F. Hobbs, and Richard P. O’Neill
27
65
95
139 141
179
6.
The Cost of Anarchy in Self-Commitment-Based Electricity Markets Ramteen Sioshansi, Shmuel Oren, and Richard O’Neill
245
7.
Market Power and Market Monitoring Parviz Adib and David Hurlbut
267
8.
Demand Participation in Restructured Markets Jay Zarnikau
297 v
Contents
vi
PART III: Capacity, Resource Adequacy and Investment 9.
325
Resource Adequacy: Alternate Perspectives and Divergent Paths Parviz Adib, Eric Schubert, and Shmuel Oren
327
10.
The Evolution of PJM’s Capacity Market Joseph E. Bowring
363
11.
Resource Adequacy and Efficient Infrastructure Investment Alan Moran and Ben Skinner
387
417
PART IV: Market Design Issues 12.
Promoting Electricity from Renewable Energy Sources – Lessons Learned from the EU, United States, and Japan Reinhard Haas, Niels I. Meyer, Anne Held, Dominique Finon, Arturo Lorenzoni, Ryan Wiser, and Ken-Ichiro Nishio
419
13.
Distributed Generation and the Regulation of Electricity Networks Dierk Bauknecht and Gert Brunekreeft
14.
Global Climate Change and the Electric Power Industry Andrew Ford
499
15.
Reform of the Reforms in Brazil: Problems and Solutions João Lizardo R. Hermes de Araújo, Agnes Maria de Aragão da Costa, Tiago Correia, and Elbia Melo
543
Index
573
EBL
469
Contributors
Parviz ADIB recently joined Automated Power Exchange (APX, Inc.) as a Director to enhance APX’s activities with regard to power and environmental markets. Previously, he was Director of Wholesale Market Oversight at the Public Utility Commission of Texas (PUCT) where he was engaged in designing competitive electricity market rules, providing policy recommendations to the Commission, and supervising wholesale market monitoring and enforcement functions. Prior to joining the Commission, he taught graduate and undergraduate courses at the University of Texas at Austin. He and two other Commission staff members were the recipient of the Center for the Advancement of Energy Markets’ Unsung Heroes Award for their leadership as a civil servant, which recognized them for making a significant difference in gas and electric competition in 2005. Dr Adib’s main research interests include energy and public policy, efficient operation of restructured electricity markets, and effective market monitoring and enforcement mechanism. He has published book chapters and papers and prepared numerous presentations and policy recommendations on these topics, notably covering Restructured Electricity Markets. Dr Adib completed his BA and MS studies in Economics at the Tehran University and holds a PhD in Economics from the University of Texas at Austin.
EBL
João Lizardo R. Hermes DE ARAÚJO is Director-General of the Centre for Electric Energy Research (CEPEL), a non-profit research center mostly funded by the Eletrobrás Group, under leave from the Federal University of Rio de Janeiro (UFRJ) where he is full professor. Former appointments include Research Director at the Institute of Economics of UFRJ (IE/UFRJ), head of the Energy Group at IE/UFRJ, head of the Graduate Programme on Energy Planning at the Co-ordination of Graduate Programmes in Engineering at UFRJ (COPPE/UFRJ), head of the Systems and Computer Science Programme at COPPE/UFRJ. He has been a visitor at SPRU, LBL, IEJE (Grenoble), and Imperial College. Professor Araújo’s main research interests include infrastructure regulation, particularly electricity market reform, energy policy, technology innovation and diffusion, energyefficient technologies; he has also worked on energy modeling and scenario-building, heuristic programming, and stochastic processes. Professor Araújo has numerous reports and publications on Brazilian energy policy and reform, including several books including the preceding book to this volume on Electricity Market Reform (2006). He has edited a UNESCO book on Energy Planning Methods (1984), and published in Energy Policy and Technological Forecasting and Social Change, among others. He is a senior researcher and referee for the Brazilian National Research Council, and referees several Brazilian scientific Journals. Dierk BAUKNECHT is a research fellow at the Oeko-Institut’s Energy and Climate Group in Germany. He is also a member of the research group Transformation and Innovations in Power Systems (TIPS), funded by the German Federal Research Department, and a PhD student with the Sussex Energy Group at the University of Sussex, UK. Before joining the institute he was modeling manager with a UK-based power market consultancy, vii
viii
Contributors
providing electricity wholesale price and generation models, forecasts, and market analysis for Europe’s liberalizing electricity markets. He works on power plant investment models, network regulation, decentralized power generation, innovation research, and transformation of energy systems. One of his main research questions is how decentralized generation can be integrated into networks and markets. He graduated in political science at the Free University of Berlin and holds an MSc in Science and Technology Policy from SPRU at the University of Sussex, UK. Joseph E. BOWRING is the Market Monitor for PJM, where he is responsible for all aspects of market monitoring. He is the principal author of the annual MMU State of the Market Report and regularly files reports on market issues with the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC). Prior to joining PJM, he worked as an independent consulting economist, with an emphasis on restructuring issues in the electric and gas industries. He worked as the Chief Economist for the New Jersey Department of the Public Advocate’s Division of Rate Counsel, as an economist with the New Jersey Board of Public Utilities, and as an economist at the US Department of Energy, Energy Information Administration. He taught economics as a member of the faculty at Villanova University and at Bucknell University. He received his PhD and MA degrees in Economics from the University of Massachusetts. Gert BRUNEKREEFT is Professor of Energy Economics at Jacobs University Bremen in Germany and Director of the Bremer Energie Institut. Before joining Jacobs University, he was Senior Economist for the energy company EnBW AG and held research positions in applied economics at Tilburg University, the University of Cambridge, and Freiburg University. He is Associate Researcher to a number of research centers and is Associate Editor for the Competition and Regulation in Network Industries. Professor Brunekreeft’s main research interests are in industrial economics, regulation theory, and competition policy of network industries, especially electricity and gas markets. Current issues concern the economics of vertical unbundling and the relation between regulation and investment. He is the author of several books and has published widely in academic journals, including Journal of Regulatory Economics, Utilities Policy, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, and Energy Journal. He holds a degree in economics from the University of Groningen and a PhD from Freiburg University, both in economics.
EBL
Hung-Po CHAO is Director, Market Monitoring at ISO New England. Before joining ISO New England in 2005, Dr Chao was with Electric Power Research Institute (EPRI) and a Consulting Professor at Stanford University. Dr Chao’s research interest includes economic analysis of market organizations, pricing and incentive mechanisms, risk management, energy and environmental analyses, and electricity market restructuring. He was a recipient of the Franz Edelman Management Science Achievement Award from INFORMS in 1988. He has written numerous papers on aspects of electricity markets and published widely in academic journals including Journal of Regulatory Economics, Operations Research, and American Economic Review. He is a co-author/editor of a book Designing Competitive Electricity Markets, by Kluwer Academic Publishing, in 1998.
Contributors
ix
Dr Chao holds a PhD in Operations Research and Economics (minor) from Stanford University. Nigel CORNWALL is Founder and President of Cornwall Energy Associates, a consulting and publishing business. He has extensive experience of electricity sector restructuring in the United Kingdom and internationally in both the public and private sectors. Prior to his return to the United Kingdom in the late 1990s he spent several years in Australia and New Zealand working in energy sector reform and abroad as a freelance consultant working in a range of emerging and developed markets. His current work is focused on the British market and retail market competition, and he was one of the main negotiators for suppliers during the development process of NETA. He has worked with a broad range of clients in the United Kingdom, especially regulators and smaller participants. He specializes in issues connected with market design, including the role of transmission and system operations in deregulated markets and the associated legal, regulatory, commercial, and governance framework. He has a BA in modern history from Pembroke College, Oxford, and an MSc in politics and administration from Birkbeck College, London. Tiago DE BARROS CORREIA is Senior Economist at the Brazilian Ministry of Mines and Energy, and specializes in energy trade and auction theory. His professional experience also includes working at the Interdisciplinary Nucleus for Energy Planning – NIPE of the State University of Campinas – Unicamp. His main research interests include electricity market reform and liberalization, demand and price forecasting, integrated resource planning, and energy auctions. He completed his BA studies in Economics and his MS studies in Energy Planning, both at the State University of Campinas (Unicamp).
EBL
Aad F. CORRELJÉ is an associate professor at the Economics of Infrastructures section of the Faculty Technology, Policy and Management at the TU Delft in the Netherlands. He is a research fellow with the Clingendael International Energy Programme (CIEP) of the Netherlands Institute for International Affairs, a member of the Editorial Board of Energy Policy, and an instructor at the Florence School of Regulation. Dr Correljé has been involved in academic research and teaching and in consulting and advising on many energy- and water-related issues, including the political economy of gas and power market developments, drinking water supply and sanitation, geopolitics of energy, sustainability policy, market design and regulatory issues, and flooding protection policy. He has written a major study on the history of natural gas in the Netherlands and has contributed to the European Commission on energy supply security. After a Masters in International Relations, he received his PhD from the Centre for International Energy Studies (EURICES) of the Erasmus University in Rotterdam in 1994. Agnes Maria DE ARAGÃO DA COSTA is Senior Economist at the Brazilian Ministry of Mines and Energy, and specializes in economics of the energy and mining sectors. Her professional experience also includes working at a Brazilian bank with project finance in the energy sector. Her main research interests comprise electricity market reform and liberalization, environmental and energy policy, demand and price forecasting, integrated resource planning, financing of energy projects in developing countries, and private sector development. She graduated in Economics at the Federal University of Rio de Janeiro (UFRJ) and completed her MS studies in Energy Economics at the University of São Paulo (USP).
x
Contributors
Laurens J. DE VRIES is an assistant professor at the Faculty of Technology, Policy and Management of Delft University of Technology. He researches and teaches about market design and policy issues in the electricity and gas markets. His research focuses primarily on generation adequacy and capacity mechanisms, but has been expanding to include the process of market design, the structuring of incentives for network expansion, and retail consumer behavior. Dr De Vries studied Mechanical Engineering at Delft University of Technology, received a Master of Environmental Studies Degree from the Evergreen State College (Olympia, Washington State, USA) and a PhD from Delft University of Technology. Dominique FINON is Senior Fellow in Economics at CNRS, France. Former head of the Institute of Energy Economics (CNRS) in Grenoble University from 1990 to 2002, he is presently member of the Center of Research on Environment and Development, CIRED, of the School of Social Sciences (EHESS) in Paris, and Director of the LARSEN (Laboratoire d’Analyse économique des Réseaux et Systèmes Energétiques), a joint institute of CNRS, EdF, and Paris University. His main research fields are the efficiency of the market reforms in the electricity and gas industries (market rules, long-term competition and investment, reliability and capacity adequacy) and the design of public policies in market environment (promotion of renewables, energy efficiency, CO2 ). His former researches dealt with technological policies, nuclear economics, and energy modeling. He has published numerous academic and professional papers and co-edited several books. He is the present chair of the French Association of Energy Economists. Dr Finon has a diploma of Engineering from Ecole Centrale de Lyon (1971) and a master in Economics from Lyon University (1971). He has a PhD. in Energy Economics from the Grenoble University (1976) and received Docteur d’Etat in Economics in 1988.
EBL
Andrew FORD is Professor of Environmental Science at Washington State University. His previous appointments have been in the Systems Management Department at the University of Southern California and the Energy Policy Group at the Los Alamos National Laboratory. His sabbaticals include visits to the Corporate Planning Department of the Pacific Gas and Electric Company, the Energy Markets Group at the London Business School, and the Sloan School of Management at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Dr Ford’s main research and consulting interests involve the use of dynamic simulation modeling to aid in policy formulation in the electric power industry. He teaches modeling with an emphasis on energy and environmental problems in the West. He is the author of the Island Press text on Modeling the Environment. He uses the system dynamics approach to modeling and is the recipient of the Jay W. Forrester Award for outstanding contribution to the field of system dynamics. Dr Ford earned his Doctorate from the Public Policy and Technology Program at Dartmouth College in 1975. Reinhard HAAS is an associate professor at the Energy Economics Group, Institute of Power Systems and Energy Economics, Vienna University of Technology. He specializes in energy policy strategies and the economics of the electric power sector. He is teaching Energy Economics, Regulation, and Competition in Energy markets, and Energy Modeling. His main research areas are evaluation of dissemination strategies for renewables, modeling paths toward sustainable energy systems, liberalization of energy markets, and energy policy strategies. He has published various papers in reviewed international journals on
Contributors
xi
these topics for the past 15 years. He has coordinated and coordinates projects for Austrian institutions as well as the European Commission and the International Energy Agency. He holds a PhD in Energy Economics from Vienna University of Technology. Anne HELD is a research associate at the Department of Energy Policy and Energy Systems at Fraunhofer Institute for Systems and Innovation Research in Karlsruhe, Germany. She joined the institute in December 2004 for realizing her master thesis about the evaluation of renewable promotion schemes in the European electricity market. Her research focuses on promotion strategies for renewable energy sources, the development of techno-economic models in the field of renewable energies, and the use of renewable energy sources in the context of climate policy. She is currently working on various international research projects in this field funded by the European Commission and on her PhD thesis. Anne Held holds a degree in Industrial Engineering and Management from the Technical University of Karlsruhe. She has authored several publications in the field of renewable energy. Udi HELMAN is an economist at the FERC. He has worked extensively on US electricity market design issues, including auction markets for wholesale energy, ancillary services and installed capacity, transmission usage pricing, and market rules for transmission property rights. His major projects have included the initial design and redesign of the Independent System Operator (ISO) New England markets, FERC’s Standard Market Design initiative, the development of the Midwest ISO markets, and the design of longterm financial transmission rights. Dr Helman has authored or co-authored a number of articles and book chapters on electricity regulatory reform. These include “Regulatory Reform of the US Wholesale Electricity Markets,” in M.K. Landy, M.A. Levin, and M. Shapiro, eds., Creating Competitive Markets: The Politics of Regulatory Reform (Brookings Institution Press, 2007); “Independent System Operators in the USA: History, Lessons Learned, and Prospects,” in F. Sioshansi and W. Pfaffenberger, eds., Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective (Elsevier, 2006); “Market Power Monitoring and Mitigation in the US Wholesale Power Markets”, Energy (May-June 2006); and “Dispatchable Transmission in RTO Markets,” IEEE Transactions on Power Systems (February 2005).
EBL
Benjamin F. HOBBS is Professor in the Department of Geography & Environmental Engineering of the Johns Hopkins University. He also holds a joint appointment with the Department of Applied Mathematics & Statistics. Previously, he was Professor of Systems Engineering and Civil Engineering at Case Western Reserve University. He has also been a member of the research staffs of Brookhaven and Oak Ridge National Laboratories. Dr Hobbs’ research interests are in electric sector policy and planning, and ecosystem management. He is a member of the California ISO Market Surveillance Committee, Scientific Advisor to the ENC Policy Studies Unit, and member of the Public Interest Advisory Committee of the Gas Technology Institute. His recent books are Energy Decisions and the Environment, a Guide to the Use of Multicriteria Methods (with P. Meier, Kluwer, 2000) and The Next Generation of Electric Power Unit Commitment Models (edited with M. Rothkopf, R. O’Neill, and H-p. Chao, Kluwer, 2001). His PhD is in Environmental System Engineering from Cornell University. David HURLBUT is a senior analyst at the National Renewable Energy Laboratory in Golden, Colorado. Formerly, he was senior economist with the PUCT, where he worked
xii
Contributors
in the Commission’s wholesale market oversight group on market power, market design, and renewable energy. Dr Hurlbut’s main research and consulting interests include renewable energy policy, electricity market reform, market power and antitrust issues, price transparency, energy efficiency, state energy policy, water policy, and factors influencing electricity market transformation toward energy efficiency and renewable energy. He authored numerous reports for the PUCT dealing with market power and renewable energy. He also led a number of investigations and rulemaking projects at the Commission. He has a Master of Public Affairs and a PhD in Public Policy from the University of Texas at Austin, as well as a degree in journalism from the University of Houston. Arturo LORENZONI is Professor of Energy Economics at the Department of Electrical Engineering of the University of Padova, Italy. He is also Research Director at the Centre for Research on Energy and Environmental Economics and Policy of Bocconi University in Milan. His scientific interests are related to the technical, economic, and regulatory aspects of the energy sector and to its overall efficiency, with particular attention to the electric power system, the utilities, and the development of renewable energy sources. He is the author of many papers on the regulation, liberalization, and organization of the electricity supply industry. He has directed various research projects for DG Research and DG TREN of the European Commission. He has degrees in Electrical Engineering and in Energy Economics at the University of Padova and got a Masters in Energy and Environmental Economics at the Scuola Superiore ENI Enrico Mattei in Milan. He was Study Fellow at SPRU, University of Sussex.
EBL
Elbia MELO is a member of the Board of the Brazilian Power Exchange Chamber (Câmara de Comercialização de Energia Elétrica). She worked at Ministry of the Mines and Energy as Principal Economist (2003–06), and at the Ministry of Finance as Senior Economist (2001–03). At the Federal Electricity Regulatory Agency – ANEEL (2000–01) – she worked as Assessor in the Market and Economic Studies Department. Her main interests include electricity market reform and liberalization, demand and price forecasting, integrated resource planning, and energy auctions. She has an MA and a Bachelor in Economics and a PhD in Production Engineering from Federal University of Santa Catarina. Niels I. MEYER is Professor Emeritus of Physics at the Technical University of Denmark (TUD). He was vice-president and Dean of Natural Sciences at TUD in the 1970s and 1980s, President of the Danish Academy of Technical Sciences for 6 years in the 1970s, and has been member of the Club of Rome since 1972. From 1982 to 1993 Dr Meyer has chaired Danish government committees for renewable energy and from 1998 to 2002 he was member of the Danish Regulatory Committee for the Energy Sector. Dr Meyer’s main research has been concerned with solid-state physics in the 1960s, but since the early 1970s he switched to the field of energy and environment, with a focus on renewable energy and planning for sustainable energy development. Dr Meyer has authored more than 80 international papers in the field of solid-state physics and energy. In recent years his main research has been concerned with the consequences of the liberalized energy market in EU in relation to supply security, support for renewables, and global warming. He has PhD and DSc degrees from the Technical University of Denmark.
Contributors
xiii
Alan MORAN is the Director of the Deregulation Unit at the Australian policy review organization, the Institute of Public Affairs (IPA). Since 1996, Dr Moran has also been the Convenor of the IPA’s Energy Forum and has published studies into many different aspects of energy regulation. Among these is the Australian chapter to a book on world electricity markets, Electricity Market Reform edited by Sioshansi and Pfaffanberger. He has also published widely on other regulatory issues, including telecommunications and housing regulation and his book on the latter, The Tragedy of Planning, was launched by the Federal Treasurer in August 2006. Before his present role, he was a senior official in Australia’s Productivity Commission and Director of the federal Office of Regulation Review. Subsequently, he played a leading role in the development of energy policy and competition policy review as the Deputy Secretary (Energy) in the Victorian Government. He was educated in the United Kingdom and has a PhD in transport economics from the University of Liverpool and degrees from the University of Salford and the London School of Economics. Ken-ichiro NISHIO is a scientist at the Socio-economic Research Center of the Central Research Institute of Electric Power Industry (CRIEPI), a research organization based in Tokyo, Japan, specializing in energy technologies, economics, and policy. He has also conducted research as a visiting scholar at the Lawrence Berkeley National Laboratory (LBNL) in California, USA. Mr Nishio’s main research interests include resource assessment of renewable energy, renewable energy policy, energy demand, end-use technologies such as heat pump and distributed generations, and more generally modeling of energy systems. He has authored reports on analyses of renewable energy development under the renewable energy policy in Japan, and energy conservation potential by introducing energy-efficient technologies in the residential sector. He has a Masters degree in Electrical Engineering from the University of Tokyo.
EBL
Richard P. O’NEILL is Chief Economic Advisor at the FERC. His previous positions included Chief Economist and Director of the Office of Economic Policy, Director of the Commission’s Office of Pipeline and Producer Regulation. Prior to joining FERC he directed oil and gas analysis, including the development of software systems, oil and gas resource analysis, energy modeling systems, analysis of natural gas markets, and oil and gas forecasting at the Energy Information Administration. He has held a number of positions including teaching and work with the World Bank His work has focused on open access, restructuring, competition, performance-based incentive regulation, and market design. His published work has appeared in academic and professional journals and books in the areas of Applied Mathematics, Optimization, Operations Research, Management Science, Computer Science, Energy, Electrical Engineering, Economics, and Law. He has a BS in chemical engineering, an MBA, and a Doctorate in operations research with minors in mathematics, statistics, economics, and accounting, all from the University of Maryland. Shmuel OREN is the Earl J. Isaac Chair Professor in the Science and Analysis of Decision Making in the Industrial Engineering and Operations Research department at the University of California, Berkeley. He is the Berkeley site director of PSERC – a multi-university Power System Engineering Research Center sponsored by the National Science Foundation and industry members.
xiv
Contributors
He has published numerous articles on aspects of electricity market design, planning, and regulation and has been a consultant to various private and government organizations including the Brazilian Electricity Regulatory Agency (ANEEL), the Alberta Energy Utility Board, the Polish system operator (PSE), and the electric power research institute (EPRI). He currently serves as Senior Adviser to the Market Oversight Division of the PUCT, and a consultant to the Energy Division of the California Public Utility Commission (CPUC). He holds BSc and MSc degrees in Mechanical Engineering from the Technion in Israel and also an MS and PhD degrees in Engineering Economic Systems from Stanford University. He is a fellow of the Institute of Electrical and Electronic Engineers (IEEE) and of the Institute for Operations Research and Management Science (INFORMS). Wolfgang PFAFFENBERGER is retired professor of economics at university Oldenburg Germany and adjunct professor at Jacobs University Bremen for Economics (European Utility Management). His main interests include economics of competition in network industries and the electricity and natural gas industries in particular. He has published a textbook on electricity economics and co-authored a textbook on energy economics (both in German) and has written numerous studies and articles on macroeconomic implications of energy and environmental policy, on various aspects of market opening in the electricity supply industry (ESI), and on the special problems of the ESI in transformation countries. Dr Pfaffenberger holds a Diploma in Economics from Freie Universität Berlin where he also got his PhD. He is Honorary Doctor of the Faculty of Economics of the State University of Novosibirsk in Russia.
EBL
Michael POLLITT is University Reader in Business Economics at the Judge Business School, University of Cambridge, and a Fellow of Sidney Sussex College, Cambridge. Dr Pollitt is specialist in utility regulation and has written extensively on the regulation of electricity networks and the lessons from the deregulation of the electricity sector. He is currently an external economic advisor to the UK energy regulator, Ofgem, and Assistant Director of the ESRC Electricity Policy Research Group. He is the author of Ownership and Performance in Electric Utilities (OUP, 1995), a co-author of A Single European Electricity Market? (CEPR, 1999), and co-editor of Future Electricity Technologies and Systems (CUP, 2006) and Delivering a low carbon electricity system (CUP, 2008). He has advised the World Bank, leading energy companies, and several national regulators on energy regulation and reform. In 2005 and 2006 he served as Acting Executive Director of the ESRC Electricity Policy Research Group. He holds a DPhil in Economics from the University of Oxford. Eric SCHUBERT is Director, Regulatory Affairs, ERCOT, for BP Energy Company. His professional experience includes working at the PUCT, Research and Planning Consultants, the Chicago Board of Trade, and Bankers Trust Company. During his tenure at the PUCT, Dr Schubert was project leader in Commission proceedings involving wholesale market design and resource adequacy issues in ERCOT. In recent years, Dr Schubert has authored articles on wholesale market design and resource adequacy issues with a focus on the evolution of electricity deregulation in a policy setting. Earlier in his career, Dr Schubert published articles on financial history with a focus on the Mississippi and South Sea Bubbles and the evolution of international financial markets in Western Europe in the eighteenth Century. He has a PhD in Economics from the University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign.
Contributors
xv
Harry SINGH is Senior Advisor at the FERC where his responsibilities include oversight of electric markets, providing expertise on issues related to market power and manipulation, and advising the Commission on policy issues in electric markets. Dr Singh has worked on implementing several initiatives related to the Energy Policy Act of 2005. These include rulemaking to implement long-term FTRs in RTO markets and an inter-agency report to Congress assessing the competitiveness of electric markets. Harry has also been involved in making recommendations on various investigations; drawing distinctions between manipulation, market power, and market design flaws. He contributes regularly to the Commission’s policies dealing with California. Prior to joining FERC, he held various positions at PG&E Corp and its subsidiaries. His assignments included work with different business units at PG&E, the regulated utility. Harry was a key member of the start-up team that implemented the California ISO and Power Exchange. His subsequent assignments were at PG&E Energy Services and PG&E National Energy Group including work with electric markets across the United States. He has authored or co-authored several technical papers as well as expert testimony. He holds a PhD in Electrical Engineering from the University of Wisconsin–Madison. Fereidoon P. SIOSHANSI is President of Menlo Energy Economics, a consulting firm serving the electric power sector. His professional experience includes working at Southern California Edison Company (SCE), the Electric Power Research Institute (EPRI), National Economic Research Associates (NERA), and most recently, Global Energy Decisions (GED). His main interests include electricity market reform, global climate change, demand and price forecasting, integrated resource planning, energy efficiency, and renewable energy technologies. He co-edited with Professor Wolfgang Pfaffenberger Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective published by Elsevier in 2006. He is the editor and publisher of EEnergy Informer, a monthly newsletter covering electric power sector, and is on the Editorial Advisory Board of The Electricity Journal where he is featured in “Electricity Currents” section. A frequent contributor to Energy Policy, he serves on the editorial board of Utilities Policy. He has degrees in Engineering and Economics, including an MS and PhD in Economics from the Krannert Graduate School of Management, Purdue University.
EBL
Ramteen M. SIOSHANSI is a postdoctoral fellow at the National Renewable Energy Laboratory (NREL) in Golden, Colorado. He has worked as a consultant for Pacific Gas & Electric Company, FERC, General Electric and Global Energy Decisions, developing optimization and decision support models for operations in competitive electricity markets. He has degrees in mathematics, economics, and operations research, including an MS and PhD in operations research, from the London School of Economics and the University of California, Berkeley. Ben SKINNER is Regulatory Manager of Wholesale Markets for TRUenergy, a CLP subsidiary based in Melbourne, Australia. His professional experience includes working with the market/system operator and managing a spot market trading desk for a portfolio of generators. Ben’s main areas of regulatory interest involve the operation of the Australian National Electricity Market (NEM) and its interface with generation and transmission investment. He was involved in some of the early design groups, which developed the NEM energyonly, real-time spot market and continues to represent TRUenergy and several industry organizations in further development. He has written and presented numerous positions
xvi
Contributors
on these matters. He has visited and contrasted the NEM against the UK-NETA, ERCOT, and emerging Chinese Markets. He has a degree in Engineering and a diploma in Applied Finance. Robert WILSON retired after 40 years as a professor at the Stanford Business School. His consulting practice included projects at the Electric Power Research Institute with Drs Hung-po Chao and Shmuel Oren, with whom he co-authored the chapter in this volume. Dr Wilson’s academic research focuses on game theory. His consulting addresses issues of market design, including several projects in the power industry. Professor Wilson has authored numerous articles, and a book on Nonlinear Pricing (Oxford Press, 1993). He received a DBA degree from Harvard and honorary degrees from Bergen and Chicago. He was elected to membership in the National Academy of Sciences and designated Distinguished Fellow of the American Economic Association. Ryan WISER is a scientist at Lawrence Berkeley National Laboratory. Prior to his employment at Berkeley Lab, Dr Wiser worked for Hansen, McOuat, and Hamrin, Inc., the Bechtel Corporation, and the AES Corporation. Dr Wiser leads research in the planning, design, and evaluation of renewable energy policies, and on the costs, benefits, and market potential of renewable electricity sources. His recent analytic work has included studies on the economics of wind power; the treatment of renewable energy in integrated resource planning; the cost of state-level renewables portfolio standards; trends in solar costs in California; and the risk mitigation value of renewable electricity. Dr Wiser regularly advises and consults with state and federal agencies in the design and evaluation of renewable energy policies, and is an advisor to the Energy Foundation’s China Sustainable Energy Program. Dr Wiser has published over 200 journal articles and research reports. His work has been quoted in the Wall Street Journal, USA Today, Washington Post, New York Times, LA Times, and numerous other publications. He received a BS in Civil Engineering from Stanford University and holds an MS and PhD in Energy and Resources from the University of California, Berkeley.
EBL
Jay ZARNIKAU is President of Frontier Associates, a consulting firm serving utilities, retail electric providers, large industrial energy consumers, and retail trade associations in the design and evaluation of energy efficiency programs, retail market strategies, electricity pricing, demand forecasting, and energy policy. He also teaches applied statistics at the University of Texas at Austin as a part-time Visiting Professor. Dr Zarnikau formerly served as a vice-president at Planergy, as a manager at the University of Texas at Austin Center for Energy Studies, and as a division director at the PUCT. His publications include articles in The Energy Journal, Resource and Energy Economics, Energy Economics, IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, Energy Policy, Energy, and The Electricity Journal. He assisted in creating ERCOT’s Demand Side Working Group, and served as its first co-chair. He has a PhD degree in Economics from the University of Texas at Austin.
Foreword: Liberalization and Regulation in Electricity Systems – How can We get the Balance Right? MICHAEL POLLITT Judge Business School and ESRC Electricity Policy Research Group, University of Cambridge
I am very grateful to Fereidoon (Perry) Sioshansi for asking me to write a foreword to this excellent volume. Perry has done scholars of electricity reform a great service by drawing together another excellent collection of chapters on various aspects of reform in electricity markets across the world. Electricity liberalization continues to be one of the longest running and most interesting set of multi-country micro-economic experiments. While most of these national experiments are on-going, some are mature enough to no longer be considered experiments, and many have been running long enough to give rise to preliminary results. Economic analysis is well served by well-informed and detailed analyses of these experiments, such as appear in the pages of this book. In this brief foreword, I want to explore the issue of the balance between liberalisation and regulation in electricity systems, which is the essence of much of the detailed policies which are implemented in the sector (Pfaffenberger also raises the issue of this balance in his preface to this volume). By liberalisation I take to mean the use of market or quasi-market mechanisms as part of a reform of the sector, by regulation I take to mean intervention to restrain the operation of market prices or to set standards (e.g. for quality or system security) at variance with those that would otherwise have operated in the absence of regulation. I use the word “system” rather than “market” to indicate the extent of the system covered by a single regulator or system operator, which may or may not involve a market. Thus national or regional electricity systems and ISO areas would be included in what I mean by an electricity system. In looking at the issue of balance, let me say where I am coming from on this: First, liberalisation of electricity systems typically happens within a context of regulation. There is no such thing as complete deregulation of electricity markets, at least for systems of any significant size. Even among the leaders in global electricity liberalisation – UK, Texas or Norway – what we observe is a liberalisation process which has gone further than in many other jurisdictions but what this means is that the balance between liberalisation and regulation has been shifted further in favour of liberalisation than elsewhere. Truly private networks (e.g., in Woking in the UK) or unregulated networks (e.g. in Mogadishu, within a failed state) can be observed but most systems are bigger than these. Second, the extent of liberalisation of electricity systems is a choice variable, generally bounded by what might be possible. As has been amply demonstrated by the leading countries in electricity reform, there seems to be a lot of freedom to choose how much liberalisation to introduce. European countries in particular, at least initially, exhibited
EBL
xvii
xviii
Competitive Electricity Markets
the full range of responses from virtually no change from a state vertically integrated monopoly to the creation of some of the most liberalized markets in the world. Among developing countries, Argentina and Chile exhibited substantial reform at an early stage while many more developed and developing countries have made less progress. Third, while liberalisation is a choice variable it is a variable conditioned by national institutional factors. Correlje and De Vries discuss this more fully in their chapter. Institutional factors do appear to constrain jurisdictions in their reform schemes. In general, only jurisdictions with substantial pro-competitive histories have attempted the most extensive set of reform measures. Arguably only Latin America provides any examples of extensive electricity reform within a tradition of state intervention – with Argentina being the most interesting example of this. I will explore the extent to which reform choices may be constrained by wider institutional factors later in this chapter. Fourth, it is difficult for me not to write from a UK perspective. Although I am familiar with the reform experience in several jurisdictions, I naturally judge what might be possible on the basis of the experience which I have observed most closely. The advantage of doing this is that that UK has an honourable tradition of leading in the area of energy market reform, the disadvantage is obvious. Increasingly I am interested in thinking about why it is that so few of the jurisdictions that have attempted to replicate the UK experience have been successful. The explanations that naturally suggest themselves include (1) that reforms have not been extensive enough or (2) that a reform package that might be effective in the UK gives rise to perverse results elsewhere. Several US markets would seem to be examples of the former, whereas developing countries might suffer from the latter problem. A final more general explanation (3) might be that institutional constraints – particularly with respect to the initial ownership structure of the industry – mean that while UK style reforms are technically possible, they would not be implemented because of the political economy of the interest groups that exist in the countries concerned. Several major European countries, such as France, Spain and Germany would seem to in this category. For example, in France the starting point is a powerful and well regarded state owned company, while in Germany the starting point involves economically powerful private companies. I will continue by examining the case for liberalisation of electricity systems, then look at the case for regulation, offer a brief evaluation of what the evidence on where the balance might be drawn, before considering what the future might hold for electricity liberalisation.
EBL
The Case for Liberalisation As Chao, Oren and Wilson remind us in their chapter, the past for most electricity systems involved a high degree of vertical integration – particularly between generation and transmission, but also between distribution and retail and frequently between all four stages of production. The economic arguments for large vertically integrated electricity companies, which were significant in size within political jurisdictions rested on a claim that vertical economies were significant. Many studies examined the nature of these vertical economies and most, if not all, concluded that vertical economies between generation and transmission were significant (e.g. Kaserman and Mayo, 1991). This provided arguments for the integration of what we now know to be potentially competitive generation and monopoly transmission networks. Papers which claim vertical economies continue to be written, e.g. on the regional Japanese electric power companies where a very high degree of vertical integration continues (see Nemoto and Goto, 2004).
Foreword: Liberalization and Regulation in Electricity Systems
xix
Experience with liberalisation shows us that there were indeed costs to vertical separation, both in generation and transmission and between distribution and retail (see Newbery and Pollitt, 1997 and Domah and Pollitt, 2001). However these costs had to be incurred to achieve the benefits of more competition in generation and also more competition in retail. Studies showing vertical economies between the various stages of electricity supply are mostly not capable of modelling these benefits properly, and indeed in the case of studies where there are no non-integrated companies with whom performance of integrated utilities can be compared are seriously mis-specified. The case for competition in generation rests on the benefits of competitive markets generally. More precisely, a central claim is that competition drives efficiency gains, which can be substantial given that generation can be as much as 65% of value added in the sector. Efficiency gains are of two main types: cost savings arising from the more efficient operation of existing assets and those arising from the choice of cheaper technologies for new generation. Both can be significant, even more so where initial operation has been in the hands of inefficient publicly owned utilities. Heavily regulated integrated utilities are subject to a potential gold plating problem if they are privately owned (following Averch and Johnson, 1962) and subject to the pressure to be instruments of government industrial policy which supports expensive home grown contractors and designs, rather than generic scalable technologies which are available off the shelf (see Henderson, 1977 and Green, 1995 on the highly expensive British nuclear programmes). Clearly the uptake of CCGT in competitive generation has been a great success in liberalized electricity markets, as has the cutting of support for expensive untried clean coal technologies (which would not have been as clean as CCGT) and the curtailing of the uneconomic roll out of nuclear power (Newbery and Pollitt, 1997). Competitive generation has clearly revealed the price of different technologies and caused clear choices to be made in line with market principles. Electricity economists are keen to point out how different electricity is to other commodities and hence what some of the problems of letting the market operate might be. Indeed Chao, Oren and Wilson note that the regulatory compact in the US electricity sector was that monopoly operation of electricity networks was essentially the price that was paid by regulators in return for smoothing of retail electricity prices. They suggest that electricity prices would be much more volatile in the absence of regulation and that this would be politically unacceptable. This is undoubtedly a powerful view of competition in retail electricity markets, which resonates today, even within the most fully liberalized markets. However it is a rather quaint given rising incomes and the increasing availability of sophisticated financial instruments. It may also be a view arising from US states where low power prices have been traditionally based on access to cheap coal (Joskow, 1997). Consumers in these states seem to have little to gain by deregulation and market extension to high price states. By contrast the enthusiastic advancement of market liberalisation in California was driven by high electricity prices in a state where demand was growing rapidly and there no cheap resources for power generation. Ambivalent views towards electricity reform are rather at odds with economists’ normal enthusiasm for market-determined prices. What full retail competition (i.e. including households) in both the UK, Nordic countries, New Zealand and Texas reveals is that consumers can be content to pay “volatile” electricity prices as long as there is a perceived benefit from retail competition. Undoubtedly the Chao et al. view does restrain regulators enthusiasm for proper retail competition in many US states and elsewhere. However it is based on the view that competition is ok in most markets, but somehow not ok in retail energy markets. This is rather odd, as economists (though not politicians) are happy to see volatile gasoline prices, but not volatile residential electricity (or natural gas?) prices. It is difficult
EBL
xx
Competitive Electricity Markets
to see how retail competition at the household level can make much progress in many jurisdictions unless this view faces serious challenge. At this point it is important to be clear about what full retail competition looks like in electricity markets. This is because what passes for retail competition in many US states is such a pale version of competition as to invite ridicule. Retail competition should involve the ability to switch electricity supplier. Effective retail competition would involve the existence of, say, five or more energy companies offering retail tariffs. If a customer switches from the incumbent supplier they would receive a bill from a different company who would purchase monopoly transmission and distribution services from incumbents but be responsible for billing, contract terms, bundling of other services and the purchase of wholesale power. In many US states this is not what is meant by “retail choice” at the household level. Retail choice simply involves buying the wholesale power component of one’s energy bill from a non-incumbent. This eliminates competition in billing, bundling of other services and contract terms. This is an unusual type of competition, which is not the same as we observe in genuinely competitive markets. To make matters worse, US retail choice often involves the offering of default regulated tariffs to retail consumers which restrict switching by being regulated at a low level or having the property that if one switches, one cannot return to the default service tariff. The lesson from deregulated markets where there has been significant customer switching is that the existence of a low regulated retail tariff discourages switching i.e., there should be a removal of price regulation of retail tariffs. The benefits of household retail competition continue to be debated (Littlechild (2002) expresses the arguments for full retail competition, while Green and McDaniel (1998) present a sceptical view). Retail competition has now been revealed to be important for competition in generation. A major observation of electricity reforms is that monopoly networks are different businesses from the competitive businesses – generation and retail. The former are, when regulated effectively, low risk infrastructure businesses, while the latter are higher risk businesses subject to the normal bankruptcy risk faced by companies in competitive markets. While the vertical economies between generation and transmission are not sufficient to offset the benefits of competition in wholesale power markets, they do appear to be significant between generation and retail. In particular the risk management advantages of generation and retail integration are very important, such that stand-alone retail electricity companies have struggled. Across the world large stand-alone start-up retail companies have, after some initial successes, have generally failed, as exemplified by the experience of the UK, Netherlands and New Zealand. A notable retail-only business model, which has succeeded is that of the former incumbent gas company in the UK (Centrica) which has very successfully diversified into electricity retailing in the UK and in the rest of Europe. However this company has been born of an unusually competitive and unbundled gas industry in the UK. The good news is that competition in retail markets is possible; the bad news is that it is only likely to be as extensive as competition in generation because non-integrated retail companies have little chance of success at any reasonable scale. Economists are fond of pointing out the many other ways in which the detailed operation of the electricity market needs to be regulated. Thus there are issues to do with the efficient operation of the transmission system and the allocation of transmission capacity and the problems of incentivising enough generation capacity to be available to limit price spikes at peak times (see Singh, this volume). The liberalisation process has revealed that market and quasi-market mechanisms can address market and regulatory failures in these areas. PJM and some other jurisdictions, for example, have successfully implemented nodal pricing
EBL
Foreword: Liberalization and Regulation in Electricity Systems
xxi
arrangements for the allocation of transmission capacity and many other markets have used price signals to make more efficient use of scarce transmission capacity. In terms of the mitigation of price spikes, special mechanisms have been introduced to pay generators to make extra capacity available, either more generally via a capacity payment (e.g. in the North East US), or specifically at the system peak (e.g. in the UK). While the long-term incentive properties of some of these mechanisms are dubious, they can mitigate the short-term capacity shortage problems (this seems to be the case in New England) and provide comfort to regulators and politicians that something is being done to prevent the lights from going out. This view is supported by Adib, Schubert and Oren, in their chapter, who suggest that “there is no evidence” that capacity support mechanisms actually promote investment in the long term. Moran and Skinner’s chapter on Australia, further suggests that a market without capacity payments can work well, even though prices do occasionally spike. However as long as these spike reduction measures are not too expensive, they may be a price worth paying for the continuation of electricity reforms elsewhere in the system. Indeed, Bowring’s chapter on PJM’s capacity markets suggests that they may have a limited role to play in reassuring stakeholders that adequate capacity will be available. Bowring concludes that capacity markets are “not a panacea” but can play “a critical but circumscribed role in wholesale power market design” [my italics]. Generation and retail electricity markets yield major market advantages over vertical integration. First, they allow the efficient handling of business risk. There are substantial uncertainties in the short, medium and long term in power markets. Markets are good at handling these types of risk. Indeed given the capacity of the oil market to handle much more significant risks, it would be odd if we did not leave these to the market in electricity. Second, price has a significant role to play in ensuring security of electricity supply. The old vertical integrated system did provide security of supply – at a cost. Most markets allow a significant role for the price in ensuring security of supply. Around the market price insurance can be offered to those who want it, while those who want to self-insure can opt out. As the UK (2004–06), New Zealand (2001), Nordic countries (2002–03) and Chile (1998–99) have all demonstrated in recent years, retail electricity customers are willing to be exposed to significant price volatility and play a significant role in demand management. Third, full retail competition offers a significant political advantage over vertical integration: the “privatisation” of the final price of electricity. Where retail prices continue to be regulated, as they are in the absence of full retail competition or the continuation of a default service tariff, political or regulatory interference is much more likely. This is important at times of rising energy commodity prices, when the pressure will be to slow the translation of these into higher retail prices. Between 2004 and 2006, wholesale gas prices quadrupled in the UK and retail electricity and gas prices rose significantly. However the most common response to this sharp rise was for politicians to point out that most electricity and gas consumers could cut their energy bills by switching to a cheaper energy supplier. In the absence of retail competition the pressure for politicians’ intervention would be much stronger than this. Continuation of regulation of the final price of electricity is usually a sign of insufficient competition in the wholesale power market. Removing such regulation focuses regulators attention on making the power market competitive. This is clearly demonstrated by the EU Energy Sector Inquiry, where advent of full retail competition at the household level has led the European Commission to focus on the removal of barriers to competition in wholesale power markets. Fourth, competition promotes innovation, some of which may be unexpected. Retail competition in electricity markets has promoted joint marketing of electricity and gas
EBL
Competitive Electricity Markets
xxii
where these were previously often provided by different local monopolies, the use of internet-based switching sites, payment by direct debit and the vertical integration of generation and retail (in jurisdictions where this did not previously exist). We have already noted the effect that competition in generation has had on the adoption of generation technologies. However it has also led to the refurbishment of assets, rather than their replacement (or originally scheduled closure). For example, the widespread life extension of the US nuclear fleet (where no plants have shut down since 1998 and where the majority seem set to be life-extended to 2035 and beyond) is something that is clearly incentivised by competition in generation (see Joskow, 2006a). The Case for Regulation Even in the leading utility reform sector – telecoms – regulators have been slow to remove regulated retail and access tariffs to networks for competitive telecom service providers. Thus we might expect there to continue to be a strong pressure for continued regulation in the electricity sector. Demsetz (1968) asked the question: why regulate utilities? He pointed out that while natural monopoly might still exist, it could be restrained by franchising or competition for the field in utility sectors, such as electricity. In New Zealand, as Bertram (2006) discussed in this book’s predecessor volume, the government conducted a rather interesting economic experiment. They left the regulation of the operation of the electricity distribution businesses to general competition policy. This resulted in the lines businesses significantly increasing their charges relative to costs and absorbing all of the benefits of competition in generation and retail (see Fig. 1). This experiment graphically demonstrates the fact that
EBL
16 14 12
12.90
2.11
12.34
13.17
2.25
13.68
13.63
14.10
14.17
14.11
2.40
2.42
3.10
3.13
3.10
1.89
10 4.05
3.84
4.62
4.92
5.01
4.86
4.89
4.90
2.18
2.06
1.90
1.86
1.85
1.80
1.80
1.79
4.56
4.55
4.40
4.50
4.35
4.34
4.35
4.32
Apr-94
Apr-95
Apr-96
Apr-97
Apr-98
Nov-99
Feb-00
8 6 4 2 0
Generation
Transmission
Apr-99 Line
Retail
Fig. 1. New Zealand residential electricity price c/kWh (2000 NZ$). Source: Ministry of Economic Development (2000).
Foreword: Liberalization and Regulation in Electricity Systems
xxiii
electricity networks do have significant market power and need to be formally price regulated. It also provides a good argument for an effective sector specific regulator formally charged with implementing a price review process in networks, even in jurisdictions with competent general competition authorities. Regulation of the average prices or revenue of natural monopoly networks is not enough to ensure that network owners do not abuse their monopoly power in situations where there continues to be vertical integration of electricity networks with either generation or retail businesses. As the experience with telecoms deregulation shows, there is a need for the regulation of access to monopoly networks for generators trying to reach customers and retailers trying to source power (see Bergman et al., 1998 on telecoms). Such access pricing needs to ensure that the incumbent network asset owners can secure a return to their investment and that switching to non-incumbents occurs simply on the basis of differences in costs, prices and service offerings in the competitive parts of the supply chain. In the case of telecoms, the efficient component pricing rule (Baumol et al., 1997) attempted to limit inefficient bypass of the incumbent’s assets in the competitive segment in conditions where the final price was regulated. In electricity, the problem of access pricing involves clear non-discrimination in the allocation of network access and the regulation of tariffs to reflect the true costs of the monopoly network. In general, energy regulators have been able to do this where their powers have been sufficient, though in some continental European countries, such as Germany, there have been substantial problems reported by non-incumbent generators trying to get access terms in the early years of restructuring (see Bergman et al., 1999). In retail, there have been examples of incumbent retailers integrated with distribution wires attempting to allocate an overly generous part of the initially shared assets to the monopoly distribution wires business and hence raising access charges for non-incumbent retailers. This effectively means that the retail customers who switch to non-incumbents subsidise the retail part of an incumbent’s business. The potential size of this cost allocation problem is substantial. The UK electricity regulator, Ofgem, reallocated an amount equivalent to around 18% (of which a third was metering costs) of the controllable cost of regulated distribution from distribution wires to retail in 2000 (see Ofgem, 1999, p.17). This reflected the misallocation of assets and costs within incumbent integrated distribution and retail companies at the time the market was opened to full retail competition. The appropriate regulation of access charges and terms continues to drive the debate over unbundling of network assets in Europe. Successive European electricity directives in 1996 and 2003 have mandated increasingly tough unbundling requirements between the network and competitive businesses within integrated companies. The recent EU Energy Sector Enquiry highlighted access problems as a major barrier to the advancement of competition in European electricity and gas markets (European Commission, 2007). In mid-2007, the European Commission is pressing for full ownership unbundling of gas and electricity transmission networks from the rest of the system. This has been proposed to finally remove the incentive on transmission owners to favour their own generation or to not propose transmission investments, which would bring system benefits at the expense of corporate profits in generation. It remains to be seen whether the Commission will eventually force ownership unbundling of just system operation along an ISO model (such as PJM) or will also achieve the ownership unbundling of transmission assets to create independent TSOs (such as in the UK or under the stalled RTO model in the US). The weaker ISO model option may prevail as a compromise with countries for whom ownership unbundling of transmission assets is politically unacceptable. ISOs without
EBL
xxiv
Competitive Electricity Markets
transmission assets may do well on non-discrimination but do not solve the problem of under-investment in transmission by companies with market power in generation. Singh discusses the problems in US transmission in his chapter, putting emphasis on the need to improve transmission investment incentives and the fact that the debate in the US has begun to focus on the case for independent transmission companies as opposed to ISOs. Regulation is also important in a number of non-price areas: for example, standards for quality of service, reliability and network losses. Unless regulators enforce some sort of penalty price for the non-delivery of minimum standards, there may be incentives for services to deteriorate or not optimally improve the quality of the operation of the network. A good example of this follows. Distribution losses are paid for by retail customers who must buy extra power to cover network losses. Network losses are assumed, for charging purposes, to be uniform and constant in most distribution networks. Hence there is little advantage for competitive suppliers seeking to minimise these, resulting in market failure. In the UK, network losses in distribution did not change much over the first ten years following liberalisation, until the regulator introduced a tougher financial penalty for distribution losses payable by network owners (see Jamasb and Pollitt, 2007). This led to a sharp and immediate cut in distribution losses as shown in Fig. 2. The creation of competitive wholesale markets has been associated with the need to create appropriate transmission access regimes. However the rise of distributed generation (embedded within the distribution network), in response to technological change and climate change concerns, has necessitated a more considered regulatory approach to the regulation of distribution access. This is pressurising regulators to develop more flexible access terms for distributed generation within the distribution network, which reflect its true value to the system. The regulatory issues raised by distributed generation are discussed in the chapter by Bauknecht and Brunekreeft. It is important to note that there has been a significant improvement in the sophistication of regulation of natural monopolies since electricity reform began. The Averch-Johnson effect, the theory of regulatory capture (Stigler, 1971) and distortions of regulated price differentials (Peltzman, 1976), not to mention the rather unimpressive early attempts at limited (and hence distortionary) incentive regulation (Berg and Jeong, 1991) are lessons
EBL
8.0% 7.5% 7.0% 6.5% 6.0% 5.5% 5.0% 1990- 1991- 1992- 1993- 1994- 1995- 1996- 1997- 1998- 1999- 2000- 2001- 2002- 200391 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 Fig. 2. Distribution losses in the UK as percentage of energy delivered. Source: Jamasb and Pollitt (2007).
Foreword: Liberalization and Regulation in Electricity Systems
xxv
that now seem to be well learned by the best regulatory agencies operating in competitive markets. Indeed there does seem to be a rather clear positive correlation between the degree of development of liberalisation and the quality of the regulatory agency (see Green et al, 2005). Particular progress has been made in the incentive regulation of electricity networks, where sophisticated analysis has been combined with the use of fixed term price controls, which incentivise cost reduction (Jamasb and Pollitt, 2001 and Joskow, 2005). Indeed an obvious potential gain from unbundling electricity networks from the rest of the supply chain is the facilitation of superior regulation of network businesses. This can lead to significant cuts in regulated tariffs and/or increases in investment, as exemplified by the experience of the UK, Nordic countries, Chile and New South Wales. Effective regulation not only brings direct benefits through more efficient networks but also through the facilitation of wholesale and retail competition across these networks. While the regulation of electricity networks is clearly necessary, electricity market liberalisation has thrown up a strong case for market monitoring (as detailed in the chapter by Adib and Hurlbut) of the operation of the competition within generation and retail markets. Market monitoring requires vigilance and quick action to correct market rules if societal welfare is to be maximised (or not significantly reduced). Specialist energy regulators seem best able to analyse market data and to propose remedies, with detailed market rule changes sometimes delegated to system operators or wholesale market governance mechanisms if sufficient regulatory threat is in place. The need for regulatory oversight of this type would seem to be more necessary in the early stages of market redesign due to the complexity and scope for gaming which exists in electricity markets. However over time regulatory oversight may be reduced as market operators become more able to self-regulate. A parallel might be drawn with financial markets in this respect where effective self-regulation may be generally desirable within a context of appropriate legal protection and the operation of the general competition authority. Electricity markets may need to be redesigned from time to time with significant regulatory involvement (in assessing the relative merits of different designs) as new analysis on optimal market design comes to light. An example of such a design question is raised in the chapter by Sioshansi, Oren and O’Neill who examine the relative merits of central versus self-commitment of generation units. They come down in favour of central commitment rather than self-commitment. Self-commitment was a significant element of the New Electricity Trading Arrangements for wholesale power which replaced the Pool (begun in 1990) in England and Wales in 2001. In their chapter O’Neill and Hobbs consider the lessons from different auction markets in the US for wholesale energy and ancillary services. All such significant redesigns need careful assessment in order to avoid imposing additional costs on electricity customers. Particular problems have been noted with the utilisation of interconnectors between jurisdictions, price signalling within power pools, withholding of capacity and mergers between energy companies. Interconnectors are a particular issue within the transmission system because they can be closely monitored. What seems to be the case, is that these can be often congested, flowing in a perverse direction and not subject to appropriate capacity upgrading. In Europe, international electricity and gas interconnectors are the subject of scrutiny of regulators (see European Commission, 2007) to detect the operation of market power by integrated incumbents. Gas interconnector utilisation (or the lack of it) and non-responsiveness to large international price differentials have been particularly noted. Power pools and organised power markets can be subject to price manipulation. This is because of the repeated game nature of such interaction and the ability of firms to signal to one another within the power pool. Such accusations were regularly made of
EBL
xxvi
Competitive Electricity Markets
firms in the early days of power pool in the UK. Indeed when the regulator imposed a price cap on the incumbents in this market, they managed to hit it exactly (see Newbery, 2006). California’s ill-fated power markets are still under investigation for the alleged withholding of capacity to drive up prices (see Sweeney, 2006). Measures of the residual market power index clearly show that in many power markets incumbents have the ability to withhold enough capacity to drive up the price significantly. Finally, power company mergers require careful assessment. This is because the sheer volume of transactions among energy companies brought about by liberalisation has the capacity to rapidly change the shape of the power sector (see Codognet et al., 2002). The increase in effective market size brought about by liberalisation in many US and European markets, requires mergers to be evaluated more carefully than would have been the case in the past. In Europe, the concentration of ownership at the European level has been the price paid to reduce concentration within individual national markets (see Jamasb and Pollitt, 2005). Meanwhile mergers between electricity and gas companies have created the potential for the sophisticated exercise of market power in the interrelation between gas and electricity markets. The highly controversial merger between EON and Ruhrgas in 2003 integrated the major supplier of wholesale gas and one of the major energy companies in Germany, eliminating a major potential competitor in the electricity market. This merger was opposed by the German competition authority but approved by the government. A similar merger between Endesa and Gas Natural in Spain in 2006 was initially approved but failed to occur. It is important to stress that while liberalisation has involved some reduction in regulation in wholesale and retail electricity, it is not necessarily the case that liberalisation and regulation are substitutes. Wholesale and retail competition may require more regulation (in terms of cost and complexity) to ensure their success. A state owned vertically integrated national monopoly may require minimal regulation, but is not consistent with a liberalised market.
EBL
Evaluating the Experience with Electricity Market Reform Globally, the evidence on the success of electricity reform is surprisingly mixed. One would have expected to find clear evidence of reform success showing up by now in the econometric evidence. This is however difficult to demonstrate as Jamasb et al. (2004) show. There are only two academic econometric studies of the price effects of electricity reform in the OECD (Steiner, 2001 and Hattori and Tsutsui, 2004). Both show some weak evidence of lower prices in the period to 1999, but it is difficult to distinguish which reform steps may be contributing to this. The evidence for developing countries is even more difficult. There is support for the view that incentive regulation, with privatisation and wholesale competition does raise investment, reduce losses and lower prices. However the precise interaction between reform steps is somewhat complex. The picture is complicated somewhat because pre-reform prices may have been artificially low relative to economic levels. Successful reform in these cases involves raising the price or simply holding prices constant while efficiency is increased. Part of the problem is that the success of electricity liberalisation might be measured on several dimensions, for example, price, quality of service, losses and investment, and may need several years of observation before a trend improvement is apparent (given “normal” year to year volatility). In recent years high commodity prices for gas further cloud the picture. Another problem is a lack of careful cost benefit analyses of reforms in particular
Foreword: Liberalization and Regulation in Electricity Systems
xxvii
jurisdictions where the counterfactual has been clearly worked out and is defensible. The basic assumption that variables of interest would have been same as before in the absence of liberalisation may not be the right one. Indeed in many cases, the liberalisation may have resulted in some variables (e.g. price) rising less rapidly or indeed falling less rapidly, than would otherwise have been case. A promising way forward is to make a list of where one might think there has been a successful electricity reform. A good start would be to look at the chapters of Sioshansi and Pfaffenberger (2006). Among developing and transition countries Argentina and Chile stand out as successful poster cases. After this, the list becomes quite thin with perhaps, Peru and Columbia as additional cases. In many others there have been significant problems (e.g. Brazil: as discussed by Araujo, Correia, Costa and Melo in their chapter), and yet others not a lot has yet been tried (e.g. Middle East, Africa, parts of India). Among developed countries, there has been a lot of reform impetus. The EU has attempted a major organised reform programme but only the UK, Norway, Sweden, Finland and the Netherlands can really be said to be making significant progress from the pre-reform model. In most other European countries demonstrating a positive impact from electricity reforms and indeed much real enthusiasm beyond that generated by wishing to be good European citizens in complying with the Directives is difficult. In North America, Texas, PJM, New England and New York demonstrate good progress in wholesale competition, but only Texas and some odd bits of Maine, Pennsylvania and Ohio have household retail choice, while many states exhibit no progress from the traditional vertically integrated model. In Maine, Pennsylvania and Ohio regulated retail tariffs continue to limit competition and “choice” is simply in the generation part of the retail bill. In Ohio one incumbent company discourages switching by highlighting consumer’s right to choose not to release data to alternative energy suppliers (on privacy grounds). Australia and New Zealand have shown enthusiasm for reform but significant problems remain in several Australian states (e.g. Queensland, Tasmania and Western Australia where only partial liberalisation has occurred), though good retail competition is developing in Victoria and South Australia (see Moran and Skinner, this volume on Australia). In New Zealand there have been a number of legislative attempts to progress reform in the face of setbacks. In Japan progress with electricity reform continues to move very slowly. Overall the picture is one of significant progress towards the maximum possible electricity reform being made in only a handful of jurisdictions, while reform progress has stalled at some intermediate stage in many more jurisdictions. Even some of the places where we think of the most progress as being made: parts of PJM, as well as Chile and Argentina have not got full retail competition at the household level. Correlje and De Vries suggest that, it is difficult to come up with clear lessons from electricity reforms which translate globally because of what they call physical, economic and institutional factors. However there are some lessons: First, ownership unbundling of electricity transmission from the rest of the electricity network has produced clear benefits in the markets where it has been tried in terms of improving access conditions for competitive generation and removing incentives to underinvest in transmission. ISOs with continued integration of transmission and generation are largely effective in improving access conditions and the operation of the transmission system but suffer significantly from continuing under investment; Chile being an excellent example of this, among others (see Pollitt, 2004). Second, getting the market structure right in electricity generation is crucial for the success of electricity reform. This involves sufficient divestiture to, say, five players by
EBL
Competitive Electricity Markets
xxviii
incumbents. Relying on new entry alone will not be enough to ensure the reduction in the market power of incumbents. Where regulators have been unable to introduce low concentration at the opening of new power markets, they have faced an uphill battle to reduce concentration. Really successful wholesale power markets either introduced competition right at the start e.g., in Argentina, PJM, Texas or undertook significant regulatory intervention subsequently, e.g., in UK. Third, incentive regulation based on RPI-X price control of monopoly networks can deliver significant incentives to reduce costs and can facilitate efficient operation with the provision of stable cash flow for new investment. Regulators that have not made best use of incentive regulation have missed out on a substantial part of the gains from ending of the vertical monopoly in electricity. This is clear from a glance at the division of the final price of electricity between generation, transmission, distribution and retail elements in European countries. The countries with tougher incentive regulation of networks have significantly lower network costs than those who do not (Jamasb and Pollitt, 2005). Fourth, regulation can address market failures in electricity markets such as those associated with quality of supply. The problem with regulatory incentives to meet nonprice objectives is that they may interact with one another and create perverse incentives. Regulators need to understand the power of incentives both to solve perceived problems in electricity systems and to inadvertently incentivise welfare reducing activity. Indeed part of the problem of electricity liberalisation is that it requires more sophisticated regulation to be successful. Overall the potential benefits of electricity reform seem to be positive. Newbery and Pollitt (1997) conservatively estimated that generation and transmission reform in the UK reduced costs permanently by 5%. Fabrizio et al. (2007) come up with a similar figure for the reduction in generation costs due to reforms in the US. Looking at final electricity prices in the US, Joskow (2006b) finds that competitive wholesale markets and retail competition have reduced prices (relative to their absence) significantly, with retail competition reducing prices by 5–10% for residential cutomers and 5% for industrial customers. Focussing on just the New England wholesale power market, Barmack et al. (2007) find a net gain of 2% of costs due to reforms. In distribution and retail, the benefits are similar in order of magnitude. Domah and Pollitt (2001) identified gains of around 10% of costs for the UK. For developing countries, Toba (2007) estimated that the liberalisation of Philippine electricity generation produced a one-off gain equivalent to around 10% of GDP, while Mota (2004) estimated that the privatisation (and incentive regulation) of Brazilian electricity distribution produced a one-off gain of more than 2% of GDP. Stephen Littlechild (2000) breaks down the benefit of the early years of the UK reforms in Table 1.
EBL
Table 1. Sources of price reduction to domestic users 1991/92–1998/9 Source Lower Lower Lower Lower
% generation costs distribution and transmission charges supply business margin fossil fuel levy (mainly to fund nuclear liabilities)
Total Source: Littlechild (2000).
10 9 1 9 29
Foreword: Liberalization and Regulation in Electricity Systems
xxix
Littlechild’s analysis helpfully focuses on residential customers and provides a point estimate of the impact of reform (in contrast to the NPV calculations of the Newbery and Pollitt (1997) and Domah and Pollitt (2001) studies). This indicates that the reduction in residential prices is split almost equally between lower generation costs (operating efficiency and fuel switching), lower distribution and transmission charges (transferred to consumers via RPI-X) and a lower fossil fuel levy, which was the subsidy to the nuclear sector to cover un-financed decommissioning liabilities (the ending of an industrial subsidy). Thus one might say that gains were coming from competition, improved economic regulation and the elimination of inefficient industrial subsidies to energy production. This highlights the fact that in many countries a clear benefit of liberalisation is likely to be the end of expensive industrial policies towards the energy sector or at the very least to increase the transparency of the cost of these.
The Future of Electricity Liberalisation Electricity reform around the world has been driven by a combination of the success of the early reformers (who inspired many followers) and the extensive reform programs at the federal level in the US and at the level of the European Commission in Europe. As the difficulty of replicating the success of the early reformers has become more apparent, particularly in developing countries, and as the US federal program has stalled, many jurisdictions have failed to pursue electricity liberalisation to its logical conclusion. Only in the EU has the sustained commitment of the European Commission within a wider single market agenda (which encompasses all industrial sectors) and a political system where energy reforms can become part of the international bargaining process has the pressure for further electricity market reforms been sustained. However, Cornwall’s chapter highlights just how far there is to go to establish regional electricity markets (covering groups of neighbouring countries) in Europe, let alone to the Commission’s goal of a single electricity market in Europe. What is becoming increasingly clear is that electricity reform has failed to convince many of its merits (e.g. Thomas, 2006). On the basis of the evidence of the delivery of clear benefits being somewhat mixed, this is hardly surprising. What seems to be the case is that the pursuit of electricity reform through to its logical conclusion is only likely to happen in jurisdictions where there is a strong ideological commitment to competition in energy markets. This will partly be driven by resource conditions – the presence of initially high costs with scope for efficiency gains is conducive to reform – but significantly by whether there is a fundamental belief that electricity prices should be left to the market. This belief is partly a belief in the market itself and partly a belief in the market for energy per se. Some who believe in the market still think energy markets sufficiently different from others to warrant the sort of intervention that prevents the emergence of effective competition in generation and/or in retail. Often this reflects (or is supported by) concerns about security of supply and increasingly concerns about pollution from electricity production. What is absolutely clear is that successful through-going electricity liberalisation requires both a belief in competition and effective institutions of competition policy. Countries, such as France and Germany, will struggle to make serious progress with electricity reform unless they can change their attitude to competition in the electricity sector. This is not beyond the bounds of possibility but it will require the sort of reluctant change in attitude, which globalisation and technological change has brought about in other sectors (such as telecoms).
EBL
xxx
Competitive Electricity Markets
A new and important challenge to electricity reform is posed by climate change. As Ford discusses in his chapter, climate change is a serious issue which the power sector will be expected to address. Economically sensible policies for the internalisation of the external costs of CO2 emissions have been enacted in the EU (as the EU Emissions Trading System) and proposed in the US (various state and regional trading initiatives are progressing, with a bill for a national scheme being put before the Senate in 2003). However, with regard to the balance of liberalisation and regulation in electricity systems, climate change is a potential vehicle for the return of old-style intervention in electricity generation and in retail competition. The argument will be that the market will not invest in low carbon generation without long-term contracts for low carbon electricity generation. Such contracts would effectively eliminate competition in the wholesale power market. On the retail side, the argument will be that consumers who switch, fail to provide long-term incentives for micro-power and demand side management (DSM) investments. Regulators face a significant challenge if they are to introduce subsidies to low carbon electricity generation which do not effectively end competition. Clearly environmental externalities should be priced properly as a first step. Competition should be viewed as part of solution, not the problem. Encouraging price sensitivity and consumer selection between own generation, DSM measures and energy supplier would be a more effective way of mobilising extra resources (from customers) and cheaper market led responses for tackling climate change than potentially highly expensive centrally imposed investments. The potential for DSM in liberalised market environments is taken up in the chapter by Zarnikau. In the context of rising political concern about climate change, we need to heed the lessons of history on the poor track record of government backed technologies in energy. Cohen and Noll (1991) highlight the “technology pork barrel” in the US and the difficulty of ceasing government funding of energy technologies which fail to deliver. Fri (2003) suggests that although the theoretical case for public funding (or consumer subsidy) of energy R&D is compelling, the track record suggests that the situations where intervention is likely to have positive net present value are rather limited. He also makes the interesting observation that subsidies for strategic deployment to exploit learning economies have been of dubious economic value as learning has been just as rapid in non-subsidised “mature” technologies. Most successful innovation in electricity systems is incremental (Fri, 2003) and best left to the forces of the competition, attempts to force the pace by subsidy are likely to be expensive mistakes (especially in aggregate across the portfolio range of technological interventions). By contrast the introduction of market based incentives to abate environmental pollution in electricity have an excellent track record. The US SO2 cap and trade programme being the most notably successful of these (see Ellerman and Dubroeucq, 2004). In this context it is vital that we properly evaluate the success of the various renewable electricity support schemes implemented around the world (as for example in the chapter by Haas et al.), while continuing to press for the establishment of a sensibly high trading price for CO2. Once this price is established the requirement for large and potentially wasteful subsides to support the roll out of renewable capacity will be substantially reduced. Liberalised electricity markets have had a good run where they have been implemented. The US, UK, New Zealand, Australia and Scandinavia initially had very favourable generation capacity reserve margins, well developed transmission and distribution networks and a favourable fuel price environment. This facilitated electricity reform by allowing for a significant period of uncertainty and learning where little net new investment was necessary. (Though in many of the early reformers there was significant new investment – Chile and Argentina being the most striking examples in terms of demand growth).
EBL
Foreword: Liberalization and Regulation in Electricity Systems
xxxi
However the investment demands, even on mature networks are now increasing as networks require replacement (or refurbishment) and significant new generation investments are required given the investment cycle. This will test the investment incentive structure in these markets (and will test government commitment to leaving investments to the market). In networks, new mechanisms need to be developed for incentivising least cost investments rather than simply incentivising efficient operation (as under RPI-X). Innovative new schemes for the selection of new investments have been successfully tried out – such as the public contest method for new transmission investments in Argentina which involved users voting for whether they wanted new lines (Littlechild and Skerk, 2004). Competitive tendering, even for investments within meshed networks, could be extended with the tender price being incorporated in the regulatory asset base. Correlje and De Vries bring us back to the consistency of electricity reforms with underlying institutional determinants as well as physical and economic factors. This is in line with recent work being done on the determinants of economic growth by La Porta et al. (1999) and the strength of financial systems by Bordo (2006). It seems clear that the detailed electricity system reform needs to be consistent with the institutional framework within which the reforms take place. Starting points are important: significant public ownership and prices which more than cover efficient economic cost greatly facilitate a structural reform which will yield positive social welfare. These starting points were present in Chile, Argentina, UK, Australia and New Zealand. Initial private ownership (e.g. in the US, Japan and Germany) and prices below economic cost (e.g. in India) make reform much more difficult. Electricity reforms are complex and require a commitment to competition and efficient regulation. Significantly they also need to show flexibility to emerging information and allow scope for mid-course adjustments. It seems clear that a jurisdiction like the UK is very well suited to delivering a successful electricity reform at the generation, network and retail levels. This is because the UK has a strong central state capable of encouraging private sector compliance under threat of legislation, a deep commitment to competition and liberalised final prices, a tradition of independent regulation and a significant capacity for institutional learning. Part of the problem faced by other jurisdictions is that some of the elements of the required institutional capability are not present and hence severely limit the capacity of the society to deliver a successful electricity reform. Another way of putting this, is to say that what we might call the Standard Reform Design as followed by the UK, Texas etc is a model with an institutional “fit” appropriate to those jurisdictions. Of course this is not to say that for a given jurisdiction an alternative and potentially equally successful model, more in keeping with the institutional environment, does not exist. It is merely to say that the Standard Reform Design to which the EU and the other reforming states are implicitly working will not be appropriate in many, if not most, jurisdictions. It is however worth pointing out that the UK’s (and one suspects, that of most other reforming states) institutional capabilities in the area of recent electricity reforms have been recently acquired and have not always been present. That said, it is true that a striking conclusion from a comprehensive survey of the electricity deregulation process in the UK is how impressive the British civil service was in designing and implementing a comprehensive reform, from scratch, in less than two years (Henney, 1994). To come full circle: I think there is an appropriate balancing of liberalisation and appropriate regulation in a given electricity system. However I think that the leading jurisdictions in electricity reform challenge everyone else to justify why reform ought not to be extended into areas previously thought to be unsuited to competition. This challenge seems particularly appropriate in the US where the contrast (at the state level) between leaders and laggards in reform seems marked and without much institutional logic (in the La Porta
EBL
xxxii
Competitive Electricity Markets
et al. and Bordo sense), though one can undoubtedly come up with theories to explain them (the Joskow, 1997, discussion of reform attitude and pre-reform price being the most economically satisfying). In other countries however the argument for the balance to be set in different places becomes easier to justify on the basis of differences in institutional capability. The challenge posed by this is then to improve institutional capability in order to exploit the possible gains from electricity liberalisation. The real prize for proceeding with this is an electricity system capable of fully harnessing the power of competitive forces to respond to an uncertain future for the world’s energy markets in the face of environmental, technological and geopolitical challenges. Acknowledgements This paper is based on a talk to the 3rd Annual Regulation Seminar, SBGI, 15 March 2007. The author is grateful for the ongoing financial support of the ESRC Electricity Policy Research Group. The comments of Perry Sioshansi, Paul Joskow, Stephen Littlechild and Andy Ford are gratefully acknowledged. All responsibility remains that of the author. References Averch, H. and Johnson, L.L. (1962). Behavior of the firm under regulatory constraint. Am. Econ. Rev., 52, 1052–69. Barmack, M., Kahn, E. and Tierney, S. (2007). A cost-benefit assessment of wholesale electricity restructuring and competition in New England. J. Reg. Econ., 31(2), 151–184. Baumol, W.J., Ordover, J.A., and Willig, R.D. (1997). Parity pricing and its Critics: A necessary condition for efficiency in the provision of bottleneck services to competitors. Yale. J. Regul., 14(1), 145–63. Berg, S.V. and Jeong, J. (1991). An evaluation of incentive regulation for electric utilities. J.Regul. Econ., 3(1), 45–55. Bergman, L., Neven, D.J., Gual, J., et al. (1998). Monitoring European Deregulation: vol.1: Europe’s Network Industries: Conflicting Priorities (Telecommunications), London: Centre for Economic Policy Research. Bergman, L., Newbery, D.M.G., Pollitt, M., et al. (1999). Monitoring European deregulation: vol.2: A European market for electricity? London: Centre for Economic Policy Research. Bertram, G. (2006). Restructuring the New Zealand Electricity Sector 1984–2005. In Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective (F.P. Sioshansi and W. Pfaffenberger eds), Oxford: Elsevier, pp.203–34. Bordo, M. (2006). Sudden Stops, Financial Crises and Original Sin in Emerging Countries: Déjà vu? http://michael.bordo.googlepages.com/SuddenStops05–08.doc. Codognet, M-K. Glachant, J-M. Lévêque F.and Plagnet M-A. (2002). Mergers and acquisitions in the European electricity sector cases and patterns, CERNA, Centre d‘économie industrielle, Ecole Nationale Supérieure des Mines de Paris, August, Paris. Cohen, L.R. and Noll, R. (1991). The Technology Pork Barrel. Washington D.C.: Brookings Institute. Demsetz, H. (1968). Why regulate utilities?. J. Law. Econ., 11, 55–65. Domah, P.D. and Pollitt, M.G. (2001). The restructuring and privatisation of the regional electricity companies in England and Wales: A social cost benefit analysis. Fiscal Studies, 22(1), 107–46. Ellerman, A. and Dubroeucq, F. (2004). The Sources of Emission Reductions: Evidence from U.S. SO2, MIT CEEPR Working Paper, 004–001. European Commission (2007). DG Competition Report on Energy Sector Inquiry. Brussels: European Commission. Fri, R.W. (2003). The role of knowledge: Technological innovation in the energy system, The Energy Journal, 24(4), 51–74. Green, R. (1995). The cost of nuclear power compared with alternatives to the magnox programme. Oxf. Econ. Pap., 47, 513–24.
EBL
Foreword: Liberalization and Regulation in Electricity Systems
xxxiii
Green, R., Lorenzoni, A., Perez, Y. and Pollitt, M. (2005). Policy assessment and good practices. In Sustainable Energy Specific Support Assessment (SESSA): Conference on implementing the internal market of electricity: proposals and timetables, 9 September 2005, Brussels. Green, R. and McDaniel, T. (1998). Competition in electricity supply: Will “1998” Be Worth It? Fiscal Studies, 19(3), 273–93. Fabrizio, K., Rose, N. and Wolfram, C. (2007). Do markets reduce costs? Assessing the impact of regulatory restructuring on U.S. Electric Generation Efficiency. Am. Econ. Rev., 97(4), 1250–77. Hattori, T. and M. Tsutsui (2004). Economic impact of regulatory reforms in the electricity supply industry: A panel data analysis for OECD countries. Energy Policy, 32(6), 823–32. Henderson, P.D. (1977). Two british errors: Their probable size and some possible lessons, Oxf. Econ. Pap., 29(2), 159–205. Henney, A. (1994). A Study of the Privatisation of the Electricity Supply Industry in England and Wales, London: EEE Ltd. Jamasb, T., Mota, R., Newbery, D., and Pollitt, M. (2004). Electricity sector reform in developing countries: A survey of empirical evidence on determinants and performance. Cambridge Working Papers in Economics, No.0439. Jamasb, T. and Pollitt, M. (2001). Benchmarking and regulation: International electricity experience. Utilities Policy, 9(3), 107–30. Jamasb, T. and Pollitt, M. (2005). Electricity market reform in the European Union: review of progress toward liberalization and integration, The Energy Journal, 26(Special Issue), 11–41. Jamasb, T. and Pollitt, M. (2007). Incentive Regulation of Electricity Distribution Networks: Lessons of Experience from Britain, Energy Policy, 35(12), 6163–6187. Joskow, P. L. (1997). Restructuring, Competition and Regulatory Reform in the U.S. Electricity Sector. J. Econ. Perspect., 11(3), 119–38. Joskow, P. L. (2005). Incentive Regulation in Theory and Practice: Electricity Distribution and Transmission Networks, EPRG Working Paper 05/11. Joskow, P. L. (2006a). The Future of Nuclear Power in the United States: Economic and Regulatory Challenges, AEI-Brookings Joint Center for Regulatory Studies, Working Paper 06–25. Joskow, P.L. (2006b). Markets for Power in the United States: An Interim Assessment. The Energy Journal, 27(1), 1–36. Kaserman, D.L. and Mayo, J.W. (1991). The measurement of vertical economies and the efficient structure of the electric utility industry. J. Ind. Econ., 39(5), 483–502. La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., and Vishny, R. (1999). The quality of government. J. Law. Econ. Org., 15, 222–79. Littlechild, S.C. (2000). Privatization, Competition, and Regulation in the British Electricity Industry, With implications for Developing Countries, Energy Sector Management Assistance Program (ESMAP), February, World Bank. Littlechild, S.C. (2002). Competition in retail electricity supply. Journal des Economists et des Etudes Humaines, Vol.12(2/3), June/September, pp.379–402. Available as CMI Electricity Project Working Paper, No.09. Littlechild, S.C. and Skerk, C.J. (2004). Regulation of transmission expansion in Argentina Part I: State ownership, reform and the Fourth Line, CMI Electricity Project Working Paper, No.61. Mota, R. (2004). Restructuring and Privatisation of Electricity Distribution and Supply Business in Brazil: A Social Cost-Benefit Analysis, CMI Electricity Project Working Paper, No.16. Nemoto, J. and Goto, M. (2004). Technological externalities and economies of vertical integration in the electric utility industry. Inter. J. Ind. Org., 22(1), 67–81. Newbery, D. (2006). Electricity liberalization in Britain and the evolution of market design. In Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective (F.P. Sioshansi and W. Pfaffenberger eds), Oxford: Elsevier, pp. 109–44. Newbery, D.M.G. and Pollitt, M.G. (1997). Restructuring and Privatisation of the CEGB – was it worth it? Journal of Industrial Economics, 45(3), 269–304. New Zealand Ministry of Economic Development (2000). Inquiry into the Electricity Industry, June 2000. http://www.electricityinquiry.govt.nz/reports/final/final-01.html Ofgem (1999). Reviews of Public Electricity Suppliers 1998 to 2000 – Distribution Price Control Review – Final Proposals, December 1999, London: Ofgem.
EBL
xxxiv
Competitive Electricity Markets
Peltzman, S. (1976). Towards a more general theory of regulation. Journal of Law and Economics, 14, 109–47. Pollitt, M.G. (2004). Electricity reform in chile: Lessons for developing countries. J. Net. Ind., 5(3–4), 221–62. Sioshansi, F.P. and Pfaffenberger, W. (eds.) (2006). Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective. Oxford: Elsevier. Steiner, F. (2001). Regulation, industry structure and performance in the electricity supply industry. OECD Economic Studies, No. 32. Stigler, G. (1971). The theory of economic regulation. Bell. J. Econ., 2, 3–21. Sweeney, J.L. (2006). California electricity restructuring, the crisis and its aftermath. In Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective (F.P. Sioshansi and W. Pfaffenberger eds), Oxford: Elsevier, pp. 319–82. Thomas, S. (2006). The grin of the Cheshire cat. Energy Policy, 34(15), 1974–83. Toba, N. (2007). Welfare Impacts of Electricity Generation Sector Reform in the Philippines, Energy Policy, 35(12), 6145–6162.
EBL
Preface: Competition and Long-Term Dimensions of Electricity Supply WOLFGANG PFAFFENBERGER Jacobs University Bremen
Has market reform in the ESI been a success story? To judge on this question we need well-defined criteria. Such criteria based on social welfare need to have a time horizon. In this introduction we ask what market opening can contribute to the long-term problems of electricity supply. Availability of energy resources, restrictions of carbon emissions, social preferences for the energy mix are some of the important dimensions of the future of electricity. This preface concentrates on the role competition can play regarding these dimensions and the appropriate regulatory mix to reconcile long-term expectations with short-term efficiency gains. The availability of energy, especially electricity, is one of the basic preconditions of modern life. Price development in recent years has indicated scarcity of energy resources. The future availability of energy for electricity production is one of the central questions for the development of modern society: how much energy in what form and at what price will be available in the future and what technologies will be used for transforming primary energy resources into electricity? Market opening in the ESI was basically driven by the wish to increase short-term benefits for consumers. This preface asks how market opening and competition can contribute to solving the longer-term problems as described in the first paragraph. This exposition is intended to ask a number of questions regarding future developments and the view taken is strongly influenced by experience with market opening in central Europe. Market restructuring on the one hand and the solutions developed for the longer-term problem of securing energy supply on the other have to be taken together. Competition in the ESI has been promoted by legislators in many countries to
EBL
• •
raise the industry’s operational and allocative efficiencies; and promote internal and external trade in the industry to make use of comparative advantages between different market participants, different regions, and countries.
Although there are many differences between market opening approaches in different countries due to their historically given institutional and political structures, a lot of similarities can be found.1 How successful are market reform measures? To find out about the success of institutional reforms we need to have an idea of the performance of a properly functioning competitive market and use it as a benchmark for the performance of the industry in its present market setup. This is not a trivial task because it is difficult to interpret market 1 See Joskow, P. (2006). Introduction to electricity sector liberalization: Lessons learned from cross-country studies. In Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective (F.P. Sioshansi, and W. Pfaffenberger, eds), Amsterdam, pp. 1–32.
xxxv
xxxvi
Competitive Electricity Markets
results unambiguously as a result of the prevailing market rules. In fact, it is almost impossible to give a definition of competition. Competition is an open process, which produces unexpected results. This understanding of markets goes back to Hayek and his idea of markets as a spontaneous order: The key idea of the spontaneous-order thesis is that self-organizing and self-replicating structures arise without even the possibility of design. To simulate the efficiency of the market order by central planning is impossible for epistemic reasons. The norm system underlying the extended order of a free society was not designed, not invented, and only retrospectively can we recognize it as the condition for retaining at least what we have got.2 Thus to design a market is a contradiction in itself. Typically, markets are created by actors within the market, and not creators or designers from outside. “The market is not simply ‘there’, given by nature, but has to be formed or produced. The producers of a market (‘market makers’) are themselves market actors.” 3 Is this general principle also applicable in electricity markets, where outsiders define and design the market and establish the rules and then the players function according to the rules laid out? One of the general principles of competition policy therefore has always been to define conditions that do not allow the development of competition rather than trying to give a positive definition of what competition is or should be. The expectations regarding the effects of competition on the short-term performance of the industry are often high and political intervention is often based on such expectations. Interventions into market rules are caused by such short-term considerations and often promised results for consumer benefits cannot be achieved. The interface between industry and state intervention is a fundamental problem of a market economy in a democratic society. In the words of Furubotn and Richter:
EBL
The decisive difference between economic and political competition is that economic competition is the struggle for economic advantages through economic exchange. It occurs on the basis of secure property rights. Political competition, on the other hand, is the struggle for authority, that is, the power to change exactly these property rights – unilaterally without any economic quid pro quo. Thus, in politics, property rights are “up for grabs,” not only economic rights but also …“political property rights,” the rights to exercise public authority. As a result, institutional frameworks may change frequently in a democracy and thus may be quite unstable.4 If you take the view of economic actors in the playing field, you will come to different conclusions regarding the desired institutional setup than if you take the view of a government feeling pressed to present successful interventions to placate to the short-term expectations of voters, most of whom are small-scale consumers. Moreover, the time horizon of the typical legislator is often much shorter than the lifetime of physical assets in the energy industry. Economists are brought up in the spirit of free markets and are generally skeptical of government intervention. Their advice usually is to leave markets alone, assuming that 2
Radnitzky, G. (1984). Die ungeplante Gesellschaft – Friedrich von Hayeks Theorie der Evolution spontaner Ordnungen und selbstorganisierender Systeme. Hamburger Jahrbuch für Wirtschafts- und Gesellschaftspolitik, 29, 9 ff. 3 Furubotn, E. and Richter, R. (2005). Institutions and economic theory, 2nd ed., Ann Arbor, 314. 4 Furubotn, E. and Richter, R. (2005). Institutions and economic theory, 2nd ed., Ann Arbor, 482.
Preface: Competition and Long-Term Dimensions of Electricity Supply
xxxvii
they are competitive, fair, and transparent. Due to the network orientation of the ESI, competition is, of course, not possible in all segments of the industry. In the ESI, transport and distribution constitute a monopolistic bottleneck for generation and supply and therefore need to be regulated. Competition in generation and supply depends on regulated network access at fair conditions for all market participants. Due to the physical integration of production, network, and supply, the regulation in transport and distribution will also have consequences for the potentially competitive parts of the system in generation and supply. Therefore regulators may be tempted to also look at the competitive parts of the industry. This, in addition to the different historically grown institutions in many countries, is the reason for different approaches to competition in this industry. Basically, we can distinguish two concepts: The first, free market with minimum regulation, puts the emphasis on the freedom of the market and tries to restrict regulation to the minimum required to allow competition5 ; the second, market results for price and investment, puts the emphasis on regulation and basically wants to achieve certain market results with regard to price development and security of supply issues particularly regarding investment in generation. The two concepts are theoretical extremes and in the real world we can find a mixture of elements of both concepts.
Free Market with Minimum Regulation
EBL
A free market requires privatization of public companies, an appropriate form of vertical separation of transmission and distribution and ancillary services from the competitive segments and free network access at fair conditions. In addition, all the usual control instruments against the misuse of market power need to exist and to be used. It is debatable whether network prices need to be regulated explicitly or implicitly by using the instruments against the misuse of market power on a case-by-case basis. In the second case, the effects may be as good as in the case of full-scale regulation but at much lower bureaucratic cost. Vertical integration in the power industry is the result of economic incentives because specialized assets in generation, transmission, and distribution need to be combined physically and vertical integration is the answer to reduce risk and transaction cost.6 Full vertical integration, however, is an obstacle to competition so that some form of disintegration is necessary for competition. The tradeoff between vertical integration and unbundling does not automatically favor a full-scale unbundling,7 including ownership unbundling as presently envisioned by the European Commission for the European power market. In a free market we expect that the market, to a large extent, invents itself and also develops rules for interaction as part of the game and through contractual relationships. This can only take effect, however, if government and legislation restrict their activity to the absolute minimum as described above. 5 See Knieps, G. (2006). Sector specific market power regulation versus general competition law: Criteria for judging competitive versus regulated markets. In Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective (F.P. Sioshansi, and W. Pfaffenberger, eds), Amsterdam, pp. 49–74. 6 Douma, S. and Schreuder, H. (2003). Economic approaches to organizations, 3rd ed., Harlow, 203. 7 See Chao, H., Oren, S., and Wilson, R. (this book). Reevaluation of Vertical Integration und Unbundling in Restructured Electricity Markets. Chapter 1.
xxxviii
Competitive Electricity Markets
Market Price and Investment In the time before liberalization of the energy markets when vertically integrated companies prevailed, energy services were often considered an infrastructure good so that a high level of public interest and regulation was the countervailing power to the market power of the local or regional vertically integrated monopolies. After market opening, the focus of regulation should shift to supporting the development of competition by adequate institutions and not look at day to day market results. This is often not the case. Regulation often goes far beyond the required minimum for the market to function. In a free market one would expect that generators would choose the mix of technology and primary energy they find suitable to minimize price and quantity risks. In addition, one would expect them to decide on the capacity they find adequate. On the other hand, the public has views on the energy mix and may restrict the choice of technology/energy and may want a higher security of supply so that a certain control of investment may be established. Governments may also want to protect consumers against price risks. Such a protective regulation hardly fits into a market environment and is a contradiction in itself. Such a regulation which had its reason in the time of development of the industry and was meant to allow universal access to the services of the industry during its infancy is outdated when the diffusion of the product has reached a high level. We observe however, that political institutions often live much longer than their intended purpose. It is a basic principle of a market economy that those who bear the risks should have the freedom to make decisions. This is true for producers and consumers assuming that the marketplace allows enough possibilities of choice. There is a general tension between intervention and market and this is particularly important in the energy industry due to its special features. Regulatory systems in different countries often represent a mix of the basic concepts of competition and the pure market model can hardly be found. In the following a few key questions are posed regarding the implementation of the market model.
EBL
Choice of Primary Energy Can markets with a high degree of regulation reach an energy mix favorable for customers? Sources for low-cost energies are restricted partly by natural factors and partly by political decision, e.g., in the case of nuclear energy. The implication of this can be seen from Fig. 1. Whereas the United Kingdom is often considered as a functional model for a competitive market (e.g., low degree of market concentration in generation, ownership unbundling in transmission), its performance in recent years as measured by the wholesale prices is much worse than in central European countries. This is partly due to the insular situation and mainly a result of the power mix with a high share of natural gas and an attempt to escape the rising gas prices by going back to coal, which resulted in a net import of carbon certificates at high prices at certain times. A perfect market model and short-termoriented optimization does not automatically lead to better performance. So what kind of freedom do utility companies need to reduce energy price and quantity risks in the longer term? Do they need a more long-term orientation and in what relation is this to the time horizon of policymakers? There definitely is a tradeoff between freedom in the market and regulation.8 8
This topic is also addressed by Michael Pollitt, Foreword, this volume.
Preface: Competition and Long-Term Dimensions of Electricity Supply
xxxix
Wholesale prices front year base 90
France
UK 80
Netherlands Germany
EUR/MWh
70
60
Nordic
Belgium
50
40
30
Source: EST 20 10.1.03
10.5.03
10.9.03
10.1.04
10.5.04
10.9.04
10.1.05
10.5.05
10.9.05
10.1.06
10.5.06
10.9.06
10.1.07
EBL
Fig. 1. European wholesale prices, Source: EST (2007).
Market Integration In Fig. 1, the Nordic countries, which are only partly connected to the central European grid, have a considerably lower price level than the rest of Europe. This can be explained to a large extent by the energy mix with a high share of low-cost hydro and nuclear. A higher degree of integration with the rest of Europe through higher transmission capacities would lead to price adjustment between the Nordic and the central European market. This could be in the interest of the producing companies in the Nordic market as they could earn additional profits because marginal capacities in central Europe would set the price in the market. But is this in the interest of Nordic consumers or governments? In the longer run, according to the standard economic paradigm, the comparative advantage of the low-cost producers should lead to an increase in low-cost capacities. Prices would adjust to the level of low-cost producers and capacities would migrate from high-cost producers to low-cost producers. But is this likely to happen? In reality this is highly unrealistic because low-cost production possibilities are scarce due to many, often political, restrictions. Taking this into account what will be the optimum market integration and to what extent should transmission capacities be expanded? Generally, the open market approach only makes sense if enough freedom of choice exists so that considerable reallocation effects can be expected. If there are too many restrictions in the system, market opening will lead to redistribution without reallocation. To give an example: Hydro power producers in Austria are happy to supply German networks with reserve power to compensate for fluctuations of wind energy at an increasing rate. This leads to windfall profits in Austria because the marginal capacity in Germany is coal-fired and has a much higher variable cost. From the point of view of allocation this makes
xl
Competitive Electricity Markets
sense, but will this increase the acceptance of markets in public and in the political system if consumer prices in Austria are also rising? Renewable Energy The promotion of renewable energy as a substitute for fossil fuels in many countries is often achieved outside of the market mechanism, because the willingness of consumers to pay for the quality differential is not sufficient to compensate for the higher cost of many renewable options, at least at current prices. After a certain level of renewable penetration has been reached, this of course distorts the market process if one section of the market lives behind a protective fence and the other has to adjust to whatever happens behind that fence. This is particularly true if renewable production is stochastic as in the case of wind. Conventional producers have to adjust their output and portfolio to the dynamics of the renewable generators without adequate compensation, whereas the production of renewables is often kept free of market risks. The question then arises: what is the best approach for market integration of renewables regarding financial support and system integration?9 There are two reasons for the promotion of renewables: Substitution of scarce fossil resources and reduction of greenhouse gas emissions. The question is, whether the signals given to the market by the political instruments for promoting renewables are consistent with these goals and the investment incentives or disincentives for conventional generation are consistent with the necessary backup function of the conventional generation section. This can only be achieved if reserve power needed for stabilizing renewable generation is integrated into the scheme of promotion. In Europe the now existing system of CO2 certificates in itself gives signals to the market regarding the portfolio of desired generation based on the carbon content of fuels used. This leads to a relative advantage for carbon-free renewables because the production cost of fuels with carbon content will rise depending on the quantity of certificates allocated to electricity generation. Again, the question to ask is whether this leads to a set of signals consistent with the other signals produced by promotion schemes for renewables. Assuming that the introduction of competition in the ESI leads to efficiency gains, it is quite likely that the economic and financial implications of support schemes for renewables are reaching levels that become much higher than any efficiency gains that can be reached through competition in the core of the electricity market. The economic relevance of competition is reduced unless schemes of promotion are made to fit much better into the competitive market. Increasing the share of renewables to a relevant size like the envisaged share of 20% in the European Union (EU) in the future will lead to a number of new questions regarding the market environment as a whole.
EBL
Miracle Competition? Intensity of competition depends strongly on the maturity of a market. In a mature market with low growth and high economies of scale, as is typical for electricity generation in developed countries, competition between existing generators will make it difficult for newcomers to enter the market. Existing generators with a historically grown portfolio of new (expensive) and old (cheap) plants and a developed set of customer relations 9
See Chapter by Haas et al., Chapter 12, this volume, for further details.
Preface: Competition and Long-Term Dimensions of Electricity Supply
xli
can reduce the risks considerably. Thus the threshold for intensive competition may be high. But does it make sense to increase the number of generators by separating existing companies and thereby increasing the risks and transaction cost?
Customer Switching Electricity is a commodity, and one with few opportunities for differentiation or added value. Still, customers may develop preferences for certain suppliers due to confidence or added services. Customer behavior, particularly by small customers, is strongly influenced by the metering and billing services and the ease of available payment options. For most consumer goods, market extraction and payment are synchronized, so that price and expenditure are experienced in the context of market extraction. In the electricity market there is no such direct connection between consumption and payment. Price and consumption are therefore not directly related as is true for most other consumer goods. It is often said that the intensity of competition can be measured by the number of customers who switch suppliers. This is certainly true for industrial and commercial companies with a professional purchasing department. It may, however, not be true for residential customers. Consumers tend to develop habits and use certain suppliers regularly. A significant price differential may be needed to change that habit – which is difficult to imagine for smaller consumers. If the competitive advantage is smaller than the margin required to make the consumer move, little switching will occur. From the point of view of the supplier, it makes sense to try to find out about that margin and keep the supply price within that margin against competitive offers. The stability arising from such a behavior certainly is a result of competition. Low switching rates are not an unambiguous proof of low degree of competition. It rather depends on availability of access and transparency of the market. After all, certain price differences can be found in all markets for goods with homogenous quality. Compare the prices for branded goods between two adjacent supermarkets and you will find a lot of differences; still, all items in both markets will sell. This can be explained by imperfect information, transaction costs as well as bounded rationality.10 We should not expect the “perfect consumer” in the power market. In the power market for residential customers it is only the competitive part of total price that matters for competition. Depending on the level of consumption, the regulated network fees, taxes, and levies, this competitive fraction of the price may be relatively small and below the margin that would induce customer switching. The German example may be extreme. For the average residential customer, after deducting taxes, levies, and regulated network fees, the competitive part of the power price is about 25% of the total. In absolute terms, a residential customer can earn $5–10 per year by switching suppliers, probably below the threshold for switching for most consumers. It is, however, necessary to have open competition so that suppliers are under pressure from potential competition; on the other hand the competitive advantage will always be relatively small for smallish consumers. How relevant then is competition in the small retail market for social welfare? Is it not the wholesale market that really matters because the advantage of reallocation and trade within the system as a whole leads to a relevant size of efficiency gains?11
EBL
10
See Douma, S. and Schreuder, H. (2003). Economic Approaches to Organizations, 3rd ed., Harlow, chapter 4 and chapter 8. 11 See also Joskow, P. (2006). Electricity Market Reform, p. 23.
xlii
Competitive Electricity Markets
Unbundling Nearly everyone agrees that a certain degree of vertical separation is necessary to allow competition. But how far should it go and should it be physical or functional? The European Commission is proposing a complete ownership unbundling for EU member countries. The unmentioned but real agenda behind this policy seems to be a desire to develop a pan European network that would be much easier to unify if national gridcos are independent from all other interests and can be merged much more easily into a pan European company. The Commission seems to think that such a scheme would help in addressing some pressing matters such as the future availability of primary energy import, help to reduce energy cost, and support European economic development. Cooperation between European grids has worked quite well in the past, there definitely will be new challenges for the grids in the future with rising energy trade, the increasing share of renewables and rising distance between point of production and consumption. This is a long-run problem that has lots of highly technical implications. Gridcos and regulators have to cooperate to develop the necessary solutions. But it seems difficult to see these future challenges being met without a clear bottom-up approach. Playing around with institutions from a central perspective might do more harm and delay the necessary development. Conclusion Around the year 2000 the paradise of abundant and relatively cheap energies came to an end. At the same time the industrial world has to accept the challenges of becoming more import dependent and having to restrict the use of fossil fuels to achieve greenhouse gas reductions. This implies a lot of fundamental changes for primary energies and technologies to be used, for the role of distributed generation, for network operation and development. Competition is an important element to achieve the changes required. But there seems to be a tradeoff between the short-term goals of customer benefit and the long-term goal of promotion of structural change including smaller share of fossil fuels, less greenhouse gas emissions. For the latter, investment incentive is the main topic. New products and technologies require adequate prices. Short-term gains maybe long-term losses! In the long term, governments have to define clear goals regarding the desired energy mix and environmental targets. Markets can then work to achieve these goals if they are left with the necessary freedom to experiment with technology and earn rates of return including the risks for innovative action. The power market is not an isolated market. We have to consider it as part of the whole industry. By regulating the power market too tightly, we also indirectly regulate all the markets that produce specific assets for the power industry. This may not be compatible with long-term goals.
EBL
Introduction: Electricity Market Reform – Progress and Remaining Challenges FEREIDOON P. SIOSHANSI Menlo Energy Economics
Summary For over two decades, policymakers and regulators in a number of countries around the world have been grappling with market reform, liberalization, restructuring, and privatization of the electric power sector. While a great deal has been achieved – including many useful lessons in what works, what does not, and why – successful design and implementation of market reform still remains partly art. Moreover, the international experience to date indicates that, in nearly all cases, initial market reform leads to unintended and occasionally unpleasant consequences or introduces new concerns and risks that must be addressed in subsequent “reform of the reforms.” This introduction provides an overview of the market reform experience, identifies a number of challenging issues facing regulators and policymakers, and provides the context for the remaining chapters of the book, which cover these topics in detail.
EBL
Electricity Market Reform: An Overview Since the mid-1980s, a number of countries around the world have engaged in market reform initiatives including liberalization, privatization, and/or restructuring the electricity supply industry (ESI). Box 1 describes terminology of different approaches to market reform. The motivations for changing the organization of the industry and the regulatory paradigm vary from case to case, but are generally driven by a desire to introduce competition in the hope of making the industry more efficient, making prices more transparent, and transferring more risks to private investors rather than ratepayers or taxpayers. The ensuing productivity improvements, better rationalization of labor and fuel costs, superior choice of generation technologies, allocation of investment risks, and other measures are believed to lead to lower electricity costs and improved services benefiting ultimate consumers. Chile is generally credited as the first country to undertake a major market reform process in 1987 (Raineri, 2006). England and Wales followed with a privatization and liberalization scheme in 1989 – which has been widely studied and copied (Newbery, 2006). Since then, the pattern has been repeated in a number of countries large and small (Table 1). 1
2
Competitive Electricity Markets
Box 1 Taxonomy of key market reform terms Terminology used to describe different approaches to change the regulatory paradigm Restructuring is a broad term, referring to attempts to reorganize the roles of the market players and the regulator, and/or redefine the rules of the game, but not necessarily “deregulate” the market. California, for example, restructured its market, “deregulated” its wholesale market by lifting nearly all restrictions to how wholesale prices could be set by generators, but kept its retail market fully “regulated,” in this case capped. Many problems ensued. Liberalization is synonymous with restructuring. It refers to attempts to introduce competition in some or all segments of the market, and remove barriers to trade and exchange. The European Union (EU), for example, refers to their efforts under this umbrella term. Privatization generally refers to selling government-owned assets to the private sector, as was done in Victoria, Australia, with former SECV, in Italy with ENEL, and in France with EdF and GdF. It must be noted that one can liberalize the market without necessarily privatizing the industry, as has successfully been done in Norway and in New South Wales, in Australia. Corporatization generally refers to attempts to make state-owned enterprises (SOEs) to look, act, and behave as if they were for-profit, private entities. In this case, an SOE is made into a corporation with the government treasury as the single shareholder. For example, former SOEs in New South Wales (NSW), Australia, have been corporatized. They vigorously compete with one another, while all belong to the same, single shareholder, namely the Government of NSW. Deregulation is essentially a misnomer. No electricity market has been (or, in fact, can be) fully deregulated. Experience suggests that even well-functioning competitive markets need a regulator, or as a minimum, a market monitoring and anticartel authority.∗ Until recently, Germany was the only major country attempting to go without a regulator but with an anticartel office, monitoring the behavior of the market participants.
EBL
Source: Sioshansi, F. and Pfaffenberger, W. (2006). Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective. Elsevier. ∗ The issue of how much regulation is needed and in what form is an open-ended issue. Most economists agree that electricity markets, at the minimum, need a market operator or manger to regulate the flow of power. There is also a general consensus that electricity markets need a market monitor to prevent monopolistic or opportunistic behavior. Most electricity markets also have a regulator to enforce the laws and the rules and to continue regulating the network components of business, which remain regulated even after liberalization. There is little agreement on what is the proper role and style of regulator because of ideological and political differences of opinion. Some economists do not see any need for a powerful and/or interventionist regulator any more than such a regulator is needed for the auto or tire industry.
Introduction
3
Table 1. Selected countries with electricity market reform Country
Market reform highlights and comments
Argentina
Has experienced problems due to external economic crises.
Australia
Various dates in various states, some states have privatized, others corporatized, resulting in uneven playing field. Generally considered a successful market despite some remaining problems further described in this volume.
Brazil
Initial market reforms continue to be modified due to problems with initial market design, further covered in this volume.
Canada
Alberta and Ontario introduced competition. Ontario has rescinded it following public pressure after price increases; Alberta has succeeded, progress stalled in other provinces.
Chile
First to introduce market reform in 1987, continues to evolve.
Colombia
Introduced market reform in 1994–95, is experiencing problems in retail, wholesale, and capacity markets, reform of reforms in progress.
England and Wales
Introduced radical privatization and restructuring in 1989, has gone through at least three major phases of reform, continues to evolve, has been widely studied and copied as a successful model.
European Union
25 members of EU continue to make slow progress, various deadlines for unbundling and introduction of retail competition have been set but not fully implemented, full retail competition was introduced in July 2007 but has not significantly changed the status quo, the goal of a fully integrated pan-European market remains elusive despite the best efforts of the EC policymakers.
EBL
Japan
Has introduced limited competition to date with a cautious pace, Japan Electric Power Exchange (JEPX) is in place but there is limited volume of trading.
South Korea*
Has created Korea Power Exchange (KPX) and broken up KEPCO into several generation companies. Full liberalization, however, has stalled due to political and labor opposition.
New Zealand
Experienced some problems in the absence of a regulator, which has been introduced; has a rather complicated nodal pricing scheme.
Nordic countries
Considered among the most successful markets based on bilateral trading, has expanded to include all Nordic countries, market survived a major drought without meltdown.
Singapore*
Considered successful despite a small market, limited number of players, and a complicated nodal pricing regime.
Thailand*
Liberalization and privatization stalled due to labor union opposition and lack of political support.
United States
Wholesale competition encouraged since 1992 with passage of Energy Policy Act and considered successful; retail competition introduced in selected markets since 1998 with mixed results, progress stalled after California electricity crisis in 2000–01, no retail progress since opening of Texas market in 2002.
Note: * Not covered in Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective (2006: Elsevier). Source: Compiled from various chapters of Sioshansi, F. and Pfaffenberger, W. (2006). Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective, Elsevier; and other sources.
4
Competitive Electricity Markets
Even when the initial design of the reformed market is sound, the implementation and transition process can go astray, sometimes with serious consequences. This may be among the reasons why market reform initiatives have all but stalled in the United States following the much-publicized failure of the California market in 2000–01. Faced with these uncertainties and risks, the introduction of market reform in South Korea and Thailand, to name a few examples, has stalled. The politicians in both countries face significant opposition from the unions and others who want to maintain the status quo. In the meantime, market reform proponents cannot guarantee tangible and immediate benefits that make it politically untenable to push for market reform. In some cases, such as in Thailand or India, the status quo, while not efficient, offers significant price subsidies to key segments of the population. The recipients of these subsidies do not favor a liberalized market that would most likely eliminate the subsidies at the first opportunity. In the case of Thailand, one study reportedly concluded that to attract sufficient foreign investment, the country’s average wholesale prices would have to be raised by 25% or more. Such a price increase, while necessary to attract foreign investment, would hardly be popular with the voters. Likewise, the liberalization of the power sector in India, another country with massive need for new infrastructure investment, is beset by chronic price subsidies to large segments of population and hampered by institutional obstacles. In the case of Japan, which has one of the highest electricity prices among developing countries, policymakers have decided to proceed incrementally and at a cautious pace (Goto and Yajima, 2006). The risk of unsettling the status quo, which in the case of Japan provides high levels of reliability at a stable but high price, is among the reasons cited for the government’s measured approach. The book Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective (Sioshansi and Pfaffenberger, eds, 2006) provides an overview of market reform initiatives in a number of countries around the world and draws useful comparisons of what appears to be working, what does not, and why. Among other things, the book points out some of the major lessons that have been learned, sometimes at great expense, from various schemes to introduce market reform in the ESI. While much has been learned in the process and a blueprint has emerged (Joskow, 2006a), market reform still remains partly art and not all science. Moreover, the international experience to date indicates that in most cases, initial market reform leads to unintended consequences that must be addressed in subsequent “reform of the reforms,” to borrow from (Joskow, 2006a). Aside from this, market reform in many countries has introduced new problems, risks, and concerns, some of which are not fully resolved. Addressing some of these remaining issues is the main objective of the present volume.
EBL
Market Design, Implementation Challenges, and Reform of the Reforms The introduction of market reform generally – but not necessarily – follows something along the following lines: The process usually starts with an acknowledgment of problems and/or deficiencies associated with the existing system – prompting a search for alternative ways to organize, operate, manage, and regulate the ESI. Motivation to fix real or perceived problems is usually prompted by gross inefficiencies in operation and/or performance, poor system reliability, high prices, supply inadequacies, inadequate investment in infrastructure, or a combination of these.
Introduction
5
The old adage, “If it ain’t broke, don’t fix it,” generally applies in the sense that if retail prices are low, supplies are adequate, and the system operates reliably and with tolerable efficiency, there is probably no compelling motivation to change. This is evident in the United States, where market reform initiatives have been largely confined to states with above-average costs. Lower-cost states have, by and large, stayed on the sidelines so far and do not appear inclined to introduce market reform initiatives. The second stage usually starts with a debate on what is broke, and how best to fix it, i.e., the process leading to an alternative, hopefully superior, market design resulting in improved performance. With more experience gained over the past two decades, there is now a growing body of knowledge on the main features of market reform (e.g., Joskow, 2006a). In most cases, new laws must be passed and the organization of the ESI must be changed before a new market structure can be implemented. Typically, new institutions, such as a market operator and/or a power exchange as well as a new regulatory framework, must be created, usually at significant costs. There are risks in changing the status quo, and the skeptics or those who stand to lose from the market reform process have to be persuaded to go along. Winners and losers must reconcile their gains and pains. In developing countries, new institutional reforms are generally needed before market restructuring can be introduced. The third stage involves the actual implementation of the market design devised in the previous step. While the theory may be sound, there is no guarantee that the implementation will go smoothly or without major hiccups. In many cases, technically sound principles do not translate well in practice resulting in problems and chaos. For example, the introduction of retail competition to large numbers of residential and small commercial consumers has proven problematic logistically in nearly all markets. Likewise, the organization and operation of centrally dispatched market operators and various markets are not trivial. The fourth stage begins with the realization that the introduction of market reform does not necessarily or automatically lead to many of the expected benefits and outcomes. For example, while wholesale auctions generally result in vigorous competition among generators, this need not necessarily result in immediate lower retail costs for consumers. Even when average wholesale prices decline, prices typically become more volatile, creating demand for risk hedging strategies. Nor is there a guarantee that competition will attract additional investment to the electric power sector when there are significant regulatory or political uncertainties, or when politicians routinely interfere in key decisions as pointed out by Pfaffenberger in the Preface to this volume. Resource adequacy (RA) is identified as a concern in many reformed markets. In most cases, the initial market design may have inherent flaws that only become apparent after the passage of some time or during the course of an external event – be it a serious drought, a heat wave, currency devaluation, economic slump, or otherwise. These events occasionally derail what could otherwise have been an acceptable outcome. Fuel price increases unrelated to the market reform process, for example, can result in significantly higher retail prices, eroding the political support for market reform.1 In nearly all cases, initial market reform has led to unforeseen and unintended consequences that must be addressed in subsequent “reform of the reforms.”
EBL
1 In the United States, restructuring in a number of states is under attack because the initial reform process legislated a rollback in retail prices, which were frozen for a period of time. The expiration of these frozen rates has resulted in public resentment for the restructuring process.
6
Competitive Electricity Markets
The fifth and final stage, usually an ongoing process, involves dealing with the problems associated with the initial market design flaws, flaws in implementation, or unanticipated problems resulting from external factors or events. Droughts, fuel price increases, market dominance of few key players, uneven competition resulting from an uneven playing field, poor and/or ineffective market monitoring and regulation, and inadequate investment in infrastructure are among the reasons often cited for the need for subsequent political or regulatory meddling in the market. Partly for these reasons, the introduction of market reform has been eventful with decidedly mixed results internationally. In a few cases, notably in California, well-publicized disasters have dampened interest in neighboring regions or states. In some cases, politicians were able to weather initial kinks, allowing markets to do what they are supposed to do, as in Alberta, Canada. In other cases, as in the Province of Ontario, the politicians withdrew their support of market reform at the first sign of trouble – allowing a temporary aberration to derail the process before it had a chance to succeed (Treblicock and Hrab, 2006). By contrast, the Nordic market was able to withstand a significant drought with serious hardships but no market manipulation, no blackouts, and no collapse, reinforcing everyone’s faith in the market (Amundsen et al., 2006). Overall, the implementation of market reform has not been easy. The British market, for example, has arguably gone through at least three distinct reform stages, from the original, central, mandatory Pool in 1989 to the New Electricity Trading Arrangements (NETA) introduced in 2001, to the British Electricity Trading and Transmission Arrangements (BETTA), introduced in 2003. Newbery (2006) provides a summary of the evolution of the British market since inception. Likewise, Brazil has gone through several reincarnations of its original reform agenda, each addressing problems introduced by the previous reforms (Araujo, 2006). De Araújo et al. (Chapter 15) use Brazil as a case study of “the reform of the reforms,” describing the evolution of the market over time, including persistent problems that are still being addressed. The process of modifying and refining the original reforms continues in most countries and states including Chile (Raineri, 2006), Argentina, and Colombia (Dyner et al., 2006), and California (Sweeney, 2006), just to mention a few. Broadly speaking, the implementation of market reform has been more manageable in smallish, isolated markets. Large interconnected markets such as those in the United States and continental Europe have proven more challenging. In the latter case, separation of generation from the grid and supply has not been satisfactorily achieved, creating opportunities for some players to subsidize competitive functions from network-based regulated functions (Haas et al., 2006). Likewise, in some markets, notably Australia, some players remain state-owned while others have been privatized, resulting in an uneven playing field.2 In the European context, despite numerous European Commission (EC) directives with specific deadlines, market liberalization has stalled in a number of key countries, and there is little meaningful competition at the retail level in some countries. While a number of European countries have liberalized both electricity and gas markets, others have done so
EBL
2 Some experts do not regard the continued existence of public/private ownership as too serious of a problem. Moran, for example, believes that despite the distortion to the level playing field introduced by mixed ownership, “the market and its investment pattern has worked well to date” – at least in the Australian context. But even he admits that, “There are clear vulnerabilities where public ownership decisions are taken on the basis of matters other than commerciality.” (Refer to Chapter 11 by Moran and Skinner)
Introduction
7
only on paper, and even that has been accomplished grudgingly. The introduction of full market liberalization in the EU, which went into effect in July 2007, is viewed as a mere formality by some skeptics. In a survey article on European energy markets, The Economist (2006) identified the following three as the prime reasons for failure to create a competitive pan-European energy market: •
Deliberate state interference motivated by a desire to support so-called national energy champions. • Lack of interest by dominant players or governments to build additional transmission lines to facilitate cross-border trade. • Weak enforcement of EU directives at the country level. Needless to say, the EU’s long-term goal of creating a harmonious, fully integrated panEuropean energy market has not yet materialized. Instead, Europe has evolved into several distinct submarkets separated by chronic transmission bottlenecks, as in Fig. 1 (Haas et al., 2006). The result is continued retail price disparities and dominant players maintaining significant market power and market share in key markets (Fig. 2). Cornwall describes current EU efforts to create a fully integrated network in Europe3 . Similar obstacles frustrate regulators at the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) in the United States where progress is being made, albeit at a slow pace.4 In this case, FERC continues to push for the creation of a number of large independent system operators (ISOs), a critical step in introducing competition at the wholesale level and a precursor to competition at the retail level (O’Neill et al., 2006). More than half of the US generation capacity is now under control of a handful of large ISOs – with significant implications for retail markets (Table 2, and Fig. 3).
EBL
Europe 2
1
5
3 4
Fig. 1. Electricity sub-markets in Western Europe. Source: R. Haas, Vienna Technology University.
3 4
See chapter in this volume. Chapter 4 by Singh and Chapter 5 by Helman et al. provide further details.
Competitive Electricity Markets
8
Fig. 2. Electricity and gas prices in selected European countries, E ¢/kWh*. Source: The Economist, 11 February 2006 based on NUS Consulting results. ∗ Electricity prices based on April 2005 data for consumer with 1000 kW demand using 450,000 kWh/mo, excluding VAT. Natural gas prices based on September 2005 data for consumer using equivalent of 2,931,000 kWh/yr excluding VAT. Including VAT, which varies from country to country, would significantly add to costs.
Table 2. US wholesale markets under ISO or RTO control, 2005 System operator
EBL
Generating capacity (MW)
ISO New England (RTO) New York ISO PJM (expanded) (RTO) Midwest ISO (MISO) California ISO (CAISO) ERCOT (Texas) Southwest Power Pool (RTO)* ISO/RTO Total
31,000 37,000 164,000 130,000 52,000 78,000 60,000 552,000
Total US generating capacity
970,000
*Organized markets being developed. Source: Joskow, P. (2006b). Markets for power in the United States: An interim assessment. The Energ. J., 27(1).
In a survey article on the state of the US electricity market, Joskow concludes that “significant progress has been made on the wholesale competition front,” but adds, “The framework for retail competition has been less successful” (Joskow, 2006b). A study of the wholesale and retail markets by FERC came to similar conclusions (FERC, 2006). In the United States, the development of well-functioning, competitive power markets continues to be a work in progress.5 Even though California has soured many state 5 For a comprehensive discussion refer to FERC 2006, Report to Congress on competition in the wholesale and retail markets for electric energy, Washington, D.C., 5 June.
Introduction
9
Fig. 3. Operating ISOs and RTOs in the United States. Source: Report to Congress on competition in the wholesale and retail markets for electric energy, FERC, Washington, D.C., 5 June 2006.
regulators’ appetite for market reform, 20 states and the District of Columbia offer some form of customer choice to all or some of their customers6 (Fig. 4). But there is little doubt that the pace of transition to a national competitive electricity market has stalled in the United States (Fig. 5) for a number of reasons including:
EBL
•
The failure of the California market has left lingering concerns among some statelevel regulators and legislatures. • Mixed results in a number of other states that have introduced retail competition and are now facing “rate shocks” as the original retail price freezes are lifted.7 • Lingering problems in some wholesale markets that have not performed as expected. • Lack of interest by the US Congress to push retail competition at the national level.8 Form, function, and intent of regulation While there is consensus on the need for an independent and competent regulator in competitive electricity markets,9 there is no agreement on how extensive or intrusive this 6
For a discussion of retail markets in the United States see Tschamler, T. (2006). In Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective (F. Sioshansi and W. Pfaffenberger, eds). Elsevier. 7 When retail competition was introduced in the mid-1990s in some states, rates were typically rolled back and frozen, in some cases for as long as 10 years. These rate freezes are about to become unfrozen, resulting in rather significant price increases in some cases. This has resulted in public discontent in a few states, notably Maryland, where the regulatory commission was essentially dismissed following a significant price increase in 2006–7. 8 This lack of interest is evident in the Energy Policy Act of 2005, where the word “retail competition” does not even appear in the massive bill. 9 Germany and New Zealand initially tried to operate their markets without one, but both have subsequently decided that one is needed.
Competitive Electricity Markets
10
Choice for all customers Choice for large customers only No Choice
Fig. 4. Current status of retail competition in the United States. Source: Tschamler, T. (2006). In Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective (F. Sioshansi and W. Pfaffenberger, eds). Elsevier.
EBL 80,000 70,000
6.3 GW
MW Migrated
60,000
6.2 GW 11.9 GW
50,000 40,000
22.3 GW 30,000 20,000 10,000
22.2 GW
0 2001 & prior
2002
2003
2004
2005 YTD
Fig. 5. US load served by competitive suppliers, 2001–05, GW. Source: Tschamler, T. (2006). In Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective (F. Sioshansi and W. Pfaffenberger, eds). Elsevier.
Introduction
11
function ought to be.10 There are differing views on the raison d’etre of the regulator. Some prefer a minimalist role limited to performing the function of a referee, merely enforcing the rules and ensuring fair play. Littlechild, himself an ex-regulator, believes in “Markets when ever possible, regulation when not” (Littlechild, 2006). Others favor a vigilant market monitor or prefer a proactive and interventionist puppeteer11 (see Box 2). While the latter option may seem safe, it is hard to imagine thriving competition coexisting with a proactive and interventionist regulator. Chapter 7 by Adib et al. is focused on the market monitoring function in competitive markets.
Box 2 Alternative views of competition and regulation in the ESI* Fundamentally, there are two extreme views on the form and purpose of regulation •
Create a level playing field and referee the game – in this case, the regulator sets the rules in a way that encourages free and fair competition among the players – and plays the role of an impartial referee. • Write a script and make the puppets dance – in this case, the regulator prepares a prescriptive script for the play, making sure that the players act according to the script.
EBL
The central ingredients of the former are well known namely, • • • • • •
•
Remove barriers to entry in generation. Privatize or corporatize all players so they are on the same footing.† Unbundle vertically integrated enterprises to remove cross-subsidies and selfdealing.‡ Ensure that the transmission network is open and accessible to all under transparent and non-discriminatory prices.§ Create wholesale markets that are open and transparent. Ensure that the grid is managed by an independent operator who maintains reliability, manages transmission congestion, and operates various markets to facilitate trade, liquidity, and risk management. Foster competition in the supply business.
∗
The author is indebted to Professor Pfaffenberger for this perspective. In the Australian context, Victoria has done this while neighboring New South Wales has maintained government control of both generation and distribution, creating an uneven playing field especially in the retail sector. ‡ Lack of rigorous physical unbundling is considered as a major obstacle to the working of vibrant competitive electricity markets. § This remains a thorny issue in the European and US context. †
10
Politt discusses these issues in this volume’s Foreword. The contributors to Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective (2006: Elsevier) exhibit varying views on this question. 11
12
Competitive Electricity Markets
These conditions will most likely lead to a number of firms active in various segments of the business engaging in short- and long-term transactions. The participants will find suitable arrangements to transact, and the regulator’s role is primarily that of a vigilant referee, making sure that the rules of the game are obeyed, infringements are caught, and offenders are punished. Otherwise, market participants are free to roam as long as they obey the rules and play within the field. This may sound unimaginative, but it is tolerably safe. Most restructured markets have adopted a variation of these two extremes – with varying levels of autonomy and authority for the regulator. This assumes that the players know best, and the market is simply the sum of its components. Free market advocates and those favoring laissez-faire policies favor a limited role for the regulator, allowing market participants maximum flexibility. For example, generators would not be obliged to bid their capacity in the market, nor would they be required to explain their bidding strategies or prices. The latter case assumes that the regulator or market designer knows better and can produce a prescriptive plot for all the players, most likely requiring many rewrites to get it right. In this case, the roles of the players are carefully orchestrated and their moves are remotely controlled, as a dance of puppets. The regulator plays the role of a chorographer in a dance studio, organizing and directing all the moves. If the players do not dance as directed or desired, the choreographer must step in to correct the plot and the script. It may be a lot of fun for a playful and highly imaginative regulator, a scarce combination – perhaps an oxymoron. Most economists would consider this an impossibility, since there is no assurance that the scriptwriter, no matter how clever, can get all the parts right.** Nevertheless, examples of this line of thinking may be found in some countries, notably those that have had a disappointing experience with market liberalization and reform as described in Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective (2006: Elsevier).
EBL
∗∗ In case of California, the powerful Public Utilities Commission had to publicly admit that it had not done a good job of regulating the industry and proposed to restructure the ESI, substituting market discipline for regulation.
Market Design, Implementation, Performance The previous book had a geographical focus, looking at a number of markets in different parts of the world, describing the reform process and providing a synopsis of how well given markets are working, given their unique characteristics and starting points. This book is focused on an examination of some of the remaining issues, perplexing problems, and persistent questions common to many competitive markets around the world. The issues are grouped into four parts and explored in the following chapters of the book. Some issues, such as industry organization, hybrid markets, or adequacy of investment in infrastructure, are common to nearly all markets. Other topics, such as capacity markets or industry unbundling, may be more pronounced in selected markets with little relevance to others. The organization of the book and a basic overview of the topics are summarized below.
Introduction
13
PART I: Market Reform Evolution The first part of the book examines the evolution of market reform from a number of perspectives, including how expectations of market designers, regulators, and policymakers have changed over the past two decades. This change in expectations is due to a more mature understanding of the inherent limitations of the market reform process and a better appreciation of the complexities of the electricity markets as well as the limitations of regulators in achieving what was expected. Chapter 1: Reevaluation of Vertical Integration and Unbundling in Restructured Electricity Markets Over a century, vertically integrated monopolies gradually evolved under a regulated rate-of-return paradigm. One of the justifications was the belief that vertical integration results in significant economies of scale while making it easier to regulate the players. Among the underlying tenets of market reform is the breakup of vertically integrated companies into sub-components, forcing them to compete when appropriate and removing cross-subsidies that may flow from regulated operations to competitive functions. But two decades after the introduction of market reform, there is clear evidence that many previously unbundled companies have re-bundled, notably by combining generation with retail business. Moreover, there is empirical evidence to suggest that such combinations are more efficient, can manage risks and price volatility better, and may be preferred by investors. At the same time, there is evidence, not universally convincing, that vertical integration – despite its obvious shortcomings – might have offered economies of scale after all. In this chapter, Hung-po Chao, Shmuel Oren, and Robert Wilson argue that the restructuring of the electric power sector is an evolutionary process that must be allowed to develop along a middle path, somewhere between the two extremes of vertical integration and instantaneous unbundling and introduction of competition at both wholesale and retail levels. The authors further suggest that the central issue is whether the physical nature of the industry necessarily implies one extreme or the other. It was long thought that vertical integration of utilities was essential for efficient investments and operations. On the other hand, restructuring has often been motivated by the view that the purported advantages of vertical integration are obsolete and that liberalized markets can work well and bring stronger incentives that are likely to result in more efficient investments and operations. The authors conclude that neither view is conclusive – that pros and cons can be mustered on either side of the argument without any clear indication that one or the other extreme is better. It is suggested that the most important determinants of the optimal degree of vertical integration is how the risks are allocated and managed.
EBL
Chapter 2: Hybrid Electricity Markets: The Problem of Explaining Different Patterns of Restructuring There is general recognition that in many parts of the world, electricity markets have or are evolving into hybrid forms: not completely unbundled and privatized nor fully competitive. Some remain partially privatized or state-owned, some combine generation with supply while others are separated either functionally or physically. In the United States, for example, a relatively vibrant and competitive wholesale market has evolved
14
Competitive Electricity Markets
despite the fact that most consumers continue to receive service under capped, regulated tariffs that do not reflect variations in hourly prices in the wholesale market. In this chapter, Aad Correljé and Laurens De Vries point out that while the movement toward liberalized electricity markets around the world is well under way, there is no apparent convergence to a single model or outcome. Textbook prescriptions of integrated markets with decentralized players are not necessarily the norm. In practice, many markets have evolved to a position somewhere between their former, pre-liberalized state and the ultimate state desired or predicted by the markets designers. In some cases, this can be considered a mere transition phase. However, in many markets there does not appear to be even an intention and/or the means of moving toward a fully liberalized state. This chapter examines the evolution of hybrid markets, how they have evolved into their present state, and their implications. Chapter 3: Achieving Electricity Market Integration in Europe Just as the markets and the expectations of policymakers have evolved, so have the role and function of the transmission system operators (TSOs), as they are called in Europe. These new institutions have emerged to be among the most important in the day-to-day operation of the markets by facilitating transactions among various market players. How a given TSO – or ISO in US parlance – is organized and manages given markets has become critically important to how other players – generators, transmission owners, distribution companies, retailers, traders, and investors – interact with one another and how the whole system performs. In this chapter, Nigel Cornwall addresses how the European TSOs have evolved over time and the key role they play in the development of the EC single energy market. The evolution of the European TSOs may be traced to the establishment of the National Grid Company (NGC) in England and Wales and institutional reform in the UK market. The author argues that, in many ways, the United Kingdom’s experiment with the NGC sets the framework and the blueprint for the continental TSOs that followed. While accelerated development has occurred in response to the EC and industry reform programs in recent years, important differences in the regulation, commercial operation, and institutional arrangements in different parts of Europe still remain. This chapter compares and contrasts the evolution of TSOs in six key markets, namely Britain, the Netherlands, France, Spain, Italy, and Germany. The chapter examines legal requirements promulgated by the EC, and looks at differences in the institutional environment between the TSOs. It addresses service provision through both balancing mechanisms and supporting ancillary services, including the commercial arrangements that underpin them. It considers the different regulatory structures and incentives, including compliance and information disclosure and examines drivers for change going forward.
EBL
PART II: Market Performance, Monitoring, and Demand Participation This part of the book examines a number of important market design and performance issues, some peculiar to the United States but others with broad international relevance. Chapter 4: Transmission Markets, Congestion Management, and Investment Current electricity networks are generation-centric, which necessitates a massive transmission and distribution network to transmit the power to major load centers. This served the
Introduction
15
industry well for over a century, especially under a regulated, vertically integrated model. But unbundling of transmission from generation, leaving the latter to private investors, has created a vacuum. There are concerns in some markets, for example, that insufficient investment is going into transmission or that transmission and generation planning have become bifurcated with adverse consequences for both. In the United States, a decade has passed since the introduction of transmission open access. During this period the industry has witnessed significant changes in the transmission business with open access under Order 888, the development of Regional Transmission Organizations (RTOs) and, more recently, the evolution of Independent Transmission Companies (ITCs). The period has also seen transmission investment generally lag behind generation investment, putting a greater emphasis on the role of congestion management in market design than has occurred elsewhere. However, there is renewed focus on transmission, with several initiatives to improve investment and transmission markets. In this chapter, Harry Singh reviews the various approaches that have been implemented, data from different markets, and recent initiatives and summarizes some of the lessons learnt. It is fair to say that in nearly all interconnected networks, transmission capacity is scarce during peak demand periods – same as generation capacity – impinging on the ability of market operators to dispatch the least-cost generation options to meet local loads, forcing them to diverge from the so-called unconstrained optimal flow. When transmission is constrained, more expensive local generation must frequently be used to serve local loads, even when lower-cost resources are available somewhere else on the network. This entails significant costs, which are ultimately passed on to customers through higher prices. With the increasing recognition of the significance of transmission bottlenecks, market operators have devised various methods to make better use of the limited transmission capacity and to encourage both loads and generation to recognize the limitations of the network. Locational or nodal pricing, also called LMP, is among the tools developed in response to this problem. While not everyone embraced this concept initially, some markets in the United States are being redesigned to incorporate it. Concepts such as transmission property rights, transmission auctions, and forward markets to allocate limited transmission capacity have evolved to address these complex issues as well.
EBL
Chapter 5: The Design of US Wholesale Energy and Ancillary Service Auction Markets: Theory and Practice In the United States, the bulk of the electric power system is now under the control of ISOs, which operate multiple markets for energy and ancillary services. Despite some initial difficulties in California and elsewhere, and an ongoing need for improvement, these large regional markets encompassing thousands of pricing points are one of the major technical achievements of electricity restructuring in the United States. In addition to providing great potential for economic efficiency, much of which is still untapped, these markets will greatly facilitate the growing inclusion of the demand side of the electricity market as well as the absorption of renewable and other supply technologies that are likely to be driven by environmental policy and regulation. In this chapter, Udi Helman, Benjamin Hobbs, and Richard O’Neill discuss the designs of the day-ahead and real-time ISO auction markets for energy and certain ancillary services. The chapter offers a detailed examination of the pricing rules and procedures in these markets. The chapter reviews the history of particular design choices, explaining why they appeared more desirable than alternative proposals. Differences among the ISO
16
Competitive Electricity Markets
designs are also examined, with a focus on PJM and New York ISO. It also provides a numerical example that illustrates primary market features, such as day-ahead and realtime locational marginal pricing (of energy, congestion, and losses), unit commitment decisions, virtual bidding, reliability commitments, revenue sufficiency guarantee, financial settlements, and disposal of auction surplus payments that accrue when congestion and losses are priced at the margin. The example can be easily replicated, allowing for its use as a teaching and study tool.
Chapter 6: The Cost of Anarchy in Self-Commitment-Based Electricity Markets A persistent design issue in the context of electricity markets is whether plant unit commitment decisions should be made centrally by the system operator or by individual generators. Although a centrally committed market can, in theory, determine the most efficient commitment, they have been shown to suffer some equity and incentive problems. A self-committed market can overcome some of these incentive issues, but will generally suffer efficiency losses from not properly coordinating commitment and dispatch decisions between individual generators. In this chapter, Ramteen Sioshansi, Shmuel Oren, and Richard O’Neil examine the issue of dispatch efficiency raised by the design of markets based on central versus selfcommitment by determining a set of “competitive benchmarks” for the two market designs. Comparing the total commitment and dispatch costs of the two markets provides a bound on the productive efficiency losses of a self-committed market.
EBL
Chapter 7: Market Power and Market Monitoring Deregulation is good public policy only to the extent it furthers competition. While proper market design is important, experience to date suggests that the success of competitive electricity markets depend first and foremost on structural conditions that do not distort market outcomes. One of the important conditions is that structural market power must be addressed as an integral part of market reform. Several states in the United States have required or encouraged the divestiture of generation by the former vertically integrated electric utilities. Even then, as the California crisis of 2000–01 has shown, those markets could experience local market power in load pockets when constrained transmission imposes limits on power imports. Market monitoring units have a crucial role to play in detecting and preventing such market manipulations. In this chapter, Parviz Adib and David Hurlbut discuss the market power problems encountered in those markets. The authors make an important distinction between scarcity pricing, which is essential for attracting investments in competitive markets, and artificially induced high prices resulting from the exercise of market power. They describe the tools that are most useful to market monitors to detect market power abuses and mitigate or minimize their impacts. To carry out their monitoring and investigative functions fairly and effectively, market monitors must be independent from the market participants and the system operator, and their findings and conclusions must not be influenced by political considerations. The authors conclude that the burden is on legislative and regulatory authorities to ensure that market monitors are empowered to do their job effectively, that their independence is respected, and that their findings and recommendations are taken into consideration.
Introduction
17
Chapter 8: Demand Participation in Restructured Markets Demand elasticity is a much talked about topic, but demand has not been effectively integrated with supply-side resources. Most markets in the United States and internationally are currently supply-focused, in the sense that hourly demand is taken as a given, and generation is adjusted to meet the variable demand. Demand inelasticity is a major problem in most markets, notably those with needle-sharp peaks and low reserve margins. But making demand more elastic remains an elusive goal, technically as well as institutionally. In this chapter, Jay Zarnikau reviews the challenges associated with facilitating demandside participation in competitive markets, provides a summary of various demand-side initiatives in restructured markets in North America, and contributes a case study describing some of the problems faced in promoting demand-side participation in the Texas market, often cited as the most successful retail market in the United States.
PART III: Capacity, Resource Adequacy, and Investment The third part of the book is focused on interrelated issues of capacity, resource adequacy – or lack thereof – and infrastructure investment. These issues, while germane to all markets, are nevertheless treated differently in different parts of the world.
Chapter 9: Resource Adequacy: Alternative Perspectives and Divergent Paths
EBL
In electricity markets characterized as energy-only, generators are rewarded for the energy delivered to the network when and if they are dispatched. In such energy-only markets, little if any reward is paid to generators for having extra capacity available for long-term system reliability. Although most markets also operate ancillary service (AS) markets, where generators are paid relatively small amounts for providing spinning reserves, reactive power, and the like, these are rewards to generators for providing an operational safety margin in real time – not for long-term system reliability. The issue of whether capacity markets, where generators are paid significant amounts for capacity – regardless of whether they are dispatched or not – continues to be important for at least two reasons: First, in countries where there is significant amount of hydropower,12 thermal generators are likely to be infrequently dispatched in years when ample hydro capacity is available. This creates problems during drought periods because lack of sufficient incentives to invest in thermal generation may result in severe shortages during such episodes. 13 • Second, in countries where excess reserves are externally mandated, as in the United States, average wholesale prices tend to be depressed, resulting in inadequate investment in future capacity. Further complicating the problem is the presence of low offer caps in many markets, which has the effect of limiting scarcity revenues to generators •
12
Examples include Chile and Colombia, both of which have capacity charges and are considered problematic. 13 The preliminary evidence from the Nordic market where a severe drought was experienced without major meltdown (Amundsen et al., 2006), however, suggests that even hydro-dominated systems can operate without a capacity market.
Competitive Electricity Markets
18
when supplies are short. But designing a capacity payment scheme that encourages adequate investment in new capacity without introducing serious unintended side effects has proven to be a monumental challenge. The question is this context is twofold: •
Do we need to pay for capacity above and beyond energy to ensure adequate supply reliability? • If so, how can we design incentives that produce the desired benefits without serious adverse consequences? There is a growing body of literature on this topic but the fundamental debate has not been settled,14 at least not in the United States, which is the focus of the chapter by Parviz Adib, Eric Schubert, and Shmuel Oren. The authors review the controversial evolution of resource adequacy mechanisms in the United States while examining alternative approaches considered in the Texas market. The necessary conditions and a potential transition mechanism to a sustainable energy-only approach are also discussed. Chapter 10: The Evolution of PJM’s Capacity Market Continuing in the same vein, in this chapter Joseph Bowring describes the evolution of capacity markets in PJM since their inception in 1999 in response to regulatory requests to facilitate retail competition through modifications and eventually wholesale changes in 2006. The chapter examines the theory underlying the need for capacity markets, the ways in which PJM capacity markets have evolved and functioned, and how reality has matched or not matched with theory. The chapter also addresses the interactions between energy markets and capacity markets and evaluates the joint functioning of the two markets based on empirical results. Total and net revenues from these markets are presented as well as the effectiveness of local price signals in incentivizing investment. The chapter provides a critical self-examination of PJM’s new capacity market, the Reliability Pricing Model (RPM) in light of the actual reliability performance of the PJM markets. The discussion provides an example of how a specific capacity market has been designed and how well or poorly it has been functioning in the single largest centrally dispatched market in the world. The experience of PJM – and the reasons it has chosen to introduce a capacity market – are relevant to discussion of capacity markets elsewhere.
EBL
Chapter 11: Resource Adequacy and Efficient Infrastructure Investment Resource adequacy and investment continue to be a major concern in a number of countries, as described in Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective (2006: Elsevier). The jury on how well markets can or will provide the necessary funds to feed the industry’s voracious appetite for long-term capital is still out. This problem is not unique to developed countries; many developing countries are attracted to market reform primarily because they need massive amounts of foreign investment in their power sector. 14 Paradoxically, markets in PJM, New York, and New England have decided to proceed with capacity payment schemes while ERCOT and MISO have examined and rejected them, and California is still debating if such a mechanism is needed.
Introduction
19
Table 3. Resource adequacy and reliability Attribute
Objective
Resources
Incentives
Resource adequacy
Have enough installed capacity to fulfill demand in the medium and long term
Installed capacity subject to availability and technical constraints
Have price signals that provide the incentives to invest in capacity, recovering operation and maintenance costs
Reliability
Have the resources to respond to short-term fluctuations
Provision of ancillary services to satisfy minimum reliability standards defined by the authority
Have price signals that explicitly account for ancillary services provision
Source: Adopted from R. Raineri, 2006, personal communications.
The main concern is that insufficient investment may be going into generation, distribution, and – most notably – the transmission sector. The evidence is mixed and it is not entirely clear if markets are failing to deliver because of delays in processing the price signals, regulatory uncertainties, or other impediments. And there are questions about how best to mitigate such market shortcomings, if indeed they exist and are real.15 This issue is closely linked to capacity market, but there are clear distinctions between adequacy and reliability as highlighted in Table 3. Concerns about supply inadequacy resulting from the “missing money” problem described in Cramton and Stoft (2006) have led to proposals for creation of dual markets where generators get paid for energy on the one hand and capacity on the other. In this chapter, Alan Moran and Ben Skinner argue that a reasonably efficient market has been achieved in Australia without regulation of generation. The outcome, which is not without some fragilities, has generally been due to less government intervention than seen in some other markets, with a higher reserve intervention price, less distortive consumer price caps, and a genuine level of retail competition that provides good market signals for new capacity.
EBL
PART IV: Market Design Issues This part of the book is devoted to several important issues that are not necessarily caused by but have become more pronounced since the introduction of market reform. Incorporation of renewable energy technologies, the role of distributed generation, and the possible menace of global climate change are not market reform issues per se. Addressing them, however, has become more urgent and important with the introduction of market reform. Each topic arguably deserves an entire book, but has been squeezed into a single chapter. 15
There are those [e.g., Moran (2006)] who attribute any shortcomings of the private sector to continued meddling and regulatory interference.
20
Competitive Electricity Markets
Chapter 15 unifies many of the concepts covered in preceding chapters of this volume, explaining how Brazil has attempted to put an order into its vast electric power sector following the introduction of market reform. Chapter 12: Promoting Electricity from Renewable Energy Sources – Lessons learned from the EU, the United States, and Japan Advocates of renewable energy technologies believe that governments must support and subsidize them, especially if one is concerned about global climate change. Among the arguments made is that renewables must gradually replace dwindling supplies of finite fossil fuels, ultimately replacing them. As the costs of fossil fuels rise, renewables will become more cost-effective, and subsidies can be reduced and eventually removed. While such arguments are gaining growing support, there is little agreement on how best to subsidize the renewable energy industry – in ways that do not interfere with the efficient workings of competitive markets. Currently, a variety of support and subsidy schemes are in place in different parts of the world with no particular rhyme or reason for some of the targets or subsidies provided. In the United States, for example, a number of states have adopted renewable portfolio standards (RPSs), with varying targets and target dates in the absence of a cohesive national policy16 (Fig. 6). Similar issues confront policymakers in Europe where very significant amounts of renewable energy have been developed in the recent past in response to highly generous
EBL
Fig. 6. Renewable portfolio standards in effect in various states in the United States. 16
The deadline for California is 2010 (not 2017 as indicated in Figure 6) and there is an Executive Order issued by California Gov. for a 33% by 2020. At the federal level, there have been proposals to impose a 15% national target.
Introduction
21
subsidies. Aside from the form and amount of subsidies, the European renewable energy now generates a large amount of power, which must be absorbed by the existing network. This is of major concern in the European context, because renewable power occasionally plays havoc with the transmission grid as well as with conventional generation, which must adjust its output to absorb the intermittent load. More research is needed to determine how various schemes, for example, renewable portfolio standards, favored in the United States, compare to feed-in tariffs, favored in Europe. In this chapter, Reinhard Haas, Niels Meyer, Anne Held, Dominique Finon, Arthuro Lorenzoni, Ryan Wiser, and Ken–ichiro Nishio explore the evolution of renewable energy resources (RES) in Europe, the United States, and Japan over the past 20 years. The authors examine a variety of programs in different countries describing their success and failures. European policymakers are currently discussing the application of harmonized policies throughout Europe. Chapter 13: Distributed Generation and the Regulation of Electricity Networks Current electricity systems are designed based on large centralized generation and topdown transmission and distribution networks serving the loads. In recent years this paradigm has been challenged as more decentralized power plants are located close to load centers and connected to the distribution network with advantages that include, apart from the economic and environmental advantages, the security of supply. Distributed generation (DG), including combined heat and power (CHP) and renewables, enjoys high policy priority in many countries and is likely to have a bright future. Yet, it does not always easily fit into today’s centralized power systems. In this chapter, Dierk Bauknecht and Gert Brunekreeft examine how a growing share of DG can be integrated into liberalized electricity markets from a regulatory point of view. While the technical debate on DG integration is well under way, the question as to how the governance structure of the electricity system can best promote and integrate DG has received less attention and has mainly been focused on the design of support mechanisms for individual plants. This chapter focuses on electricity networks and the role of network regulation for the integration of DG. It is often argued that DG can reduce network costs. However, in many cases networks need to adapt to DG, which may entail incurring additional costs. Even if the overall benefits of DG are positive, additional network costs represent a disincentive for network operators to connect DG. The regulatory framework within which they operate is crucial for efficient integration of DG. This includes unbundling rules and the regulation of connection charges and network tariffs.
EBL
Chapter 14: Global Climate Change and the Electric Power Industry Economists view global climate change as an externality. So long as there is no price or penalty on emitting CO2 into the atmosphere, we emit more than we should. The same is true for disposal of industrial waste or SOx . The most efficient way to control CO2 emissions would be to price it – or put a mandatory cap on what can be emitted – which will have the same result. Once CO2 emissions are priced, firms will take measures to limit their emissions using the most cost-effective options at their disposal. Firms that cannot meet their quota will pay others, buying credits. In this chapter, Andrew Ford begins with the premise that the accumulation of greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions in the atmosphere is a serious problem that warrants serious
22
Competitive Electricity Markets
action and provides a summary of the initiatives at the international, national, and regional levels. The chapter focuses on emission trading scheme (ETS) to limit GHG and the central role of the electric power sector in combating global climate change.
Chapter 15: Reform of the Reforms in Brazil: Problems and Solutions This chapter starts with a discussion of the “reform of the reforms,” namely the fact that most markets require secondary and tertiary meddling to fix the problems introduced by the initial process of market reform. No market in the world has been entirely immune to this, although some have required minor adjustments and fine-tuning as opposed to major post-operative surgery. Nowhere has this problem been more pronounced than in Brazil. In the Brazilian electricity supply industry, the first market-oriented reform ran into investment troubles. The reform of the reforms, led by the Lula administration, purports to overcome this through a combination of free bilateral contracts between free consumers, traders, distributors, producers, and regulated contracts between generators and distributors through auctions. In this chapter, Lizardo de Araújo, Agnes Maria de Aragão da Costa, Tiago B. Correia, and Elbia Melo analyze the characteristics of the Brazilian electric power sector in terms of original market reforms as well as the ongoing process of “reform of the reforms,” covering power auctions, investments in generation and transmission, and efforts to regulate electricity prices. In many ways, this chapter unifies many of the concepts described in earlier chapters of the volume, serving as a case study.
EBL
References Amundsen, E., von der Fehr, N.H., and Bergman, L. (2006). The Nordic market: Robust by design? In Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective (F. Sioshansi and W. Pfaffenberger, eds). Elsevier. Araujo, Jo˜ao Lizardo R. Hermes de (2006). The case of Brazil: Reform by trial and error? In Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective. (F. Sioshansi and W. Pfaffenberger, eds). Elsevier. Cramton, P. and Stoft, S. (2006). The convergence of market designs for adequate generating capacity. Prepared for California Electricity Oversight Board, 25 June. Dyner, I., Arango, S., and Larsen, E.R. (2006). Understanding the Argentinea and colombian electricity markets. In Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective. (F. Sioshansi and W. Pfaffenberger, eds). Elsevier. The Economist (2006). 11 February. Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (2006). Report to Congress on competition in the wholesale & retail markets for electric energy. Washington, D.C., 5 June. Goto, M. and Yajima, M. (2006). A new stage of electricity liberalization in Japan: Issues and expectations. In Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective (F. Sioshansi and W. Pfaffenberger, eds). Elsevier. Haas, R., Glachant, J.M., Keseric, N., and Perez, Y. (2006). Competition in the Continental European electricity market: Despair of work in progress? In Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective (F. Sioshansi and W. Pfaffenberger, eds). Elsevier. Joskow, P. (2006a). In Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective (F. Sioshansi and W. Pfaffenberger, eds). Elsevier. Joskow, P. (2006b). Markets for power in the United States: An interim assessment. The Energ. J., 27(1). Littlechild, S. (2006). Foreword: the market versus regulation. In Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective (F. Sioshansi and W. Pfaffenberger, eds). Elsevier.
Introduction
23
Moran, A. (2006). The electricity industry in Australia: Problems along the way to a national electricity market. In Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective (F.P. Sioshansi and W. Pfaffenberger, eds). Amsterdam: Elsevier. Newbery, D. (2006). Electricity liberalization in Britain and the evolution of market design. In Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective (F. Sioshansi and W. Pfaffenberger, eds). Elsevier. O’Neill, R., Helman, U., Hobbs, B., and Baldick, R. (2006). Independent system operators in the United States: History, lessons learned, and prospects. In Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective (F. Sioshansi and W. Pfaffenberger, eds). Elsevier. Raineri, R. (2006). Chile: Where it all started. In Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective. (F. Sioshansi and W. Pfaffenberger, eds). Elsevier. Sioshansi, F. and Pfaffenberger, W. (2006). Why Restructure Electricity Markets? In Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective. (F. Sioshansi and W. Pfaffenberger, eds). Elsevier. Sweeney, J. (2006). California electricity restructuring, the crisis, and its aftermath. In Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective. (F. Sioshansi and W. Pfaffenberger, eds). Elsevier. Treblicock Michael & Hrab, Roy (2006). Electricity restructuring in Canada. In Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective (F. Sioshansi and W. Pfaffenberger, eds). Elsevier. Tschamler, Taff (2006). Competitive retail power markets and default service. In Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective (F. Sioshansi and W. Pfaffenberger, eds). Elsevier.
EBL
EBL
This page intentionally left blank
Part I Market Reform Evolution
EBL
EBL
This page intentionally left blank
Chapter 1 Reevaluation of Vertical Integration and Unbundling in Restructured Electricity Markets HUNG-PO CHAO1 , SHMUEL OREN2 , AND ROBERT WILSON3 1
ISO New England, USA; 2 University of California, Berkeley, USA; 3 Stanford Business School, USA
Summary
EBL
This chapter critically reviews the argument for vertical integration in the electricity industry, and also the argument for restructuring based on unbundling of its products and organizations in favor of market mechanisms. The authors conclude that both arguments are deficient, and that a balanced mixture of vertical integration and liberalized markets is superior to the extremes. Their central conclusion is that efficient management of the risks inherent in the electricity industry requires that restructuring retain universal service for the core of non-industrial customers who rely on regulated rates smoothed over time to recover the costs of service. 1.1. Introduction This chapter addresses basic economic issues posed by restructuring. The central issue is whether the overall technology of the industry – wholesale generation, transmission, and retail service – necessarily implies more or less vertical integration. It was long thought and is still being argued by many that vertical integration of retail utilities was essential for efficient investments and operations (e.g., see Michaels, 2006). On the other hand, restructuring has often been motivated by the view that the purported advantages of vertical integration are obsolete, that liberalized markets can work well, and that they bring stronger incentives that are likely to result in more efficient investments and operations (e.g., California Public Utilities Commission, 1993). The argument presented here is that neither view is conclusive – that pros and cons can be mustered on either side without any clear indication that one or the other extreme is better. In prior work (Chao et al., 2006) the authors argued that restructuring of the electricity industry should develop along a middle path between the extremes of vertical integration and liberalization of wholesale and retail markets. This middle path establishes the boundaries of the firm – the extent to which a retail utility should retain some degree of vertical 27
28
Competitive Electricity Markets
integration. A key element of this choice is the make-or-buy decision about whether to own and manage supply resources, or to rely on wholesale markets via either spot purchases or longer-term contracts. A middle path also requires restructuring of regulatory policies and redefinition of the regulatory compact to recognize the effects of investment, purchasing, and contracting decisions by utilities in the context of liberalized wholesale markets, and to strengthen incentives for efficient operations and demand response. Moreover, the optimal extent of vertical integration is ultimately determined by the requirements for efficient allocation of risk bearing. After restructuring, the most important determinants of the optimal degree of vertical integration concern risk management, which affects the cost of capital – the ultimate measure of financial risk – and supply reliability and resource adequacy – the ultimate measures of physical risk. (See also Correljé and De Vries, Chapter 2 in this volume.) From the perspective of risk management, the mutual interests of suppliers of generation and retail service enable risk sharing that mitigates financial risks. Depending on local circumstances, their shared interests imply a greater or lesser degree of reliance on markets and contracts, or on direct ownership that perpetuates some degree of vertical integration. For example, a utility might meet some resource adequacy requirements by contracts or by purchases in capacity markets, and also own generation facilities that serve its core retail customers within a regulatory scheme that continues the traditional regulatory compact, albeit with stronger incentives from market forces and performance-based regulation. Section 1.2. begins by reviewing the case for vertical integration of utilities that prevailed through most of the twentieth century. Section 1.3. examines anew these arguments in the current context and finds them greatly altered – in part by the evident successes of some aspects of restructuring. The discussion of economic issues in Section 1.2. includes a summary of explanations of vertical integration in the literature. This discussion is necessary because ideas from this debate have greatly influenced restructuring decisions by regulators and legislators, especially in Europe recently. It also clarifies the distinction between financial and organizational “unbundling” of a utility’s vertical components – wholesale generation, transmission, and retail service – and unbundling of the corresponding products. In the regulated era, the organization of the electricity industry stemmed from vertical integration of utilities in all respects, while in the past decade much reorganization aimed at segmenting utilities into their vertical components in conjunction with unbundling of their products. In several cases, organizational unbundling of firms was seen as a necessary or desirable complement to unbundling of products to facilitate liberalized wholesale markets. Although organizational disintegration was rejected in most other liberalized industries (transport, telecommunications, etc.), regulators and legislators favored dissolution of vertical organization in the electricity industry for reasons that are reviewed. Section 1.4. reviews some of the unsolved problems of liberalized markets, including both those that cannot be solved efficiently by market processes and those that have not yet been solved adequately by market restructuring. Section 1.5. develops the case that risk management considerations are major determinants of the degree of vertical integration in terms of organization and ownership and vertical contracting. Section 1.6. concludes by outlining some implications for the evolution of restructuring. This discussion introduces scenarios in which a desirable degree of vertical integration coexists within liberalized wholesale markets for unbundled products, and which allow a utility to serve core customers at regulated rates while others opt to purchase from competing suppliers.
EBL
Reevaluation of Vertical Integration and Unbundling in Restructured Electricity Markets
29
1.2. The Historical Motives for Vertical Integration The origin of vertical integration in the electricity industry lies in a dominant public interest. Like other infrastructure industries – water, transport, communications – the energy industries were recognized as essential for economic development. Universal service, efficiently supplied at minimum cost, was imperative. In many countries these needs in the case of electricity were addressed by monopolies conducted or owned by local or national governments, and in some cases by government projects or subsidies; e.g., in the United States by the Tennessee Valley Authority, Bonneville Power Administration, Western Area Power Authorities, and the Rural Electrification Administration. The prevalence of government monopolies and government-sanctioned monopolies had three sources. One was technical, resulting from the advantages of alternating current synchronized over grids spanning large regions. Another was economic, resulting from the large scale of transmission and distribution (T&D) systems and the large scale of some generation facilities, especially hydroelectric dams but also the most efficient coal-fired and, later, nuclear plants. The third was financial, because the government was the sole or chief source or guarantor of sufficient capital at low cost. All three reflected the capital intensity of the technology used by the power industry, certainly in T&D, and in combination with fuel intensity in the case of generation. Historians of economic development view the twentieth century, in part, as an era of accumulation in which massive investments established the infrastructure on which a modern economy depends. (Chandler, 1969; Devine, 1983) The industry’s organization differed in those countries like the United States, Japan, and Germany that relied heavily on investor-owned utilities (IOUs). Although Nebraska and some municipalities developed public power systems, and federal projects were important elsewhere, within the United States most major urban areas depended on IOUs for provision of retail service. The role of IOUs stemmed from a conjunction of public and private interests. The public interest in universal service at minimum cost was matched by firms’ interest in obtaining ample capital at low cost. The states established Public Utility Commissions (PUCs) to regulate the industry (except federal regulation of interstate trade), with authority to mandate the quality, conditions, and terms of retail service (Bonbright, 1961). In return, each utility obtained an exclusive regional franchise, except for municipal utilities and rural cooperatives, which were exempt. In principle, this was a retail monopoly but it evolved into a total franchise that encompassed local supply, transmission, and distribution as well as retail service. A state’s grant of monopoly franchises on transmission and generation was artificial since it derived from comprehensive cost-of-service regulation rather than basic economic considerations. It was fundamentally at variance with federal legislation and regulation, but enforced by each state’s control of siting of facilities, cost recovery from retail rates, and authority to exclude independent power producers (IPPs) from selling to retail customers. Under the old “regulatory compact,” risk management was provided through an insurance mechanism by vertical integration along the electricity supply chain. The single utility ownership of generation and transmission facilities buffered wholesale price volatility. Retail regulation smoothed the rate effects of cost changes on customers, imposed an obligation to serve, and offered utility shareholders a reasonable opportunity of recovering investments with a largely assured rate of return. Although all the risks – both physical and financial – were socialized to a high degree, customers bore the residual risk. Importantly, a utility was assured full recovery of prudently incurred investments and expenses, including the cost of capital. This part of the regulatory compact was implemented by nearly level retail rates; that is, a utility’s recovery of an approved cost (one accepted into the rate base) was amortized over many years, with repayments obtained
EBL
Competitive Electricity Markets
30
from retail revenues. The regulatory compact was a perfect means of obtaining capital from private sources to build a growing industry – because cost recovery was assured, utilities obtained capital from financial markets at low cost without drawing on public funds. Amortization of cost recovery reduced risks for lenders and shareholders, and equally, it reduced the volatility of rates paid by retail customers. For regulators, cost-of-service regulation brought difficulties judging prudency and measuring costs, and they were often dismayed by a utility’s weakened incentives for cost minimization and strengthened incentives for capital-intensive projects (CPUC, 1993; Joskow, 1997). But until the last decade before restructuring these deficiencies were viewed as of second-order importance compared to the advantages. A utility’s monopoly on local generation and T&D was implemented by vertical integration of all aspects, including organization. The electricity industry has a linear supply chain from fuel to generation to transmission to distribution to service delivery. Each utility integrated backward from retail service to encompass at least generation, and occasionally some fuel sources. There were two motives for extension of a utility’s monopoly backward into the supply chain, and with it the resulting vertical integration. One was the advantage of a single coherent investment strategy. Given the load-duration profile and the costs of building and operating generators, there is a particular mix of generation technologies that serves the load at least the overall cost in the long run. There is also an optimal configuration of the transmission grid and locations of generators, and moreover, an optimal substitution between local generation and transmission to access distant generation – as well as occasional use of local generation to alleviate congestion on transmission elements, sustain voltage, etc. The second motive was the advantage of consolidated operations. Centralized dispatch of generation and transmission had the explicit objective of minimizing the total cost of serving the load subject to constraints intended to ensure service reliability and protect the transmission grid from cascading failures.
EBL
1.2.1. Theoretical framework These motives were always based on ideal realization of the alleged advantages in investments and operations. In reality the actual results were often driven by practical financial considerations, as explained below. Even so, a substantial body of economic theory was constructed to explain the prevalence of vertically integrated utilities (e.g., Williamson, 1975, 1985). Its main ingredients were as given below: •
Public good. The T&D system is the enabling infrastructure of the power industry. Tight control, operating on very short time frames, is required to sustain service reliability and to avert cascading failures of grid elements and generation units. Also necessary are uniform standards and procedures among interconnecting segments of the grid. • Natural monopoly. Duplication of T&D facilities is wasteful except where it improves grid security or service reliability. • Economies of scale. Natural monopoly was extended to generation by citing the large size and capital requirements of efficiently scaled units and plants. This argument applied mainly to hydro projects and base-load plants using coal and later nuclear fuels. • Economies of scope. This catch-all category (in principle, a subset of economies of scale) cites advantages from tight coordination, such as the above-cited advantages
Reevaluation of Vertical Integration and Unbundling in Restructured Electricity Markets
31
of centralized investment and operations. It also includes advantages from substitution (e.g., generation capacity usable for either energy production or a contingency reserve, and generation used to alleviate transmission congestion), and the possibility that standards, technology, information systems, and skills used for one kind of generation are applicable to other kinds and to engineering control of the grid. Savings in metering, billing, and financial settlements are sometimes included in this category. • Economies of transaction costs. Despite its name, this category refers not to costs of metering and billing, but to difficulties and risks in contracting. Its premises include asset specificity and incompleteness of contracts. A seller’s investment in a transmission or generation facility is irreversible and long lived, and the facility cannot be moved or used for another purpose. The value of the investment is therefore tied specifically to expected use by or sale of output to buyers. If there is a single buyer then an initial contract between them might seem to ensure that the seller obtains the value he anticipates when he commits to investment and construction. But a contract that covers all contingencies is usually infeasible, and in those unlikely contingencies that are not covered (or if the buyer can renege) the seller might not be able to renegotiate with the buyer to recover the sunk costs of investment. Anticipating this, the seller might not undertake the investment initially. This scenario is the basis for the argument that contracts may be insufficient to stimulate adequate investments, and therefore vertical integration of the seller and the buyer might be necessary to ensure that efficient investments are undertaken. These technical explanations of vertical integration did not, however, address the more practical aspects that were constantly at the forefront of regulatory considerations. These were dominated by financial considerations that are described next.
EBL
1.2.2. Financial motives In keeping with their primary responsibilities, PUCs focused on capturing the advantages of vertical integration for retail service. Cost-of-service regulation was the means to obtain mandated universal service at minimum cost and with high reliability. In some ways a vertically integrated utility was easier to monitor, its total costs were easier to measure, and it could be held directly accountable for deficiencies of quality or reliability. Universal service required subsidies to those residential and commercial customers who were more expensive to serve, and vertical integration offered the expedient of relying on implicit cross-subsidies rather than explicit financial subsidies. Although industrial customers were especially disadvantaged by this policy, the inefficiencies of cross-subsidies were secondary to the political influence of residential and commercial customers. The magnitude of cross-subsidies declined in later years as the development of efficient plants of small size and the growth of co-generation enabled an industrial customer to negotiate lower rates, since it had the option to self-generate to serve its own load. Most important for PUCs was that retail rates could be smoothed over time by amortizing the utility’s recovery of its costs, and the cost of capital could be minimized by indirectly invoking the credit of the state. Full recovery of costs via retail rates necessarily implies that retail customers ultimately bear nearly all of the financial risks; indeed, this is the first fundamental principle of the regulatory compact. For many customers their aversion to volatile rates is profound, in part because on short timescales they have limited options to alter usage patterns or to invest in alternative appliances and production technologies, and generally they cannot obtain financial hedges against fluctuating rates.
32
Competitive Electricity Markets
However, the second fundamental principle is that cost recovery is amortized so that rates can be smoothed inter-temporally over long periods. The feasibility of this scheme stems basically from the difference between the high volatility of fuel and power prices in the short term and their low volatility over the long term. Short-term volatility is mainly cyclical and load-based, ranging from daily variation to seasonal weather cycles to business cycles. Thus, retail customers are exposed only to secular risks and trends, and only gradually. These include trends in fuel prices and generation technologies, and inevitable mistakes such as misestimates of the amount and location of load growth. However, this rosy scenario was upset in the years after the oil embargo of 1973 and before restructuring in the 1990s by cost overruns for nuclear plants and by the prices guaranteed to “qualifying facilities” (QFs) as specified in the Public Utilities Regulatory Policies Act (PURPA) of 1978. But until well into the 1980s cost-of-service regulation was generally viewed as successful in spite of the difficulties during the 1970s and 1980s from gyrating fuel prices, monetary inflation and high interest rates, and technical advances that rendered major investments inefficient. The natural monopoly aspects of T&D systems implied regulation and control of rates. Most investments in T&D facilities could not be recovered by marginal-cost pricing or by congestion pricing. Therefore, cost-of-service regulation that provided recovery of investment and maintenance costs extended naturally to T&D. In later years there were instances of performance-based regulation (Hunt, 2002), and, rarely, of merchant transmission investments in direct current lines, but overall the expansion of the grid was a massive investment in infrastructure that continued until in the United States and Canada it is now composed of only two interconnected systems plus one within Texas. Although essentially a public asset, the grid is largely privately owned by utilities and financed mainly by recovering the costs from charges included in the rates paid by retail customers. Like some other infrastructure networks (railroads, telecommunications, gas pipelines) it was regulated according to principles of contract carriage – until superseded in 1996 by common carriage when the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) required open access and nondiscriminatory pricing. Reliance on private ownership and contracting prevailed in some countries (e.g., Germany and Japan) while state-owned transmission companies developed the grid in others (e.g., the United Kingdom, France, New Zealand, and Scandinavia). The latter developed systematically but those relying on local utilityowned transmission developed through increasing interconnections among them as energy trading increased and the utilities increasingly relied on exchange agreements to improve reliability. The financial aspects of generation were fundamental motives for vertical integration. Mentioned previously were the role of capital intensity, the scale economies of base-load plants before smaller gas-fired plants were developed in the 1980s, and possible economies of scope. These are reinforced by the great variation of loads on short time frames and the resulting high volatility of prices in spot markets, plus longer-term secular trends. Since a generation plant has a lifetime of 20 to 40 years, its inherent value is largely unaffected by short-term price volatility. Moreover, the supplier and a buyer such as a utility have mutual interests to ensure each other against price variations, since every price that is good for one is bad for other. Thus, one might surmise that long-term contracting will ensure investments in generation capacity; indeed, the investor can use the contract as security to obtain loans to finance construction. This scenario is jeopardized, however, by two factors. One is that a 20- or 40-year contract differs from utility ownership of a plant only in its lack of direct investment and operational management and control, but requires comparable justification to the
EBL
Reevaluation of Vertical Integration and Unbundling in Restructured Electricity Markets
33
PUC that it is prudent, and further that it is invulnerable to the supplier’s default or bankruptcy. The other factor is that the investor or its lender prefers a contract that fixes both price and quantity, while the utility prefers flexible dispatch to meet changing loads and overall demand growth, so their mutual interest in price insurance is diminished by their opposing interests in “volumetric” insurance. All the intermediate contract forms (e.g., option contracts, tolling contracts) require at least one and usually both parties to bear risks of one kind or another. For the investor or its lender, risk reduces the value of the investment, and for the utility, any residual risk borne by its shareholders is inferior to assured cost recovery if it undertakes the investment itself – in the usual circumstance that it can obtain capital at lower cost than non-utility investors – and thereby transfers the risk to ratepayers. These financial considerations in generation investments are variants of the factors invoked in the analysis of economies of transaction costs described earlier. A contract sufficiently complete to deal with all contingencies is too complex to be practical, and even if it were feasible and could miraculously insure both parties so that for the utility it is not inferior to inclusion of the new plant in the rate base over the lifetime of the plant, approval of the contract in a prudency review would be problematic – and in some contingencies might not be enforceable. For example, if the contract extended over decades then during a prolonged period of low prices the supplier might default on the contract.1 The realistic contracts are therefore short-term (usually a few years, rarely 10) and incomplete, with both parties bearing shares of the price and volumetric risks. Until shortly before restructuring, this picture doomed non-utility generation from the start. With its low cost of capital and other advantages, a utility could always undertake a more efficient portfolio of investments than could private investors exposed to price and/or volumetric risks, and do so without sacrificing dispatch control. In the United States, PURPA first forced utilities to purchase generation from the QFs. This wedge initiated further opening of wholesale markets. Next were the Energy Policy Act of 1992 and the FERC’s ensuing Orders 886 and 888 that forced utilities to allow open access to unused transmission at nondiscriminatory prices. This wedge also initiated bilateral contracting between non-utility power generators and large industrial customers in the late 1990s.
EBL
1.2.3. The hidden assumptions The justifications of vertically integrated utilities contain hidden assumptions. As described in Section 1.3., many of these were revealed by actual experience after restructuring. Several that bear on how one interprets the foregoing arguments for vertical integration are listed below. •
A utility obtains capital at lower cost than its supplier. This assumption might seem to contradict theories of finance, but in fact it was realistic before restructuring. The seeming contradiction stems from the fact that one can invest equally in shares of the contracting parties (the independent generator and the utility). It therefore seems that an investor can hedge against price and volumetric risks that affect the seller and buyer oppositely, and therefore the seller and buyer should obtain
1 This assumes omission of provisions in recent contracts that enable the utility to take over the plant immediately in the event of default. Since restructuring, utilities’ contracts with suppliers have increasingly included stringent provisions to protect against the consequences of default.
34
Competitive Electricity Markets capital at comparable costs. In fact, however, cost-of-service regulation transfers the utility’s risks to ratepayers, and an investor cannot easily invest in shares of the general ratepayer population, especially over the extended period of cost recovery. If the transfer were not mixed with cross-subsidies then an investor might hedge by buying shares of a generator and an industrial customer, but this strategy was ineffective in the regulated era. Thus, one must view utilities’ lower cost of capital as both a cause and a consequence of vertical integration under cost-of-service regulation. • The utility is the sole buyer of generation. Those arguments that invoke economies of transaction costs depend heavily on the bilateral character of supply contracts and on the dominant monopsony power of the local utility, derived from its exclusive retail and transmission franchises. The advent of bilateral trading of bulk power supplies over wide regions, enabled by open access to transmission on nondiscriminatory terms, undercut this argument, and it evaporated with the arrival of multilateral trading in power exchanges managed by system operators. Both parties to contracts now have comparable options outside their bilateral relationship, namely to sell or buy at prevailing spot prices or to contract on a longer-term basis with competing alternatives. The prospect that a generation investment would be hostage to the sole utility buyer of energy, and to its transmission system, must now be seen as a consequence of the utility’s exclusive franchises, and thus an artifact of regulatory policy. • The owner of the transmission grid has the authority to manage it. Another artifact of regulatory policy was a utility’s right to exclude access to other parties, even if ample capacity were available after serving its native load. Arguments were mustered that the utility needed exclusive control to assure reliability and security, but with the advent of regional system operators (in 1998 in the United States for those systems not previously organized as power pools, but years earlier elsewhere) this argument dissolved. Indeed, the efficiency gains from regional dispatch and transmission allocation are now widely recognized. The argument for economies of scope also dissolved since nearly all components of this category now pertain to the system operator. What remains is the vestigial argument that coordinated planning of transmission expansion and generation investments might be more efficient if it were centralized, but even so the advantages occur at the level of regional systems rather than utility service territories. • Incentive effects are minor compared to economies of scale and scope. The engineering expertise of the utilities was always admired, and the PUCs took some credit for the fine performance by attributing it to the high standards they imposed (one day of outage in 10 years was the prevailing standard), as well as the advantages of vertical integration in establishing operating standards and procedures and in internalizing the public-good aspects of system security. This credit was less convincing after engineering operations and many skilled personnel were transferred to the FERC-regulated regional system operator. The regulated era was always beset by complaints that the commercial parts of utilities were complacent bureaucracies, and motivated more by cost recovery at inflated costs of capital than by minimizing overall costs (e.g., by favoring capital-intensive projects).
EBL
In later years these complaints led PUCs to experiment with performance-based regulation, rate caps, negotiated rates for industrial customers, and other devices. Behind these complaints, however, lay the basic fact that a utility’s financial incentive was muted by assured cost recovery and thus by full insurance against contingencies – and after the PUC
Reevaluation of Vertical Integration and Unbundling in Restructured Electricity Markets
35
accepted an asset into the rate base, by insurance against errors of judgment. The source of this comprehensive insurance was the regulatory compact. In some states, guaranteed cost recovery escalated rates to levels higher than neighboring states that then attracted away industrial and commercial firms seeking lower energy costs, or required negotiated industrial rates to forestall self-generation. In the United States restructuring was precipitated by one such state when the California PUC announced in 1993 that it would consider new regulatory principles and policies based on greater reliance on markets (see Borenstein et al., 2002). A chief consideration was the view that generation investments would be more efficient if private investors rather than ratepayers were to bear the consequences of erroneous judgments. Since insurance mutes incentives, one of the alternative policies it outlined, the one adopted in 1994, withdrew some or all of the provisions for assured recovery of investments in generation. These four assumptions, mostly hidden in the standard justifications and explanations of vertical integration, are typical of a longer list. They are emphasized here because they exemplify a tendency for the merits to be addressed within the regulatory policies, institutional structure, and market rules that sustain vertical integration. Section 1.3. takes the opposite approach and describes the fundamental changes that preceded and followed restructuring. Restructuring introduced new regulatory policies and market structures that reflected a new view that vertical integration is not intrinsic to the electricity industry; indeed, one can assemble a comparable argument that electricity is amenable to an industrial organization that relies heavily on liberalized markets.
EBL
1.3. The Case Now for Liberalized Markets
The case for liberalized wholesale markets is now examined from several perspectives. First we provide a brief review of the situation after restructuring. Then theoretical arguments are examined in light of empirical evidence. In both cases the discussion includes some developments in the two decades before restructuring in the United States, along with the experience after restructuring. The analysis focuses on those aspects that indicate the future role of vertically integrated utilities. The discussion is organized around four utility functions after restructuring: system operations, wholesale markets, retail service, and generation.
1.3.1. System operations after restructuring Some aspects of the industry remain unaffected by restructuring. The importance of universal service is reinforced now because economic development depends on technologies that rely on reliable power supplies. The traditional role of lighting is now supplemented by digital information and communication systems. Heating and cooling applications that were considered secondary are now considered essential for much commercial activity. The increased role of reliability enhances the public-good character of the transmission system, which remains a natural monopoly. But management of the grid is now viewed as a technical task, one that the engineering profession is well able to conduct, and that can meet the highest standards when its span is regional. This consensus developed early in those systems with national transmission companies, but in the United States it evolved from cooperative power pools and from the observation that local utilities were well able to integrate supplies purchased from QFs into their routine operations and dispatch procedures.
36
Competitive Electricity Markets
Control areas confined to utility service territories are an impediment to coordination over the wide areas now required. The magnitude of coordination problems at seams will eventually reveal the optimal span of regional operations, but only the largest utilities are viable candidates for retaining their own control areas. Equally, a utility’s motive to hoard its transmission facilities to serve its native load impairs efficient allocation of generation and transmission capacity. Recognizing this, orders by American regulators have steadily mandated or encouraged formation of independent system operators (ISOs) and regional transmission organizations (RTOs) with authority to manage regional transmission systems on a daily basis, and responsibility for ensuring open access and nondiscriminatory pricing. These changes are partly organizational, but also financial since they invoke principles of common carriage, remove “pancaking” of transmission charges, and impose charges to recover costs of ancillary services and re-dispatch to alleviate transmission congestion. 1.3.1.1. Consolidation of grid and market control From an economic viewpoint, the organizational specialization represented by system operators is notable for two features. Most important is that the externalities inherent in grid operations are handled by engineering procedures that enforce standards for reliability and security. The most obvious externality stems from the grid’s role as a public good enabling transmission among locations. Because the grid is vulnerable to cascading failures, automatic switches open lines and disconnect generators to minimize damage to facilities. The consequences for suppliers and retail customers are partly transitory due to loss of power production and consumption, but their equipment and appliances can also be injured, and industrial customers can lose goods in intermediate stages of production and incur the costs of idle labor. A subtler externality stems from differences between the technologies of supply and demand. On the supply side, sufficient fast-response reserves must be available to meet most contingencies because the ramp rates of generators are limited. The high value of ramp rate on the supply side has no counterpart on the demand side, since customers care only about whether power is on or off.2 If there is only one customer (e.g., a utility) then it sees clearly that continuous power availability depends on its provision and payment for reserves. But if there are many customers then each knows that what it pays for reserves has little effect on its own access to power. This is a classic free-rider problem (if there are many customers then each prefers that others provide and pay for reliability) since the marginal effect of any one customer’s contribution to reserves has a small effect on overall system reliability and therefore a small effect on the reliability of that customer’s supply. The free-rider problem is significant even when the customers are a few utilities, since each sees that its own marginal value from a marginal dollar expended for reserves depends heavily on how much others contribute.
EBL
2 A mathematical model leading to the conclusion that a completely decentralized market for energy and reserve capacity does not obtain full efficiency is by Chen et al. (2004). They conclude: “The decentralized market tends to depress ancillary service prices, which leads to the failure of the second welfare theorem. At each time the two market prices represent the market value of the on-line capacity of ancillary and primary services. From the system operator’s viewpoint, the ancillary service is more valuable because of its higher ramping rate. However, from the utility’s viewpoint, both services are identical, as long as they are available. In the decentralized market, the utility does not consider the ramping rate, since this is a constraint on production rather than consumption. As a result, the utility does not want to pay a higher price for the ancillary service.”
Reevaluation of Vertical Integration and Unbundling in Restructured Electricity Markets
37
Thus, without regulatory intervention and engineering command-and-control, markets for reserves are bound to be inefficient or even to collapse. These considerations extend beyond daily operating reserves to the general problem of ensuring adequate supply resources, including both generation and transmission capacity. To an investor, constructing a plant that will be idle most of the time seems a waste because it is called only rarely to meet contingencies, and this is equally true of a transmission line constructed to provide a backup for others that might fail. Thus, some form of payment to idle capacity is necessary to ensure that investments are sufficient. The practical issues of implementing resource adequacy requirements are addressed in Chao et al. (2006). In principle, each customer could be charged for the rate of variation in its load, and thus pay for reserve generators with high ramp rates. However, a basic economic advantage of a regional electricity system is that variations of customers’ loads largely cancel out, and aggregate loads are substantially predictable – the day-ahead prediction of the aggregate peak load in an hour is usually considered to be accurate within 3% or 4%. For this reason, retail pricing has largely ignored the possibility of charging for load variation other than on the basis of a customer’s load-duration profile over an extended period such as a year and to some extent, by real-time energy prices revised every few minutes. One could charge for load variation in some conditions of aggregate variation, such as the morning ramp at the beginning of the workday, or for increasing use of air conditioning when temperatures escalate on a hot summer afternoon, but in fact metering and pricing have not been developed to this degree of refinement.3 Instead, system operations provide a buffer to ensure the steady matching of supply and demand, re-dispatching online generators and calling on reserves as necessary to follow the aggregate load. The buffer is partly automatic, since generators equipped with governors and automatic controls (AGC) adjust power output in response to frequency variations detected by sensors. The automatic buffer provides an operator with an interval, usually considered to be about 10 minutes, in which to re-dispatch and call on reserves, beginning with hydro and spinning reserves, and then non-spinning reserves that require start-up and synchronization. The basic economic significance of system operations is that they supplant price-mediated market mechanisms in favor of command-and-control to ensure reliability and real-time matching of supply and demand. Market processes might conceivably be used to balance supply and demand almost continuously, but the costs and risks are too extreme to make them feasible on the short time frame that is relevant in a power system. Thus, the economies of scope invoked to justify vertically integrated utilities in the United States are now mostly obtained by consolidation of grid management and wholesale spot markets in system operators. These developments in the United States imitated earlier initiatives in other countries with national transmission companies. Linking of the Scandinavian state-owned systems into the coordinated multinational NordPool was one model, and the other was the England–Wales Pool that began in 1989 [e.g. Hunt (2002) and its analogs in Argentina, Alberta, and Australia – followed later by New Zealand, Spain, and others, e.g. EPRI 2002 and Rudnick et al. (2005) and Barker et al. (1997)]. Some consolidated systems encountered initial operational and economic problems, and all were reformed later in some ways, but the basic principle that regional systems are more efficient and more reliable has not been challenged.
EBL
3 However, after the California crisis the state provided $35 million to fund installation of interval meters at all large industrial and commercial customers, accounting for about a third of the aggregate load. Estimates of the costs of meters and the resulting benefits typically imply substantial net benefits; (cf. Borenstein 2004).
38
Competitive Electricity Markets
1.3.1.2. Unbundling of products A second feature of system operations is unbundling of wholesale supply into constituent products such as energy, reserves, and transmission, which nevertheless are allocated jointly by a consolidated spot market conducted by the system operator. Unbundling of supplies into relatively homogeneous products like energy, reserves, and transmission recognizes the basic scarce resources managed by engineers. These products must be differentiated by attributes like time and location, and operational constraints like a generator’s start-up time, minimum energy output, and ramp rate. Earlier arguments that this complex mix of products and attributes could not be efficiently priced are now, after successful implementations of time- and location-differentiated nodal pricing, confined to the operational constraints that involve nonconvexities, such as the start-up costs of a generator. Similarly, the various categories of regulation and operating reserves (spin, non-spin, replacement) are now priced systematically by recognizing that speed of response is the scarce resource, and therefore prices for slower reserves are limited by the feasibility of substitution with faster reserves. Unbundling wholesale supply into standard products enables efficient allocation among multiple parties, and more specifically, unbundling facilitates markets and settlement procedures for multilateral trade. Markets for medium-term bilateral contracts for energy (e.g., Eltermin in NordPool and the UK Power Exchange) also rely on standard product specifications.4 The responsibilities of a system operator now exemplify the economies of scope argument, since the engineers protect reliability and system security while also facilitating and/or conducting wholesale markets, and, indeed, procure resources needed for grid management from these same markets. For instance, the real-time balancing market is a market for both buyers and sellers, and also provides the bids from which the operating engineers obtain resources to follow the load, alleviate transmission congestion, and sustain voltage. Even so, spot markets have been organized quite differently among various system operators. Some reflect technology, as in the first version of NordPool where ample hydro resources allowed self-scheduling and an emphasis on energy trading, and zonal pricing sufficed since the chief transmission bottleneck was between Norway and Sweden. Those adopting the England–Wales Pool model focused on efficient day-ahead scheduling of thermal generators using a comprehensive optimization of dispatch. The ISOs in the US northeast also adopted this model since it simply extended the procedures of pre-existing power pools. Their relative success during and after the California crisis in 2000–01 motivated FERC to propose a Standard Market Design (SMD) that is now adopted also by California, among others (FERC, 2002). The SMD’s emphasis on comprehensive day-ahead optimization of all aspects does more than consolidate spot markets for products like energy, reserves, and transmission, since the optimization allocates available generation and transmission capacity by including unit commitments and scheduling along with assignments to energy generation and reserve status. Settlements are based on hourly locational prices for energy, reserves, and transmission, but the scarce resources are capacities rather than flows.
EBL
4
A peculiarity of bilateral contracting is that the resulting demands for transmission need not result in an efficient allocation. That is, with bilateral contracting the use value of transmission depends on the pairings of sellers and buyers, whereas multilateral trading can provide the maximum value obtainable among all pairings. This potential problem has been insignificant in systems that have enough multilateral trading (e.g., 30–40% is scheduled centrally in PJM) to ensure that transmission is accurately priced to reflect scarcity values at the margin.
Reevaluation of Vertical Integration and Unbundling in Restructured Electricity Markets
39
California considered the pool model but opted for an initial design closer to NordPool, including self-scheduling of generation and loads, a power exchange separate from the ISO, zonal pricing of transmission, and simple market clearing for standard products rather than comprehensive optimization (cf. Sweeney, 2006). This design was plagued by loose coordination and gaming of market rules almost from inception, and then virtually collapsed in a series of events initiated by scarcity of imported supplies from hydro sources.5 In the United States it is now widely accepted that the system operator must retain tight control, and in particular, that its authority must extend beyond reliability to maintenance of orderly wholesale markets. For instance, FERC now allows ISOs to impose various protective measures on generators: must-offer obligations, bid caps, automatic procedures for mitigation of market power, obligations to respond to dispatch instructions, mandatory scheduling of maintenance, penalties for large deviations from day-ahead schedules, and a dozen more interventions that might be listed. Analogous problems occurred elsewhere (e.g., New Zealand) when supplies were scarce, but there is no exact parallel to the California crisis. The panoply of ad hoc protective measures now imposed in the United States have not been adopted widely because other countries provide system operators with ample authority to ensure reliability and more discretion in managing their markets. The United States is unique in requiring an ISO to adhere rigorously to the terms of its FERC-approved tariff and market rules, and avoid any influence on energy markets. The California ISO was allowed the least discretion and was least able to bring its markets under control, but inability to weather a crisis is inherent in the strictures placed on all ISOs. The exact opposite can be seen in the United Kingdom’s reformed New Electricity Trading Arrangements (NETA) system, where the transmission system is owned and operated by an independent transmission company (ITC), the National Grid Company (NGC), rather than a non-profit bureaucratic ISO. NGC must adhere to a Balancing Code for settlements but, within a scheme of performance-based regulation that rewards reductions in its grid management charge, it has wide discretion to manage the grid, including taking positions in the energy market to acquire reserves and counter market power. The NETA system is also the opposite of FERC’s SMD, since all energy trading is conducted through private power exchanges for bilateral contracts, and physical feasibility is established hours-ahead rather than day-ahead (Newbery, 2006).
EBL
1.3.1.3. Lessons learned The lessons learned from the recent experience with system operations can be summarized thus: The organization, governance, and procedures of a regional system operator are very important and very complicated. Creating such an entity is a major task from an engineering viewpoint, and the design of its markets is equally challenging from an economic viewpoint. The complexity of system operations ensures that an initial design must be revised as deficiencies are discovered. The task is worthwhile because the regional scope can enhance reliability and improve overall efficiency of the short-term allocation of generation and transmission capacity. The vigor and growth of wholesale energy markets attests to gains from trade from system operations and markets on a regional scale. On the other hand, the California crisis was a salutary warning that wholesale power markets are 5 The origins and history of the California crisis are described by Blumstein et al. (2002) and Wilson (2002). An empirical analysis of the role of market power during the crisis is by Borenstein et al. (2002).
40
Competitive Electricity Markets
fragile when supplies are scarce, demand is inelastic, and utilities are obligated to serve but financially exposed. It is necessary to address these vulnerabilities – in terms of both resource adequacy and financial exposure – as argued later, but a backup remedy should be adequate authority and discretion for the system operator to intervene to stabilize its markets. That is, it should not rely solely on engineering procedures and established market rules when active intervention can stabilize markets or suppress the influence on market prices of dominant suppliers, and thus its scope should include some provisions for active management of markets. There is no indication yet that any one design is best. The diversity of designs now working reasonably well in various countries and within the United States suggests that local factors are important. A principal reason that local considerations can be determinative is that engineering management of a transmission system is so well developed (and virtually uniform worldwide) that it assures most of the gains from a regional system regardless of which among several alternative market designs are used. Wholesale markets for energy might be bilateral or multilateral, decentralized or optimized, provided system operators have adequate means to ensure reliability and allocation efficiency. A relevant comparison observes that the United Kingdom relies on private markets for bilateral contracts, Australia relies on an energy-only real-time market, and NordPool uses a day-ahead and real-time market; and zonal pricing of transmission congestion suffices in the latter two. Seemingly quite different are the day-ahead and real-time markets in the Pennsylvania–New Jersey–Maryland (PJM), New York, and New England systems that include unit commitment and scheduling and co-optimization of energy and reserves, and insist on the importance of nodal pricing of congestion. Yet differences in performance among these systems must be considered of second-order importance compared to their overall successes. This in particular requires that markets are workably competitive; that is, incentives promote productive and allocative efficiency. The California experience especially demonstrates the need for a design that discourages gaming of market rules. Gaming is essentially always due to a market imperfection, usually an unpriced scarce resource, and therefore a signal that efficiency can be improved by the measures that also eliminate gaming. For instance, the costly “dec game” in California was possible because congestion charges were imposed only between large zones and only day-ahead, which enabled those who caused intra-zonal congestion to escape congestion charges day-ahead and then be paid in real-time for alleviating the congestion they caused. The fact that nodal pricing eliminates the dec game illustrates the more general principle that even though many market designs are possible it is still true that efficiency requires that all scarce resources are priced, in this case intra-zonal transmission capacity.
EBL
1.3.2. Wholesale markets after restructuring This subsection outlines the economic argument that a liberalized wholesale power market is potentially an efficient means of allocation among buyers and sellers of energy. This argument assumes, of course, that engineering aspects are conducted by a system operator whose procedures supplant market processes on the short time frames relevant for protecting reliability and ensuring continuous matching of supply and demand. The discussion focuses first on the spot market for multilateral trading, then extends the analysis to the forward market for bilateral contracting, and then examines the incentives for efficient investments. The argument is mainly theoretical but mentions indications that its
Reevaluation of Vertical Integration and Unbundling in Restructured Electricity Markets
41
predictions are confirmed in some markets now in operation. The complexity of the markets now conducted by ISOs is evidence that implementation is difficult, but the concern here is whether wholesale markets are efficient in principle. 1.3.2.1. Models of restructuring The pace and scope of liberalized wholesale markets differ greatly among countries. The focus below is on those with comprehensive markets, some of which extended their scope gradually (e.g., NordPool, and Australia, which evolved from Victoria’s VicPool) while others liberalized in a single decisive act (e.g., England–Wales in 1989). There are two basic models: In one model the utility remains the single buyer, but regulators require the utility’s “make or buy” decision to consider competing offers from IPPs. In the United States this approach took an extreme form due to the 1978 PURPA that essentially required a utility to pay its avoided cost for supplies from small plants (less than 80 MW) that used co-generation of heat and power or renewable sources of energy. The second model allows a market for bilateral contracting between IPPs and large industrial customers, augmented by provisions for enhanced opportunities for trading among utilities. This model was in effect in the United States in the period after federal regulators required that utilities provide open access to transmission on nondiscriminatory terms, and it too stimulated substantial investments by IPPs. It is currently seen in the interim phase of the European Union’s directives for partial liberalization, and more specifically in the organization of the electricity industry in Germany. It may be that most of the gains and fewer problems are obtained with these intermediate forms of liberalization. Indeed, even in the United States those restructured systems that have allowed utilities to remain substantially integrated are cited as more successful – and the complete divestiture of gas- and oil-fired plants by California’s utilities is cited as one source of the crisis there. However, the aim here is to examine the viability of fully liberalized wholesale markets, and therefore to focus on those systems with comprehensive markets. The argument for restructuring depends crucially on its most important innovation, which is management of the regional transmission system by a system operator such as an ISO (O’Neill et al., 2006). Initially the discussion simply assumes that a system operator manages the transmission grid, although some of the difficulties encountered by a system operator are mentioned in passing. This enables bypassing the public-good and naturalmonopoly aspects of transmission, and some of the operational tasks required to assure reliability and system security. At the end of this subsection are comments on deficiencies due to inefficient allocation of risks, and an outline of the role of regulated utilities in improving risk management. The main motive for a market is to realize gains from trade. This motive originates in some separation of ownership. Power markets (and cooperative power pools) began with exchange agreements among utilities to enhance reliability, extended to long-term trading of energy supplies based on differing costs and asynchronous loads, and then expanded to daily “economy” trading to minimize generation costs. The gains from trade in a modern market stem from its regional scope and from substantial separation of ownership between sellers (generators) and buyers (utilities and other load-serving entities, LSEs). Separation of ownership between generators and LSEs may reflect advantages from specialization, but restructuring has proceeded more on the premise that the main advantages come from stronger incentives. One incentive effect is supposed to be more efficient investments when investors in generation bear the consequences of their decisions and operating decisions, rather than
EBL
42
Competitive Electricity Markets
relying on utilities’ assured recovery of costs. The second incentive effect is vigorous competition among generators when they are sufficiently numerous and small to have little influence on prices. Competition among generators is imperfect in most wholesale markets, and therefore typically requires some regulatory interventions; e.g., price or bid caps and must-offer obligations are typical. The vigor of competition depends ultimately on sufficient investments in generation and transmission capacities. At a minimum this requires that no firm is “pivotal” in the sense that its capacity is needed to meet a peak load in a transmission-constrained area. Over a longer time frame, competition stems from contestability, in the sense that incumbents cannot maintain high prices without stimulating new investments by entrants. Contestability has become a more effective constraint as smaller combined-cycle units can be installed in a few years, and for peak loads and offline fast-response reserves, combustion turbines (CTs) can be installed in a few months. Competition among LSEs is usually considered to be of secondary importance because their service obligations and the price inelasticity of retail demands limit their opportunities for strategic behavior to arbitrage between forward and spot markets. 1.3.2.2. Spot markets The spot markets conducted by ISOs are multilateral; that is, they allocate supplies offered by several sellers to several buyers. They are also “smart markets” in that energy trades are optimized subject to constraints on transmission capacities and generators’ ramp rates, required quality attributes (frequency, voltage), and operational procedures that ensure sufficient reserves to meet contingencies and avert cascading failures of equipment. A multilateral market is feasible only if several basic requirements are met. These include standardized commodities and qualities, accurate metering, explicit market rules, and settlement procedures that include assured creditworthiness of market participants. These requirements and other enabling aspects are now routine among system operators. Participants must subscribe to a contractual agreement that imposes reciprocal obligations, such as compliance with dispatch instructions, scheduling of outages for maintenance. After allegations of manipulations during the California crisis in 2000–01, the importance of a rigorous code of conduct and steady scrutiny by an independent market monitor is now universally accepted. Here it is taken as given that the mainly smooth operations of spot markets conducted by system operators are evidence that the basic enabling requirements of spot markets are feasible, and their implementation is now well developed. The gains from trade obtained from an ISO’s multilateral spot market are reduced in proportion to the extent of bilateral contracting in forward markets. Even so, gains remain because forward contracts account incompletely for contingencies and imperfect predictions of loads. Even Britain’s NETA system, which relies on forward contracting up to a few hours ahead of real-time operations, conducts a real-time balancing market in which operators re-allocate supplies to follow the load, alleviate congestion, and procure supplementary reserves. Most other ISOs rely on a day-ahead market as the primary multilateral market for energy trading because it can be integrated with unit commitments and scheduling, and engineering operations can ensure physical feasibility in advance by establishing reserve assignments and alleviating transmission congestion. In the United States, FERC insists that physical feasibility is established day-ahead so that the realtime balancing market is less volatile and less vulnerable to gaming that might threaten reliability or cause extreme prices. But the choice between the extremes represented by the NETA system and the tight controls enforced in the United States evidently depends on local circumstances; e.g., the greater prevalence of transmission congestion and tighter energy supplies in some regions may account for the choice in the United States.
EBL
Reevaluation of Vertical Integration and Unbundling in Restructured Electricity Markets
43
The efficiency of a multilateral spot market depends ultimately on whether pricemediated transactions are sufficient. They are insufficient if efficiency depends on significant public goods or other externalities. One can interpret the system operator’s management of the grid as ensuring the public-good aspects of reliability. The other main externality is environmental, and in many countries it is addressed by markets for emission allowances. Even so, the more fundamental impediment to efficiency concerns the scope of wholesale markets. In principle, efficiency requires that each scarce resource has its appropriate price. To a great extent this requirement has been addressed by multiple simultaneous markets for energy, reserves, and transmission, and further, by prices for each that are differentiated by time and location; i.e. by spatially differentiated “nodal” prices established at short intervals. But a peculiarity of power markets is that there are other resources that occasionally are scarce; e.g., reactive power for local voltage support. Also, some products are imperfect versions of the resource that is actually scarce; e.g., the reserve categories reflect imperfectly the scarcity of fast-response resources, and in particular the key quality attribute, which is ramp rate or start-up time. Schemes have been tried to establish prices for reactive power and ramp rate, but system operators usually find it sufficient to rely on engineering procedures and standard reserve categories. In the occasional instances that its markets do not provide adequate resources to manage the grid, engineers retain authority to issue dispatch directives that are settled according to rules for “out of market” transactions. A prevalent deficiency in the United States is persistent under-scheduling: when day-ahead generation schedules derived from the energy and reserve markets provide insufficient online generation to meet predicted loads, the ISO must make additional unit commitments and pay generators whatever portions of their start-up costs are not recovered from market sales. Some ISOs encourage arbitrage between day-ahead and real-time prices (by allowing “virtual” bids day-ahead that are not backed by physical resources or loads) in an attempt to reduce under-scheduling. In sum, one can conclude that from an operational viewpoint the market conducted by a system operator is inherently inferior to fully consolidated operations within a vertically integrated utility, but increasingly the prevalent view is that the disparity is small, and that such markets are mainly successful. The sufficiency of price-mediated transactions must also be considered from the viewpoint of market participants. At a mundane level, the obvious burdens that the ISO imposes on participants (bidding, responses to dispatch directives, settlements, etc.) are likely greater than those in vertically integrated systems, and in some the ISO’s expenses and therefore its grid management charges (called “uplift”) are higher than anticipated. Britain’s NETA system is notable for using performance-based regulation of NGC that rewards reduction of this charge. A basic deficiency of simple market clearing is that it cannot cope directly with thermal generators’ nonconvex cost components such as startup and no-load running costs, and nonconvex operating constraints such as minimum generation rates and maximum ramp rates. Since this deficiency arises partly from the definition of the traded products, alternative definitions have been proposed (e.g., enabling a base-load generator to bid to supply energy steadily over the day) but not widely adopted. The two main alternatives are self-scheduling of generators by their owners (e.g., NordPool, NETA, California, Texas) and in those systems that inherited the operating procedures of power pools (e.g., PJM, New England, New York), central optimization of schedules for those units not committed to bilateral contracts (using “three part bids” that include the fixed-cost components and generators’ reports of their operating constraints). Unit commitments by the ISO require that the portion of fixed costs not recovered from market prices is uplifted. The ISO schedules additional units to enhance reliability, but in
EBL
44
Competitive Electricity Markets
several systems it is alleged to depress energy and reserve prices. New England introduced separate semi-annual markets for offline fast-start reserves mainly to provide adequate revenues to attract sufficient installations of CTs needed to protect against large contingencies. As described later, a general issue is whether an ISO’s markets stimulate investments in an optimal mix of generation technologies. 1.3.2.3. Forward markets Forward markets for longer-term bilateral contracts enable both parties to hedge against price and/or quantity risks. Bilateral contracting plays a large role in all wholesale power markets due to the high volatility of spot prices. Some contracts impose physical requirements but most are essentially financial hedges against spot prices, as for example in a “contract for differences” (CFD) in which the seller and buyer insure each other against deviations of the spot price from the strike price specified in the contract. The central role of forward contracting was evident in the California crisis when the California utilities, which were largely prohibited from contracting forward, encountered severe financial difficulties while other utilities in nearby states in western United States that faced equally high spot prices were not jeopardized because they relied on spot markets for small shares of their procurements, usually less than 10%. When the state intervened to stabilize the California market its principal tactic was to secure long-term contracts that thereafter provided the bulk of the utilities’ requirements. It is important to realize, however, that long-term contracts are risky in a different way. In California the state signed contracts with generators that specified prices that turned out to be exorbitant in the long run; moreover, the contracts specified fixed quantities that in some circumstances were excessive. This debacle repeated California’s earlier mistake in the 1980s when it offered QFs long-term contracts at prices that later were revealed as excessive. Although contracts written as options could have avoided these unfavorable outcomes, this experience illustrates the more basic source of the risks inherent in longterm contracts. Wholesale power markets are inherently vulnerable to systemic risks, i.e., risks that cannot be fully dissipated by mutual insurance between contracting parties. Systems with substantial hydro resources are vulnerable to prolonged droughts, those with mainly thermal plants are vulnerable to changing fuel prices and new-generation technologies, and on the demand side, both are affected by seasonal and annual weather patterns, business cycles, and other large-scale economic developments – some cyclical and some reflecting secular trends. In the regulated era, systemic risks were moderated by recovering costs from retail rates that varied slowly over extended periods. Restructuring introduced a new tension between the advantages of forward contracting in insuring against short-term spot-price volatility and the risk that the strike price or promised quantity specified in a contract would turn out ex post facto to be unfavorable to one or the other party. Trading of standard intermediate-term bilateral contracts is vigorous in those systems (e.g., NordPool and Britain) with power exchanges that effectively minimize search and transaction costs. These contracts are usually for fixed quantities, which is somewhat anomalous since on general grounds one might expect other forms, such as option contracts, to be useful hedges against quantity risks. However, recent years have brought a greater variety of contract forms and tolling agreements, and some of the innovative contract forms that might be used to ensure resource adequacy. In all systems the major share of power generation is covered by forward contracts; e.g., in PJM bilateral contracts account for about twice the volume traded in its spot market, and in Britain’s NETA system they are nearly 100%. FERC’s SMD supposes that the bulk
EBL
Reevaluation of Vertical Integration and Unbundling in Restructured Electricity Markets
45
of power trading will rely on forward contracts. In particular, it aims to confine the spot market to adjustments day-ahead and real-time to address contingencies and to assure physical feasibility and reliability. The volume of real-time trading is usually under 10% in well-functioning systems – except during California’s crisis when real-time trading approached 50%, presenting dire threats to reliability. Since then, forward contracting in California has been essentially mandatory, enforced with penalties for deviations from day-ahead schedules that exceed 5%, until recent changes to its market rules. Regulators usually exempt a utility from prudency reviews for a moderate amount of purchases via intermediate-term bilateral contracts, provided they are standard contracts traded in organized markets with adequate competition and transparency. But this exemption does not apply to long-term contracts and to any transactions that hint of self-dealing with affiliated generation companies. During the initial phase of restructuring, divestiture of a utility’s generation assets was eased in those systems that included so-called vesting contracts in terms of the spin-off of the generation subsidiary or sales of its assets. The assets were bundled together with contracts that fixed the prices and quantities of continued sales to the utility for several years. This procedure avoided self-dealing while providing the requisite financial hedges for the seller and buyer after divestiture. It also had a profound effect on dominant suppliers’ influence on prices in spot markets. In general, a generation firm’s gain from withholding supply or bidding higher to raise spot prices is reduced in proportion to the amount of its capacity that is committed to filling the requirements of forward contracts. The market influence of dominant suppliers in the England–Wales system increased after the expiration of vesting contracts, and analogous effects are now evident in Australia. Regulatory policy has therefore often focused on measures to ensure that both generators and utilities are substantially hedged against spotprice volatility by forward contracts. A significant impediment, however, is that utilities subject to competition from other LSEs and from IPPs are reluctant to sign very long contracts in view of the risk that their service obligations might change substantially. Their role as the retail provider of last resort (POLR) exacerbates this risk; e.g., an industrial customer might opt for bilateral contracting with an IPP when market prices are low and then later opt to return to service from the utility when prices rise. Many generation companies insist on the importance of long-term forward contracting. Their incentive to insure against spot-price volatility is greatly strengthened by effects on their costs of capital. The profitability of an investment in a new plant depends crucially on the cost of capital obtained from lenders and equity investors. Long-term contracts for major portions of the plant’s capacity reduce the risk of the investment, and thereby the rate of return demanded by sources of funds; indeed, a lender often treats long-term contracts rather than the physical asset as the main security for a loan.
EBL
1.3.3. Retail service after restructuring Cost-of-service regulation was long implemented in a way that contradicted its premise. A utility was reimbursed for costs incurred, but not until late in the regulated era was a customer charged the actual incremental cost of the service provided. Equally inefficient was the absence of differentiated service conditions that would allow customers a range of choices beyond simply the number of kilowatt-hours (kWh) to draw from the system at the standard cents-per-kWh (¢/kWh) price. Limited choice and uniform pricing were expedient in the years when the infrastructure of the electricity industry was being established, universal service was a dominant consideration, the technology of retail service
46
Competitive Electricity Markets
delivery was primitive, and metering and billing were major impediments to service differentiation. Nevertheless, regulators continued these policies long after the limitations that previously justified them had relaxed. Cross-subsidization from industrial and commercial to residential customers was a basic feature of universal service, but there were others derived from technical and economic factors. The most obvious considerations stemmed from the public-good aspect of grid security and the fact that service reliability is largely uniform. A customer’s service might be interrupted or curtailed, but quality attributes like frequency, waveform, and voltage are inherently uniform in a system with alternating current. Interruptions and curtailments can be imposed selectively only with costly metering and control technologies, or by direct communication that was practically confined to large industrial customers. The uniformity of quality attributes implied a basic tension between those customers who preferred lower rates for lower-quality and less reliable service (e.g., heating and cooling applications) and those who preferred higher rates for higher-quality and more reliable service (e.g., lighting and industrial production). This tension was resolved in favor of greater reliability for several reasons. One was the technical advantage of a highly secure grid and the low cost of extending high quality to all customers, and another was the importance of high quality in promoting economic development. But the basic enabling feature was cross-subsidization that in effect charged premium rates to industrial customers for high quality that allowed lower rates for residential customers and extension of universal service. There was always an array of special provisions (e.g., low offpeak rates for street lighting and other municipal services) and special considerations (e.g., provision of the highest quality to hospitals and other essential facilities) but here we focus on the main tensions among industrial, commercial, and residential customers. These customer categories are used here as surrogates for the much more complex diversity of preferences among customers; and even for a single customer, diverse preferences in relation to different appliances and technologies (e.g., heating/cooling, lighting, production, information/communication). This heterogeneity implies efficiency gains from service differentiation, but in the electricity industry there were, and remain, severe technical and cost barriers that preclude full differentiation of service conditions and rates. One can describe restructuring as a late stage of the more general trend to improve overall efficiency. At the retail level, this entailed unbundling of service components, pricing based on incremental cost, and, inevitably, a declining role for cross-subsidization. This trend included all the infrastructure industries, but the discussion here addresses only its effects in the electricity industry and the developments in the retail sector, and the next subsection addresses developments in the generation sector. Both cases emphasize the efficiency improvements that were sought through restructuring, and largely ignore the political resistance that inevitably accompanied the elimination of subsidies. It also ignores the role of subsidies from the government in some developing countries.6
EBL
6 The major industrial countries decided long ago that the electricity industry must cover its costs from retail rates paid by customers. A major exception occurred when the state of California issued debt to fund a 10% retail rate reduction during the first years of restructuring, and then during the crisis assumed financial responsibility for the utilities’ wholesale procurements, and later issued debt to fund it. National transmission companies indirectly rely on the government’s good credit but costs are recovered from customers.
Reevaluation of Vertical Integration and Unbundling in Restructured Electricity Markets
47
Economic theory predicts that a uniform flat rate causes inefficiencies for three reasons, all due to the heterogeneity of customers. •
A uniform rate does not reflect directly the incremental costs of services demanded by different customers in response to that rate; customers are more or less sensitive to the costs they impose on the system. • A uniform rate applies to an undifferentiated commodity, whereas customers have differing preferences for the various quality attributes of service. • A flat rate foregoes opportunities to recover infrastructure costs with less distortion of incentives. Economists invoke two general theories about how to recover fixed costs from regulated retail rates in a way that promotes overall efficiency. One theory is due to Ramsey and its application to pricing by utilities is due to Boiteux and Mirrlees (summarized in Wilson, 1993). Generally, it supposes that the utility would run a deficit if infrastructure costs were not recovered by commodity taxes included in retail rates. Its characteristic implication is that customers with more inelastic demands should pay larger shares of the deficit. This theory was largely rejected by regulators due to the characteristic feature of retail service that demands are most inelastic among residential customers and least among industrial customers. The other theory aims to sensitize customers to the cost implications of their demands for service. This theory has been applied in two very different ways, depending on whether costs are measured in the long run or the short run.
EBL
•
A prominent application of pricing that reflects long-run costs is used in France, where tariffs are designed to emphasize the long-run implications for the utility’s investments. A commercial or industrial customer pays a “demand charge” that depends on its peak load and then, for each kilowatt within that peak load, an energy charge that depends on the number of hours that kilowatt is used during the year (which requires a special meter).7 In effect, this scheme charges the customer for its load-duration profile over the year. • Rates that reflect short-run costs are differentiated by time or events. The simplest tariffs distinguish only between peak and offpeak periods. Equally simple in concept is real-time pricing based on the actual system marginal cost in each hour, but metering costs have confined applications to large industrial customers. Until recently, the costs of communication or control, metering, and billing were long the impediments to differentiation of rates based on peak–offpeak periods or real-time pricing (Zarnikau, Chapter 8 in this volume). It remains one reason that rates differentiated by times or contingencies rarely extend to residential and small commercial customers, but equally important are customers’ own costs of real-time communication and control, and most fundamentally, their reluctance to bear short-term price volatility and inability to obtain financial insurance. 7
This form of retail pricing, called a Wright tariff in the United States, was used in the early years of the industry. See Wilson (1993, section 2) for an extended description of the tariffs in France, circa 1990.
48
Competitive Electricity Markets
1.3.4. Generation operations and investments after restructuring Most systems allow self-scheduling of generation committed to bilateral contracts, including generation within utilities, and some allow self-scheduling for all generation. In the United States those systems that give the ISO responsibility for all other scheduling impose substantial requirements for adherence to directives for advance unit commitment and scheduling, and continuing compliance with dispatch directives. In addition, the ISO can designate plants that “must run” for reliability and pay them their incremental costs. However, these requirements differ immaterially from the previous procedures within utilities and in power pools. Even the proliferating regulatory interventions (e.g., “must-offer” obligations to bid all available capacity, and advance scheduling of deferrable maintenance) largely re-establish the comprehensive control by the utility or the power pool before restructuring – the notion that tight control is unnecessary was abandoned after the California crisis. Following the California crisis, FERC proposed its SMD that essentially replicates the design of the northeastern ISOs descended from previous power pools. From the viewpoint of a generator, SMD really has only one product, which is generation capacity that is mostly stable from day to day and in every hour, as are its other attributes such as location and ramp rate. The SMD requires that an IPP must provide each day for each generation unit a “three-part” bid that specifies its start-up and no-load costs and its schedule of bids for energy. In addition, the ISO knows its location, maintenance schedule, heat rate, ramp rate, minimum and maximum generation levels, and other technical parameters, as well as its fuel constraints and commitments to bilateral contracts and to exports to other control areas. If one takes FERC’s SMD as the standard, then one can summarize a generator’s viewpoint rather simply. Operations are about the same as they would be in a vertically integrated utility or a power pool. Indeed, because many IPPs are subsidiaries of energy companies that own both generators and utilities, the organizational aspects are unchanged in some respects. But financial matters are vastly different because remuneration derives entirely from market prices. The main effects are therefore strong incentives to minimize costs, and because they are completely exposed to the volatility of market prices, strong incentives to contract forward via bilateral contracts. This conclusion differs somewhat for other systems (e.g., NETA, NordPool, Germany, Australia) that rely less on optimization by the system operator and more on selfscheduling, and rely more on forward contracting than on spot markets. The main conclusion remains, however, that for generators it is the financial implications of restructuring and liberalized markets that are most important. This accords with expectations that were raised when restructuring was initiated, since even then it was believed that operational aspects would not be changed materially if a system operator took over ongoing management of the grid, and possibly also spot markets. The results attest to the success in establishing well-functioning system operators (of various designs), and also to success in making profit as measured by regional market prices the criterion of financial performance.
EBL
1.4. The Unsolved Problems of Liberalized Markets This section compiles a summary of the problems that persist after the initial years of restructuring of the electricity industry, and the accompanying liberalization of wholesale and retail markets. The discussion is divided into two subsections. The first summarizes the problems that cannot be solved efficiently by market processes. The second summarizes the problems that might in principle be solved by market processes, but that in fact current
Reevaluation of Vertical Integration and Unbundling in Restructured Electricity Markets
49
designs have made little progress in solving adequately due to various practical aspects. In both cases these problems are deeply intertwined with the fundamental problem of how best to allocate risk bearing among market participants.
1.4.1. Problems not to be solved by markets This subsection focuses on electricity industry functions that require continuing regulatory interventions, regardless of market design. These functions including meeting transmission system requirements, maintaining a reliable grid, and guaranteeing universal service. 1.4.1.1. Meeting transmission system requirements The role of the transmission grid as necessary infrastructure is even more important in liberalized markets because it is the common highway for energy trading. An AC system is synchronized continuously over its entire span, and flows must be adjusted continuously to control frequency, voltage, and line loadings. Flexible AC Transmission System (FACTS) technology may eventually allow flows to be regulated by varying impedances, but most systems presently require operators to manage regional segments and to coordinate among them. The natural monopoly and economies of scale of transmission investments are therefore reinforced by the necessity of tightly coordinated operations. Recognizing this, many countries long ago established state-owned or regulated national transmission companies charged with ensuring adequate investments and ongoing operations. Those with privately owned or predominantly utility-owned transmission systems depend instead on regulation. Most simply provide for recovery of investment and maintenance costs, while the more advanced impose grid management charges and congestion charges and eliminate pancaking of transmission access charges. A fundamental innovation of restructuring, however, is to require open access and nondiscriminatory pricing according to the principles of common carriage – minimal requirements for liberalized wholesale markets. These measures, however, omit three fundamental requirements. One is efficient management of grid operations. This is not assured by assigning the task to an ISO of the form that, in United States, is a non-profit bureaucratic organization with diffuse incentives, unresponsive governance, and discretion restricted to explicit rules codified in its tariff. Performance-based regulation, as exemplified in the United Kingdom’s regulation of the NGC, offers prospects for stronger incentives and greater discretion to manage grid operations flexibly to cope with circumstances as they arise. The second fundamental requirement is planning of transmission expansion. Restructuring has weakened the integrated resource planning previously undertaken by utilities and in the United States left no agency responsible. This is especially serious now that liberalization has impaired coordination between transmission and generation investments. When generation investments are undertaken privately, it is imperative that transmission planning establishes reliable forecasts of the topology of the grid in future years so that decisions about generation investments can be adapted to the configuration that will be in place during at least the first 10 years of a plant’s life. The best plan will likely exploit the possibilities for substitution between generation and transmission that an integrated plan might achieve incompletely, but it is still necessary to establish reliable predictions of grid expansion. Regulatory authority is often required because private generation companies invariably prefer to build in a load pocket even if transmission expansion might be more efficient.
EBL
50
Competitive Electricity Markets
The third fundamental requirement is financial incentive for transmission investment. The regulated rate of return usually allowed for cost recovery of transmission investments is inherently vulnerable to the “Averch–Johnson effect” of favoring excessively capital-intensive investments (Sherman, 1985).8 This is especially true in liberalized markets because transmission projects must compete for funds with other projects, such as generation investments. A deeper problem, however, is that private incentives for transmission investments can differ substantially from social motives because the distributional effects can be substantial. For example, a retail utility in region A may want to fund a transmission line that enables it to purchase energy from region B where generation costs are lower. But if the effect of the new line is to equalize wholesale energy prices in regions A and B then an accounting of the aggregate social benefit must also consider the higher energy prices charged to retail customers in region B, as well as the effects of price equalization on suppliers in both regions. There are also new motives for transmission projects undertaken to diminish the market power of local generators. 1.4.1.2. Maintaining reliable grid operations An important innovation of restructuring is the assignment of ongoing grid management to a system operator. The public good obtained from the transmission infrastructure depends continuously on protecting quality attributes (frequency, voltage, waveform), service reliability, and security against cascading failures. As mentioned previously, power markets are fundamentally incomplete due to disparities between technical constraints on supply (e.g., generator ramp rates, reactive power requirements) that affect reliability, and customers’ perceptions that they have no choice for power of the requisite quality. Rather than relying on markets, operating procedures rely on well-developed engineering principles to sustain quality and to protect reliability and security. A system operator obtains needed resources from spot markets (or “out of market” if necessary), and it supports and facilitates these markets, but ultimately it invokes command-and-control methods to ensure rigorous coordination. This reflects the reality that grid management assures physical feasibility, whereas markets determine mainly the financial terms for settling transactions. There remains, however, considerable latitude for the system operator to affect the efficiency of congestion management and the efficiency of its spot markets. The performancebased incentives and wide discretion allowed NGC in the United Kingdom recognize this. Indeed, the reductions in NGC’s uplift and the increases in PJM’s congestion cost strongly support a conclusion that incentives for the system operator should be an important ingredient of regulatory policy. In contrast, in the United States the prevalent view that engineering “best practice” determines the ISO’s actions is the main justification for ignoring incentives and relying on a bureaucratic non-profit organization. FERC’s orders allow ITCs, like NGC, to operate within ISOs and RTOs so one expects that in the future their role may increase, and thereby incentives might be strengthened. However, a basic impediment to the flexibility and discretion required for full efficiency remains the reliance in the United States on the rigid tariff prescribing the main aspects of each ISO’s operating procedures and market rules, as well as the prohibition against stakeholder involvement in governance.
EBL
8 Averch–Johnson effect (AJ effect), named after two economists who found that under rate-of-return regulation, if the allowed return is greater than the required return on capital, the firm will tend to over-invest in capacity beyond what is needed for economically efficient production.
Reevaluation of Vertical Integration and Unbundling in Restructured Electricity Markets
51
Among system operators, the designs of spot markets differ markedly. Their scopes range from a single balancing market to multiple forward and real-time markets. Their procedures range from simple market clearing to elaborate optimizations of all aspects simultaneously. And their financial settlements range from energy payments to prices elaborately differentiated by time and location and differentiated among energy, various reserve categories, transmission, and in rare cases even payments for reactive power and other related products. There is no simple explanation for the huge difference between the United Kingdom’s NETA, which uses only bilateral trading and self-scheduling up to a few hours before the real-time balancing market, and the enormously complex markets of the ISOs in the United States. A few features are evidently relevant (e.g., the lower incidence of transmission congestion in the United Kingdom) but both evolved from power pools with somewhat similar procedures initially. A key difference is that, for complex reasons, the United Kingdom rejected the previous pool style of organization when it devised the simpler NETA, whereas at nearly the same time in the United States the experience of the California crisis motivated FERC to guard vigorously against a repetition by proposing its SMD. The result is that NETA relies on NGC to assure physical feasibility on a time frame of hours, while the ISOs establish physical feasibility day-ahead in consolidated markets for energy, reserves, and transmission (including unit commitments), maintain dispatch control throughout, and penalize real-time deviations. It remains unclear whether these and other system operators might converge to market designs with somewhat similar features. Continued experimentation with market designs might eventually produce convergence, but it is also possible that they will differ permanently due to initial conditions. Certainly in the United States the shock of the California crisis just 2 years after its ISO began operation has remained so vivid that comparisons with the performance of the NETA design are ignored. The crux of the difference is the considerable confidence in the United Kingdom that NGC can manage physical feasibility and that bilateral trading suffices for efficient trading, while the accepted view in the United States is that physical feasibility must be established absolutely a full day ahead – for fear that any discrepancy will again open opportunities for gaming and abuses of market power – and therefore that the ISO’s markets must be multilateral, consolidated, and optimized. Differing experiences are also relevant to comparisons among other systems – NordPool, Germany, Australia, New Zealand – each of which has a market design whose unique features were heavily influenced by experience. However, an open issue for every market is the provision of adequate investment incentives to ensure long-term resource adequacy. A facet of these considerations is paramount when predicting the future role of system operations. One might make the case that markets in NordPool (established by the national transmission companies) and Germany (conducted by utilities) developed organically as energy trading grew, and in the United Kingdom the privately run markets for bilateral trading have developed vigorously after NETA began. But in other cases regulators and/or legislators have either chosen the market design or largely determined its main features, except for those aspects narrowly circumscribed by engineering requirements. Some may be good designs, and certainly others have been deficient – notably the deep flaws imposed on the California design by the legislature and the PUC. A basic issue to be resolved is whether in the future the spot markets of the system operator can and should cater to the commercial interests of the market participants the way other commodity markets do, or whether the peculiar technical requirements of power systems require that regulators have final authority to specify the market design.
EBL
52
Competitive Electricity Markets
1.4.1.3. Guaranteeing universal service One part of retail service that is not entirely amenable to market processes is assurance of universal service. Extension of distribution lines to remote customers is now rarely a problem, so the main requirement is provision of service under standard terms and conditions. Regulators retain authority to define standard service plans, and to ensure that there is a POLR. The regulatory compact was the means in the era of vertically integrated utilities, but other means are now possible. The POLR was selected via a procurement auction in some cases where the utility’s incumbency advantage was not so great as to exclude effective competition from other LSEs. But competitive procurement with fixed remuneration runs the risk that a POLR that is an unregulated LSE becomes insolvent when wholesale prices rise. As a result, the dominant mode is to rely again on the regulatory compact, so that utilities provide basic service and recover their costs from retail rates that are nearly level over time. This mode is deeply at odds with the initial view of what liberalization of retail markets could accomplish. Ideally, retail liberalization implies that retail customers pay the hourly wholesale price for energy (in addition to other charges for distribution) but they also purchase financial hedges against price volatility to the extent they prefer. This ideal cannot be realized anytime soon because metering is still primitive and the markets for financial hedges are undeveloped, but more basically this ideal is impractical for the (mostly small residential) customers most affected by universal service, even if financial hedges were subsidized. Relying instead on utilities, and using the regulatory compact to assure cost recovery over time, is likely to remain the only practical solution for decades. This poses two basic problems. The first is that the “core” of customers opting for basic service is inherently unstable. Those who opt out when wholesale prices are low are equally motivated to opt again for basic service when wholesale prices are high. Charges might be imposed on those who leave the core and again on those who return, but exactly how such a system would ensure financial stability through prolonged swings of wholesale prices is not well understood and has not been fully developed. The second basic problem occurs even if those who opt out of the core never return. The customers who are least costly to serve (e.g., those with flat load profiles) are precisely those who will be offered the most attractive terms by IPPs and non-utility LSEs, and therefore they are the ones most likely to opt out of the core. This leaves in the core only the customers most expensive to serve, implying that their retail rates (even if leveled over time) will rise as the core is depleted of the more profitable customers. This scenario is entirely realistic since it merely repeats the dire experience of those utilities that, late in the regulated era, were subject to bypass by profitable industrial customers who opted for self-generation or co-generation, or later, direct contracting with IPPs.
EBL
1.4.2. Problems not yet solved by markets The discussion now turns to a different class of problems, those that liberalized markets were initially believed to solve, but in fact have not. These include assuring adequate generation resources and benefiting retail customers, an issue also addressed in Chapters 9–13 of this volume. 1.4.2.1. Assuring adequate generation resources The generation sector was thought to be the most amenable to market solutions. There is some evidence that operating efficiency has improved at divested plants, as measured by labor and fuel (heat rate) inputs. Other aspects of operations are less clear in those systems
Reevaluation of Vertical Integration and Unbundling in Restructured Electricity Markets
53
that exclude self-scheduling for those plants not committed to bilateral contracts. Those ISOs in the United States that use variants of FERC’s SMD are most extreme in abandoning market-clearing processes in favor of comprehensive optimization, including unit commitments and scheduling of energy generation and reserve assignments. Although these ISOs settle accounts using prices computed as the marginal costs of unbundled products, their operations consist essentially of centralized allocations of available generation and transmission capacities. These procedures differ little from those used previously in vertically integrated utilities and power pools. These ISOs in the United States might eventually resemble the more decentralized systems in other countries if, as FERC intends, bilateral contracting becomes more pervasive. At present, however, the fraction of plants scheduled centrally is substantial and stable, and in many ways FERC’s insistence that each ISO must ensure day-ahead physical feasibility necessitates centralized unit commitment and scheduling, and continuing dispatch control until real-time. The mix of generation investments has been problematic in most ISOs. An encouraging sign is that many systems now have substantial dispatchable loads that compete with generators in reserve markets, and increasingly the demands of industrial customers respond to real-time prices. The number of interruptible or curtailable retail service contracts remains comparable to the pre-restructuring period, but in general the utilities’ active promotion of demand-side management declined after restructuring as regulators withdrew the subsidies and incentives previously provided. Regulators have continued some subsidies of generation from renewable sources, often by using market mechanisms such as auctions, but also by innovative schemes such as the tradable “green certificates” introduced in Europe. In addition, renewable sources increasingly compete on equal terms, albeit with inherent disadvantages because generation need not be dispatchable and can be intermittent (e.g., wind and solar). Now the mix of generation investments is also affected by requirements for tradable permits for emission of pollutants, such as sulfur dioxide and nitrous oxides. The ratification of the Kyoto Treaty will in future years lead to comparable requirements for emissions of carbon dioxide and other greenhouse gases. The most severe problem concerns investments in peakers (e.g., CTs) that routinely provide fast-response offline reserves and occasionally generate to meet peak loads when prices exceed their high marginal costs. In other countries such as Australia, bid or price caps are sufficiently high that peakers obtain substantial revenues in times of supply scarcity (and encourage demanders to obtain financial hedges). While a high price cap is arguably the best solution, the low caps in the United States curtail CTs’ revenues from occasional generation and force them to rely mainly on payments for reserve assignments. However, centralized unit commitment by the ISO, usually undertaken to strengthen reliability, has the side effect that it depresses the price for offline reserve capacity, because the minimum operating level of a newly committed unit tends to create an excess supply of spinning reserve. The usual motive for extra unit commitments is under-scheduling of loads in the dayahead market, compared to the ISO’s forecast of the next day’s peak load. This problem is acute in New England because its ISO needs substantial offline reserve capacity to meet its unusually large contingencies, but reserve prices are insufficient to cover the carrying cost of a CT. The ISO there is exceptional for addressing this problem by allowing CTs to capture scarcity rents. One device is a separate semi-annual market for offline reserves, and a second is a contingent capacity payment awarded to all available capacity whenever reserves are in short supply in real-time operations.
EBL
54
Competitive Electricity Markets
These measures are indicative of a general trend toward special provisions intended to obtain sufficient supplies of reserves in daily operations and more elaborate efforts to assure adequate generation resources. The plain fact seems to be that adequate reserve capacity – both fast-response reserves in the short term and total available capacity in the long-term – is not assuredly provided by the financial incentives derived from wholesale markets. Reserve capacity can be insufficient when prices in these markets are depressed by regulatory interventions, as in the United States where low price caps and residual unit commitments for reliability affect revenues obtained by CTs. But the basic economic problem is that individual customers have insufficient incentives to pay for reserve capacity (and its chief attribute, a high ramp rate) that is idle most of the time and that serves mainly to provide the public goods of system reliability and grid security. Customers and regulators are acutely sensitive to these matters when prices are high because loads are high or supply is scarce, but ordinarily their financial incentives are myopic compared to the integrated resource planning previously conducted by utilities. A chief motive for separating the organizational components of vertically integrated utilities was to establish stronger incentives for efficient investments in generation. Rather than assured cost recovery obtained by a utility, a private investor in generation obtains the subsequent rewards and bears the risks that follow from its decision. But the evidence is mixed as regards investment. Success stories in countries like Australia and in ERCOT, which is not subject to FERC jurisdiction, are matched by a bleaker picture in other parts of the United States and in Europe. The insufficiency of new investments was initially attributed to prolonged regulatory uncertainty, compounded by the demise of new contracts for QFs, including both co-generation and those using renewable energy sources. Then high wholesale prices in the period surrounding the California crisis stimulated substantial investments by IPPs, mainly in combined-cycle gas-fired plants. But this was followed by rather low prices that resulted in financial distress for many IPPs and bankruptcy for some. This could be a sign that boom and bust cycles are endemic in the generation sector, as they are in some other commodity industries. But if so then it reflects a basic deficiency in implementing liberalized markets, which we now address. Restructuring was based on two premises implied in the seminal book by Joskow and Schmalensee (1983). One was that the vertical integration of utilities could be replaced by bilateral contracts between generators and large customers, or with retail utilities and other LSEs, assisted by multilateral markets for spot trading. The other was that generators could obtain capital on comparable terms directly from financial markets without relying on inclusion within a regulated utility with its assured cost recovery. Even California, which prohibited long-term bilateral contracting by utilities during the 4 years allowed for recovery of stranded costs, presumed that contracting would ultimately prevail. Contracting was certainly the dominant mode initially in those systems that used vesting contracts to smooth the first years of transition. In some systems (e.g., NETA, NordPool, Australia) both long- and mid-term contracting are vigorous, and others (e.g. France, Alberta) stimulated contracting by auctioning power procurement agreements (PPAs) sold by incumbent owners of large amounts of generation who were not required to divest ownership and management of their plants. But experience has shown that there are basic problems involved in extending the role of contracting. As described earlier, sellers and buyers have a natural incentive to insure others against volatile spot prices, since these are just financial transfers between them. The prevalence of mid-term CFDs reflects this mutual incentive for price insurance. Other stipulations involve the contract duration and the quantities involved. Utilities and other LSEs are hesitant to contract long-term for fixed quantities when their customers can switch
EBL
Reevaluation of Vertical Integration and Unbundling in Restructured Electricity Markets
55
to alternative providers, while generators prefer such contracts. Similarly, utilities and other LSEs want to adjust contracted quantities to contingencies affecting loads whereas generators do not. These considerations may account for the smaller role of contracting in the United States. The creditworthiness of the contracting parties also seems to have been an impediment in the United States, both in the California crisis when the utilities were financially distressed and later when there were several bankruptcies of major generation companies. Utilities’ regulators are wary of default on supply contracts, and they are also reluctant to approve utilities’ purchases of purely financial short-term contracts (e.g., futures contracts, as opposed to forward contracts that entail delivery). Indeed, most PUCs prohibit their inclusion in cost recovery on the grounds that they amount to speculation or arbitrage, a view that is evident also in federal legislation that requires separate and more intrusive regulation of exchanges for commodity futures. Also relevant is the slow development of innovative forms of forward contracts. For instance, an option contract can enable an LSE to “call” for the delivery of power supply at a pre-specified strike price in contingencies when the spot price exceeds the strike price. An option contract enables a buyer to hedge against high prices without exposure to the “volumetric” risk that the contracted quantity exceeds the amount required to serve its load. A multitude of other contract forms are also possible; e.g., a “spark-spread” contract enables a seller to hedge differences between fuel and power prices. Predictions that contracting would develop vigorously, and fund investments in generation, were predicated on the assumption that adequate contract forms could be developed to overcome the concerns of sellers and buyers, and that prudency reviews and creditworthiness would not be major problems. Predictions that contracting would replace vertical integration have been only partly realized because in fact the impediments to contracting interacted with the other major premise of restructuring – namely, that generation companies could obtain capital directly from loans and from financial markets for bonds and equity shares, much like suppliers in other deregulated industries (transport, telecommunications, gas). In the United States the chief models were gas transmission companies, which typically obtained funds at low cost because before construction of a pipeline most of its capacity was pre-sold as firm transmission rights under long-term contracts, often for durations as long as 20 years. Some IPPs have pre-sold capacity for durations long enough to provide security for loans to fund investments, but the overall pattern is mixed. In California, over 90% of the 8 GW of new capacity (an increase of 20%) installed in the years after the crisis was being financed by the long-term fixed-price, fixed-quantity contracts that the state purchased when it intervened. The state later found itself burdened with contracted prices and quantities that turned out to be excessive. This salutary lesson now encourages PUCs to restrict the durations of utilities’ contracts for resource adequacy, and further, to impose stringent conditions for taking over the plants of a supplier in default. Default risks are substantial because of the inherent volatility of wholesale prices, even over extended periods. Recent years of sustained low prices have jeopardized the financial viability of even the major generation companies, especially those active in energy trading with exposed positions (e.g., Calpine, Dynergy, Enron, Mirant, Williams). In principle, a generation company could be fully hedged by long-term fixed-price, fixed-quantity contracts and therefore be immune to long swings of wholesale prices, and if its counterparty is a utility with assured cost recovery, then its credit is essentially comparable to the utility’s credit. But complete hedging is rarely available, and the contract duration is typically no more than 3 years, a minor fraction of the life of the plant. Financial
EBL
56
Competitive Electricity Markets
hedges (e.g., futures contracts) are intrinsically short-term because no counterparty to a long-term financial contract is creditworthy unless it has physical resources as a collateral. A forward contract for physical delivery over a long duration can be viable for the seller, but no LSE other than a utility is a creditworthy buyer. As mentioned earlier, the LSEs, utilities, and industrial customers must guard against quantity risks. An option contract mitigates the buyer’s quantity risk, but equally it imposes on the seller the quantity risk that over long periods with low prices the option will not be called. Because the option will be called only when spot market prices are higher than the strike price, the seller serves mainly as insurer of the buyer with no comparable insurance for itself. The result of these difficulties is that two basic premises of restructuring have been fulfilled only partly. Contracting is not as pervasive as expected, and contracting obtains only part of the financial advantages of vertical integration. Most important is that IPPs are risky companies and therefore they have higher costs of capital – and during the recent period of sustained low prices, some of the most prominent are financially distressed, bankrupt, or reorganized after bankruptcy. The ultimate consequence is that investments in new generation by IPPs are substantially impaired. For example, Calpine obtained regulatory approvals for siting and construction of three new plants in California for which it did not obtain investment funds. 1.4.2.2. Benefiting retail customers Restructuring and liberalization of retail markets were expected to benefit customers substantially. For example, California’s announcement of its decision extolled at length the merits of differentiated services that customers would obtain at competitive prices from LSEs and from utilities freed from the confines of standard service plans. Much of the gain was supposed to come from service plans that rewarded customers’ efforts at demand-side management of their energy consumption, complemented by integration (called “convergence”) of energy services with other basic services – especially telecommunication and (remote or local) automated control of appliances, which have yet to materialize to any great extent.9 Large industrial and commercial customers certainly obtained advantages from new freedom to contract bilaterally with IPPs and to purchase directly from retail energy providers (REPs) or wholesale markets.10 But LSEs made slight inroads into commercial and residential retail markets in the United States, and subsequently, those who survived financial stresses during and after the California crisis withdrew from these markets.11 The utilities retained 90% or more of the residential market in most states simply because few customers considered switching energy suppliers. An exception is ERCOT where retail competition is thriving and 50% of the load has switched away from their local utility suppliers. A significant fraction of commercial customers chose service from LSE’s whose rates were gauged to each customer’s load profile, but this was perhaps the only significant differentiation and succeeded mainly because it provided lower prices to customers less
EBL
9
California’s 1994 restructuring decision devoted two pages to a section entitled “The Convergence of Telecommunications with Electric Service Promotes Direct Access” (pp. 21–23). 10 For example the University of California at Berkeley signed a supply contract with ENRON that guaranteed a minimum of 5% saving over the PG&E regulated rate. During the energy crisis ENRON attempted to renege on that contract and force the university to return to PG&E, but lost its bid in court. 11 California suspended “direct access” at the end of the crisis, and the suspension continues still.
Reevaluation of Vertical Integration and Unbundling in Restructured Electricity Markets
57
costly to serve. More elaborate differentiation was impeded by the prevalent absence of interval meters, and the costs of more elaborate meters and billing procedures. Prior beliefs that customers would actively monitor and control usage to reduce their costs under new service plans were falsified by the same practical obstacles that had limited the results obtained previously from utilities’ demand-side management programs. Equally falsified was the expectation that a majority of customers would willingly bear short-term price volatility (or could and would purchase financial hedges) in order to obtain lower prices on average. In fact, when wholesale prices were passed through to customers (in San Diego in 2000 as the California crisis began), the howls of outrage from customers prompted immediate intervention by regulators who canceled provisions allowing the utility to pass through its wholesale procurement costs.12 A particular example of misguided expectations was the prediction, obtained from surveys of mainly residential customers, that 30% would willingly pay a premium of 10% for “green” power from renewable sources. In fact, those subscribing to green power never exceeded 3%. More successful liberalizations of retail markets do not rely on visions of elaborately differentiated services. Instead, they concentrate on competitive retail markets as means of lowering prices for standard service plans, and for enabling negotiated rates based on a customer’s load profile. Alberta’s auction of PPAs, for instance, enables LSEs who purchase them to compete against the incumbent utility. Texas encouraged the entry of competitive REPs by requiring utilities to refrain from price competition with the REPs at prices below a “price to beat” until 2007 or until the utilities’ market share dropped to 40%, whichever occurred first. A basic lesson from recent years of liberalized retail markets is that only the market for large industrial and commercial customers is sufficiently developed presently to benefit fully from liberalization (see Joskow, 2005). Extending retail competition to other market segments requires major advances in infrastructure (especially metering), and fundamental redesign of differentiated services. Also required are measures that allow LSEs to enter successfully, to establish significant market shares, and to remain financially viable through periods of high prices. The reason is, in part, that they insure their customers against wholesale price volatility, although on the timeframe of a month or a year, which is shorter than utilities provide. Most fundamental is the lesson that most customers in the commercial and residential segments are deeply averse to price volatility, and equally reluctant to undertake the measures required to continually monitor and control usage. These customers will remain in the “core” served by the utility using fairly standard service plans (only slightly differentiated, say, by peak and offpeak periods) with rates leveled over extended periods. Only if there are major advances in providing them with financial hedges against price volatility, and with compensation for service interruption or curtailment, are these customers likely to depart from the core.
EBL
12
Similarly, Ontario canceled liberalization of retail markets after prices rose 30% in the first months. Customers’ attitudes about pass-through of wholesale electricity prices have no easy explanation. During the California crisis there was widespread anxiety about their monthly bills, but in fact throughout the crisis electricity rates were regulated and rigidly fixed. The anxiety can be explained in part by the fact that gas prices were passed through to customers and bills from PG&E and SDG&E included charges for both electricity and gas. But why many customers did not notice that it was higher gas prices that accounted for their higher monthly bills is mysterious. The new role of electricity as necessary for commerce and for personal well being – even TV – may be as good an explanation as any for these attitudes.
58
Competitive Electricity Markets
1.5. The Allocation of Risk Bearing in Liberalized Markets This section analyzes risk management in the electricity industry and indicates the continuing role of regulatory policies and regulated retail utilities in mitigating risks for a segment of retail customers. Rather than the simplistic version of liberalization that aims simply to break apart the vertically integrated utilities, and to unbundle the products traded in markets, there is a continuing role for utilities in providing inter-temporal smoothing of retail rates, and in lowering the cost of capital by reducing their financial exposure.13 This role requires redesign of utility investments and contracting within the context of liberalized wholesale markets, and redesign of retail rates within competitive retail markets. First reviewed are the risks peculiar to the industry, and then the institutional arrangements that have been or can be used to obtain an efficient allocation of risk bearing. 1.5.1. The basic risks affecting the electricity industry Much of the theory and practice of risk management is based on diversification. Insurance companies are financially viable because they aggregate many small independent risks to life, health, property, etc. They can operate with relatively small reserves of equity capital because their aggregate risk is small on a per capita basis, that is, when divided relatively equally among all participants. Another form of diversification is seen in a mutual fund. Its earnings are less volatile than the earnings of the companies whose shares it owns because its portfolio is divided among the shares of many companies. Again, the aggregate is less risky per dollar invested because the companies’ earnings are imperfectly correlated. Diversification is also very important in electricity markets. For instance, the aggregate load on a per customer basis is more stable than the loads of the customers individually because the aggregate is composed of individual loads that are imperfectly correlated. Thus, for each hour of the next day, a system operator’s day-ahead prediction of the average load per customer is more accurate than its predictions of the loads of individual customers. Similar considerations apply to other contexts; e.g., the system operator uses the transmission system to compensate for equipment failures in one area by drawing on resources in other areas. Analogously, the system operator can meet a high load in one area by drawing on resources in other areas that are not affected by the same weather conditions. Energy trades also take advantage of differences between seasonal variations among regions; e.g., California buys power from the Northwest to meet summer daytime air conditioning loads, and sells power to the Northwest to meet winter nighttime heating loads. The mix of generation technologies that is most cost-effective in meeting a particular load-duration profile is really the solution to a risk management problem in which diversification of generation investments is optimized. Both spatial and temporal diversification, however, are inherently limited in the electricity industry. Investments in generation and transmission facilities require years to complete. After construction, they are irreversible, specialized, immobile, and long lived.
EBL
13
One problem underlying the spotty record of power industry restructuring so far is that the economic theory used to justify functional unbundling of utilities has not proved as useful as originally expected. This theory, which emphasized the importance of transaction costs, depended largely on assumptions that have become outdated because of innovations in technology and market design. It now appears that many of the economic benefits sought through unbundling can better be attained through wider use of risk management contracts, obviating a compelling reason why restructuring should begin with the irreversible task of vertical unbundling of the supply chain.
Reevaluation of Vertical Integration and Unbundling in Restructured Electricity Markets
59
In contrast, loads vary greatly on much shorter time frames. Some variation in loads is predictable and cyclical, such as the typical variations over the hours of a day, and over the seasons of the year, so the mix of generation technologies can be designed to minimize total costs over the cycle. On the supply side too there are regular patterns of downtime for maintenance, and to a substantial extent the average frequency of equipment outages is predictable. But the electricity industry is also affected by large and relatively unpredictable variations that occur over wide regions and/or over long timescales. These bring risks that cannot be mitigated by various strategies of diversification based on averaging over people, locations, or time in a cycle. These are called non-diversifiable or “systemic” risks. Among systemic risks, the most extreme event is collapse of the grid due to cascading failures. Systems that rely heavily on hydroelectric sources are vulnerable to prolonged droughts that curtail water storage behind dams, and those that rely on fossil fuels are vulnerable to eras of high prices. Over long periods, load patterns trend away from the aggregate load-duration profile and the spatial distribution used initially to justify generation and transmission investments. Technical change can also render a generation plant or transmission line inefficient compared to subsequent investments in newer technologies. For a casualty insurer, the analog of a systemic risk is the rare storm (e.g., hurricane) or an earthquake that devastates an area and requires that compensation be paid simultaneously to many victims of the same event. In other words, the injuries to insured customers are perfectly correlated due to their common dependence on the single event of the storm. Because a single event can exhaust its financial reserves, a casualty insurer often excludes coverage of systemic risks. For instance, a farmer can purchase insurance against damage to crops by hail (which occurs locally and briefly) but cannot purchase insurance against drought (which is widespread and prolonged). Casualty insurers typically diversify further by re-insuring a portion of their risks with other companies that specialize in aggregating calamitous risks on a global scale. Such strategies might conceivably be invoked in the electricity industry, but presently the scale of the financial risks of major events in the electricity industry is so large, and can extend over such long times that it is often the state that ultimately bears the cost – as when the state of California intervened to purchase power for utilities during the crisis. Systemic risks are addressed in many different ways. Provision of reserve generation capacity is the first defense: it is costly to build and maintain generators that are idle most of the time, but over the long run their ultimate value is realized in the occasional events when they are called to produce power. As with an insurer, a second defense is a reserve of equity capital that can be drawn down to pay extraordinary expenses. Again, it is costly to retain financial reserves that, in effect, are idle until used to meet unexpected expenses. Like an insurer, a utility can use the third defense of re-insuring its financial risks in various ways, such as long-term contracts that transfer some portion of its risk of high wholesale prices to its suppliers, and retail service plans that transfer some risk to customers. Risk associated with moderate weather fluctuations can also be diversified through instruments such as weather derivatives that enable risk sharing among industries that are affected by weather in complementary ways. But some entities must ultimately bear the costs of rare extreme events, and in the electricity industry the prospects that financial contracting can entirely diversify systemic risks are limited. The problem stems partly from the attributes of physical assets, which are built slowly, and are irreversible, specialized, immobile, and long lived, and, thus, largely inflexible in dealing with contingencies that occur on large scales of space and time. A contract that transfers risk from a regulated utility to an unregulated generation company leaves the company exposed to the risk but with limited flexibility, since it cannot redeploy or
EBL
60
Competitive Electricity Markets
quickly expand its assets to cope with events as they develop. Ideally, a long-term fixedprice contract protects the utility against sustained high spot prices (while forgoing high profits for the company), and protects the company against sustained low prices (while foregoing lower procurement costs for the utility). The advantages for the company are inherently greater since its investments require irreversible commitments measured in decades, while the utility’s advantages are confined to the durations of extreme events. But this mutual insurance against price variations is not sustainable over prolonged periods that jeopardize the financial viability of either party – as evidenced by the bankruptcies of generators in the United Kingdom and the United States during the recent period of low prices, and before that the financial distress of utilities and other LSEs during a period of high prices. The problem also stems partly from high correlation between prices and quantities; i.e., prices are high when loads are high. A contract that provides price insurance is mainly financial, since it fixes the terms of trade, and brings mutual advantages to buyer and seller by eliminating price volatility. But a contract fixes the quantity to the benefit of the seller only by removing the buyer’s flexibility in procuring the amounts needed to meet its load in each event. If the amount is too large or small, then the surplus or deficit must be corrected by spot sales or purchases. Basically, the seller wants to insure its flow of net revenues (especially if it is burdened by debt) and the utility wants to insure its total cost of procuring supplies to meet its varying load. Some contracts address these considerations directly, notably tolling contracts (sometimes called “virtual capacity” contracts) and some PPAs, in which essentially the seller is remunerated continuously for its capacity availability and operation. Meanwhile, the buyer dispatches the plant as needed and pays variable generation costs, chiefly for fuel. This achieves the primary goal of restructuring, which is to make generation companies bear the consequences of their investment decisions and to strengthen their incentives for efficient operating practices, while also enabling the utility to obtain scheduling flexibility. Restructuring assumed that the strategies described above – physical reserves, financial reserves, and contracting – would suffice in the new era of liberalized markets. Each strategy has limitations and costs that have became clearer as experience accumulated. Remarkably, restructuring has often abandoned the traditional means of risk management, namely cost-of-service regulation of utilities. Risk was borne ultimately by retail customers, but only by amortizing recovery of a utility’s accumulated costs over time so that its retail rates were substantially level. This strategy uses diversification in two ways: it distributes risk bearing widely among customers and over time. It also removes most risk bearing by the utility and its suppliers so that their capital costs are low, and eliminates the creditworthiness problem. It depends implicitly on the good faith and credit of the state in fulfilling the regulatory compact; indeed, it may be that the state is the only entity that can provide credible assurance that costs will be recovered later as promised. This strategy also has limitations and costs. These became very clear at the time of restructuring, since regulators had often seen evidence that utilities’ incentives for cost minimization were weak, and investments were rewarded on the basis of “tonnage of money invested.”14 California’s initial consideration of how to restructure proposed a scheme in which utilities would continue to serve core customers much as they had
EBL
14 This quote is from the February 1993 staff report to the California Public Utilities Commission by its Division of Strategic Planning, “California’s Electric Services Industry: Perspectives on the Past, Strategies for the Future”, page 100.
Reevaluation of Vertical Integration and Unbundling in Restructured Electricity Markets
61
previously, while allowing non-core customers to purchase their power supplies directly.15 Although California rejected this scheme, other states retained a central role for utilities and continued the practice of amortizing costs over time to level retail rates. This necessarily implies that core customers ultimately pay the full cost of the services obtained, and in particular they collectively bear the systemic risk that the cost of service for the core will be high due to extreme events and long-term trends. 1.5.2. Institutions for risk bearing in the electricity industry Restructuring was a response to many considerations. One was the reduced role of economies of scale in generation as smaller combined cycle units became cost-effective. This and other technical advances obviated the dominant role of retail utilities on the supply side and opened prospects of bilateral contracting between IPPs and large industrial and commercial customers. For those systems not already organized as power pools, there were potential operational gains from regional operations and trading based on open access to transmission. Naïve expectations that service differentiation would proliferate amid vigorous retail competition were realized only partly, and mainly for large industrial and commercial customers. Some PUCs emphasized reduced costs of contentious procedures and litigation required to implement cost-of-service regulation, but in fact this outcome was precluded by the continuing dominant role of retail utilities in serving core customers. A primary goal of restructuring was to strengthen incentives for efficient operational and investment decisions. Cost-of-service regulation is inherently a kind of insurance for utilities, since it guarantees to a utility that its costs accepted as prudent and accepted into its rate base are eventually recovered in full from retail rates on an amortized basis that includes the cost of capital. Insuring utilities’ cost recovery was very effective in reducing the cost of capital, since their bonds and shares carried negligible risks of default and provided steady payments of interest and dividends. But inevitably, insurance dilutes incentives, since a utility does not bear the costs that result from its investment decisions and operating practices. Restructuring apparently succeeded as regards cost reduction in daily operations, but it has had mixed success in investments, and the unfavorable consequences for the riskiness of utility shares was not anticipated.16 Restructuring envisioned that supply-side contracts with independent suppliers, supplemented by spot market purchases, would supplant in-house generation by vertically integrated utilities. And on the demand side, differentiated service plans would include risk bearing by customers (possibly hedged by financial instruments) on a more nearly current basis than the previous regime of rates leveled over extended periods. Also expected was that customers’ loads would become more sensitive to market prices. These two developments on the supply side and the demand side were
EBL
15
The reasons for rejecting this alternative are not entirely clear. One explanation is that California rates had already reached averages 30% to 50% above the national average while relying on costbased regulation, and they might rise further if the most profitable customers opted out of the core. But the PUC’s decision focused also on predictions that complete liberalization would bring benefits from service differentiation among competing LSEs that in fact did not materialize. In 2004 the PUC reinstated the policy of promoting utilities as the provider of services for core customers. This reversed the decision made a decade earlier. 16 Regulators did not expect utilities to be in financial jeopardy, but equity markets reacted differently. After the California PUC’s decision in 1994 prices of the utilities’ shares declined about 25% over the next few months.
62
Competitive Electricity Markets
expected to leave retail utilities with moderate commercial and financial risks, much like other firms in commodity industries – analogies to successful deregulation of the transport, telecommunications, and gas industries were often cited. The limits to the success of restructuring regarding investments include effects of imperfect planning, especially as regards the mix of technologies and the provision of adequate reserves. But the main limit is due to imperfect contracting that leaves generation companies exposed to substantial risk and therefore required to pay higher costs for capital. The failure of demand-side innovations to develop is now viewed as fundamental. This perception may change gradually through a long process of developing retail markets – expansion of sophisticated metering and redesign of marketing strategies – but the basic impediment is the absence of adequate financial instruments for small customers to hedge against price volatility. A utility retains its obligation for universal service as the provider-of-last-resort, and its standard service plans include leveled rates that effectively insure against short-term price volatility. Most small customers therefore choose to remain in the core served by the utility. (In the United States, those who opted for service from alternative LSEs were sent back to their utilities for default service when wholesale prices rose in the period 2000–02.) There is no evident substitute now for the retail financial services of utilities, and there may indeed be no credible substitute for the state’s guarantees of universal service and of cost recovery via leveled rates. In retrospect, the anticipated gains from service differentiation for small customers must presently be seen as secondary compared to the gains from leveled rates for those in the core. From an economic viewpoint, there are persuasive arguments that the most efficient allocation of risk bearing in the electricity industry has core customers paying leveled rates for amortized cost recovery. Except for some economically disadvantaged customers, they should pay the full cost of service in the long run because costs vary with usage. Since electricity is used universally, they should pay directly for service rather than rely on distortionary taxation by the state to cover deficits. Some industrial and commercial customers can bear short-term price volatility without difficulty, and therefore they can pay spot prices and/or contract directly with suppliers. But if other customers are deeply averse to short-run volatility then ideally they should pay level rates that recover their costs over time. Inter-temporal smoothing of rates might be achieved by well-developed markets for financial instruments for hedging against price variations and for insurance against the consequences of curtailed service. Alternatively, cost-of-service regulation provides smoothing of rates. The choice between these two approaches depends on how seriously systemic risk limits the market for financial instruments, and how serious are the deficiencies of cost-of-service regulation in providing strong incentives. The defects of cost-of-service regulation were well known before restructuring, but the slow and ultimately inadequate development of competitive markets for financial instruments was not expected. It was also thought to be a secondary consideration, since customers retained the option to rely on core service, and in any case little or no attention was given to the problem of systemic risk. For instance, documents and orders of the California PUC and state legislation mention only short-term price variation, with no recognition that extreme events like those that initiated the later crisis might affect the restructured industry. Most firms in the financial services industry were well aware of the threat posed by systemic risks. They hesitated about offering long-term financial instruments because they had no physical hedges. A firm that offers financial hedges against high wholesale prices runs the risk of ruin unless it can compensate by simultaneously profiting from selling power at high prices. Several firms within the energy industry became active traders and
EBL
Reevaluation of Vertical Integration and Unbundling in Restructured Electricity Markets
63
arbitrageurs (including Dynergy, Enron, Mirant, and Williams) and they claimed that their portfolios of long and short positions were well hedged against extraordinary events. But in fact, among the major trading companies in the United States, the only ones solvent after the California crisis and ensuing events at the national level were those that had the foresight to liquidate their positions and close their trading operations in the early months of the calamity. A summary view of these deficiencies on the demand and supply sides is that both are instances of insufficient development of auxiliary markets for financial instruments and contracts that hedge against risks. Diversifiable risks are allocated inefficiently when financial markets are poorly developed, and more seriously, non-diversifiable risks can jeopardize the entire industry as financial distress affects many participants. Dire scenarios were not envisioned when restructuring began, but they became worrisome concerns after episodes in several countries, and then became crystal clear during the California crisis, and later in some other countries such as New Zealand. The view now is that even after restructuring and liberalization there remains a valuable role for retail utilities that use financial reserves from capital markets to smooth cost recovery over time for those customers who opt to remain in the core. The importance of strengthening incentives is also recognized, and therefore new regulatory policies are required. Remuneration of utilities via simple cost-of-service regulation must be replaced by a scheme that enables a utility to insure core customers against short-term price volatility, while also rewarding the utility for efficient operations. Chao et al. (2006) address these matters in detail, including the role of performance-based regulation of utilities.17 1.6. Conclusions
EBL
The argument for vertical integration in the electricity industry and also the argument for restructuring based on unbundling of its products and organizations in favor of market mechanisms are both deficient. The notion that all is needed is unbundling of the electricity supply chain and establishment of efficient short-term trading institutions, while longterm contracting and markets for financial risk management instruments will emerge spontaneously, was naïve. In retrospect, cost-of-service regulation and vertical integration of generation and retail service continues to be a powerful means of risk diversification. The extremes of vertical integration and liberalized markets are inferior to a balanced mixture of the two approaches. While unbundling may benefit large industrial and commercial customers that are able to absorb the inherent risks in the electricity supply chain, efficient management of these risks requires that restructuring retains universal service for the core of non-industrial customers who rely on regulated rates smoothed over time to recover the costs of service. Acknowledgment The chapter is based on research sponsored by Electric Power Research Institute. The opinions expressed in this chapter are those of the authors and do not represent the positions of any of the organizations with whom the authors are affiliated. Any errors and opinions are solely the responsibility of the authors. 17 In its 1994 decision the California PUC explicitly provided for performance-based regulation of utilities that continued to serve core customers, but this was not implemented due to the restrictions imposed to enable utilities to recover the “stranded” costs of previous investments.
64
Competitive Electricity Markets
References Barker, J. Jr., Tenenbaum, B., and Wolf, F. (1997). Governance and regulation of power pools and system operators: An international comparison. World Bank Technical Paper No. 382. Blumstein, C., Friedman, L., and Green R. (2002). The history of electricity restructuring in California. CSEM Working Paper 103, Berkeley, CA: University of California Energy Institute. Bonbright, J.C. (1961). Principles of public utility rates. Public Utilities Reports, Incorporated. Borenstein, S. (2004). The long-run effects of real-time electricity pricing. CSEM WP-133, Berkeley, CA: University of California. Borenstein, S., Bushnell, J., and Wolak, F. (2002). Measuring market inefficiencies in California’s restructured wholesale electricity market. CSEM Working Paper 102. Berkeley, CA: University of California Energy Institute. California Public Utilities Commission (1993). California’s electric services industry: perspectives on the past, strategies for the future. San Francisco, CA. Chandler, A.D. (1969). Strategy and Structure: Chapters in the History of the Industrial Enterprise. The MIT Press. Chao, H-P, Oren, S.S., and Wilson, R.B. (2006). Alternative pathways to electricity market reform: risk management approach. Proceedings of the 39th Hawaii International Conference on Systems Sciences HICSS39. Kauai, Hawaii, 4–7 January. Chen, M., Cho, I-K., and Meyn, S. (2004). Reliability by design in distributed power transmission networks. University of Illinois, Urbana Champaign. Correljé, A.F. and. De Vries, L.J (this book). Hybrid electricity markets: The problem of explaining different patterns of restructuring. Chapter 2. Devine, W.D. Jr. (1983). From shafts to wire: Historical perspective on electrification. J. of Econ. Hist., 43(2), 347–72. EPRI. (2002). Review of the Current Status of Power Market Reforms in the United States and Europe. Palo Alto, CA. Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (2002). Standard Market Design Proposed Rulemaking. Washington, DC. Hunt, S. (2002). Making Competition Work in Electricity. Wiley. Joskow, P. (1997). Restructuring, competition and regulatory reform in the U.S. electricity sector. J. of Econ. Pers., 11(3), 119–38. Joskow, P. and Schmalensee, R. (1983). Markets for Power: An Analysis of Electrical Utility Deregulation. MIT Press. Michaels, R. (2006). Vertical integration and the restructuring of the U.S. electricity industry. Pol. Analy., No. 572, 1–32, published by the Cato Institute, 13 July. Newbery, D. (2006). Electricity liberalization in Britain and the evolution of market design. In Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective (F.P. Shioshansi and W. Pfaffenberger, eds). Elsevier. O’Neill, R., Helman, U., Hobbs, B., and Baldick, R. (2006). Independent system operators in the USA: History, lessons learned, and prospects. In Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective (F.P. Shioshansi and W. Pfaffenberger, eds). Elsevier. Rudnick, H., Barroso, L.A, Skerk, C., and Blanco, A. (2005). South American reform lessons – twenty years of restructuring and reform in Argentina, Brazil, and Chile., Pow. and Energ. Mag., IEEE, 3(4), 49–59. Sherman, R. (1985). The Averch and Johnson analysis of public utility regulation twenty years later. Rev. of Ind. Org., 2, 178–93. Sweeney, J. (2006). The California electricity restructuring, the crisis, and its aftermath. In Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective (F.P. Shioshansi and W. Pfaffenberger eds.). Elsevier. Williamson, O. (1975). Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications. The Free Press. Williamson, O. (1985). The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting. The Free Press. Wilson, R. (1993). Nonlinear Pricing. Oxford University Press. Wilson, R. (2002). Architecture of power markets. Econometrica, 70, 1299–340. Zarnikau, J. (this book). Demand participation and demand response: Evidence from US ISOs, Chapter 9.
EBL
Chapter 2 Hybrid Electricity Markets: The Problem of Explaining Different Patterns of Restructuring A.F. CORRELJÉ AND L.J. DE VRIES Delft University of Technology, The Netherlands
Summary
EBL
This chapter explains the divergence in the design and structure of liberalized electricity markets. The main question is why there are so many “hybrid” markets, markets that are somewhere between their former state of a regulated monopoly and perfect competition. Electricity market design is found to be shaped by the relevant policy goals, the situation in the market at the outset of the restructuring process, and a variety of exogenous factors, outside the control of market participants and government policymakers. Moreover, feedback from market performance to the policy process is limited by time lags and bounded rationality. 2.1. Introduction Many electricity markets around the world have been or are in the process of being restructured with the purpose of introducing or expanding competition, but few have actually reached a state that could be described as commensurate with the economics textbook ideal of a liberalized, competitive market (cf. Joskow, 1996; Stoft, 2002). Perhaps the electricity markets in the United Kingdom, Argentina, Texas, New Zealand, Chile, and Alberta have come closest to this ideal, at least in terms of market design. However, they also have many idiosyncrasies, vestiges of their pre-liberalized state or results of political compromises, such as publicly owned competitive companies, preferred treatment of incumbents, inadequate network regulation, price regulations, or limited competition. Most electricity markets are still further removed from the textbook ideal and are somewhere in between their former pre-liberalized state and retail competition (Joskow, 2006; Newbery, 2005a,b; Victor, 2006; Rudnick et al., 2005; F. Sioshansi, this volume). If a function can be performed adequately by competitive firms, there is no need for public ownership. Nevertheless, public ownership remains common in restructured power 65
66
Competitive Electricity Markets
markets, so the state can often retain a strategic position. For instance, in many developing countries the single buyer remains a public entity. If the single buyer also owns some of the generating capacity, this leads to a situation in which it competes with independent power producers (IPPs) (Dehdashti, 2004). In many OECD (Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development) countries, the state, provinces, or municipalities maintain their shares in power production and networks. Another phenomenon is that markets have been restructured with all the features of a competitive wholesale market, but continue to be dominated by a single party – often, the former monopolist. Examples are Electricité de France, Electrabel in Belgium, or CFE in Mexico. Whereas ENEL, in Italy, was forced to divest a substantial amount of its generating capacity a few years ago, currently there appears to be a tendency in Europe to create “national champions” – large power companies that are expected to protect national interests in an increasingly international power market (Thomas, 2003; Haas et al. 2006). Finally, there are countries in which many of the requirements for a competitive market are met, both with respect to market design and industry structure, but in which the government continues to intervene beyond the minimal requirements for facilitating competition such as network regulation. Examples of government intervention are the use of a capacity mechanism, which influences investment in generating capacity (e.g., in Ireland, Spain, and in several markets in the United States) and wholesale or consumer price regulation. Price controls are common both in developing countries and in restructured OECD markets. Whereas in some markets a state of incomplete liberalization is clearly a transition phase, other markets appear static, stuck somewhere on the path to reform, while in a third group of markets the reforms are being reconsidered. Is this an indication that there are multiple steady states possible? Is there not a natural tendency for the design of markets to converge over time? Are markets typically moving toward more competition, or have some achieved a steady state? What drives these structural changes? What are the hurdles for further liberalization? What are the prospects for agreement upon a single market design, even within the European Union (EU) and the United States, where there are mechanisms available for coordinating state policies? The aim of this chapter is to investigate these “hybrid” markets and to provide an explanation of the apparent stagnation of the process. The main focus of this chapter is, How can the current divergence in the design and structure of liberalized electricity markets be explained and what are the prospects for convergence and agreement upon a single market design? In this chapter, countries that have undertaken attempts to introduce competition, from opening of their systems to new entry by IPPs to full-fledged restructuring, but have not adhered to the textbook model for competition will be examined. Neoclassic economic theory provides the contours of the desired end state of a restructuring process by defining the characteristics of an ideal market. It also provides a framework for diagnosing market imperfections (see Shuttleworth, 2000; Newbery, 2005b; Joskow, 2006; Jamasb and Pollitt, 2005; Haas et al., 2006; Kwoka, 2006). However, due to its prescriptive nature, neoclassic economic theory does not explain differences between the ways in which countries go about the restructuring process, or why markets in practice are so rarely fully organized according to the neoclassical economic textbook ideal. Neither does the neoclassic economic theory make clear why some companies are horizontally separated or privatized while others are not. There is a lack of understanding of the evolution of restructuring processes and hence also of their outcomes in as far as they do not conform to economists’ expectations. In this respect Heller and Victor (2004, p. 6) note: “Experts
EBL
Hybrid Electricity Markets
67
attribute this yawning gap between theory and practice to ‘politics,’ poor ‘rule of law’ and other ‘weak institutions’ that are needed to put the state on the sideline and to give the space for markets to operate. Yet, so far, nearly all scholarship has treated them as a residual category. [….] The lack of rigorous attention to these factors is particularly strange since political, legal, and institutional forces are hardly transient. Indeed, these factors appear to be the dominant ones in explaining the actual pace and character of market reforms in the electric power system in developing countries.” A promising approach for exploring the situation in these hybrid electricity markets is provided by Institutional Economics, a sub-discipline of economic science that deals with the evolution of institutional arrangements in markets (see, for example, North, 1990; Williamson, 1998; Glachant and Finon, 2000; Victor et al., 2006). In this theory, the behavior of market actors, as regards pricing, production, resource allocation, investment, strategies of horizontal and vertical integration, and so on, is assumed to be influenced by a market-specific body of rules and conventions: the institutional arrangements. Of course, the traditional economic perspective also relates the conduct of actors and their performance to structural characteristics of markets, like the degree of concentration, the shape of production functions, regulation. Yet, these characteristics are considered as a given, exogenous to a market. What distinguishes the approach of institutional economics is that it considers this body of rules as being an endogenous part of the market. Institutional arrangements are shaped by a path-dependent interaction between political, economic, and physical factors, driving deliberate interests, choices, and strategies of the policymakers, the firms in the industry, (groups of) consumers, and other parties involved, like international organizations and NGOs. This implies that an explanation of why certain types of hybrid markets have developed – and their future – should include the interaction between these factors and the resulting behavior of the actors in a specific market. The main elements in the institutional economy of power system restructuring are the situation at the start of the restructuring process, policy decisions regarding market design, related policies such as competition policy, fuel policy and environmental policy, and a number of exogenous factors that constrain the decision space, like the scale of systems and the availability of primary energy resources. Section 2.2 will further elaborate on this analytic framework. In Section 2.3 an overview is presented of the characteristics and achievements in respect of restructuring in a selection of electricity markets. The evaluation of the restructuring process of the electricity supply industry is based upon case studies of OECD countries, developing countries, and formerly communist countries (e.g., Heller and Victor, 2004; Victor and Heller, 2006; Newbery, 2005a; Joskow, 2005a; Rudnick et al., 2005; Sioshansi and Pfaffenberger, 2006). By considering North America and Europe as well as nonOECD countries, the full range of possible market designs becomes apparent. This section attempts to explain this diversity within the framework that was developed in Section 2.2. Section 2.4 provides an analysis of the country comparisons, while the conclusions are summarized in Section 2.5.
EBL
2.2. The Institutional Setting for Restructuring In this section an analytic framework will be developed. Section 2.2.1 starts with an analysis of the constraints that limit the decision space of governments as well as market players. Within this context, the motives of public authorities and the industry determine the direction of the restructuring process (Section 2.2.2) Section 2.2.3 describes the different market design variables. Given a specific restructuring policy, the strategies of
68
Competitive Electricity Markets
market parties determine the market outcomes in a dynamic process, as is described in Section 2.2.4. Section 2.2.5 summarizes the analytic framework. 2.2.1. The restructuring context The physical situation in a country provides a set of relatively “hard” constraints. A crucial element is the presence of indigenous energy resources, such as hydropower, coal, natural gas and oil, or – at the other end – dependence upon other countries for energy resources. Market size and degree of isolation matter too. Small isolated systems, in small countries or on islands, like Iceland, Malta, or in the Caribbean, cannot efficiently support multiple competing generating companies as a consequence of the relatively large minimum efficient scale of the several types of generation units. This also impedes the use of specific technologies or fuels, such as large-scale coal plants. The geographic distribution of demand also plays a role: in thinly populated areas or small, remote concentrations of electricity demand it may be difficult to create competition in supply (see also Weinmann and Bunn, 2004). A second set of constraints relates to macro-economic characteristics such as the level of economic development, the rate of demand growth, and the availability of investment capital. These factors influence the acceptability of changes in tariffs or prices to different categories of users, the need for investment, and financing options for system expansion and/or rehabilitation. Three obvious categories of countries are, firstly, developing countries with a relatively stagnant economy; secondly, countries on the path of economic development and industrialization; and, thirdly, the OECD countries. The third category of constraints derives from the institutional and socio-political environment of a power system. North (1990), Williamson (1998), Glachant and Finon (2000), and Finon (2003) explain how informal institutions such as culture, traditions, and values affect the development of formal institutions, such as property rights, legislation, regulation, and the role of the (federal) state in the economy. In De Vries and Correljé (2006) it was discussed how formal institutions can be divided into general institutions, such as the polity, the judiciary, and the bureaucracy, and sector-specific institutions, such as sector legislation and regulation and jurisprudence, which are the main tools of market design. Arguing that the freedom of action for those who are in control of the reform process and the need to coordinate different aspects of the reform process are essential to the success of a restructuring process, Glachant and Finon (2000) consider the power of the central government a key factor with respect to the success of market reform. Table 2.1 provides an overview of the physical, macro-economic, and institutional constraints. Together they determine to a large extent the solution space that is available to governments that wish to restructure their power sectors. Within the context of these constraints, governments need to find a balance between their own multiple objectives and those of the energy sector and of consumers. Some confusion may arise with respect to the difference between variables and constraints, as the starting value of a variable itself may pose a constraint on the liberalization process. For instance, the fuel mix at the outset of liberalization influences the economic and environmental performance of the sector for many years after the reforms have been instituted. However, this should not be considered a constraint, but rather the beginning value of the variable “fuel mix,” which may change over time. Undeniably, “take-off” variables such as the fuel mix have a significant path-dependent impact, but analytically it is essential to make a clear distinction between fixed constraints, as factors that lie outside the control of the actors within our system, and variables that are (more or less) under their control. Market design variables will be discussed in Section 2.3.
EBL
Hybrid Electricity Markets
69
Institutional factors
Economic factors
Physical factors
Table 2.1. Factors that determine the context of the restructuring process Factor
Impact
Natural endowment with energy sources
Presence or absence of primary energy sources drives the choice of primary fuels, the technical and economic characteristics of the sector, and interests and policies.
Physical size of the market
Due to scale effects, small markets are likely to be more concentrated. Larger markets may constitute a number of separate subsystems, with their own economic and institutional structure.
Geographic distribution of demand in relation to network capacity
Relatively dispersed demand and/or limited network capacity increase the likelihood of network congestion, which results in market fragmentation and limits competition.
Level of economic development and growth
Influences demand growth, the potential for investments, and institutional stability.
Growth rate of demand
Capacity investment lead times are long. With a high growth rate, large volumes of capacity must be under construction. Market signals or regulation must be effective. Stable demand, on the other hand, limits the “room” for new market entrants.
Financing options
Especially in developing or transition countries; with a weaker economy financing options may be limited.
Ideology
General acceptability of and commitment to particular policies and institutions.
Institutional stability and rule of law
Facilitates investment and external funding; stabilizes and provides coherence in policies; helps align policy, regulation, and the legal framework.
Degree of institutional centralization and homogeneity
The power of the central government influences the coherence of policies and their support in terms of regional, sectoral, and social dispersion.
Influence of stakeholders
Strong stakeholders may be able to influence the reforms in their own interest.
EBL
2.2.2. Motives for restructuring A large number of states have embarked on the process of power sector restructuring, each starting from its particular national context (see Jamasb, 2002). A wide variety of motives can be observed for these attempts. Prior to liberalization, the electricity sector was considered a natural monopoly which, in the prevailing neoclassical approach, justified state intervention (Scherer, 1980; Stiglitz, 1986). In the United States, privately owned utilities where regulated by sector-specific Federal and State agencies. In Europe and its many (former) colonies and Latin America, public ownership became the dominant mode. In the communist world, of course, the state was
70
Competitive Electricity Markets
the owner and operator of virtually the entire economy. In addition to providing electricity at reasonable rates, the power sector policy served a number of public interests associated with these services, such as issues of safety, security of supply, acceptable prices for specific types of users, objectives of local and sector development, the supply of jobs, and – more recently – sustainability and environmental protection (see, for example, Foreman-Peck and Milward, 1994; Correljé et al., 2003). By the early 1980s, this perspective was replaced by the kind of “liberalism” that was associated with the ideas promoted by the governments of the late Ronald Reagan and Margaret Thatcher, which were based on monetarist and public choice theories. Efficiency, economic reform, and political power were sought through a reduction of taxes, “rolling back the state,” and by bringing market-driven competition into so-called “gold-plated” industries. Competition – modeled after the revised economic textbooks – was to be imposed upon public sectors wherever possible (Friedman, 1962; Demsetz, 1968; Helm, 2003; Parker, 2000). Gradually – initially only in a number of Anglo-Saxon countries and Chile – privatization and competition were introduced as the basic elements of structural change in the energy sector. Encouraged by the apparent successes of the early efforts, the introduction of competition became a common goal for many markets (see also Chao et al., Chapter 1 in this volume). As the competitive market paradigm became accepted in OECD countries, international organizations such as the World Bank and the IMF started to require developing countries to implement similar market reforms if they wished to be eligible for support. Thus, for many developing countries – as for some EU countries – reform was imposed, rather than a voluntary effort. Another possible reason for reform in developing countries is to attract private capital when the public owners cannot provide sufficient investment. In addition, other policy objectives often play a role, such as social and economic stability, fuel policy, environmental policy, and CO2 trading. These policies may impact restructuring policy by excluding or enforcing particular fuel mixes and through systems of levies and subsidies (see Glachant and Lévêque, 2005). Moreover, competition policy may influence the success of restructuring. In general terms, it appears that the commitment to, and faith in, competition as a means of maximizing welfare is an important factor. The success of market reforms in other utility sectors may turn out to be an important example to policymakers (see F. Sioshansi’s Introduction).
EBL
2.2.3. Market design The preceding section provided an overview of the motives for power sector restructuring. Now the analysis will turn to the options for achieving these goals, the market design variables. Basic choices are the pace of market opening, the degree in which competition is introduced, the market model, decisions to restructure horizontally or vertically, and decisions to privatize (Glachant and Finon, 2000; Newbery, 2005a; Littlechild, 2003). An important means of achieving competition is by redesigning the market to make it attractive enough for new entrants to whittle away the market power of the incumbents. In designing markets, however, a tradeoff is to be made between competition and the investment climate. Ideally, the combination of economic and institutional structures and contract forms in a market reflects the risk structure in that market, involving market, fuel, regulatory, technical, and other risk components, as regards both short-term operating decisions and long-term investments (Joskow, 2005b; Alexander and Harris, 2005). The first question is to what degree competition is to be introduced. A relatively light form of restructuring of publicly owned industries is their corporatization. State-owned
Hybrid Electricity Markets
71
enterprises normally operate under the responsibility and control of a particular department with “soft” budget constraints. Placing the enterprise at arm’s length from the responsible public body, while imposing a hard budget constraint, is a first step toward enhancing the efficiency of the electricity industry and making it less responsive to political and interest group capture. A next step, introducing some competition without structurally addressing the state monopoly, is to allow IPPs. They sell to the state-owned monopolist (called the single buyer), who often continues to generate electricity (Heller and Victor, 2004). While this allows the state monopoly to dominate the system, the IPPs may provide benchmarks for performance and may increase their influence over time. The following step is to remove the single buyer and create a wholesale market in which there is wholesale competition between a number of generators, supplying large customers and distribution companies with a retail franchise. The final step is the introduction of competition at the level of retail customers. To an increasing extent, these categories of market design allow for competition (Hunt and Shuttleworth, 1996). It is possible to open up the market to full retail competition at once, but it is also possible to gradually introduce competition by moving through these different models. The pace of restructuring is therefore a variable. Retail competition was often regarded as the desired end state of restructuring (it is, for instance, required by the EU in Directive 2003/54/EC), but in Chapter 1 of this volume Chao et al. make a case against competition at the retail level. Newbery (2002) also pointed out the advantages of retaining the retail franchise, such as retail companies being able to enter into long-term contracts for generation. With respect to the wholesale market model, there is a fundamental choice between integrated markets and decentralized markets (Hunt, 2002). Integrated markets are preferred in the United States. In these markets the system operator operates a mandatory pool, in which the physical and economic aspects of electricity trade are strongly connected. In decentralized markets, the preferred model in Europe, the system operator only has a technical function and supply and demand meet elsewhere, either bilaterally or in voluntary power exchanges. In the case of restructuring publicly owned utilities, privatization becomes an issue, as it is generally not considered necessary or desirable for government to be involved in competitive activities. Nevertheless, it is not uncommon for states to have their publicly owned companies operating in competitive electricity markets, perhaps due to the strong public goals with respect to this sector. Public authorities may engage private capital via a system of concessions, a flotation of packets of shares in the industry on the exchange, or via a merger with a foreign firm. The choice of approach has important consequences for the resulting vertical and horizontal structure of the electricity sector and for the behavior of firms. The main variables are, firstly, the degree of privatization of the industry, ranging from a government monopoly via the admission of new privately financed firms into the sector to full privatization. Secondly, there is the issue of what segments may be privatized – generation, wholesale and retail trade, the networks? In some cases, as in the Netherlands, it is argued that the networks, as critical infrastructures, should remain in public ownership (see Künneke and Fens, 2007). The third element involves the character of the new private owners: will they be anonymous shareholders, national or foreign financing institutions, foreign electricity companies? A final aspect involves the timing of privatization, relative to other elements of a restructuring. Depending on these choices, a new market structure emerges with a specific pattern of interests, strategies, and behavior. Obviously, the degree of privatization not only impacts the economic behavior of the firms in the industry, but also their activities in influencing
EBL
Competitive Electricity Markets
72
public authorities and regulators. Indeed, shifts in the structure of ownership bring about different constellations of interests, involving new parties and new strategies vis-à-vis the government, the regulators, and the market. The arguments for choosing a particular approach emerge only to a certain extent from pure efficiency considerations associated with restructuring. Other policy motives may include the size of the revenues to the state from privatizing the industry, the degree of control a government wishes to maintain over specific segments of the industry, international relations, security of supply issues, and the management of national energy resources such as gas or coal, and so on. If the goal of restructuring is to introduce competition, it may be necessary to break up existing companies into smaller ones or to force the incumbent to divest some of its assets. Indeed, a debate is currently taking place within the EU about the question as to what extent large cross-national firms should be allowed, as a means to enhance security of supply and investment potential, or whether these former national champions should be divided up in a number of potentially competing firms. Even if the market design is perfect, the potential benefits of restructuring are not likely to be obtained if the market continues to be dominated by the former monopolist. Fringe competition may provide some benefits, but due to economies of scale and the long life cycle of key assets such as power plants, it is not likely to lead to a level playing field for competition very quickly. Therefore, horizontal unbundling is a key element of restructuring if multiple potential competitors are not already present. Public monopolies are in principle easier to split up than private companies (Finon, 2003). However, in case of public ownership, conflicts of interest with, for example, powerful labor unions may keep a government from acting. Some also consider it desirable to prevent or break up vertical integration between generation and retail. However, in Chapter 1 of this volume Chao et al. argue that this is a necessary instrument for risk hedging. This argument is supported by the observation that in most electricity markets there is a strong tendency toward vertical integration between generation and retail. The way the networks are regulated will fundamentally affect the network owners’ investment policies and therefore impact the adequacy with which demand growth and shifts in the pattern of supply and demand are met. Depending on the choice for a model, the issue of the position of the transmission and distribution networks’ monopoly becomes important. The regulation of network tariffs, the provision of regulated or negotiated third party access, and the degree of unbundling of the networks from competitive generation, trading, and retail activities strongly influence the overall effectiveness of competition in the market:
EBL
•
The quality of access regulation and the level and structure of tariffs affect the competitiveness of the supply of power and the development of trade. • The degree of unbundling also plays an important role in this respect, as it keeps incumbent owners of networks from obstructing access for new entrants and avoids cross-subsidization of competitive activities by non-competitive activities (see also Chapter 1). • Incentive regulation of transmission and distribution networks directly impacts the level of transport costs as a component of overall supply cost. In addition to access to transport, there are certain essential system operation functions that need to be provided. The main functions are scheduling and dispatch of transmission and distribution, balancing (in case of decentralized markets), congestion management, and ancillary services (such as black-start capacity and voltage control). These functions can be designed in multiple ways, but because of their relation with network management they are often provided by the transmission network manager (Knops, 2003).
Hybrid Electricity Markets
73
Trade between different electricity markets is often an issue. The connection with neighboring electricity systems may have a significant impact upon the competitiveness of the market and the incentives to market parties. At the same time, it exposes the industries of connected countries to competitive forces, a phenomenon that may or may not be appreciated. In many markets, wholesale and/or retail prices are regulated. In this respect a balance needs to be struck between the interests of consumer groups, who often embody specific political power, and the incentives to the industry for providing sufficient investment to cover future demand. It is still debated whether competitive electricity markets without price restrictions provide sufficient investment incentives, or whether consumers would be better off with some kind of capacity mechanism. If there are price restrictions, theoretically a capacity mechanism is necessary to compensate generating companies for the foregone revenues; otherwise, they will under-invest (Hogan, 2005; Stoft, 2002). A capacity mechanism may also be needed, or be beneficial, for other reasons (De Vries, 2004). An overarching issue is the role and position of the regulatory function. At what level should the regulator be placed? Local, provincial, national, or even supranational regulatory bodies may exist. The choice has consequences for the relation between the regulator and the regulated industry and its independence from other parts of the public realm. It also affects the degree of detail, specificity, and generality in which regulatory problems can be solved. A second aspect is the balance between sector-specific regulation and the application of general competition law. Both approaches have an ex ante component, addressing structural sector characteristics, prescribing behavior, and evaluating plans for mergers and acquisitions, and an ex post component for the monitoring and mitigation of abuse of market power. Consequently, the position of the regulator(s) and competition authorities within the policymaking arena and vis-à-vis interest groups has consequences for the transition toward a competitive market and the design of that market and, ultimately, for the allocative and dynamic efficiency of the sector and the market outcomes in terms of efficiency and welfare. The organization of the electricity supply industry prior to the restructuring process affects a number of these decisions by providing default choices. The number of generating companies at the beginning of the restructuring process, the degree to which they are integrated with network companies, the ownership structure of these companies, generating and network capacity, the capacity of network links with neighboring systems, whether there already is a regulator (e.g., for the regulation of private utilities) determine the starting conditions of the restructuring process. These conditions are relevant, as will be seen later in this chapter, because the restructuring process is subject to path dependency.
EBL
2.2.4. The dynamics of restructuring The solution space of governments with respect to restructuring – the range within which governments can choose the market design variables that were discussed in Section 2.2.3 – is restricted by the situation at the outset of the restructuring process and by the “hard” constraints that were described in Section 2.2.1. Within the context of the different constraints, governments need to find a balance between multiple objectives with respect to the energy sector. To a large extent the specific balance between the policy objectives is a function of a country’s socio-political context, involving ideology and the representation of interest groups such as specific categories of energy consumers, producers of indigenous energy resources and their staff, the citizens at large, and components of the central and local administrations (see also Heller et al., 2004).
74
Competitive Electricity Markets
The solution space of market parties is restricted by the market design decisions of government, as well as by the exogenous constraints that were described in Section 2.2.1. Within these limits, parties optimize their positions through the contracts and transactions that they enter into with their suppliers and customers. An important element in this respect is the facilitation of trade by exchanges and other trading places by providing more or less standardized contracts. To a large extent, these market institutions emerge from the initiative of actors in the market, reflecting the opportunities for trade within a given system. The market structure evolves over time through mergers, takeovers, and the establishment of joint ventures. This process accelerates during the process of restructuring, as a consequence of firms’ growing insights in the newly developing context and the associated changes in their roles and opportunities (see also Kwoka, 2006; Jamasb, 2002). These strategic decisions by the firms, finally, determine the space within which they make their operational decisions, which lead to the market outcomes (Williamson, 1998). Based upon the performance of the market with respect to the government’s policy goals – and responding to public perception – government may adjust its policies (Willman et al., 2003; Correljé, 2005). The feedback from market performance to government may be weak, however, as North (1990) points out. First, for some of the market design choices, there may not be sufficient information to reach an unambiguous conclusion about which is the better one. For instance, as of now, the experience with liberalized markets is too limited to provide definitive evidence whether a market design without a capacity mechanism provides sufficient incentives for investment in generating capacity. Similarly, there is no consensus about the optimal design of a capacity mechanism. Given that the lead time for new generating capacity is several years, the length of the business cycle in the electricity generation business will probably be longer than a decade. Adding to that, many markets started restructuring with excess generating capacity, and it is clear that current experience with competitive markets is relatively short. There simply is not sufficient empirical data with respect to the issue of generation adequacy. Economic models cannot sufficiently capture the details of existing markets, generation parks, and oligopolistic industry strategies to provide an unambiguous answer to the question of generation adequacy. Therefore, for the time being, answers to the issue will remain somewhat speculative (see De Vries, 2004; Cavaliere et al., 2007; Weinmann 2007). A second reason, according to North (1990), may be that the models with which actors process information may not be adequate. This is true both of formal models, such as simulation models, and of the “mental” models of reality that policymakers have in their mind. Regardless of the type, a model is a simplification of reality and therefore always highlights particular elements of the real world. Different national policy traditions and socio-political backgrounds equip policymakers with differing mental models. Of course, these models improve over time if there is coherent feedback from what is happening in the real-world power sector and the economy at large. However, if the process takes too long, or when feedback signals are too weak and diffuse or contradictory, it stalls. The mental models are not consolidated and adjusted and insights remain ambiguous and open to multiple interpretations. In a highly complex system such as a competitive electricity market, this may easily be the case. The limited feedback is the main cause of path dependency. If it is not clear whether a change constitutes an improvement, the change is not made. This may explain the differences in market design between the United States and Europe, where many believe their own model is the best choice. Starting conditions were quite
EBL
Hybrid Electricity Markets
75
different, with much of the industry in the United States privatized before the restructuring process. Perceptions are also different, with European countries emphasizing the need for “national champions,” among others, as a balance against the large national energy companies that supply Europe with natural gas or against foreign electricity suppliers that would give preference to supplying their home country, in case of problems. This focus on national (or state) “champions” is absent in the United States. Finally, the blocking power of key actors may be another important cause of path dependency. Even if government has a clear vision for its market reforms, as the EU does with respect to electricity market restructuring, key actors such as powerful EU member states or incumbent companies may prevent it from happening. 2.2.5. Conceptual framework Combining the above elements leads to the conceptual framework that is represented in Fig. 2.1. This figure summarizes the relations between the different factors that influence the development of electricity markets. The market design process takes place within an institutional context: the process is influenced by informal institutions such as culture and values and constrained by formal institutions such as international treaties and the constitution. This context influences the choice and relative weight of the policy goals, as well as the general effectiveness of policymaking and implementation, as a function of the “power” and legitimacy of the government (Williamson, 1998; North, 1990). The institutional context also manifests itself through decisions of the past, as the institutional context is relatively static. The policy goals set the direction for the restructuring process. The policy goals, and the relative weights attached to them, vary widely. Objectives in related policy areas, such as energy security of supply, environmental and employment policy (fuel choice), social policy (energy prices) may also affect electricity market policy. The way these policy
EBL
Institutional context
Related policies
Objectives of restructuring
– Security of supply – Environment – Social issues
– Liberal policy and ideology – Economic efficiency – Investment in electricity system – International market integration – Externally imposed restructuring
Past policies
Horizontal unbundling, competition policy
Starting conditions
– Time delay – Bounded rationality
Market design
Exogenous factors
Table 2
Table 1
Market parties’ strategies
Market outcome
Fig. 2.1. Conceptual framework.
Feedback:
76
Competitive Electricity Markets
Table 2.2. Market design variables Variable
Consequences
Degree of market opening
Corporatization of a state monopoly, single buyer, wholesale market and competition in the retail market allow for an increasing degree of competition, but involve increasing transaction costs and requirements as regards the economic and institutional structure.
Pace of market opening
Being a leader or a follower vis-à-vis neighboring countries/states, or higher (EU, USA Federal) policy.
Integrated versus decentralized market
Integrated markets with mandatory pools, reduce transaction costs, but combine both economic and physical control over the system in the hands of a single party, potentially facilitating governance.
Public versus private ownership
Public ownership provides a means for direct control but entails policy captivity, may impede effective regulation and limits financial resources. Private ownership requires political and institutional stability and regulatory commitment.
Competition policy and horizontal unbundling
Influences the competitiveness in market segments, trading off economies of scale and scope.
Network unbundling
EBL
Unbundling influences the independence of network managers and their interest in providing equal conditions for all network users.
Network regulation of network tariffs and access conditions
Influence the conditions for competition and the pressure upon network managers to work efficiently.
Congestion management method
Affects trade opportunities between regions.
Arrangements with neighboring networks and interconnector congestion management
Market integration may enhance the competitiveness but may also cause higher prices in the exporting country.
Balancing mechanism (in decentralized markets)
Balancing mechanisms affect cost and revenues of type generation, especially for intermittent sources, and influence entry.
Wholesale and end-user price regulation
Protects consumers, at the expense of investment stimuli to the industry.
Capacity mechanism
Different types of capacity mechanisms exist in order to stimulate investment in capacity.
Position of regulator
Ex ante or ex post regulation.
goals are combined influences the design of the market. The actual design choices are summarized in Table 2.2. The restructuring process is further constrained by a number of exogenous factors, as are listed in Table 2.1. These factors not only affect the market design process as policymakers take them into account, but they also affect the behavior of market parties directly.
Hybrid Electricity Markets
77
For instance, difficulty with financing capacity expansion in developing countries will stimulate a market design that reduces investment risk; the combination of the incentives provided by the market design and the financing possibilities together determine investment behavior. As argued above, due to path dependency, the starting conditions influence the restructuring process. It is easier to introduce competition into a market with fragmented ownership than into one with a monopoly. If the monopoly is state owned, the government has the power (if not always the willingness) to break up this company. Similarly, past fuel policies will affect the market for decades after the beginning of restructuring, due to the long life cycle of generation assets. Within these constraints, market design and competition policy provide the tools for restructuring. Feedback exists in that government observes the performance of the market and responds by changing policies, also stimulated by involved interest groups. However, this feedback is characterized by long time delays, due to investment lead times, incomplete information, and incomplete understanding of the meaning of that information. Faster feedback takes place in the form of lobbying by market players, trying to influence competition policy and market design decisions. 2.3. Hybrid Markets and Patterns of Restructuring The objective of this section is to investigate the evolution of a number of restructured electricity markets and to examine their prospects for convergence toward a single market design. A review of recent case studies on power market restructuring in a number of countries provides an insight into the factors that led them to their current situation as hybrid power systems. First the situation in a number of developing countries is discussed, followed by an examination of OECD countries.
EBL
2.3.1. Developing countries The power sector of Chile, the first example of liberalization in the 1980s, was plunged into crisis when Argentina curtailed its natural gas exports to Chile in 2004. The power system had become dependent upon natural gas from Argentina as a consequence of its border conflict with the alternative supplier Bolivia. Investors debated between coal, using LNG for natural gas plants, and banking on a return of the cheaper Argentine gas. As they could handle these risks, which were partly political, they turned to the government for leadership (Rudnick et al., 2005). Despite being pioneers worldwide, these South American countries almost “froze” the reforms and – partly due to their political instability – no substantial adjustments have been made to cope with the challenges that emerged in recent years (Arango et al., 2006a, b). Argentina was also among the first countries to reform its power sector in the early 1990s. Initially it was a showcase with a highly competitive generation market, but the deep macro-economic and political crisis in 2001 and 2002 and the subsequent devaluation of the peso led the government to freeze consumer electricity prices below cost. This, in turn, created a need for credit support to generating companies and government involvement in generation expansion. Eventually, the government resorted to the establishment of a new public firm (Arango et al., 2006b; Rudnick et al., 2005). Brazil was also confronted with the need to adjust its power sector by the end of the 1980s. Until then, the centralized power system of Electrobras, largely based on hydropower, had been expanding significantly. A macro-economic crisis led to the need
78
Competitive Electricity Markets
for foreign investment in the sector. However, tariff adjustments and the lack of a stable regulatory environment posed obstacles to private investors (De Araújo et al., 2006; De Araújo et al., Chapter 15 in this volume). The adoption of a price mechanism that protected the operators of hydropower plants, at the expense of thermal gas-fired power plants, further discouraged private investment. Reform efforts stalled during a major power crisis in 2001 and 2002, when a drought led to the rationing of electricity for 9 months. It was concluded that spot prices were inadequate for signaling the need for investment, considering the price volatility of a hydro-based system and the large fluctuations in the growth rate of demand that were due to periodic economic crises. Within this context, the leftwing government that was elected in 2002 re-established central planning based upon hydro generation, involving cost-plus pricing and power purchase agreements for existing and new capacity, including a capacity mechanism in the form of mandatory forward contracts (Rudnick et al., 2005). In Mexico, the drive for reform has not been very strong, perhaps because the traditional system was successful in providing electricity to more than 96% of the population. Historically, the state-owned utilities could purchase oil at subsidized prices from the large publicly owned oil industry. In the mid-1980s, pressure arose to restructure the power sector, as part of a general wave of market reform in other sectors of the Mexican economy (Carreón-Rodriguez et al., 2003). This involved reforms in tariffs and fuel pricing, the creation of an IPP scheme by 1992, the creation of a (fragile) regulatory commission (CRE) by 1993, and the establishment of a new tariff structure in 2000. The current move toward populism, common in many countries in Latin America, has caused the policy to shift away from further private involvement in the power sector. Toward the end of the 1980s, the government of India was confronted with strong economic development, associated growth in power consumption, and limitations on public resources. The central government responded by trying to attract private investment in IPPs within the traditional framework of the State Electricity Boards (SEB), but this attempt failed. Consequently a decentralized approach was undertaken by a new reformoriented national government, in which the federal states were left free to adopt their solutions. In most states, the transmission company was given the role of single buyer. While this involved a combination of decentralization and corporatization, states were able to maintain their influence in the sector. The role of IPPs remained marginal. Political opposition to market-based tariffs by farmers and others who previously had enjoyed relatively low tariffs led to their continued cross-subsidization at the cost of industrial and commercial consumers (Tongia, 2003). As a consequence, industrial users started to engage in self-supply, thereby reducing their contribution to the cost recovery of the network and public generation. The financial situation of the single buyers continued to be weak as a consequence. At the instigation of the central government, State Electric Regulatory Commissions were established, but they were unable to improve the situation. Currently there appears little motivation for reforms, but the gap between the regulated tariffs and the cost of investment may force change in the future (Tongia, 2003, p. 58). Several countries in South-East Asia, like Thailand, the Philippines, Malaysia, and Indonesia, have implemented modest forms of restructuring, generally involving IPP investments under power purchasing contracts. A crucial element was the robustness of these contracts during the Asian crisis at the end of the 1990s. Due to the relatively stable institutional and political framework, IPP investments in Thailand and the Philippines survived the South-East Asian crisis better than in Malaysia and Indonesia, which were affected by political clientelism, under which local and national politicians provided advantages and protection to the incumbent firms (Henisz and Zelner, 2001).
EBL
Hybrid Electricity Markets
79
The following picture emerges with respect to developing countries with strong demand growth. Reform was typically triggered by a large need for capital to finance the rapid expansion of the sector. For political reasons, the strong position of the publicly owned incumbents was often used for continuing the dominance of the state, which led to hybrid markets in which private initiative had a limited role. Usually, market restructuring was limited to allowing IPPs and/or establishing a single buyer model in order to minimize investment risk (Heller and Victor, 2004; Victor and Heller, 2006). In markets with wholesale competition, or a single buyer without retail competition, it is not necessary to unbundle the distribution networks and to regulate access to them. This model yields an ambiguous, unstable situation, particularly in the context of the macro-economic shocks that have occurred in many of these countries. Often, governments have sought to provide security to investors, for instance through a single buyer who would offer very long-term power purchasing contracts. Due to these macro-economic shocks, exchange risk became a serious issue to foreign investors that required adjustment of these contracts, which sometimes happened and sometimes did not. In most developing countries the introduction of retail competition has not been considered an option, as domestic consumption is often so low that it is not worth the restructuring and transaction costs. Especially in countries with substantial poverty, governments have attempted to protect the poor from high energy prices, for example by keeping consumer prices below average cost via cross-subsidization, or by squeezing the revenues of the IPPs. This of course discourages investment and causes a return to the initial problem of capital scarcity (see also Williams and Ghanadan, 2006).
EBL
2.3.2. OECD countries: the United States
The restructuring of electricity markets in the United States took place in a more decentralized manner than in the EU. A series of initiatives of the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) brought about considerable development in open access to large-scale regional transmission systems, but FERC has not been able to implement a single market design. An explicit attempt at doing so in 2002, FERC’s Standard Market Design, failed due to opposition from the states and lukewarm support from the Federal Government. Consequently, the states have considerable room for deciding whether and how to restructure. Due to significant differences between the electricity market context and between the interests of stakeholders in the states, a variety of restructuring paths have developed. According to Joskow (2005a), a key obstacle to the “difficult and contentious” reform process in the United States is a lack of political willingness. A number of states did not go further than opening up their transmission lines to wholesale “wheeling.” A lack of network capacity and of network unbundling hampers wholesale trade in many regions. Other areas have better-developed wholesale markets, most notably the East Coast, California, and Texas. Market designs vary, but there is a preference for integrated markets with locational marginal pricing and for capacity mechanisms for stimulating investment in generating capacity (except in Texas). In addition to differences in the design of these capacity mechanisms, electricity markets in the United States vary with respect to price caps, retail price regulation and default supplier regulations, the position of the system operator, and network unbundling and access regulations. Differences between market designs reflect differences in interests and political influence of different stakeholder groups such as generators and consumers (cf. Cronin and Motluk 2006). The success of retail competition has been limited (Blumsack et al., 2005). The interest of consumers in switching to a different electricity provider has been minimal – perhaps
80
Competitive Electricity Markets
due to the attractiveness of staying with the regulated prices of “default providers” – and in general there was no noticeable decrease of retail prices (cf. Joskow, 2006; Newbery, 2005b). An interesting difference between the United States and Europe is the preference for integrated markets in the former and decentralized markets in the latter, using Hunt’s (2002) terminology. In Europe, there was a deliberate choice against the integrated model, as it would put too much power in the hands of the integrated system and market operator. In addition, the decentralized system, with physical bilateral trade, was deemed more transparent, while in the United States, the same reason was used in favor of integrated markets (Blumsack et al., 2005). This illustrates the degree to which bounded rationality plays a role. It can be concluded that there is a patchwork of more or less interconnected hybrid markets and supply systems in the United States. This patchwork is the consequence of the large variety in political decision making regarding the reform approach in the individual states, reflecting local conditions, as regards primary fuel supply, age of plant, structure of demand, and interconnection (see Joskow, 2005a). Many of the substantive issues of market design are decided at the state level, whereas the FERC provides general guidelines on particular aspects of interstate aspects of the market. Political and interest group pressure drives the states’ choices, primarily, toward optimizing the design of their local market from their own perspective. In the restructuring process in the United States, state governments have had to confront a number of regulated private companies. Some of these firms defended their positions, but others saw a window of opportunity for expanding outside their franchise areas. Nevertheless, unbundling typically involved a struggle over compensation payments for “stranded cost.” Incumbent firms tried to maintain their strong market position by obstructing competition or through mergers, if they were not taken over. In some states the process of restructuring was effective in the end, whereas in others it was limited to minimal compliance with FERC standards. Despite this mixed picture, the United States tends to be more inclined to pursue effective competition with a larger number of smaller players than European countries, perhaps because the United States is endowed with sufficient indigenous energy sources whereas the EU is severely dependent upon imports of fossil fuels. For the latter, the purchasing power of their energy companies in the international fuel markets is thought to play an important role with respect to security of supply issues. A tendency toward large, national gas and power companies can be observed in Europe, whereas the North American gas industry is much more fragmented and hence more competitive. The US experience underlines the significance of path dependency and learning effects. The industry structure at the outset of liberalization drove the political commitment to restructuring in particular states. States developed a variety of approaches to restructuring, based upon their particular circumstances, starting situations, and preferences. Over time, states have the opportunity to learn from each other, so something of a natural selection model develops. The success of some states in overcoming problems common to other states provides an example to others. The PJM system appears to have this role. PJM Interconnection is the regional transmission organization (RTO) that coordinates the movement of wholesale electricity in all or parts of Delaware, Illinois, Indiana, Kentucky, Maryland, Michigan, New Jersey, North Carolina, Ohio, Pennsylvania, Tennessee, Virginia, West Virginia, and the District of Columbia. In this respect Joskow’s argument (2006) about the lack of a generic model, as in the EU, may also be construed as an advantage. In the EU, the pressure of such a common “one size fits nobody” model appears to generate
EBL
Hybrid Electricity Markets
81
considerable resistance, whereas the American diversity of approaches may in the end lead to voluntary convergence upon a preferred model (Weinmann, 2007).
2.3.3. OECD countries: Europe With the exception of the United Kingdom, the Netherlands, and Scandinavian countries, the restructuring of electricity markets in Europe is driven by EU policy. The European Commission (EC) started with a rather loosely defined model of sector reform – with clear Anglo-Saxon principles – but has imposed increasingly strict requirements with respect to market design (CEC, 1996, 2003). The intention of the EU was to increase economic efficiency through the introduction of competition and thereby reduce end-user prices. With respect to the goal of sustainability, restructuring is also intended to facilitate the application of economic instruments, most notably the CO2 emissions trading system. The goal of security of supply, the third general policy goal, is expected to be served by restructuring, as the unbundling of the industry and the introduction of competition where possible should lead to optimal investment in each link of the value chain. Moreover, well-functioning markets should promote diversity, which provides resilience in case of disturbances. Recent reports by the EC show that these objectives have not been reached (CEC, 2006a, 2007b). The Sector Inquiry provides a thorough analysis, supported by a wealth of empirical data, that shows that European electricity markets are far from integrated and in most cases also far from competitive (CEC, 2006b, 2007c). A main problem is that the restructuring effort focused on market design but ignored competition issues and horizontal integration in most member states. Consequently, many member states’ electricity markets are dominated by a very small number of companies. Other important shortcomings are as given below:
EBL
•
•
• • • •
Insufficient unbundling of the transmission networks from generating companies. The EC now strives for ownership unbundling or, if that is not feasible, the creation of independent system operators (ISOs). A lack of effective regulation (in particular in case of incompletely unbundled networks) and too strong a focus by regulators on their national markets instead of on the development of the EU internal electricity market. A continuing lack of sufficient transparency. The availability of information varies significantly between member states. Inadequate capacity of the infrastructure between member states. Insufficient network security standards. Insufficient signals for investment in generating capacity.
Many of the “hard” measures that are prescribed by the EC have been implemented only pro forma, which has not led to an effective single market or even a set of competitive national or regional markets. Member states strategically interpret and implement the directives and guidelines of the EU, their main concern being their own (future) position within the emerging EU energy market. Countries differ with respect to their commitment to, and faith in, competition, which appears to have an important impact upon the extent to which effective competition is created. Table 2.3 presents an overview of the present state of restructuring in the EU. Three groups of countries can be discerned
Table 2.3. The state of restructuring in the EU Wholesale market Concentration
GDP in PPS 2006
Population (in millions)
Greece Cyprus (d) Malta (d) Latvia Estonia France Belgium Slovenia Ireland Luxemb. (d)
85 88 70 52 65 107 118 84 139 257
11 0 7 0 4 2 3 1 3 59 9 10 4 2 4 0 5
100 100 100 95 90 85 85 70 85 14
100 100 100 100 100 95 95 95 90 ?
Public Public Public Public Public Public Private Public Public Mixed
62 35 0 76 10 70 90 75 56 57
Portugal Poland Slovakia Lithuania Spain Czech Rep. Italy Austria Germany Hungary Netherlands
70 51 59 55 98 76 99 123 110 64 126
10 5 38 2 5 4 3 4 42 3 10 2 57 9 8 1 82 5 10 1 16 2
50 15 75 50 40 65 55 45 30 30 25
80 35 85 80 80 75 75 75 70 65 80
Mixed Public Mixed Public Mixed Mixed Mixed Public Mixed Mixed Mixed
100 52 66 0 100 100 79 100 100 67 100
UK Sweden Denmark Finland Norway
117 116 122 113 169
59 6 8 9 5 4 5 2 4 6
20 15 15 15 15
40 40 40 40 40
Private Private Mixed Mixed Public
100 100 100 100 100
Largest Top 3 Ownership
Market opening
Sources: CEC (2005), (2006a,b), (2007a); Haas et al. (2006); EFTA 2007.
Transmission
Distribution
TSO Institutions Unbundling
DSO Ownership Unbundling
End-user price Ownership regulation
Regulator
Pool Bilateral None None None OTC/PX None None VIPP None
Legal Legal None Man. Legal Legal Own. Legal Own. Legal
Public Public n.a. Public Public Public Private Pub? Public Private
Acc. Legal Int. Int. Exempt Own. Legal None Own. Legal
Public Public Public Public Public Pub/loc Private Public Public Private
All All All All All All Dom. Dom. All Dom.
OK Weak Multi OK Weak Weak Weak Weak OK Weak
Bilateral Bil./PX Bilateral Bilateral Pool None PX None? Small Bilateral PX
Own. None Legal Legal Own. Own. Own. Legal Legal Legal Own.
Mixed Public Mixed Public Public Public Mixed Public Mixed Public Public
Legal None Legal Own. Legal Acc. Legal Legal Acc. Acc. Legal
Public Public Mixed Public Mixed Mixed Mixed Public Mixed Mixed Mixed
All All Dom. All All None All None Dom., com All None
OK Weak OK OK Weak Weak Strong Weak Weak Weak Strong
Large PX PX PX PX
Own. Own. Own. Own. Own.
Private Private Public Mixed Public
Own. None Exempt None Legal
Private Public Public Public Public
None None All Dom. None
Strong Strong Strong OK OK
EBL
Hybrid Electricity Markets
83
with more or less comparable characteristics regarding the implementation of the EU Directives. The first group is characterized by a highly concentrated market and a near monopoly of the incumbent. This is generally paired with weak unbundling, absence of retail competition, and regulated tariffs for all consumers. This group includes many of the small new accession countries like in Estonia, Latvia, and Slovenia, which have low incomes and an underdeveloped post-communist institutional framework, and islands such as Malta, Cyprus, and Ireland, whose size limits the options for competition. The limitations of small, isolated systems are recognized by the EU and they may obtain a derogation of substantial parts of the EU Directive 2003/54/EC, art 26. Also traditionally state-oriented, monopolistic countries such as Greece, Portugal, France, and Belgium are in this group, in which a negative attitude toward competitive power markets dominates. Consequently, the governments in these countries see no pressing motivation, or possibility, for bringing about change. This is either because of their difficult economic position or because of their being captive to electricity industry lobbies, via the channels of business and labor interest. This position is also reflected in the generally weak position of regulators (see Glachant and Finon, 2005; Finon, 2003; Meritet, 2007). In addition, the absence of indigenous resources has given rise to the nuclear energy policies of France and Belgium. In the second group the market is moderately concentrated. Most countries have opened their markets fully, but the degree of network unbundling varies and in some cases price regulation is applied. This group is fairly heterogeneous and includes new accession countries such as Hungary, the Czech Republic, Poland, and Lithuania, plus long-standing member states such as Germany, Spain, Austria, Italy, and the Netherlands. These countries are characterized by the fact that their electricity industry always included multiple companies. In the central European countries the common objective to get rid of their past dependence on energy supply from Russia is a strong driver for change. Particularly these industrialized countries may harvest the advantages of improving the competitiveness of their economies. However, social and regional antagonisms need to be solved and economic problems arise in this process. The group of long-time EU members is characterized by a variety of governance traditions, ranging from corporatism to clientelism. Generally, intra-industry relations are relatively informal, but the industry is at some distance from the state. These countries all depend to a large extent on imported fuels. Generally, public policy in these countries needs to balance between opening up the power sector and their strategic interest with respect to security of supply and the survival of their national industries. In Spain and Germany, the use of indigenous coal and lignite has been supported to protect the jobs of miners. The multiple objectives cause conflicts between the state, regulators, and the industry, while political parties remain divided over restructuring issues. Compromises in the restructuring policy are the consequence. For example, Germany was one of the first EU members to fully open up its electricity market. However, as the cooperating incumbents were not required to unbundle their networks and because network access and tariffs were not regulated, the market remained virtually closed to new entrants. Only recently the process was given an impulse by the establishment of an independent regulator and the further implementation of the EU Directive (see Brunekreeft and Twelemann, 2005). During the 1990s, the Netherlands appeared to make a strong shift toward the Anglo-Saxon model. However, after years of intense conflicts between the electricity sector and government, there now appears to be a movement back toward a more consensus-based approach in which network tariff regulation is less strict and companies are more involved in rule making. As a defense against foreign influence in the industry via takeover, the Dutch government decided
EBL
84
Competitive Electricity Markets
to prohibit privatization of the networks (Van Damme, 2005). The Spanish process of adjustment is also rather conflictive. From its protectionist background, the Spanish state chose for a policy of restructuring from a position of “strength,” allowing the national industry to compete with foreign firms, at home and abroad. Given the diversity of interests in the Spanish system and their relations with the polity, this policy does not produce clear guidelines and choices. This is also illustrated by the ongoing struggle between the government and industrial interests over the position of the electricity company Endesa (Crampes and Fabra, 2005; Serrallés, 2006). The third group of countries, consisting of the United Kingdom and the Nordic countries, are the most liberal, with low market concentration, integrated markets (in Scandinavia), and retail competition. These countries have deliberately chosen, on an ideological basis, to liberalize their power systems, by dismantling their former monopolies and restructuring their industries. In the United Kingdom, an important additional objective for restructuring was the limitation of the coal miners’ union power. The strength of these countries appears to be their relative independence from imports and their access to a variety of fuels, which has ascertained their belief that the process of allocative decision making can be trusted to the “internal” market. Moreover, the institutional context of these countries places organized industrial interests at some distance from policymaking, while economic growth and ideology make them less vulnerable to the consequences of occasionally high consumer prices (Kinnunen, 2004). This process is illustrated by the political reactions to the electricity prices spikes in the Nordpool market in 2001 and 2003 and the price hikes in the UK gas market during the winter of 2005–06. An important explanatory factor for the market situation in European countries appears to be the initial ownership structure of the power sector. Apparently, the existence of national monopolies, as in France, Portugal, Belgium, and Greece, makes it difficult for a government to create competition. The only exception is the United Kingdom that split up its Central Electricity Generating Board. The general solution is “fringe competition,” the facilitation of “competitive” entry alongside the monopoly. However, because of the continued alliance between the dominant public monopoly and the state, the development of new institutional arrangements and the regulatory body proceed slowly. Price regulation needs to be maintained against the market power of the monopoly, but this often harms the interests of (potential) new entrants (Glachant and Finon, 2005). If the government is confronted with a number of vertically integrated firms that are publicly owned, whether by the state or by provinces and/or municipalities, the situation appears relatively straightforward. Unbundling, the introduction of access rules and tariffs, and wholesale and retail competition can be established by political decision making. Main causes of resistance are conflicts of interest between public bodies at different levels and interest groups clamoring for consumer protection, environmental issues, and the unions. Eventually, this state of affairs may progress and lead toward privatization. When the government needs to confront a number of private firms the situation is more complex. In the EU it can be doubted whether effective unbundling is legally possible, as it may be considered expropriation. States that only reluctantly accepted liberalization may try to protect the interest of their “national” firms through influencing its quasi-independent regulator, assuming that they will serve the country better than new entrants. This argument runs two ways. If new entrants are private firms, they are thought to be driven only by profits and ignorant of the public character of electricity supply. If the new entrants are foreign public firms, the situation is also suspect, as these firms are thought to give preference to their home market in case of supply problems.
EBL
Hybrid Electricity Markets
85
The European markets have witnessed the emergence of a set of large multinational conglomerates, the so-called seven brothers (see Thomas, 2003; Green, 2006; Haas et al., 2006) that extend their activities by taking over energy companies in their home country and abroad. These companies may be considered as (potential) competitors in the future pan-European market. Their purchasing power in the international fuel markets is often brought forward as an important asset with respect to security of supply issues, as it provides a counterbalance to the market power of Gazprom and the Middle Eastern gas suppliers. On the other hand, the EC recently announced plans to take on the dominant position of companies such as Electricité de France, E.On, RWI, and ENI (EC, 2006, 2007). In response, governments of countries that are not home to one of the seven brothers feel an even stronger need to protect their power market against “foreign domination,” either by establishing their own mini-champions or by keeping the market relatively closed to takeovers, for instance by a minimalist implementation of the Directives or by not privatizing their companies. So while these governments may sound supportive of the notion of introducing competition and may not oppose the corresponding changes to the market design, they may oppose attempts to really restructure the market. This situation causes inconsistencies, on/off policies, and a slow development of an effective market. It also leads to competition between the EU member states’ “national” companies, which has led to the reintroduction of a great deal of economic nationalism in the restructuring process, often veiled in terms of environmental protection, security of supply measures, or public service obligations.
2.4. Analysis
EBL
This section will review how the empirical evidence that was presented in Section 2.3 fits with the conceptual framework that was proposed in Section 2.2.5. While in general, the empirical observations appear to match our expectations, it is now possible to fill in the blanks in the conceptual framework. Clearly, restructuring processes are driven by a wide variety of objectives. Much of the literature describes projects that were meant to evaluate and support policies of particular organizations, such as the World Bank and regional organizations such as the EU, APEC (2000), and industrial associations, which is why these studies tend to focus on sets of relatively comparable countries with similar objectives. Without such a restricted focus, a rich variation in motives for restructuring and in the backgrounds of such processes emerges. After the adoption of the single European market in 1985, liberalization became a priority for the EC, initially as the main instrument for removing the existing intra-communal barriers to trade and later as an objective on its own merit (Haaland and Matláry, 1997). In addition to economic efficiency, an important motive is the idea that open markets would increase the interdependence of European countries and therefore bring them closer together. However, the goal of competition is not shared by all EU member states and some have restructured merely in order to comply with the Directives. Even when states believe in competition as a means of maximizing social welfare, they will need to balance the commitment to restructuring with other policy goals. Country-specific motives also play a role, such as in the case of Britain’s Prime Minister Thatcher, who used liberalization of the electricity industry and the subsequent dash for gas as a means to put an end to the political power of the coal unions (Parker, 2000). Similar decisions are
86
Competitive Electricity Markets
made by states in the United States that need to comply with FERC regulations (Joskow, 2006). The end of the Communist regimes in the Soviet Union (Tompson, 2004; Balaschak, 2006) and its former satellite states in Eastern Europe and elsewhere was the starting point of a “transition” toward a market-based economy. In these countries, restructuring the electricity sector was part of the general economic transition, which was partly an autonomous process and partly driven by the prospect of EU membership. Developing countries, which inherited the industry structures from their former colonizers, have announced restructuring plans on a large scale. In some cases restructuring is a direct corollary of the existing political ideology and economic strategy. However, Victor and Heller (2004) argue the principal driving force for reform is financial: “Even in cases where reformers have held the reins of power, substantial reform has rarely followed until the state dominated system is bankrupt and the lights are dimming.” Within the context of a financially fragile public sector, this meant that investments in the supply and provision of electricity would have to be undertaken mainly by private operators and funded by private funding agencies. In many developing countries, however, restructuring was imposed by the IMF or the World Bank as part of economic support packages (see Rosenzweig et al., 2004; Yi-chong, 2006; Potts Voll et al., 2006). Generally, these packages are geared toward providing the necessary investment in infrastructures and institution building to facilitate further development of these economies (Thomas, 2006). Hence, expanding and renovating the electricity system in developing countries requires a certain degree of restructuring and a shift in the role of government and publicly owned firms. The relatively weak capacity of the public organizations and the allegedly more efficient operation of private sector firms is also a motivation for restructuring (Bacon and Besant-Jones, 2001; Victor, 2006). In other developing countries the situation is somewhere in between these two extremes. Restructuring may be undertaken voluntarily, not because of an inherent faith in competitive markets, but as a means of attracting foreign investment. The restructuring process in these countries is vulnerable. A shortage of electricity in a competitive market or high fuel prices (which may also be caused by a devaluation of the local currency) may cause high electricity prices, which may be socially and politically unacceptable. The temptation would be strong to re-regulate prices, which, without compensating measures, would discourage investment, returning the country to the original problem of attracting investment. So whereas the introduction of competition is often presented as a logical and inescapable consequence of the superiority of “the market” as an economic coordination device, it can be observed that a range of different motives exist in different countries and at different times. Shifts in drivers and process dynamics lead governments and market parties to adjust their strategies (see Green, 2006). Hence, when evaluating the progress in restructuring and the emergence of hybrid markets, it is necessary to distinguish the initial drivers behind the process from later adjustments to them. Indeed, Rudnick et al. (2005) and Sioshansi (forthcoming), respectively, refer to “second stage” and the “reform of the reforms.” The impact of related policies, such as environmental policies, upon market design appears to be limited. These policies are typically achieved through other means, such as standards or taxes. The main exception is security of supply of primary fuels, which may run counter to the drive to create a market with many small competitors, as the perception may exist that the market power of large firms is needed to secure good fuel import contracts.
EBL
Hybrid Electricity Markets
87
In summary, with respect to the motives for restructuring, empirical analysis shows that governments may or may not: • • •
•
•
•
support a neo-liberal program in order to enhance the efficiency of public sector management in the broadest sense by privatization and restructuring; seek to enhance the efficiency of their power systems specifically, to achieve lower supply prices, to improve quality of supply, and to diversify their fuels; seek private investment in their electricity industry, to facilitate an expansion of their supply potential and therefore accept some degree of restructuring, most likely involving higher prices to (groups of) consumers; seek to achieve market integration with (groups of) adjoining countries and accept some degree of reduction in their autonomy over “public interest” sectors, in exchange for advantages for other economic sectors; support integration with neighboring markets, for the purpose of exploiting (potential) advantages in exporting or importing power, or by engaging in the electricity industry of associated countries; restructure merely to satisfy requirements of other authorities, such as the EU, the FERC, the IMF, or the World Bank.
Of the exogenous factors that were proposed in Section 2.2.1, two, apart from the cultural and ideological commitment to competition as a means of maximizing welfare, stand out. The first is the level of economic development, in which a high income per capita generally correlates with a lower rate of growth in electricity demand and the presence of a relatively stable legal and policy framework. Lower income countries often experience higher rates of growth in their electricity demand, but also experience higher risks of economic and institutional instability. Consequently, investment risk is higher and they face greater difficulty in attracting sufficient investment capital. Indeed, a competitive energy-only market significantly raises investment risks. To reduce this risk, the introduction of competition can be limited to wholesale competition or be accompanied with a capacity mechanism (De Vries, 2007). A second important exogenous factor is the availability of indigenous primary energy resources, like hydropower, coal, petroleum, or gas. Hydropower fundamentally changes the dynamics of the market, as peak capacity is cheap, but the total amount of energy stored in the reservoirs needs to be spread out over the dry season. Coal exploitation is often associated with employment and social issues. Petroleum production generally yields high revenues to the state, thus reducing financial pressures to restructure, while supporting particular political interest coalitions in maintaining the status quo. The presence of (un)tapped natural gas reserves may support pressures to restructure the power industry, as it promises low (capital) cost and an efficient expansion of generation capacity. Here geopolitics and the organization of the gas industry are important variables. Countries that are endowed with sufficient indigenous energy sources show a stronger tendency to pursue effective competition with a number of smaller players. In contrast, in Europe, resistance to privatization and horizontal unbundling is sometimes linked to concerns about fuel import dependency, in particular with respect to natural gas (Correljé and Van der Linde, 2006). Due to path dependency, history matters. Decisions made in the past affect future options. Therefore, the situation at the start of the restructuring process has a significant impact upon the restructuring process and its outcome. Most important is whether at the outset of restructuring there is a national monopoly in the power sector or a number of regional firms. Glachant and Finon (2000) consider the presence of an incumbent monopoly
EBL
88
Competitive Electricity Markets
the “Achilles’ heel” of restructuring as it will be difficult for a government to split it up in order to create competition, especially if the company is privately owned. A likely outcome is the facilitation of “competitive” entry alongside the incumbent. Empirically, this situation is observed in developing countries, where IPPs were encouraged, and in some EU countries. If the alliance between the (public) monopoly and the state is continued, new institutional arrangements and a regulatory body develop only slowly. To mitigate the market power of the monopoly, price regulation needs to be maintained, but this often harms the interests of (potential) new entrants. Also, with respect to vertical unbundling, ownership is an important factor. If incumbent, vertically integrated firms are publicly owned, unbundling, the introduction of access rules and tariffs, and wholesale and retail competition are more or less easily established through the political process. In addition to opposition by the incumbents, the main sources of resistance to restructuring may be public bodies at different levels and with different interests, consumer protection interest groups, environmental advocacy groups, and, last but not least, trade unions. When a government wishes to restructure private firms, the situation is much more complex. Unbundling often involves a struggle over compensation payments for “stranded cost.” Moreover, the incumbent firms will try to maintain their oligopolistic position by obstruction of the market or by mergers, or they may be taken over by foreign firms. On the other hand, if the state only halfheartedly pursued liberalization in the first place, it may try to protect the interests of the “national” firms, for instance because they are presumed to serve the country better than foreign parties, the more so if these firms have other public tasks. This situation causes inconsistencies, on/off policies, and a very slow development of an effective market. Taking all these issues into consideration, what is the prospect for agreement upon a single market design? To the extent that exogenous factors or fundamental differences in policy objectives are the causes of differences in the market design, they will likely have a lasting effect and multiple market designs are likely to continue to coexist. Examples are markets in which concerns for security of supply, particular physical conditions, or high investment risk have prompted government intervention. On the other hand, when variations in market design are due to differences in opinion regarding the means, in a context of similar policy goals and similar exogenous conditions, one would expect that mutual learning would eventually lead to convergence of the market design. North (1990), however, warns that this may be a slow process. The bounded rationality of the actors contributes to path dependency in which preexisting patterns are replicated with only modest alterations. This may explain, for instance, the preference for integrated markets (with mandatory pools) in the United States versus the decentralized markets of Europe, as well as the presence of capacity markets in the United States and their absence in Europe.
EBL
2.5. Conclusions This chapter has presented a framework for explaining the many differences in the approach to electricity market restructuring around the world. A number of policy objectives exist with regard to power market restructuring; the particular institutional context has a strong influence upon which policy objectives are chosen and how they are prioritized. Implementation of these objectives takes place through two main policy areas: the market design process and competition policy (including the policy with respect to horizontal unbundling of dominant incumbent firms). This process is constrained by external factors such as the economic climate and the physical situation in a country. In addition,
Hybrid Electricity Markets
89
the situation at the outset of the restructuring process influences the process itself. Due to path dependency, this influence may be long-lasting. Feedback exists in the sense that governments observe the performance of the electricity market and respond by adjusting their policies. This feedback is limited by time lags, incomplete data, bounded rationality, and the fact that much of the feedback represents the perspectives of lobbyists. The limitations of the information feedback loop give rise to path dependency: given uncertainty about the best direction for policy, decisions that generate the least resistance are favored, which means those that depart the least from the status quo. A second cause of path dependency may be that the government is not able to overcome resistance to change by vested interests. This framework has helped to explain the diversity of restructuring processes and market designs that can be observed. The prospects for future convergence of these different market designs hinge upon a number of factors: •
The policy goals and their relative weights vary. A key factor is whether the restructuring of a country’s power sector is ideologically and politically motivated or whether it is more or less forced upon a country by a higher authority, the latter often leading to a half-hearted and unstable approach. • Due to path dependency, the situation at the start of a process of restructuring significantly influences the potential for competition, especially the degree of concentration and whether or not the industry is already privatized. • Exogenous factors, such as physical scale, endowment with natural resources, and macro-economic conditions, may have a dominant influence upon the design of the market. Countries that are endowed with sufficient indigenous energy sources tend to be more inclined toward pursuing effective competition with a number of smaller players than countries that are severely dependent upon imports of fossil fuels.
EBL
When exogenous factors or fundamental differences in policy objectives are the causes of differences in the market design, there is little prospect for convergence of market designs. Otherwise, if the circumstances and policy goals are similar, mutual learning should lead to convergence, but this process is limited to similar markets and will be slow due to the imperfections of the policy feedback loop. References Alexander, I. and Harris, C. (2005). The regulation of investment in utilities: concepts and applications. World Bank Working Paper no. 52, The World Bank, Washington. APEC (2000). Electricity sector deregulation in the APEC region. Asia Pacific Energy Research Center, March, Tokyo. Arango, S, Dyner, I., and Larsen, E.R. (2006a). Lessons from deregulation: Understanding electricity markets in South America. Uti. Pol., 14, 196–207. Arango, S, Dyner, I., and Larsen, E.R. (2006b). Understanding the Argentinean and Colombian electricity markets. In Electricity Market Reform, An International Perspective (F.P. Sioshansi and W. Pfaffenberger, eds). Amsterdam: Elsevier, pp. 595–616. Bacon, R.W. and Besant-Jones, J. (2001). Global electric power reform, privatization, and liberalization of the electric power industry in developing countries. Ann. Rev. of Energ. and the Env., 26, 331–59. Balaschak, J. (2006). Restructuring the Power Industry in Russia, 15 December. Available at: http:// www.amcham.ru/doing_business/oil_and_gas_issues/restructuring_power_industry_in_russia. Blumsack, S.A., Apt, J., and Lave, L.B. (2005). Lessons from the failure of U.S. electricity restructuring. The Elec. J., 19(2), 5–31. Brunekreeft, G. and Twelemann, S. (2005). Regulation, competition and investment in the German electricity market: Reg TP of REGTP. Energ. J., Special Issue, 99–126.
90
Competitive Electricity Markets
Cavaliere, C., Larsen, E.R., and Dyner, I. (2007). The privatization of EEB: From cash drain to major contributor. Energ. Pol., 35, 1884–95. Carreón-Rodriguez, V.G., Jiménez San Vicente, A., and Rosellón, J. (2003). The Mexican Electricity Sector: Economic, Legal and Political Issues. Working Paper #5. Program on Energy and Sustainable Development, Center for Environmental Science and Policy Stanford Institute for International Studies, November. CEC (1996). Directive 96/92/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 19 December 1996 concerning common rules for the internal market in electricity. Off. J. of the Eur. U. 1997, L 27, 20–9. CEC (2003). Directive 2003/54/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 26 June 2003, concerning common rules for the internal market in electricity and repealing Directive 96/92/EC. Of. J. of the Eur. U. 2003, L 176, 37–55. CEC (2005). Report on progress in creating the internal gas and electricity market. Brussels: CEC. CEC (2006a). Sector Inquiry under Art 17 Regulation 1/2003 on the gas and electricity markets (Preliminary report). Brussels: CEC. CEC (2006b). Sector Inquiry under Art. 17 of Regulation 1/2003 on the gas and electricity markets (final report), SEC 1724. Brussels: CEC. CEC (2007a). Prospects for the internal gas and electricity market: Communication From The Commission To The European Council And The European Parliament (COM(2006) 841 final). Brussels: CEC. CEC (2007b). An energy policy for Europe: Communication from the Commission to the European Council and the European Parliament (COM(2007) 1 final). Brussels: CEC. CEC (2007c). DG competition report on energy sector inquiry. Brussels: CEC, DG Competition. Chao, H., Oren, S., and Wilson, R. (this book). Reevaluation of vertical integration and unbundling in restructured electricity markets. Chapter 1. Correljé, A. F. (2005). Dilemmas in network regulation: The Dutch gas industry. In Innovations in liberalized network industries: Between private initiatives and public interest (R. Künneke, J. Groenewegen, and A. Correljé, eds). Edward Elgar, 115–50. Correljé, A.F., Van der Linde, J.G., and Westerwoudt, T. (2003). Natural Gas in the Netherlands: From cooperation to competition? The Hague: Clingendael International Energy Programme/Oranje Nassau. Correljé, A.F. and Van der Linde, C. (2006). Energy supply security and geopolitics: A European perspective. Energ. Pol., 34, 532–43. Crampes, C. and Fabra, N. (2005). The Spanish electricity industry: Plus ça change The Energ. J., European Energy Liberalization Special, 127–53. Cronin, F.J. and Motluk, S.A. (2006). Reviewing electric distribution restructuring in Ontario: Policy without substance or commitment. Uti. Pol., 14, 1–7. De Araújo, J.L.R.H. (2006). The case of Brazil: Reform by trial and error? In Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective (F.P. Sioshansi and W. Pfaffenberger, eds). Amsterdam: Elsevier. De Araújo, J.L.R.H., Correia, T., Da Costa, A.M.d.A., and Melo, E. (this book). Reform of the reforms in Brazil: Problems and solutions. Chapter 15. De Vries, L.J. (2004). Securing the public interest in electricity generation markets, The myths of the invisible hand and the copper plate. Ph.D. dissertation, Delft University of Technology, Faculty of Technology, Policy and Management. De Vries, L.J. (2007). Generation adequacy: Helping the market do its job. Uti. Pol., Article in press. De Vries, L.J. and Correljé, A.F. (2006). Hybrid electricity markets. In Proceedings, 26th USAEE/IAEE North American Conference on Energy in a World of Changing Costs and Technologies, Ann Arbor, Michigan. Dehdashti, E.S. (2004). Developing countries; restructuring with benefits from competition (or not). IEEE Pow. & Energ. Mag., September/October, 16–23. Demsetz, H. (1968). Why regulate utilities? J. Law and Econ., 11, 55–65. EFTA (European Free Trade Association) (2007). Energy sector enquiry: Concluding report. EFTA Surveillance Authority, 10 January. Finon, D. (2003). Introducing competition in the French electricity supply industry: The destabilisation of a public hierarchy in an open institutional environment. Working Paper. Cambridge: the Cambridge-MIT Institute.
EBL
Hybrid Electricity Markets
91
Foreman-Peck, J. and Milward, R. (1994). Public and Private Ownership of British Industry 1820-1990. Oxford: Clarendon Press. Friedman, M. (1962). Capitalism and Freedom. Chicago: Chicago University Press. Glachant, J.-M. and Finon, D. (2000). Why do the European Union’s electricity industries continue to differ? A new institutional analysis. In Institution, Contracts and Organizations: Perspectives from New Institutional Economics (C. Ménard, ed.). London: Edward Elgar. Glachant, J.-M. and Finon, D. (2005). A competitive fringe in the shadow of a state monopoly. The Energ. J., European Energy Liberalization Special, 181–204. Glachant, J.-M and Lévêque, F. (2005). Electricity internal market in the European Union: What to do next? Working Paper. SESSA research project on European electricity regulation, www.sessa.eu.com, September. Green, R. (2006). Electricity liberalisation in Europe – how competitive will it be? Energ. Pol. 34(16): 2532–41. Haaland Matláry, J. (1997). Energy Policy in the European Union. Houndmills: Macmillan. Haas, R., Glachant, J.-M., Keseric, N., and Perez, Y. (2006). Competition in the continental European electricity market: Despair or work in progress? In Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective (F.P. Sioshansi and W. Pfaffenberger, eds). Amsterdam: Elsevier. Heller, T.C., Tjiong, H.I., and Victor, D.G. (2004). Electricity restructuring and the social contract. Working Paper #15. Program on Energy and Sustainable Development, Center for Environmental Science and Policy, Stanford University, Stanford, May. Heller, T.C. and Victor, D.G. (2004). A political economy of electric power market restructuring: Introduction to issues and expectations. Working Paper #1. Program on Energy and Sustainable Development, Center for Environmental Science and Policy, Stanford Institute for International Studies, Revised, May. Helm, D. (2003). Energy, the State and the Market: British Energy Policy since 1979. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Henisz, W.J. and Zelner, B.A. (2001). The political economy of private electricity provision in Southeast Asia, WP 2001—02. Working Paper of the Reginald H. Jones Center The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania. http://jonescenter.wharton.upenn.edu/papers/2001/wp01-02.pdf Hogan, W. (2005). On an ‘Energy-Only’ Electricity Market Design for Resource Adequacy. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University. Available from http://ksghome.harvard.edu/∼whogan. Hunt, S. (2002). Making Competition Work in Electricity. New York: John Wiley & Sons, Inc. Hunt, S. and Shuttleworth, G. (1996). Competition and Choice in Electricity. Chichester: John Wiley & Sons, Inc. Jamasb, T. (2002) Reform and regulation of the electricity sectors in developing countries. DEA Working Paper WP 0226, University of Cambridge. Jamasb, T. and Pollitt, M. (2005). Electricity market reform in the European Union: Review of progress toward liberalization & integration. The Energ. J., European Energy Liberalization Special, 11–42. Joskow, P.L. (1996). Introducing competition into regulated network industries from hierarchies to markets in electricity. Ind. and Corp. Ch., 2, 341–82. Joskow P.L. (2005a). Markets for power in the United States, an interim assessment. The Energ. J., 27(1), 1–37. Joskow, P. L. (2005b). Vertical integration. In Handbook of New Institutional Economics (C. Menard and M. Shirley, eds). Springer. Joskow, P. (2006). Introduction to electricity sector liberalization: Lessons learned from cross-country studies. In Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective (F.P. Sioshansi and W. Pfaffenberger, eds). Amsterdam: Elsevier. Kinnunen, K. (2004). Electricity network regulation – practical implementation in the Nordic countries. In Trends in Infrastructure Regulation and Financing. International Experience and Case Studies from Germany (C. Von Hirschhausen, T. Beckers, and K. Mitusch, eds). Edward Elgar Publishing. Knops, H.P.A. (2003). Weighing ways of keeping the energy balance. In Proceedings, 26th Annual IAEE Conference, Prague, 4–7 June. Künneke, R. and Fens, T. (2007). Ownership unbundling in electricity distribution: The case of The Netherlands. Energ. Pol., 35, 1920–30.
EBL
92
Competitive Electricity Markets
Kwoka, John (2006). Restructuring the US power sector: A review of recent studies. Report Prepared for the American Public Power Association, Northeastern University, November. http://www.appanet.org/files/PDFs/RestructuringStudyKwoka1.pdf Littlechild, S.C. (2003). Electricity: Regulatory Developments from Around the World. IEA/LBS Beesley lectures on regulation series XI, 9 October 2001, reprinted in Colin Robinson (ed.) Competition and Regulation in Utility Markets, London: Institute of Economic Affairs and London Business School, 2003, pp. 61–87. Meritet, Sophie (2007). French energy policy in the European context. For. Pol. in Dial., 8(20), 25–34. Newbery, D.M. (2002). Regulatory Challenges to European Electricity Liberalisation, Cambridge: DAE Working Papers. Newbery, D. (2005a). Electricity market reform in the European Union: Review of progress towards liberalization & integration. The Energ. J., European Energy Liberalization Special, 155–79. Newbery, D. (2005b). Refining market design. Paper presented at the Conference on Implementing the Internal Market of Electricity: Proposals and Time-Tables, 9 September, Brussels, Sessa, http://www.sessa.eu.com/public/publications.php North, D. (1990). Institutions, Institutional Change And Economic Performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Parker, M.J. (2000). Thatcherism and the Fall of Coal. Oxford University Press. Potts Voll, S., Rosenzweig, M.B., and Pabon-Agudelo, C. (2006). Power sector reform: Is there a road forward. The Elec. J., 19(6), 24–37. Rosenzweig, M.B., Potts Voll, S., and Pabon-Agudelo, C. (2004). Power sector reform: Experiences from the road. The Elec. J., 17(11), 16–28. Rudnick, H., Barroso, L.A., Skerk, C., and Blanco, A. (2005). South American reform lessons: Twenty years of restructuring in Argentina, Brazil, and Chile. IEEE Pow. and Energ. Mag., July/August, 49–59. Scherer, F.M. (1980). Industrial Market Structure And Economic Performance, 2nd edn. Boston: Houghton Mifflin Comp. Serrallés, R.J. (2006). Electric energy restructuring in the European Union: Integration, subsidiarity and the challenge of harmonization. Energ. Pol., 34, 2542–51. Sioshansi, F.P. and Pfaffenberger, W. (eds.) (2006), Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective, Oxford: Elsevier. Sioshansi, P. (forthcoming) Electricity markets and the ‘reform of the reforms’. Int. J. of Glob. Energ. Iss., x, No x. Shuttleworth, G. (2000). Opening European Electricity and Gas Markets. NERA. Stoft, S. (2002). Power System Economics, Designing Markets for Electricity. Piscataway, NJ: IEEE Press. Stiglitz, J. (1986). Economics of the Public Sector. New York: W.W. Norton and Company. Thomas, S. (2003). The seven brothers. Energ. Pol., 31(15), 393–403. Thomas, S. (2006). The grin of the Cheshire cat. Energ. Pol., 34(15), 1974–83. Tompson, W. (2004). Restructuring Russia’s electricity sector: towards effective competition of faux liberalisation?, Economics Department Working Papers No. 403 ECO/WKP(2004)26, OECD, Paris. Tongia, R. (2003). The Political Economy of Indian Power Sector Reforms. Working Paper #5. Program on Energy and Sustainable Development, Center for Environmental Science and Policy, Stanford Institute for International Studies, November. Van Damme, E. (2005). Liberalising the Dutch electricity market. The Energ. J., European Energy Liberalization Special, 155–79. Victor, D.G. (2006). Power sector reform in developing countries: Lessons from a comparative study of Brazil, China, India, Mexico and South Africa. World Forum on Energy Regulation III, Washington DC, 8–11 October. Victor, D.G. and Heller, T.C. (2006). The Political Economy of Power Sector Reform: The Experiences of Five Major Developing Countries. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Williams, J.H. and Ghanadan, R. (2006). Electricity reform in developing and transition countries: A reappraisal. Energ. Pol. 31, 815–44. Weinmann, J. (2007). Agglomerative magnets and informal regulatory networks – Electricity market design convergence in the USA and Continental Europe. Working Paper, Florence School of Regulation.
EBL
Hybrid Electricity Markets
93
Weinmann, J. and Bunn, D. (2004). Resource endowment and electricity sector reform. London Business School, Working Paper, Energy Markets Group. Williamson, O.E. (1998). Transaction cost economics how it works; where it is headed., De Economist, 146(1), 23–58. Willman, P., Coen, D., Currie, D., and Siner, M. (2003). The Evolution of regulatory relationships: regulatory institutions and firm behavior in privatized industries. Ind. and Corp. Ch., 12(1), 69–89. Yi-chong, X. (2006). The myth of the single solution: Electricity reforms and the World Bank. Energy, 31, 802–14.
EBL
EBL
This page intentionally left blank
Chapter 3 Achieving Electricity Market Integration in Europe NIGEL CORNWALL Managing Consultant, Cornwall Energy Associates
Summary This chapter describes the evolution toward the single electricity market in Europe under the auspices of the European Union (EU) following over a decade of reform. Its focus is on a number of centrally driven initiatives, but specific technical and regional initiatives to market integration are also examined. The chapter also looks at convergence of key market and network access activities, and considers collaboration between transmission system operators (TSOs) who initially took the lead. It seeks above all to synthesize a lot of sometimes confusing activity, disparate initiatives, and abundant literature into a single account. The chapter concludes that there are now reasonable prospects of achieving incremental and possibly sustained change. However, while there have been some successes, the reform path continues to prove much more difficult than was initially envisaged. At this stage, while the likely direction of the evolutionary path toward functional and market harmonization is clear, it is not obvious when and in what precise form further convergence between markets will take.
EBL
3.1. Introduction European Union (EU) policymakers have been trying to develop an integrated European market. This chapter describes the evolution toward the single electricity market in Europe under the auspices of the EU following a decade of reform. The chapter’s focus is on a number of centrally driven initiatives, but specific technical and regional initiatives to market integration are also examined. It also looks at convergence of key market and network access activities and considers technical collaborations between transmission system operators (TSOs) who initially took the lead. Section 3.2. sets the contextual information on the European interconnected system and some of the key players. Section 3.3. runs through four distinct, though sometimes overlapping, milestones or phases of activity: • •
the first phase concerned work by the TSOs in a number of regional sub-groupings; the debate on market convergence in Europe then picked up momentum under the stimulus of the first electricity directive in 1996, with the European 95
Competitive Electricity Markets
96
Commission (hereafter the commission) taking over the driving seat for a second phase; • since the turn of the century the commission has become much more directional, and, with a second electricity directive in 2003 and regulations issued under it, it has reinvigorated a number of important workstreams, which effectively constitute a third phase; and • a fourth and new phase of market integration has recently begun. The commission has actively co-opted national regulators and refocused its efforts to help bring about sub-regional markets as a staging post to its one market vision. It has also initiated debate on further key measures as part of its January 2007 energy package. Under the stimulus of the commission and regional technical and regulatory agencies, the discussion by early 2007 was definitely back in full swing after a number of false dawns. However, the conviction that liberalization, market opening, price deregulation, and functional unbundling on their own would lead to competition and lower prices has long since dissipated in the commission and among those supporting the reform process. Section 3.4. takes a detailed look at key workstreams that have allowed some of the technical barriers to market convergence to be addressed. Some of these have been brought into clearer focus by the second directive and supporting regulation and guidelines. Section 3.5. examines how one sub-regional grouping comprising Britain, France, and Ireland (both north and south) is currently collaborating in a regional market initiative being led by the commission. There is relatively abundant literature available on these states, and the regional initiative involving them is making early progress. Unlike previous initiatives, this effort is being managed by the participating national regulators. The chapter’s main conclusions are summarized in Section 3.6.
EBL
3.2. Contextual Setting This section looks at the physical background, the key players, and the development of pan-European trade and mechanisms and is organized into five subsections: • • • • •
an overview of the European grid; a primer on the European TSOs; a discussion on trading convergence; an introduction to European exchanges; and a discussion of technical collaborations among the TSOs.
3.2.1. An overview of the European grid The electricity networks of the 25 member states at end-December 20061 are interconnected but to widely different degrees. A stylized representation is presented in Fig. 3.1.2 1
From 1 January, Romania and Bulgaria also accessed to the union. Original 15 member states: IE=Ireland, UK=United Kingdom, NL=Netherlands, DK_W=Denmark West, DK_E = Denmark East, NO = Norway, FI = Finland, SE = Sweden, DE = Germany, BE = Belgium, FR = France, ES = Spain, PT = Portugal, IT = Italy, AT = Austria, GR = Greece, Luxembourg not shown. Acceded prior to 2006: PL = Poland, EE = Estonia, LV = Latvia, LT = Lithuania, CZ = Czech Republic, SK = Slovakia, SL = Slovenia. HU = Hungary, Acceded 2007: RO = Romania, BA = Bulgaria. South East TSOs outside European Union: MK = Macedonia, AL = Albania. Others: Russia, BY = Belarussia, UA = Ukraine, TR = Turkey, MA = Morocco, and CH = Switzerland, are not part of the EU but are interconnected. 2
Achieving Electricity Market Integration in Europe
97
EBL
Fig. 3.1. Representation of European cross-border power flows, 2005. Source: ETSO 2006.
Presently flows between national markets are very limited. Within the EU cross-border trading of electricity is more important than exchange with countries outside the EU. Luxembourg, Latvia, and Hungary have net imports of 62%, 51%, and 22%, respectively, of their national consumption. At the other end of the spectrum sit the Czech Republic and Estonia that have net exports amounting to 31% and 41%, respectively, of their domestic consumption, whereas Lithuania’s net exports are, at 106%, higher than its domestic consumption. In terms of volumes the largest net exporter of electricity is France, which exported 67T Wh in 2003, four times more electricity than the next largest net exporter, the Czech Republic whose exports, however, grew 23-fold since 1990. Poland is third in this ranking. Italy was by far the most important net importer of electricity, importing approximately three times as much as the Netherlands, with Sweden coming as third largest net importer. Full data for 2004 and 2005 are shown in Table 3.1. Flows between markets are inhibited by wide-ranging differences in the access arrangements on different interconnectors or links. Even where a similar type of mechanism has been applied, timescales and details of allocation can differ widely.3 3 http://ec.europa.eu/energy/electricity/benchmarking/doc/2/sec_2003_448_en.pdf, see especially table page 81. This chapter provides detailed footnotes with relevant sources rather than a bibliography at the end.
Competitive Electricity Markets
98
Table 3.1. Electricity imports and exports, 2004 and 2005
Area/Country EU-25 EU-15 New -10 Austria Belgium Cyprus Czech Republic Germany Denmark Estonia Spain Finland France United Kingdom Greece Hungary Ireland Italy Lithuania Luxembourg Latvia Malta Netherlands Poland Portugal Sweden Slovenia Slovakia
Total electricity demand
Imports from foreign countries
TWh
MW
Exports to foreign countries TWh
2005
2004
2005
2004
2005
3 0135 2 7108 3926
2893 2458 435
3015 2509 506
2942 2235 707
2811 2072 739
638 882 41 250 5635 352 74 2716 849 4824 3866 584 388 265 3294 101 62 68 23 1147 1306 521 1473 137 262
166 146 00 −09 442 87 03 01 117 291 98 49 138 15 465 01 65 56 00 214 53 65 156 43 43
204 143 00 98 534 134 03 101 179 00 113 56 150 21 502 11 64 51 00 237 50 75 146 72 45
135 60 00 124 215 115 23 111 68 910 23 20 63 00 08 73 31 35 00 52 146 01 178 50 62
177 80 00 255 619 121 21 11050 09 602 00 18 88 00 141 41 32 29 00 54 162 07 220 76 72
EBL
Source: Eurelectric, March 2007.
Most existing links between member states are also heavily constrained. Congestion management methods also differ widely, with a number of variations apparent and typically based around three different models, namely re-dispatch, counter-trading, and multilateral transmission capacity allocation. A key objective of the single pan-European electricity market is to increase the extent of interconnection and levels of trade between markets, and the commission has long recognized that interconnectors facilitate the inter-regional and cross-border transport of power and that a high level of interconnection is a pre-requisite for a well-functioning internal market. It was agreed at the Barcelona European Council in 2002, following a range of fitful and largely unsuccessful initiatives over the 1990s, to strengthen policy to facilitate the completion of infrastructure projects seen by member states as priorities.
Achieving Electricity Market Integration in Europe
99
The need for a strengthened policy to facilitate the completion of priority infrastructure projects was underlined by the EU heads of state and government at Hampton Court in October 2005. Ministers agreed to formalize a policy to increase minimum interconnection levels to 10%. However, a significant number of member states have not achieved this target.4 Consequently, the EU has formulated a series of policies aimed at supporting the development of effective energy infrastructure in Europe. Those impacting on electricity include: Guidelines for trans-European energy networks (the so-called TEN-E Guidelines)5 – the commission has identified 314 projects of common interest whose completion, it considers, should be speeded up. These include 42 high-priority “projects of European interest,” which may be either cross-border in nature or have a significant impact on cross-border transmission capacity. The Guidelines provide a framework for increased coordination, for monitoring progress in implementation, and where appropriate, for financial support, usually in the form of loans by the European Investment Bank. • Specific rules to ensure an appropriate level of electricity interconnection between member states, while facilitating a stable investment climate as mandated by a 2005 directive.6 •
Despite these and other measures, the commission continues to consider that progress on development of common networks is insufficient. The European Council of March 2006 called for the adoption of a Priority Interconnection Plan7 (the Plan), as part of the Strategic European Energy Review (SEER). And this was issued in January 2007. This plan addresses how the priority projects can be stimulated, especially the 42 high-priority schemes, 32 of which are electricity schemes out of which 20 have faced significant delays. In all the commission considers that some E6 bn of investment is necessary by 2013. The issues have taken on more immediacy following the blackout that occurred in eight EU
EBL
4
These include Poland, the United Kingdom, Spain, Ireland, Italy, France, Portugal as well as Bulgaria and Poland. 5 Decision No 1364/2006/EC (OJ L 262, 22 September 2006, p.1). 6 Directive to safeguard security of electricity supply and infrastructure investment, 2005/89/EC. 7 The Priority Interconnection Plan sets out five priorities: • identifying the most significant missing infrastructure up to 2013 and ensuring pan-European political support to fill the gaps; • appointing four European coordinators to pursue the four of the most important priority projects, three on which are in the power sector: the Power-Link between Germany, Poland, and Lithuania; connections to offshore wind power in Northern Europe; electricity interconnections between France and Spain; • agreeing for a maximum of 5 years within which planning and approval procedures must be completed for projects that are defined as being “of European interest” under the commission’s TEN-E Guidelines; • examining the need to increase funding for the Energy Trans-European networks, particularly to facilitate the integration of renewable electricity into the grid; and • establishing a new Community mechanism and structure for TSO, responsible for coordinated network planning. http://eur-lex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/site/en/com/2006/com2006_0846en01.pdf
100
Competitive Electricity Markets
countries on 4 November 2006 affecting 15 mn customers,8 which highlighted that the European grid is already behaving in some important respects as a single power system, but with the network not designed accordingly.
3.2.2. The European TSOs In Europe, as in other large interconnected systems, TSOs have been key players in stimulating market convergence. A TSO is a Transmission System Operator, in principle, similar to regional transmission organizations (RTOs) in US parlance. Its job in a nutshell is to “keep the lights on,” within prescribed statutory and technical limits over the part of the network it has jurisdiction over. The European Transmission System Operator (ETSO) organization, which loosely acts as a trade association for them, defines a TSO as the party who is: responsible for the bulk transmission of electric power on the main high voltage electric networks. TSOs provide grid access to the electricity market players according to non-discriminatory and transparent rules. In order to ensure the security of supply, they also guarantee the safe operation and maintenance of the system. In many countries, TSOs are in charge of the development of the grid infrastructure too. TSOs in the European Union internal electricity market are entities operating independently from the other electricity market players.9 Typically, each country in Europe has its own national TSO, though some have more than one (e.g., Germany), usually in areas where regional utilities have historically been the industry model. Most TSOs own the transmission system, some don’t, but they all exercise operational control over high-voltage networks, though actual boundaries and demarcations differ.10 In many jurisdictions – and all of those this chapter is most interested in – the TSO is also responsible for trading and settlement of energy imbalances where parties inject or withdraw power from the physical system without energy contracts. While there is great diversity in form and to a lesser degree function, the degree of unbundling achieved is lesser than that evident in most parts of North America and Australia. There also tends
EBL
8 In its advice delivered at the request of the commission on 20 December 2006, ERGEG concluded that lessons from an earlier 2003 Italian blackout have not been followed through, and that the following was needed to keep the lights on in Europe in the future: • adoption, on proposal of the European Commission, of legally binding operational security rules; • development by the commission of a framework for the electricity network as part of its energy strategy; • improvement of the cooperation between EU electricity grid operators, which should be publicly accountable for their actions. http://www.ergeg.org/portal/page/portal/ERGEG_HOME/ERGEG_ADMIN/PR-07-03_ERGEG_ FinalReport_Blackout_2007-02-06.doc Ergeg’s Final Report identifies three main causes: (1) non-fulfilment of the (n-1) security rule, (2) inappropriate inter-TSO coordination during the event and (3) distributed generation units were not monitored or controlled appropriately by TSOs The uncoordinated behavior worsened the effects. 9 www.etso-net.org/association/aboutus/tso/e_default.asp. 10 In all member states, voltage levels of 220 kV and above are included as transmission. There exists a range from 50 kV to 200 kV where the voltage level is ether transmission or distribution. All voltage levels below 50 kV are included in the distribution networks.
Achieving Electricity Market Integration in Europe
101
to be less differentiation between the respective roles of asset owner and system operator than in other deregulated electricity markets. TSOs undertake a number of essential functions, which are typically performed under legislative or regulatory provisions. The precise way in which TSOs achieve these functions varies, but the core activities are: •
• • •
•
•
network capacity and investment – TSOs manage network investment to ensure that the infrastructure continues to meet technical security standards and to ensure that sufficient capacity is delivered; network access – TSOs contract with grid users to provide access to their respective transmission networks; transmission charging – TSOs also levy charges on grid users to recover the costs of the network; network operation – TSOs operate the transmission system in real time and carry out congestion management and procure balancing or ancillary services to help them do this; emergency planning and, in extremis, system restart – TSOs plan and make arrangements for possible network disturbance situations such as the failure of a major generating station or the more widespread failure of part or all of the network. Each TSO will establish operational plans to recover from these situations and will enter into contracts for the procurement of adequate services needed for recovery, e.g., black start of generators, reserves etc; and network maintenance – TSOs undertake the day-to-day maintenance of their transmission network equipment.
EBL
Managing access to the system is also a key activity. This entails providing a contractual interface with grid users, and developing rules for connection to the system and its use. As well as applying terms for grid use, TSOs levy charges not just for use of the assets but also to deal with congestion and thermal network losses. Table 3.2 lists the key TSOs in Europe. The markets most relevant to this chapter are in the top four country rows. Electricity systems across the countries of Europe have many shared characteristics, and the measures TSOs adopt to maintain balance of the electricity system also have common drivers. The operation of TSOs and the technical parameters that apply in Europe is well documented,11 12 13 14 and is not covered further in this chapter. 3.2.3. Deregulation The uniformity of the timetable for deregulation conceals important differences at which the pace of change has been introduced by different member states. The size and composition of national markets also differ widely. Basic data are shown in Fig. 3.2. The red part of the bar shows the extent of the market for non-domestic customers’, dark blue the part of the domestic retail market that has been opened, and light blue the part of 11
ETSO (2003). Current State of Balance Management in Europe. December. Frontier Economics Ltd for the European Commission (2005). Benefits and Practical Steps Towards the Integration of Intraday Electricity Markets and Balancing Mechanisms. December. 13 Ergeg (2006). Guidelines of Good Practice for Electricity Balancing Markets Integration. 7 June. 14 Verhaegen, K., Meeus, L., and Belmans, R. (2006). Development of balancing in the internal electricity market in Europe.presented at EWEC 2006 Athens, 28 February. 12
Competitive Electricity Markets
102
Table 3.2. European TSOs Country
Transmission system operator
Grid operator/ owner
Imbalance settlement
Power exchange
Britain
NGET
NGET (England and Wales) SSE (North Scotland) SP (South Scotland)
Elexon
APX (UK)
Ireland
EirGrid
ESB NG
EirGrid
Northern Ireland
SONI
France
RTE
Powernext
Denmark
Energinet.dk
NordPool
Finland
Fingrid
Norway
Statnett
Sweden
Svenska Kraftnat
Austria (APG)
VERBUND APG
Austria (Tirol)
TIRAG
Austria (Vorarlberg)
VKW Netz
Belgium
Elia
Germany
EnBW Transportnetze AG, E.ON Netz GmbH, RWE Transportnetz Strom GmbHNET, Vattenfall Europe Transmission GmbH
Greece
HTSO
HTSO / PPC
HTSO
Hungary
MAVIR Rt. (ISO)
MVM Rt.
MAVIR Rt.
Italy
GRTN
13 owners with TERNA >95%
GME/GRTN
Luxembourg
Cegedel
Netherlands
TenneT
Poland
Polskie Sieci Elektroenergetyczne SA
Portugal
REN
EBL
APCS
EXAA
A&B
EEX
Towarowa Gielda Energii SA
Achieving Electricity Market Integration in Europe
103
Table 3.2. (Continued) Country
Transmission system operator
Grid operator/ owner
Imbalance settlement
Power exchange
Romania
C.N. Transelectrica S.A.
Slovak Republic
Slovenska elektrizacna prenosova sustava, a.s.
Slovenia
ELES
BORZEN (controlled subsidary of ELES)
BORZEN
Spain
Red Electrica de Espana (REE)
Compania Operadora del Mercado de Electricidad (OMEL)
Source: Cornwall Energy, 2007. DE
556.4
FR
482.4
UK
355.0
IT
329.1
ES
Total national market volume(TWh)
247.9
SE
147.3
PL
130.6
NO
EBL
125.9
NL
114.7
BE
86.8
FI
85.0
AT
63.2
CH
63.0
CZ
62.7
GR
52.9
PT
49.9
HU
Opened I&C market
39.3
DK
35.7
SK
26.3
IRL
23.7
SI
Non eligible I&C market Opened retail market Non eligible retail market
12.8
LU
6.2 0
100
200
300 Annual volume (TWh)
400
500
600
Fig. 3.2. Market size and contestability. Source: EU data as consolidated by Cap Gemini.
the domestic market that remains closed prior to 1 July 2007 when full market opening is set to occur. It shows that in 10 of the original group of 15, full competition has been established legally. Actual competition is a rather different matter and is not the focus of this chapter. 3.2.4. Trading convergence Technical collaboration and convergence has been accompanied by continuing divergence in regulatory and commercial rules across national markets. Trading between participants in the different European electricity markets also takes place over different timescales,
Competitive Electricity Markets
104
though a common broad structure is emerging in most jurisdictions now. This standardization has developed in the main without the unifying pressures seen across North America and Australia through federal initiatives and orders covered in other chapters of this volume. Of recent power exchanges (PXs) have emerged and, through the trade association Europex, a pan-European trade association that now has 14 members representing existing or planned national exchanges, they have begin to express a common voice on trading matters and convergences between markets. EFET, the European Federation of Energy Traders, has also acted as a focus for energy traders. In both cases the trade associations have produced their own agendas and priority lists for action to help expedite the single market not just for electricity but also for gas. The basic components of the electricity trading model that is emerging is summarized in Fig. 3.3. It is explained in more detail in Box 3.1.
Year (s) Ahead
Month/Week Ahead
Day Ahead
In Day
Settlement
Balancing Period
Point of Delivery
Gate Closure Bilateral Over the Counter (O.T.C.) Trading: Hedging Trades Against Generation/Supply Speculative Large Granularity (Volume and Time Range)
EBL
Anonymous Power Exchange (P.X.) Trading: Hedging/Refining Position Balancing Trades Medium Granularity (Volume and Time Range)
P.X. / Bilateral Trading: Refining Position Balancing Trades Small Granularity
System Operator (T.S.O.) Trading: System Operator strikes long term contracts for the provision of system services (to ensure capacity to provide services is available). The method of procurement may extend to organized – complementary – markets for the procurement of specific products
Balancing mechanisms and balancing markets T.S.O. buys balancing energy and system services and calls off services under longer term contracts
Fig. 3.3. Typical timescales for trading of energy. Source: Based on a diagram from Benefits and Practical Steps Towards the Integration of Intraday Electricity Markets and Balancing Mechanisms, December 2005, modified by Cornwall Energy, March 2007.
Achieving Electricity Market Integration in Europe
105
Box 3.1 Key elements of market design – European style There are six core elements to the basic trading model. First, there are bilateral and over-the-counter (OTC) markets, where the bulk of energy wholesale trades occur (typically up to over 95%). Trading usually occurs prior to the day-ahead stage, and it often stretches a year or more ahead. With an OTC trade, the transaction is facilitated by a third-party agent. Second, there are the organized exchanges, which are anonymous. They are usually optional (APX in Britain, EEX in Germany, Powernext in France) or semi-optional in the sense that trading is obligatory for un-contracted quantities (NordPool, APX in Netherlands), where standardized contracts ranging from the very short term (day-ahead) to the medium term (1-month to 2-year futures) are traded. Within the EU, these organized regional markets account for between 1 and 2% of the energy consumed as in the United Kingdom to 20% (maximum) as in NordPool. Third, there are different forms of TSO trading to manage network constraints and ensure system balance. These include congestion management mechanisms, which may function as energy markets for allocating transmission capacity (as in the NordPool, which breaks into different price zones when a transmission constraint occurs), or as an organized, single-buyer market (the TSO purchasing on the balancing “countertrading” market), or in the form of a bilateral contracting with the TSO negotiating a portfolio of contracts (re-dispatching). In Britain a hybrid form of counter-trading and re-dispatch is adopted. They also include balancing mechanisms, which give TSOs the means for real-time balancing of energy injections and withdrawals from the physical system. These mechanisms may rely on bilateral contacts negotiated by the TSO or on an organized market for the purchase and sale of incremental and decremental energy. Where energy imbalances are discouraged by applying a penalty on the cost of energy balancing, the term “balancing mechanism” is often used. If, on the other hand, energy is sold (upward or downward as in France) at cost and if parties are permitted to purchase (upward or downward), the term “balancing or adjustment market” is usually used. Further, there are complementary markets, such as ancillary service markets and capacity markets, under which a TSO may provide centralized markets with the means to ensure their functioning or contribute to both short- and long-term security of supply. Generally speaking, these complementary markets in Europe are not well developed compared with North America in the sense that they tend not to be open, with TSOs instead having wide discretionary powers to procure reserves and balancing energy bilaterally. Spain is a notable exception. Finally, there are retail markets. As summarized in Section 3.2.3. these are showing common and converging characteristics. All markets within the EU had to introduce competition to all non-domestic customers by July 2004. Full retail competition is to be introduced by July 2007. Despite efforts by the commission to benchmark competitive behavior within member states, retail markets are still governed by a significant diversity of rules, and they are a considerable way from being subject to a uniform regulatory retail framework.
EBL
Competitive Electricity Markets
106 3.2.5. European exchanges
Trading on organized exchanges in Europe has been slow to take off outside of the Scandinavian market NordPool primarily because of the high levels of vertical integration and consolidation that prevail but, in its preliminary report from its sector investigation, the commission was upbeat about recent improvements and the prospects for increased liquidity in traded markets. Figure 3.4 shows the development of traded spot volumes relative to the consumption in the relevant geographical area for selected markets. Table 3.3 shows spot volumes traded on PXs and on OTC markets relative to electricity consumption in the relevant geographical area. It is evident that large differences exist between geographical areas. These differences are partly the result of diverging national wholesale market frameworks. PXs, as previously noted, can be divided into two broad groups. In the first group, members of PXs have some requirement or incentive to trade via the exchange (OMEL, GME, NordPool), and which as a consequence show a high percentage of trading. In the second group exchange members have no such incentives and open trading in electricity is in effect only just emerging. In this group EEX and APX saw significantly higher spot volumes traded than Powernext, EXAA, Pol PX, and the UKPX. Because of these differences a direct comparison between the two groups of exchanges reveals little, but from Table 3.3 it also emerges that traded spot volumes on exchanges are larger than brokered spot markets in most of the countries. As can be seen from Table 3.4, total traded volumes in standardized forward contracts show large variations among countries, suggesting varying degrees of market development. Again, market design is an important factor. Forward trading in Spain is insignificant, reflecting the mandatory nature of the pool system. In contrast, the Dutch and German OTC forward markets traded by far the highest volumes (relative to consumption) on the continent. In terms of trades a number of continental markets saw their volumes rise. The German and the Dutch markets in particular experienced increasing OTC volumes.
EBL
Spot volumes are developing Development of spot traded volumes on selected power exchanges as a percentage of national consumption
18% 16% 14% 12% 10% 8% 6% 4% 2% 0% 2000
2001 Powernext
2002
2003 APX
2004
2005 EEX
Fig. 3.4. Traded volumes on spot markets. Source: European Commission (2006). Preliminary sector report. February.
Achieving Electricity Market Integration in Europe
107
Table 3.3. Spot traded volumes as a percentage of national electricity consumption (June 2004– May 2005)
Powernext – France UKPX – UK OMEL –Spain GME – Italy NordPool – Nordic Region EEX – Germany APX – The Netherlands Belgium EXAA – Austria Pol PX – Poland
Power exchanges
OTC brokered
3.37% 2.17% 84.02% 43.67% 42.82% 13.24% 11.88% No power exchange 2.96% 1.28%
1.50% 8.60% Negligible n/a n/a 5.40% 5.90% 0.04% n.a n.a
Source: European Commission (2006). Preliminary sector report. February. Note: This table does not contain an exhaustive list of all power exchanges in Europe. OTC brokered numbers refer to volumes reported to the commission by major energy brokers. Table 3.4. Traded volumes in futures/forward contracts as a percentage of national electricity consumption (June 2004–May 2005) Power exchanges
OTC brokered
OMEL – Spain
No exchange trading
Negligible
n/a
GME – Italy
No exchange trading
n/a
n/a
NordPool – Nordic region(2004)
151%
n/a
n/a
EEX – Germany
74%
565%
639%
Endex – The Netherlands (since December 2004)
39%
509%
548%
Belgium
No exchange trading
22%
22%
Powernext – France
6%
79%
85%
EXAA – Austria
No exchange trading
n/a
n/a
Pol PX – Poland
No exchange trading
n/a
n/a
UKPX – UK
0%
146%
146%
EBL
Power exchange + OTC
Source: European Commission (2006). Preliminary sector report. February.
While the development of total traded volumes as a proportion of national electricity consumption has increased, the absolute levels of trading need to be kept in perspective. The United Kingdom is the only market in the sample where traded volumes have significantly declined during the last 2 years. This development is ascribed by the commission to vertical reintegration of the industry, i.e., the trend to combine independent generation and supply businesses into a single operation under the same ownership. Volumes continue to be quite low in France and in Belgium owing to the high level of concentration and vertical integration in these countries. European power trading experienced its best year ever in 2005. In 2005, European PX volumes were up 30%, reaching a record high of 3781 TWh, representing 126% of total European power consumption (Box 3.2). The increasing number of exchanges,
108
Competitive Electricity Markets
standardization and simplification of rules, and official encouragement all played their part. Spot volumes in major West European PXs reached 734 TWh, increasing by 38% over 2004. European spot volumes also increased by 20% between Winter 2005–06 and Winter 2004–05, which may point to a confirmation of the upward trend in 2006.
Box 3.2 European power exchanges NordPool NordPool was established in 1991. It has progressively expanded from Norway, to Sweden then Finland and Denmark. It remains by far Europe’s largest PX in terms of volumes. In 2005, its total spot, futures, and OTC volumes rose by 27% to 962 TWh, 50% of West European PX trading in 2005. EEX Germany’s EEX is now Europe’s second largest PX. It recorded total spot and futures contract volumes of 347 TWh in 2005, up 52% on the year. EEX launched in summer 2005 an OTC clearing offer for French power forwards, allowing the two markets to be connected, the first joint clearing procedure in Europe. Omel
EBL
Omel is the pool operator in Spain. The exchange, established in 1997, is mandatory. Its day-ahead volumes rose by 11% to 223 TWh in 2005, making Omel Europe’s largest spot market. IPEX In its second year of trading (the exchange opened in 2004), Italy’s IPEX’s day-ahead market recorded volumes of 203 TWh, making it Europe’s largest spot market after Spain’s Omel. Again, trading through it is not discretionary for most participants in the Italian market. Powernext Powernext commenced operations in 2002. Spot market volumes on France’s Powernext jumped by 39% in 2005 to 19.7 TWh, whereas futures volumes increased by a factor of three from 13 TWh in 2004 to 62.4 TWh in 2005. Endex Endex offers Dutch power futures and clearing of Dutch OTC power forward contracts and Belgian power forwards. In 2005 Endex booked total volumes of 106 TWh, up 150% on the previous year. Most of the trading activity was Dutch. The creation of a regional French–Belgian–Dutch day-ahead power market and single trading zone, Belpex, was also approved by the Belgian Government in January 2006. Belpex will establish a single trading zone. The project will also create
Achieving Electricity Market Integration in Europe
109
a single power price for France, the Netherlands, and Belgium in the absence of constraints. East European Power exchanges There are four other operating PXs in Eastern Europe. They serve the Czech Republic, Poland, Romania, and Slovenia. All the exchanges presently offer spot market services alone. In 2005, the combined volumes of the Eastern exchanges were 4 TWh, accounting for 2% of total electricity consumption in the four countries.
Integrated regional market areas are developing in spite of remaining regulatory and political uncertainties. In 2005, different market prices were highly correlated15 despite the fact that the implementation of cross-border regulation was lagging, as explained in Section 3.5. However, regional trading structures are very varied and, outside of NordPool, the development remains a significant way from the development of strong regional trading hubs. 3.2.6. Technical collaborations TSOs, particularly those that are part of a highly meshed and synchronized network, cooperate with other TSOs to ensure the secure technical operation of their joint networks. This is not just a European phenomenon, as the evolution of security coordinating councils in North America illustrates. In Europe significant progress has already been made under the aegis of pan-European technical agencies toward a more harmonized grid over a period in excess of fifty years. There are now four groupings in Central and Western Europe where TSOs cooperate together or where they have formed formal collaborations. These areas are:
EBL
UCTE,16 which is a grouping of mainland European and some northern African countries; • Nordel,17 which is a grouping of the four Scandinavian countries; •
15
German and French prices were 99.69% correlated, up from 98.28% in 2004, and German and UK 96.27%, up from 79.75%. 16 The Union for the Co-ordination of Transmission of Electricity was originally set up in 1951 with seven members, Austria, Belgium, France, Federal Republic of Germany, Italy, Luxembourg, and the Netherlands followed by the connection of Denmark. In 1987 Portugal, Spain, Yugoslavia, Greece, and Albania were connected to the system, although the southeastern European states were disconnected during the Balkan wars of the 1990s. In 1995 the CENTREL system countries of Poland, Czech Republic, Slovak Republic, and Hungary were synchronized. In 1996, Romania and Bulgaria were connected. In 1997 the Maghreb countries Morocco, Algeria, and Tunisia were connected via the Gibraltar interconnector, and the Western Ukraine was connected in 2003. Currently UCTE is investigating the addition of Turkey and the eastern Mediterranean to the system, a project it calls “completing the ring.” 17 Nordel is a body for cooperation between the TSOs in Denmark, Finland, Iceland, Norway, and Sweden, whose primary objective is to create the conditions for, and to develop further, an efficient and harmonized Nordic electricity market. Iceland is also a member of Nordel but there is no interconnection to the other countries, the closest of which is Norway at 970 km. Denmark also has a foot in the UCTE camp and the western part of the country is therefore synchronized with UCTE.
110 • •
Competitive Electricity Markets Island of Ireland, which is Northern Ireland and the Irish Republic;18 and Island of Britain, which is the English and Welsh market and the Scottish market.19
With the emergence of the commission’s policy to create a single electricity market, the TSOs of the four regional market groupings decided to set up the international association ETSO to accelerate the harmonization of network access and conditions of usage to facilitate cross-border electricity trade. Added to these regional technical initiatives, ETSO has looked across these regional groupings and provided a forum for cohesion and achieving consistency on a wide range of technical and access issues, from the definition and specification of system services to information shared protocols and common disclosure. More recently ETSO has also progressed several areas of work under wider programs, including inter-TSO compensation (ITC) to deal with cross-border flows, congestion management, electronic data interchange, network use tariffs, security of supply, integration of renewables, and balance management, which is described in more detail later. It is also working closely with national regulators and the commission through the Florence Forum process established by the commission in 1998 to stimulate progress under the first electricity directive. That said, the degree of convergence and consistency achieved between the various TSO entities is often overstated, and in a 2005 report the commission was able to highlight wide-ranging differences in the legal status and in the degree of unbundling achieved between them.20 Further, in February 2006 consultants retained by the commission carried out an inventory and comparative analysis of the transmission network security and reliability rules in Europe. The report concluded that there was a significant diversity in the style and content of the codes and even “in the direct purposes for which they are written.” They recommended a general form of standardization of grid codes and a clearer legal hierarchy, and advocated a consistent scope and format, coverage, and governance arrangements using common terminology.21
EBL
3.3. European Commission Initiatives The commission is playing an increasingly important role in the development of closer working relationships between TSOs, regulators, and other market participants to achieve 18
The Island of Ireland collaboration is a relatively recent exercise. ESB was until recently responsible for all aspects of generation, supply, and infrastructure in the Republic of Ireland. In 2000 the market began to be opened up. On 1 July, 2006, a ring-fenced subsidiary EirGrid plc took over the TSO responsibilities from ESB, which still owns the infrastructure. SONI, the System Operator for Northern Ireland, is a wholly owned subsidiary of Northern Ireland Electricity and is the TSO for Northern Ireland. Discussions are progressing between EirGrid, SONI, and various regulators on the creation of an “All Island Electricity Market.” The new TSO for the whole island market will be called AIME. 19 Until 2005, the transmission systems in England and Wales and Scotland operated separately though there was a high-level technical protocol between the system operators on either side of the Scottish border. From April 2005 a single trading and transmission arrangement across Britain was implemented, termed Betta, which essentially reflected the rollout of the England and Wales Neta style market and a single GB system operator from England and Wales into Scotland. As part of these changes, a number of key changes were introduced that impacted on system operation, including uniform transmission access and pricing rules and appointment of a single TSO independent of market players, with the two Scottish utilities divesting themselves of system operation functions. 20 http://ec.europa.eu/energy/electricity/report_2005/doc/2005_report_technical_annex.pdf 21 http://ec.europa.eu/energy/electricity/publications/doc/security_rules_pb_power_february_ 2006.pdf.
Achieving Electricity Market Integration in Europe
111
a competitive, integrated internal market and in tackling barriers to harmonization. It has to, as its legal mandate is to establish a single energy market, which presupposes the free movement and trade of electricity within and between member states. Setting aside legalities, it has in recent years seized the initiative following haphazard progress by many member states in transcribing two landmark electricity directives into national law, and it is in the process of taking infringement proceedings against several member states.22 A series of benchmarking reports that began in 2001 on progress in implementation of the internal markets and addressing the practical results of the commission’s policies have also highlighted mounting dissatisfaction on the part of the commission at what it sees as some member states acting against the spirit as well as the letter of community law. “In summary, stakeholders do not have a high degree of confidence in the internal market,” the commission wrote in January 2007,23 and it has under way a wide-ranging inquiry of the sector (with gas) under competition law. This section addresses three areas of commission activity that is designed to stimulate progress to the evolution of the single electricity market: •
the legislative background to electricity market restructuring established by the commission; and • other initiatives by the commission to foster harmonization, including establishment of a devolved regional process. 3.3.1. Legislation As Europe as a whole has moved to a closer political union, the electricity market has followed the trend though not as fast as the commission would like. A pivotal point in the development of a common policy was the enactment of the first electricity directive in 1996.24 The first directive provided for a gradual minimum market opening in three steps:
EBL
• • •
22
first step on 19 February 1999; second step on 19 February 2000; and third step on 19 February 2003.
The commission took action against 20 member states for violation and non-transposition of the existing Directives. Following letters of formal notice sent in April 2006 and in advance, if needed, of starting procedure before the European Court of Justice, on 12 December 2006, the commission decided to send 26 reasoned opinions to 16 member states including all the biggest. The main deficiencies observed in transposition of the new internal market directives are the following: • regulated prices preventing entry of new market players • insufficient unbundling of transmission and distribution system operators, which cannot guarantee their independence • discriminatory third-party access to the network, in particular as regards preferential access being granted to incumbents for historical long-term contracts • insufficient competencies of the regulators • no information given to the commission on public service obligations, especially as regards regulated supply tariffs • insufficient indication of the origin of electricity, which is essential in particular for the promotion of renewable energy 23 Communication from the commission to the council and the European Parliament on the prospects for the gas and electricity market, COM(2006) 841 final, p. 2. 24 Directive 96/92/EC concerning common rules of the internal market in electricity was adopted by the Council of Ministers on 19 December 1996. It entered into force 2 months later on 19 February 1997.
112
Competitive Electricity Markets
These requirements, which essentially imposed reducing size bands for “eligible” customers (those that were able to choose supplier), opened up the non-domestic retail markets. The commission also concentrated on establishing minimal requirements for unbundling of generation and transmission, and contemplated standardization of approaches to network access and its regulation.25 This emphasis on providing access to the market dominated over issues of restructuring generation and supply and market design. The commission’s leadership of the implementation process has primarily been through the Florence Forum, which first met in February 1998 and typically meets annually (curiously now in Rome), and its various sub-groups. The 13th full meeting took place in September 2006.26 Over recent years the forum has provided a focus for direction of ETSO’s deliberations and liaison with national regulators, and it has also stimulated the formation of the pan-European energy regulators’ group, the Council of European Energy Regulators (CEER). Limited progress toward the objective of an internal market without barriers has already been achieved. The deregulation timetable – that for permitting competition for customers – has tended to be the political focus, but national diversity has continued to be a strong characteristic. As one commentator has noted the first directive allowed nearly everything except an integrated internal market.27 However, there have been other important initiatives, which have increasingly been absorbed under the supervision of the forum. For example, from 2002 ETSO introduced a mechanism for cross-border tariffs (CBTs) for transactions between participating member states, and which has now removed specific transmission charges associated with exchanging electricity across most of the internal borders of the EU. In addition, voluntary guidelines for congestion management were agreed at the sixth meeting of the Florence Forum, and these have been partially implemented. Finally, considerable technical work has been carried out in preparation for a more comprehensive integration of markets by ETSO, EuroPEX, EFET, and the UCTE, as well as by the CEER. Many of their detailed initiatives are now reaching more detailed expression through the work program of Ergeg, which is explored below.
EBL
Table 3.5. EU deregulation milestones, 1996–2007 1996
European Council of Energy Ministers and Parliament reached agreement on an electricity market liberalization directive
February 1997
This “Directive concerning common rules for the internal market in electricity” (Directive 96/92EC) took legal effect
February 1999
Directive went into force after a two-year transposition delay
2001
Approval of the “Directive of the European Parliament and the Council on the promotion of electricity from renewable energy sources in the internal electricity market (RES-E directive)”
2003
Approval of the Directive concerning common rules for the internal market in electricity (officially directive 2003/54; usually named “the second directive”)
25
This comprised regulated or negotiated third-party access, but also permitted single buyer models. Florence Forum papers can be found at: http://ec.europa.eu/energy/electricity/florence/index_ en.htm. 27 Lee Hancher, quoted by J-M Glachant (2005). Implementing the European internal energy market in 2005–09, available at www.grjm.net. 26
Achieving Electricity Market Integration in Europe
113
Table 3.5. (Continued) 2004
Extension of the EU 15 to 25 member countries; new member countries to open their market with 30% minimum
2004
Electricity directive 2003/54 due to be transposed by member states All non-domestic customers made eligible in the EU in July 2004 An EU regulation on cross-border electricity trade came into effect (Regulation 1228/2003) in July 2004
2007
Due to Electricity directive 2003/54, 100% market opening in all EU-25 countries in July 2007
The gradual market opening introduced by the first directive resulted in significant differences between member states regarding the level of market opening. By 2003 some alignment had occurred. However, the non-eligible segment of the retail markets remained – and still remains – significant in many markets. The existence of negotiated third-party access regimes, the limited level of functional unbundling obligations, and the lack of any requirement to establish a national energy regulator were also viewed as obstacles. To address these concerns further measures were proposed by the commission leading to the adoption of a second directive. The second electricity directive and an important accompanying regulation on crossborder exchanges were adopted by the Council and Parliament on 16 June 2003.28 Its primary focus was the removal of discrepancies in the level of market opening between member states. Among the measures required by it are market opening (i.e., full retail competition) by July 2007, legal unbundling of functions and the introduction of sectorspecific regulation, and the establishment of national regulators independent from the sectors they regulate in all member states in order to ensure non-discriminatory access to networks through dealing with complaints and controlling network tariffs. National regulators retain a key role in setting up and enforcing most of the aspects of market design, in particular by removing inappropriate local technical and financial impediments. Similarly, legal and functionally independent TSOs will, by providing non-discriminatory access to networks, be responsible for the day-to-day functioning of the electric system. The directive also contemplated specific areas of focus in developing local blueprints to improve market access and functioning. At the same time the existing national regulators recognized the need for close cooperation especially with regard to cross-border trade, and formed CEER as an association for discussion and the development of common positions. The measures by which the success of the second directive is to be judged are set out in its Article 28, paragraph 3. They are:
EBL
• • •
the existence of non-discriminatory network access; effective regulation; the development of interconnection infrastructure and the security of supply situation; • the extent to which markets are open to effective competition; 28
The Electricity directive 2003/54/EC is the key European legislation to establish the internal market of electricity. The directive had to be implemented by the member states by 1 July 2004.
114
Competitive Electricity Markets
•
the extent to which the full benefits of market opening are accruing to small enterprises and households, “notably with respect to public service and universal service standards”; • the extent to which customers are actually switching suppliers; • price developments; and • independence of TSOs. As such the criteria apply a framework that mixes political, regulatory, operation, and trading considerations. Subsequently, the regulation on cross-border electricity exchanges29 was introduced to implement aspects of the second directive, and it aims to foster cross-border trade by allowing the commission, working within a “comitology”30 procedure, to adopt three binding guidelines: the allocation of cross-border electricity interconnector capacity (i.e., congestion management), harmonization of transmission tariffs, and compensation for TSOs for hosting transmission flows originating in other TSOs’ areas. Accordingly, the regulation allows for the adoption of specific binding guidelines for cross-border transactions. It allows the development of harmonized conditions of access to the European network for those wishing to buy or sell (or trade) electricity. It is intended to lead to cost-reflective charges for the use of European transmission networks, the removal of other distortions of cross-border trade, and the operation of the transmission system, in particular congestion management, to promote fair competition and economic efficiency. The second directive represents a much more prescriptive and coherent attempt to stimulate progress toward a single electricity market through a top-down approach. However, it quickly became evident to the commission that the problems inherent in moving from theory to practice were no fewer with the second directive than the first, and that important gaps remained.
EBL
3.3.2. Regional harmonization A 2004 report31 from the commission assessed and commented on progress in a number of aspects of harmonization, and produced a less than healthy prognosis of progress with implementation. This commentary raised issues concerning the appropriate way of judging progress and indeed how success or failure is to be assessed. The 2005 benchmarking report, the most recent, also hinted that a different approach was needed: The most important persisting shortcoming is the lack of integration between national markets. Key indicators in this respect are the absence of price convergence across the EU and the low level of cross-border trade. This is generally due to the existence of barriers to entry, inadequate use of existing infrastructure and – in the case of electricity – insufficient interconnection between many member states, leading to 29
Regulation 1228/2003, dated 15 July 2003. http://eur-lex.europa.eu/smartapi/cgi/sga_doc?smartapi! elexdoc!prod!CELEXnumdoc&lg=EN&numdoc=32003R1228&model=guicheti 30 That is, the commission may only amend the guidelines following approval by a committee of member state representatives. 31 2004 Report of the Commission on Implementation of the Gas and Electricity Internal Market, at http://ec.europa.eu/energy/electricity/publications/doc/2004_07_09_memo_en.pdf
Achieving Electricity Market Integration in Europe
115
congestion. Moreover, many national markets display a high degree of concentration of the industry, impeding the development of effective competition.32 Furthermore, the report continues, “it must be recalled that the objective of opening the market is to create a single electricity and gas market, not a juxtaposition of 25 national markets. This is a challenging task and integration of all national markets will not happen overnight. At the moment the degree of market integration remains insufficient.” To address problems of this nature, the commission set out a statement of the vision and process for the creation of a single electricity market in its March 2004 strategy paper Medium-term Vision for the Internal Electricity Market.33 This important statement anticipates for the first time the integrated single market being reached via the interim step of the establishment and development of a number of regional markets. In turn the commission’s more limited focus at least over the near term was that more compatible arrangements even if applied locally could lead to the application of similar rules for market players regionally and hence promote efficient trade. In other words there was an acceptance that the objective of a single harmonized energy market cannot be achieved even if (big if) all member states were to implement the relevant legislation. The overall goal of the EU vision remains the same – for the market to function as a single market – but the means to this end is somewhat different. Eventually, all TSOs should use to the greatest extent possible the same mechanisms and approaches to manage their networks, and network users should face a single, consistent interface. Thus, over the longer term, the commission still believes a pan-European tarification mechanism may contribute to the further integration of markets. For the foreseeable future, however, the “vision” paper outlined an approach whereby tariffs for cross-border trade are a combination of different national tariff schemes and where TSOs are compensated for transit and/or other costs and inducing flows is the “most sensible” way forward. For congestion management and system operation more generally, it considers that methods for allocating capacity should be market-based and designed to give correct locational signals to producers and consumers. This approach should help regulators and participants to identify appropriate interconnection projects, depending on the volatility of the signals. Congestion management methods should also be non-discriminatory so that all participants should have an equal chance of obtaining capacity for both long-term and short-term transactions. There should also be an automatically functioning use-it-or-lose-it rule, with mechanisms for reallocation in the event of unused access rights. These objectives imply coordination of the congestion management process with that of short-term energy trading, including the intraday and balancing markets, as well as ancillary services. Finally, such harmonization efforts imply a review of network security rules, grid codes, and access and tariff methodologies, such that trade within a region is no more difficult than trade within a TSO control area. The commission goes on to say it believes that difference of treatment between internal and cross-border congestions was an essential flaw of the Californian market model and that this characteristic is potentially present in some regional European markets. It believes this issue can ultimately be solved by adoption
EBL
32
http://ec.europa.eu/energy/electricity/report_2005/doc/2005_report_en.pdf. The commission issued benchmarking reports in 2001, 2003, 2004, and 2005. A 2006 report is listed on the commission’s website but this is in fact the energy sector package issued in January 2007, which is covered in more detail below. 33 http://ec.europa.eu/energy/electricity/florence/doc/florence_10/strategy_paper/strategy_paper_ march_2004.pdf.
Competitive Electricity Markets
116
of a nodal pricing model coupled with financial transmission rights, as proposed by the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission’s (FERC) Standard Market Design or competing models. According to the 2004 vision paper, the following specific objectives are to be pursued. In the medium term: • • • •
• •
ITC should be allowed for suitable compensation between member states for, as a minimum, transit flows and other cross-border flows in some cases; transmission charges on generators should be harmonized within a fairly narrow range with, if appropriate, some locational signals introduced at the EU level; interconnection capacity should be allocated by non-discriminatory, market-based mechanisms consisting of either; within regional markets, there should be a single common coordinated market-based mechanism that allows for both “market coupling” encompassing existing dayahead and possibly intraday spot markets via the adoption of a common timetable, as well as long-term financial hedging; between regional markets, there should be specific market-based mechanisms that, as far as possible, allow for coupling of wholesale markets; and there should be a high degree of transparency to network users, including the publication of necessary data relating to transport capabilities of interconnector lines.
In the longer term: •
there should be both tariffs and ITC based on a single common model of the European network with, ultimately, zone-based transmission charges at the EU level covering, as a minimum, losses, and also potentially fixed investment costs; and • there should be regional market areas served by a single wholesale market (allowing both day-ahead and within-day nomination), which would contain different price areas in the case of persistent congestion.
EBL
In addition to this shopping list the commission called for the following: •
• • •
•
•
transparency, with network users having access to harmonized information on both the transmission networks and the behavior of producers and consumers in the electricity market; mechanisms to allocate capacity designed to avoid manipulation by, and/or collusion of, those generators with a dominant position in certain regions; effective monitoring of market behavior; where congestion management is based on short-term wholesale markets, participants should also have the scope to make longer-term arrangements to obtain financial certainty for longer-term contracts through the use of hedging instruments; system operation between national markets should be fully coordinated, and crossborder capacity should be increased through re-dispatching within the national network and through the separation of national markets into different prices areas; and use should be made of revenues from congestion or any other constraint resolution scheme, and these should be clearly regulated and audited, and preferably used for the removal of congestion.
To date a number of key milestones have been achieved or are proposed consistent with this blueprint outlined in Box 3.3.
Achieving Electricity Market Integration in Europe
Box 3.3 Commission medium-term vision – Key milestones Achieved milestones have been: 2004 •
entry into force of the cross-border trade regulation, adoption of first set of guidelines, for entry into force on 1 January 2005 including; • a pilot project on co-ordinated congestion management in the “West European market region” was undertaken. 2005 • • •
agreed methodology for inter-TSO compensation came into force; agreed rules for initial harmonization of transmission tariffs were adopted; there was introduction of congestion management based on non-discriminatory and coordinated market-based mechanisms for all congested interconnectors; • UCTE handbook providing core common parameters for system operations became legally binding; • TSOs were required to provide an audited report on amount and use of congestion proceeds and reconciliation; • TSO unbundled accounts implemented.
EBL
2006 •
market participants in all member states gained access to a relevant functioning power exchange by this date; • congestion management methods coordinated between member states for market coupling by the power exchanges concerned within regional market areas enabled; • feasibility study on integration of balancing mechanisms initiated. Looking forward, further, key targets are: 2008 • • •
review of inter-TSO compensation mechanism; possible introduction of locational signals for generation at European level; introduction of regionalized wholesale markets.
2008–10 •
integration of intra-day and balancing markets.
2010 onwards •
progressive integration of all regional groupings.
117
118
Competitive Electricity Markets
3.3.2.1. Ergeg In the absence of sufficient progress toward a single electricity market, the commission and the national regulators are looking to consolidate best practices and pursue a more devolved path to an integrated market. In defining this process it has set out a much more involved role for the regulators. Consequently, an intermediate solution – and an essential transitional step – is to regionally organize physical balancing and market rules across control zones by 2010. Thereafter the aim will be to integrate regional groupings beyond that date. To this end a series of regional initiatives are being supported by the commission. To bring better engagement in the process from national regulators, the commission has explicitly tied them into the process. The European Regulators’ Group for Electricity and Gas (Ergeg), which the commission set up on 11 November 2003 by Decision 2003/796/EC, is an advisory group of independent national regulatory authorities established to assist it in consolidating the internal market for electricity and gas. Its members are the heads of the national energy regulators in the member states. There is considerable overlap with the work and membership of CEER, but Ergeg has a specific mandate to advise the commission and is formally constituted under community law.34 Ergeg’s work is led by three focus groups, dealing separately with electricity, gas, and transparency. The Electricity Focus Group is developing views and policies on priority topics. The focus group has taken as its broad agenda the provisions of regulation 1228/2003. The commission in 2004 asked Ergeg to consider these topics and advise it concerning texts for the three guidelines envisaged by the regulation. To do this, it set up three task forces under the auspices of the Electricity Focus Group. They are: •
EBL
System Operation Task Force – this deals with security and reliability issues, guidelines on good practice for electricity balancing markets integration, the congestion management guidelines, firm transmission access rights, and coordination between TSOs; • Cross-border Trade Task Force – this leads work associated with transmission tariff harmonization and guidelines for a longer-term ITC mechanism; and • Regional Electricity Markets Task Force – Ergeg’s launch of the Electricity Regional Initiative (ERI) in spring 2006 and its monitoring and reporting is a key part of the Ergeg’s work program, as we explain in Section 3.4. This task force manages this workstream. Key issues within its locus are reviewing how national legal and commercial conditions for cross-border electricity trade can create barriers to crossborder trade and the framework for cross-border transmission investment. Much of the work of the first two groups has developed out of pre-existing initiatives led by ETSO and the commission, though the regional initiative is wholly new (Box 3.3). 3.3.2.2. Electricity regional initiatives Following the 2005 public consultation The Creation of Regional Electricity Markets, which reiterated support for a regional approach to market integration35 and made a concerted 34 Ergeg and CEER have no formal powers, and the commission has been trying to establish a single national regulator for wholesale electricity trades between states, closer to the US model of FERC. To date, member states have been largely unenthusiastic about this direction. 35 www.ergeg.org/portal/page/portal/ERGEG_HOME/ERGEG_DOCS/ERGEG_DOCUMENTS_ NEW/ELECTRICITY_FOCUS_GROUP/ERGEG_CREATION_OF_REM_%20DISCUSSIONPAPER_ PUBLICCONSULT.PDF
Achieving Electricity Market Integration in Europe
119
Fig. 3.5. Regional electricity markets. Source: Ergeg 2006.
call at the 12th Florence Forum in September 2005, Ergeg announced a major EU-wide initiative of electricity Regional Energy Markets (REMs) in Spring 2006. The workstream was launched with the publication of its conclusions paper, which confirmed action areas and set out a proposal for the ERI.36 It created seven electricity regions as an interim step (the first of many) toward a fully functioning single electricity market, as illustrated in Fig. 3.5. Each region is tasked with identifying and seeking to remove the barriers to competition in its region and report, via Ergeg, to the commission and the Florence Forum. Each regional initiative is intended to bring together regulators, companies, governments, the commission, and other interested parties. The seven regions, some of which overlap, will have similar aims “but reflect the very different concerns and level of progress so far achieved in each region.” The process was initiated through a series of mini-fora in spring 2006, which brought together local players under the aegis of the participating national regulators and TSOs. The common task set for the seven groups include:
EBL
• • •
establishing of functioning regional markets; identifying and publishing of priority areas; establishing and publishing an action timetable; identifying who should take action; and • monitoring and fostering progress. In establishing priority topics a number of common themes have emerged from the regional groupings, including: • •
36
congestion management; interconnections;
www.ergeg.org/portal/page/portal/ERGEG_HOME/ERGEG_DOCS/ERGEG_DOCUMENTS_ NEW/ELECTRICITY_FOCUS_GROUP/ERGEG_REMCREATION-CONCLUSIONS_2006-02-08.PDF. There is a parallel workstream for regional gas markets, which was launched in April 2006, and is based round three regional groupings.
Competitive Electricity Markets
120 • •
balancing; and regulatory interfaces.
The initial focus of the project is to map out action plans and timetables, and effort is then to be directed at tackling the first priority topics. The next step will be for the regional workstreams to identify a second raft of priority topics. An overall monitoring process overseen by Ergeg is intended to ensure that progress toward a single energy market is not hampered by the regional initiatives, and that each regional initiative is producing proposals and solutions that are compatible with each other. Given the overall goal of a single market for electricity, Ergeg will therefore retain a strong role in overseeing and comparing progress in each of the regional initiatives. Ergeg will for example ensure the cooperation, coherence and compatibility of relevant developments among the different initiatives, relying on Ergeg regular work and procedures as well as on any necessary dedicated tasks.37 There is also a Regional Co-ordination Committee, together with the Implementation and Stakeholder Groups. The TSOs are integral to this initiative and its prospects for success. A lead regulator has been appointed for each REM to chair and coordinate work within the region. Ergeg will report at meetings of the Florence Forum on progress. Each REM must also provide quarterly reports “about measurable results and progress,” 38 primarily as an internal monitoring tool, “to illustrate that the ERI is producing concrete results and delivering on the expectations raised.” The reports are to be accompanied by quarterly
EBL
FLORENCE FORUM EU Commission
Overall forum for discussing progress in progressing regional initiatives and panEuropean consistency
ERGEG
MEMBER STATES
established Regional Co-ordination Committees (RCCs). Each RCC: – comprises regulators from the region; – has autonomy, & adopts its own decision making process; & chairs minifora
IMPLEMENTATION GROUP Includes TSOs, Market Operators (where appropriate) This is the ‘do-er’ for each Regional Initiative Chaired by RCC
Input into identifying and solving market integration issues – e.g. legislative proposals, Member State to Member State interface
STAKEHOLDER GROUP (Based on mini-fora) Wide participation including market players Each mini-fora chaired by RCC and used for consultation
Fig. 3.6. Regional initiatives project structure. Source: Ergeg 2007 work plan.
37
Link as above, p. 39. www.ergeg.org/portal/page/portal/ERGEG_HOME/ERGEG_DOCS/ERGEG_WORK_ PROGRAMME/C06-WPDC-06-04_CEER-ERGEG_WP2007_Public.pdf 38
Achieving Electricity Market Integration in Europe
121
workshops. These reports will be used in turn to produce an annual report, submitted which was39 to the 14th Florence Forum scheduled for September 2007. They will also be used to produce a “convergence and coherence” review report, an initial assessment of the seven REMs, also for discussion at Florence. Based on these outputs the Electricity Task Force will then begin work on a further strategic vision paper, outlining its view on the features that a single market will need to have, plus a road map on how to proceed from REMs to “a true single market.” Ergeg hopes to finalize this paper during 2008. The structure for rollout of the regional initiatives is shown in Fig. 3.6. Section 3.4 will review the main features of this diagram in more detail. 3.4. Removing Barriers to Market Harmonization This section considers various European-level initiatives that have occurred to stimulate cross-border trade and to help move toward the single electricity market. In several instances the work programs were initiated stimulated by the TSOs acting jointly through ETSO, but over recent years the commission has taken over leadership. The reporting mechanism through the Florence Forum has remained a key means of achieving sign-off of policy development and its outcomes. More recently the national regulators have begun to take ownership of some workstreams and develop their own complementary streams. Eight specific areas of work are described in this section: • • • • • • • •
managing system-to-system costs; transmission constraints; transmission tarification; cross-border investment framework; balancing management; information transparency and management; regulatory independence and powers; and functional unbundling.
EBL
While these are the main workstreams they are not the only ones.40 Further, each area is tending to converge and integrate with the regional initiatives. The section also briefly reviews the main points from the energy sector review initiated in 2005, which reported in January 2007, in so far as it addresses impediments to market harmonization. 3.4.1. Managing system-to-system costs The tarification of cross-border network access between member states has been on the priority list for consideration since liberalization commenced at the EU level in 1996 and has been an active area of focus since 2001, when ETSO published proposals for a temporary CBT. A workstream under the auspices of the commission evolved from this, and a task force was organized and assigned with identifying an ITC mechanism. 39
http://ec.europa.eu/energy/electricity/florence/doc/florence_14/ergeg_eri_r.pdf Under the aegis of Ergeg further streams have recently been initiated for electricity on technical issues such as voltage quality and retail competition issues on best practice propositions dealing with customer protection, the supplier switching process, and transparency of prices. 40
122
Competitive Electricity Markets
This is a key mechanism to enable elimination to barriers to trading as the intention is that exchanges across-borders should be treated as far as possible free of barriers when compared to trade within borders, but recognizing that cross-border flows do affect neighboring networks and create costs. “The ITC mechanism is designed to deal with the costs associated with this effect and compensate network owners. By identifying the cost TSOs incur due to cross-border PX, and by compensating them, the ITC mechanism allows trade to function as if there were no such cost.”41 Since 2002 ETSO members have used a temporary system to address the costs of hosting cross-border flows. Initially the focus was on designing an ITC mechanism, and how the mechanism implemented in 2002 should work. ETSO has developed a model to define the horizontal network of each country. The costs associated with transits (including network losses) on the identified assets are determined, and the level of ITC is then calculated with appropriate funding set aside into a reserve fund.42 In 2006 the fund was E395 mn. Settlement payments are initially calculated using prior year data but then adjusted for actual power flows. More recently the development has concentrated on enlarging the area of countries among which ITC payments are made43 under the joint mechanism and on the structure of payments. To date the methodology used to determine the amount of payments has changed little even though the mechanism has been regarded as a preliminary solution.44 This system has now been in use for 4 years. The Ergeg Regional Electricity Markets Task Force has been working with the commission and ETSO and aimed to have a longerterm ITC mechanism in place for 2007. However agreement was not forthcoming, and a further temporary scheme was agreed and implemented in June 2007, and this will run to the end of the year. ETSO announced in December 2006 that no voluntary agreement could be reached so far for a new ITC mechanism. A rollover of the prevailing mechanism to end-January 2007 was instead agreed, with the possibility to extend it beyond that if agreement remained elusive.
EBL
3.4.2. Managing transmission constraints The Florence Forum agreed at its fifth meeting in March 2000 that it was important that congestion management within the union be based on market solutions, which give “proper and justified incentives to both market parties and TSOs to act in a rational and economic way.” Further work led to an initial set of guidelines for congestion management being set out in the conclusions of the sixth meeting in November 2000. These guidelines emphasized the need for TSOs to set out in a transparent manner the congestion management methods in use, and for TSOs to maximize the available interconnector capacity. They were not legally binding. In 2002 reports on congestion management were produced by, among others, the CEER and the commission, which noted progress but concluded that further work was required. ETSO’s work program on congestion management effectively started in 2001. A position paper was put to the Florence Forum meeting in that year45 , and the organization also 41
http://ec.europa.eu/energy/electricity/publications/doc/2006_03_tso_compensation_mechanism. pdf 42 www.etso-net.org/upload/documents/ETSO%20porposal%20for%202006%20CBT.pdf 43 Britain and the two Irish jurisdictions still do not participate. 44 The only substantive change made to date has been the abandonment of an export fee in 2005. 45 www.etso-net.org/upload/documents/Position_Paper_on_Congestion_Management.pdf
Achieving Electricity Market Integration in Europe
123
considered how it should evaluate congestion management methods46 recognizing in its conclusions that a mix of methods may be appropriate across the union. The commission then published a communication, which called upon ETSO (with others) to develop the guidelines further and to propose common standards on “soft measures” to increase cross-border transmission capacity.47 This request led to a vision paper circulated in April 200248 and development of an outline of a coordinated congestion management scheme in September that year.49 A methodology for defining and quantifying transfer capacity definition was subsequently agreed in June 2004.50 ETSO also developed its own position based on flow-based market coupling51 , and it began to address the development of transmission risk-hedging products52 . The Directive 1228/2003 specifically addressed the need to stimulate convergence among member states in the area of congestion management. General principles are set out in Article 6. Congestion problems must, for example, be solved using market-based solutions that give efficient economic signals. The supporting regulation allows the commission working within a comitology53 process to set binding guidelines on congestion management. The adopted version of the regulation already contained draft guidelines that cover some general aspects of congestion management and allocation of available transfer capacity of interconnections between national systems. It was intended that these be refined by regulators and the commission following consultation. Subsequently Ergeg has taken up the development process, and it issued reworked draft congestion management guidelines in September 2004. and a revised set in 200554 . These entered the comitology process later that year. The cross-border electricity committee gave a positive opinion on the guidelines in June 2006, and the European Parliament then had the right of scrutiny until end-September. Since 1 January 2007 the guidelines55 require use of a common flow-based network model, application of a market-based allocation system for securing rights on transmission capacity, and the use of common products (including conditions, timeframes). The commission in parallel is also scrutinizing some existing long-term priority reservations. A number have already been cancelled, and others are likely to be subject to infringement proceedings.
EBL
46
www.etso-net.org/upload/documents/Evaluation_of_Congestion_Management_Methods_for_ Cross-Border_Transmission_(Florence).pdf 47 European Energy Infrastructure, Communication from the Commission to the Council and the European Parliament, January 2001. 48 www.etso-net.org/upload/documents/ETSO%20Vision%20on%20CCM.pdf 49 www.etso-net.org/upload/documents/Outline%20Proposals%20for%20CCM5.pdf 50 www.etso-net.org/upload/documents/Transfer%20Capacity%20Definitions%20-%20Final.pdf 51 www.etso-net.org/upload/documents/ETSO-EuroPEX_Interimreport_Sept-2004-.pdf 52 www.etso-net.org/upload/documents/Short%20ETSO%20Risk%20hedging%20in%20CM_final%20 PUBLIC.pdf 53 That is, the commission may only amend the guidelines following approval by a committee of member state representatives. [Moved] 54 www.ergeg.org/portal/page/portal/ERGEG_HOME/ERGEG_PC/ARCHIVE1/CM_GL/ERGEG_ AMENDMENTS_GUIDELINES_CM_PUBLIC_CONSULTATION_20050.PDF 55 http://ec.europa.eu/energy/electricity/florence/doc/florence_13/cm_guidelines.pdf
124
Competitive Electricity Markets
3.4.3. Transmission tariff harmonization Progress in this area has also been intermittent. At the fifth meeting of the Florence Forum in March 2000 parties stressed the importance of making progress in harmonizing the split of transmission charges between generation and load across member states. ETSO initially brought some focus in 2002 when it formed a task force to consider transmission tarification methodologies and charges across member states, and it issued a benchmarking study based on 2002 tariffs of 12 member states56 and again in 2005 based on 2004 tariffs of 19 member states.57 A legal basis for dealing with the issue came with the adoption in June 2003 of Regulation 1228/2003. In particular: •
Article 8(3) provided for guidelines to be adopted to “determine appropriate rules leading to a progressive harmonisation of the underlying principles for the setting of charges applied to producers and consumers (load) under national tariff systems, including the reflection of the ITC mechanism in national network charges and the provision of appropriate and efficient locational signals, in accordance with the principles set out in Article 4”; • Article 4 discusses the requirements relating to transmission tariffs. In particular, Article 4(2) states that “where appropriate, the level of the tariffs applied to producers and/or consumers shall provide locational signals at European level, and take into account the amount of network losses and congestion caused, and investment costs for infrastructure”; and • Article 4(4) requires that providing that appropriate and efficient locational signals are in place, charges for access to networks applied to producers and consumers shall be applied regardless of the countries of destination and origin, respectively, of the electricity, as specified in the underlying commercial arrangement.
EBL
The Regulation allows the commission, again working within a comitology process, to set binding guidelines. In June 2003, the commission produced a discussion document on harmonization of network access charges.58 This consultation provided the first basis for discussion of form and content of guidelines. The subject was discussed further during the 10th Florence Forum of July 2003, and the commission issued draft guidelines in March 2004. Subsequently Ergeg and the commission have worked together to produce a refined text, which was presented to the 11th meeting of the Florence Forum in September 2004. Ergeg further worked up the text, and it formally consulted on this in May 2005.59 It then gave its advice to the commission on tarification guidelines in July 2005. The objective of the proposed guidelines was the first step to harmonize charges paid by generation. The commission formally put a proposal on tariff guidelines to the comitology procedure in July 2006. Ergeg approved this in December 2006, and also stated that it considered that there was a need for widening the tariff harmonization to lower voltage levels. It also approved the details for calculating and reporting of transmission tariff levels under the 56
www.etso-net.org/upload/documents/Benchmarking.pdf www.etso-net.org/upload/documents/08-04-05%20Synthesis%202004%20FINAL%20%20.pdf 58 www.europa.eu.int/comm/energy/electricity/florence/doc/florence_10/g_and_l/ec_g_ harmonization.pdf 59 www.ergeg.org/portal/page/portal/ERGEG_HOME/ERGEG_PC/ARCHIVE1/TT_GL/ INTRODUCTORY_NOTE_ERGEG_AMENDMENTS_GUIDELINES_TARIFICATI.PDF 57
Achieving Electricity Market Integration in Europe
125
proposed tarification guidelines. The intention was that the guideline will come into force at the same point as the ITC guidelines. Ergeg was preparing the first report on transmission charging structure and generator values during the first half of 2007. Furthermore, it continues to address the issue of tariff harmonization in its work program for 2007, as part of which more studies on the transmission tariff structures and further harmonization are planned. 3.4.4. Cross-border interconnector framework Cross-border investment has also been part of a wider series of initiatives by the commission. They were emphasized in the Green Paper, a European Strategy for Sustainable, Competitive and Secure Energy,60 in which the commission noted there that “there is an urgent need for investment” in electricity sector infrastructure, especially interconnection between states. It also stated that private and public investments in infrastructure needed to be stimulated, and called for authorization procedures to be accelerated. Consequently it committed to identify by end-2006 individual measures that it considered important at the member state level. Further, in order to promote EU single internal markets and to foster economic and social cohesion, the treaty establishing the union also provides a legal basis for the further development of Trans-European Networks (TENs), including those for electricity. This development includes the interconnection and interoperability of national transmission networks, as well as access to such networks.61 In January 2006 Directive 89/200562 concerning measures to safeguard security of electricity supply and infrastructure investment was adopted. Among other things, the directive establishes measures aimed at ensuring an appropriate level of interconnection between member states for the development of the internal market. Measures also include provisions related to ensuring operational network security and appropriate network investment, taking into account relevant market actors and TSOs. In addition, member states are also permitted to require TSOs to provide information on investments related to the building of internal lines that materially affect the provision of cross- border interconnection. In support of these initiatives and also of the implementation of the 2003 regulation, Ergeg’s June 2005 public consultation paper The Creation of Regional Electricity Markets re-emphasized cross-border investment as a priority issue for development, and it included the matter in its work program for 2006. The consultation was also partly informed by two papers from ETSO on cross-border investment.63 Ergeg subsequently launched a public consultation on the cross-border framework for transmission investment in October 2006.64 This paper set out views of an Ergeg expert group on the issues, in particular the process
EBL
60
http://europa.eu/scadplus/leg/en/lvb/l27062.htm Accordingly, the European Union provides some finance under the remit of TENs for some electricity and gas transmission infrastructure projects of European interest. A yearly budget of about E25 mn is spent mainly for supporting feasibility studies. Guidelines on TENs specify which projects are eligible for funding. Financial rules specify the financial procedures involved. 62 http://eur-lex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/site/en/oj/2006/l_033/l_03320060204en00220027.pdf. The directive has to be implemented by 24 February 2008. 63 Roles and Responsibilities of TSOs and other Actors in Cross-border Network Investment and Overview of Procedures for Building 110 kV to 400 kV lines, which both called for the expedition of planning processes. 64 www.ergeg.org/portal/page/portal/ERGEG_HOME/ERGEG_PC/Cross%20Border%20 Framework/ERGEG_CrossBorderFramework_PC_2006-10-04.doc 61
126
Competitive Electricity Markets
for obtaining building and construction authorizations and permissions for transmission network infrastructure, which “needs to be recognized and tackled.” At present provision of transmission network infrastructure is largely driven by national law and requirements and “the obligations on authorities or TSOs seldom or insufficiently extend to cross-border infrastructure or the need to integrate markets.” The paper makes recommendations regarding an appropriate framework for the provision of cross-border transmission infrastructure. In particular Ergeg called for: •
extensions to planning and operation standards on TSOs to include cross-border obligations; • adjustment of regulators’ duties and competences to include some cross-border or regional elements; • reorientation of the role of TSOs in order that they act collectively, subject to regulators; and • views on the feasibility of a merchant model for development of new interconnectors and its regulatory treatment. In support of this effort ETSO has established a public database on interconnections between participating countries. In addition to physical details and scheduled outage data, there is also data on allocation mechanisms and results of their application. It is also being expanded to include common data on grid availability as well as national load and generation data. As ETSO makes clear, “The responsibility for data edition, checking and publication is clearly on individual TSOs. For many legal and organisational reasons, ETSO cannot act in their name. But ETSO may make the information access easier. It can also allow a quick overview of what is available, and of the reasons why a piece of information may not be available in a given area.”65 In support of its work in this area and to increase market transparency ETSO has also recently launched its “ETSO-vista platform,” which sets out hourly power flows between national markets.
EBL
3.4.5. Balancing services ETSO has initiated a process that is leading to scoping the issues associated with balance management and enabling cooperation between national operators and markets. As a first step in December 2003 it formed a task force that produced a report intended to increase understanding of prevailing current approaches to balance management, which it described as “the management processes and services associated with power system operation, which ensure quality and short-term security of supply (but in particular focusing on active power (MW) balancing and frequency control.”66 The report observed that there are a number of fundamental physical differences between transmission systems across Europe, and these affect the way in which balance management is approached currently (and could be approached in the future). These differences include the size and inertia of the system, AC or DC interconnection, availability of secondary control, and type of generating plant connected. A key conclusion of the task force was that different national labels concealed the procurement and application of essentially the same services and products. The survey 65 66
www.etso-net.org/MarketInfo/marketdata/e_default.asp www.etso-net.org/upload/documents/BalanceManagemeninEurope.pdf
Achieving Electricity Market Integration in Europe
127
identified a number of common features, but there were a variety of ways of paying for services. The scope of reserves available to TSOs is varied and wide. The limits imposed on the TSO in terms of dispatching reserve in a balancing mechanism also vary. All reserves and energy balancing services are procured on a commercial basis. The payment mechanism for such services tended to be based upon a utilization payment for energy and an availability payment based on capacity, of which there are different types depending on contractual arrangements and the type of service. Primary control reserves for the individual groups UCTE, Nordel, and England and Wales and Scotland are generally shared between TSOs based upon relative annual consumption or generation. Secondary control only applies to countries in UCTE, and the TSO responsible for managing a control block coordinates the control area TSOs in that block. A number of different arrangements were described for gate closure (when expected physical notifications become firm). In some countries this is day-ahead, some are fixed windows in the operational day and some are based upon a rolling settlement period basis. There are a range of times between gate closure and real time in use, including 1 minute, 1 hour, 3 hours, and day-ahead. Calling services via a balancing mechanism gives rise to two common types of pricing. These are either “pay as bid” (most countries) or marginal pricing (the Netherlands, Sweden, Norway, Finland, Spain, and Greece). In November 2005 ETSO produced a further report, which explored the prospects for establishing or increasing cross-border trading of balancing services, and which examined the commercial market design and relevant technical issues associated with facilitating an increase in such activity. “The potential benefits of increasing opportunities for TSO balancing activities across-borders relate primarily to the procurement of balancing services in an efficient manner by the possibility of using internal and external reserve resources in a competitive environment across a wider area,” the report noted, adding “this is likely to have associated benefits in relation to plant loading efficiency (with associated environmental benefit) and a decrease in balancing costs, which are ultimately borne by consumers.”67 The task force went on to develop two generic models that describe how trading of balancing services across borders could be realized, including the principles of the models, covering the roles and responsibilities of each participant. The two conceptual models that have been developed are: (i) reserve provider to TSO trading and (ii) TSO to TSO trading. It also addressed how the models function in practice based on case studies and documented the issues associated with each of them. However, the task force emphasized that it is not intending to restrict possible solutions to these two models. A third report was issued in May 2006.68 It examined the commercial market design and relevant technical issues, including security of supply, associated with facilitating an increase in cross-border trading of tertiary (i.e., manually instructed) reserves for system balancing purposes. More specifically, ETSO’s objective in this work stream was “to analyse the consequences of steps in the integration of these markets if the differences (or incompatibilities) in balancing mechanisms are kept, in order to identify measures needed to allow these integration steps.” It examined the potential benefits of increasing opportunities for TSO balancing activities across borders “relating especially to the procurement
EBL
67 www.etso-net.org/upload/documents/Report%20BMnov2005.pdf. The report went on to note: “The issues and potential benefits are similar to those that could result from increased facilitation of energy trading between markets, particularly in respect of intra-day energy trading. Many of the issues associated with the facilitation of energy trading relate to the harmonisation of market and trading rules across Europe, which will be addressed in later work.” 68 www.etso-net.org/upload/documents/Report%20BM%2018-05-06.pdf
128
Competitive Electricity Markets
of tertiary reserves through use of both internal and external reserve resources in a competitive environment across a wider area, to achieve better plant loading efficiency and a decrease in balancing costs.” The trading of automatically delivered frequency control services (primary and secondary control) was intentionally not considered due to the much more complex nature of these services. Additionally, “it is believed that there is potentially more economic value in developing arrangements related to cross-border trade of tertiary reserves and balancing energy for timeframes between day ahead and some minutes before real time (that is before the action of automatic devices),” the report notes. The analysis examined four models (and several variants) for the procurement and trade of tertiary reserves, the impact of finite cross-border transmission capacity, and the possible need for possible priority rules for these services. It observed that different TSO roles lead to different balancing mechanisms, which use incompatible products, but that differences in gate closure times across balancing markets in Europe do not have a strong impact on the possibility of cross-border balancing services trading, but that differences in bidding rules do. It advocated that differences in regulatory regimes regarding reserve markets should be leveled out to prevent buying out of reserves from areas with a low reserve price. The next assignment for this task force is to develop a balance management reference model that can be a “guideline in the development process towards facilitation of crossborder tertiary reserves trade and regionally integrated balancing mechanisms.” Ergeg has also been developing views on balancing convergence and is developing guidelines on good practice in this area following the presentation to the 12th Florence Forum in September 2005 of its position on balancing mechanisms compatibility. Separately the commission appointed consultants Frontier Economics and Consentec to look at ways in which trade close to real time could be facilitated and to recommend measures that would help to improve the efficiency of cross-border trade “without imposing a disproportionate cost on the systems in question,” which has informed the Ergeg process.69 Following consultation, Ergeg adopted initial advice to the commission on the aspects of electricity balancing markets integration in line with the congestion management guidelines in December 2006,70 and which constitutes its initial advice to the commission on electricity balancing markets integration as required by the 2003 regulation. Final advice is to be provided to the commission after the development and consideration of the aspects on intraday markets and automatically activated reserves as part of the 2007 work program.
EBL
3.4.6. Market transparency In March 2006 Ergeg launched a public consultation on guidelines for good practice on information management and transparency in electricity markets. These guidelines 69
http://ec.europa.eu/energy/electricity/publications/doc/frontier_consentec_balancing_dec_ 2005.pdf 70 www.ergeg.org/portal/page/portal/ERGEG_HOME/ERGEG_DOCS/ERGEG_DOCUMENTS_ NEW/ELECTRICITY_FOCUS_GROUP/E05-ESO-06-08_GGP-EBMI_2006-12-06.pdf Benefits and Practical Developments of Intraday Electricity Markets and Balancing Mechanisms, December 2005. The report looked at three basic types of integration: linkages of intraday markets (i.e., before either system gate closure); linkages of balancing arrangements after one gate closure; and linkages of balancing arrangements after both gate closures. It concluded that, given that in many cases model 1 may be capable of implementation relatively quickly, a phased approach to the development of final arrangements using model 1 as a transitional step within regional blocks may be worthy of consideration. Such a phased approach may have the advantage that, under model 1, harmonization between balancing regimes is less important – a number of differences can be internalized by the TSOs.
Achieving Electricity Market Integration in Europe
129
seek to establish a consistent approach to the provision of market-related information by wholesale market participants across member states.71 The guidelines set out Ergeg’s views on the minimum required level of transparency across the European market. Moreover, they are intended to give a set of rules required for the organization of information and its dissemination across the markets of common member states. Finally, they define general principles governing information release, either through publication or through information released to market participants on request. Unlike other areas where guidelines are anticipated by the 2003 regulation, this initiative has developed from further thinking by the national regulators themselves. The issue of transparency has been one of increasing concern at Florence Forum meetings, and at the 12th forum a number of stakeholders (including Eurelectric,72 EFET,73 ETSO74 ) stressed the need for greater market transparency. Ergeg said in its consultation that it would “anticipate that regulators, working together with stakeholders, will put in place and monitor functioning of the guidelines to the extent possible. Such work is likely to involve dialogue and discussion with TSOs and market participants. 2007 will therefore be a year of appraisal.”75 In practice other legislative developments are likely to have a bearing on this period of monitoring and appraisal. The final reports were issued in January 2007, and both contained analyses and remedies extending to transparency issues, which are now being assimilated. Market integration through the formation and continuation of the regional initiatives proposed by Ergeg is also likely to raise strongly the issue of transparency, and lead to further development of policy. 3.4.7. Unbundling
EBL
Article 19 of Directive 2003/54/EC set out the legal minimum requirements of accounting unbundling. However, the commission’s 2005 benchmarking report showed that insufficient unbundling was one of the key factors reducing retail competition in many markets. It observed that the development of wholesale markets was impeded by too close a relationship between TSOs and affiliated producers or importers. Ergeg launched a public consultation on guidelines for good practice on regulatory accounts unbundling in April 2006. The guidelines which were issued in April 2007, establish basic principles on regulatory account unbundling, reinforcing the requirements of the second directive, under which by 1 July 2007 distribution network operators with more than 100,000 customers were required to be unbundled in legal terms. The guidelines recognize the importance of TSO independence; separation of distribution and supply businesses; and other separation requirements. The guidelines are directed to regulators, but the group hopes they can also serve as a benchmark for analyzing national unbundling of accounts. The presented guidelines are the first set of unbundling guidelines. Those on informational and management unbundling will be elaborated after more experience is gathered on the actual implementation of the relevant requirements. 71
Information management and transparency for information to retail customers is the subject of separate work being undertaken by Ergeg with the CEER. 72 http://ec.europa.eu/energy/electricity/florence/doc/florence_12/eurelectric_iem.pdf. Eurelectric is a trade association of power utilities. EFET is the European Federation of Energy Traders. 73 http://ec.europa.eu/energy/electricity/florence/doc/florence_12/efet_iem_p.pdf 74 http://ec.europa.eu/energy/electricity/florence/doc/florence_12/etso_iem.pdf 75 www.ergeg.org/portal/page/portal/ERGEG_HOME/ERGEG_PC/ARCHIVE1/GGP_ Transparency/E05-EMK-06-10_GGPa_transparency_info_mgmt_off.pdf
130
Competitive Electricity Markets
The 2005 benchmarking report again highlighted insufficient functional unbundling as “a persistent impediment” to competition in EU electricity and gas markets. Ergeg criticized what it termed the “vague” implementation of the unbundling provisions of existing directives so that when they are transposed into national law they leave a lot of discretion to the integrated companies who “often act without fear of enforcement because of a lack of adequate powers of the regulators.” To address this issue, Ergeg recommended that new legislation is required. Further, the report says regulators need to have the appropriate powers to ensure wholesale and generation market transparency and that information and data held by network operators is either ring-fenced or released to the market in a non-discriminatory manner. It also recommends that regulators monitor and share information with each other on cross-border unbundling arrangements and develop and/or enforce binding guidelines on unbundling where necessary. The sector inquiry has underlined the commission’s concerns in these areas. 3.4.8. Regulatory independence and powers In its 2006 review Ergeg identifies the gaps between what it terms “the reality and the desired set of competencies of regulators,” and makes recommendations on how to close these gaps.76 The report says that while all national regulators are separate from the relevant ministries in charge of electricity, those in Austria, France, Germany, Greece, Italy, and Malta still retain some powers to approve, reject, or amend regulatory decisions. The recommendations were part of a series of reports submitted to the energy commissioner Andries Piebalgs in December, assessing the development of EU energy markets in 2006. Ergeg called for more legislation to provide national regulators with the power to: • •
EBL
facilitate the development of and competition in the internal electricity market; enable them to act jointly to oversee investment in transmission networks to ensure appropriate cross-border transmission capacity; and • enable them to gather and exchange information and pursue monitoring or investigations into activities that occur in one territory that affect markets in another. The assessment also said regulators were concerned of a “real danger” that political declarations of support for regional integration were not being followed through with the necessary action on the ground. “The tendency to put independent regulators under greater political control and protect ‘national champions’ acts against regional integration and the single market objective,” it argued. “Political support to the regional initiatives was also required,” Ergeg added. As far as national markets were concerned, Ergeg said the regulator must be independent of industry and be able to make decisions without government intervention. The regulator must also have a role in advising government on energy markets. In addition, it must have sufficient power to enforce its decisions and apply sanctions and penalties when breaches of market rules occur or there is evidence of discriminatory behavior. The regulator should also be able oversee monopoly network activities. To ensure power markets are “effectively competitive,” the group also said that regulators need to have the power to approve and monitor compliance with market rules for wholesale trading. They should also be able to require market information and data from 76
www.ergeg.org/portal/page/portal/ERGEG_HOME/ERGEG_DOCS/PRESS_RELEASES/PR-0614_ERGEG_AssesmentNatReports_2006-12-08.doc
Achieving Electricity Market Integration in Europe
131
all participants and have the legal right to pass this on to the relevant national and EU competition authorities in the case of an investigation. Further, the regulator should be able to require all participants to publish or make available any information and data in order to improve market transparency and ensure compliance with national and European market rules. Ergeg called for a “flexible legal approach” regarding any new powers for the regulators as a result of its recommendations. These powers, it said, “need to be sufficiently flexible in order to allow regulators scope to make timely and efficient adjustments to the regulatory framework that reflect current and anticipated market developments.” 3.4.9. Energy sector review Notwithstanding the Ergeg process the commission’s language on the health of the liberalized single market has continued to become more strident. “Meaningful competition does not exist in many member states. Often customers do not have any real possibility of opting for an alternative supplier…. In summary, stakeholders do not yet have a high degree of confidence in the internal market.”77 As a consequence of these shortcomings, the commission initiated in 2005 an inquiry for the gas and electricity sectors under competition law. The sector inquiry carried out in conjunction with country reviews conducted by the commission during 2006 was completed in January 2007. It “unearthed a variety of specific examples which demonstrate the shortcomings of the existing regulatory framework.” The focus of these was the predominating vertically integrated structure and the informational and strategic advantages enjoyed by dominant companies, including their continuing ability to exert influence over TSOs where they owned them. More specifically:
EBL
•
• •
•
•
TSOs, especially when vertically integrated, failed to create conditions conducive to liquid competitive markets – for example by maintaining localized separate balancing zones rather than facilitating the integration at national and cross-border level: TSOs have been slow to act to increase cross-border capacity; there is evidence that both TSOs and regulators tend to be over-oriented to shortterm national concerns rather than be proactive in trying to develop integrated markets; on many issues, certain regulators are constrained in their relations with the industry, lacking the appropriate powers and discretion; some regulators are also subject to continuing strong direction from national governments; and concentrated national markets have tended to encourage regulators to introduce intrusive regulation into wholesale and balancing markets, for example, price caps, which are a strong disincentive to invest.
As a result of these widespread shortcomings, incumbent electricity and gas companies largely maintain their dominant positions on “their” national markets. This situation has led, in the commission’s view, many Member States to retain tight control on the electricity and gas prices charged to end-users. Unfortunately this is often a serious constraint on competition. 77
http://eur-lex.europa.eu/smartapi/cgi/sga_doc?smartapi!celexplus!prod!DocNumber&lg=en& type_doc=COMfinal&an_doc=2006&nu_doc=841
132
Competitive Electricity Markets
In response to the inquiry, a number of investigations have been launched against companies in the electricity and gas sectors. The commission has said it also intends to take action to address remaining issues in the following areas: •
Ensuring non-discriminatory access to networks The commission is considering two main avenues for further TSO unbundling measures, with a view to making formal proposals. These are: – fully (ownership) unbundled TSOs: the TSO would both own the transmission assets and operate the network. It would be independently owned, i.e., supply/ generation companies could no longer hold a significant stake in the TSOs; and – separate system operators without ownership unbundling: this solution would require separation of system operation from ownership of the assets. The commission notes that the independent system operator (ISO) model would require detailed regulation and permanent regulatory monitoring, implying clearly that it prefers the independent ownership approach. • Improving regulation of network access at national and EU level The commission came to the conclusion that energy regulators need to be strengthened at the national level and have “the required level of discretion to take decisions on all relevant issues.” The commission said regulators needed strong powers over a number of key areas including: (i) all aspects of third-party access to networks, (ii) balancing mechanisms, (iii) market surveillance of, e.g., PXs, (iv) all cross-border issues, (v) consumer protection including any end-user price controls (vi) information gathering, and (vii) sanctions for non-compliance. It proposed a strengthening of the Directives on this basis. •
EBL
Reducing the scope for unfair competition
In addition to contemplating creation of powers to free up sites for new entrants and to force termination of long-term contracts over-hanging the market, the commission intends to introduce binding guidelines for transparency either through new legislation or by modifying the regulation 1228/2003. The advice of Ergeg will be taken in the first instance. •
Providing a clear framework for investment by further harmonizing TSO activity
A higher level of technical cooperation between TSOs is proposed, including detailed exchange of information, both in terms of long-term network planning and on a real-time operational basis. The commission suggests that it is doubtful whether this can be achieved in the current framework where both TSOs and regulators are inclined or even obliged to follow a national focus. An enhanced level of TSO coordination would require a new legislative framework. Existing associations of TSOs would be granted an institutional role, with formal obligations and objectives being added to their role, The TSO could be required by the commission or the regulators to report on European grid operation and investment, as well as the development of common technical standards for network security. It could also be responsible for monitoring the developments of networks so as to improve the transmission capacities between member states. Efforts should also be made to have a gradual evolution toward regional system operators, and cross-border system operators could be set up. These would be independently owned and would require additional functional unbundling. 3.5. Establishing the “Western” Regional Market This section looks more closely at how the jurisdictions that comprise the Western market for electricity – Britain, France, and Ireland – are tackling convergence through the ERI.
Achieving Electricity Market Integration in Europe
133
By January 2007 this was the only one of the seven electricity regions to have published substantive consultations. 3.5.1. Project overview The France, Ireland, and UK electricity REM is termed UK and Ireland, which is rather misleading as it includes France. France also participates in three other regional initiatives given its pivotal position within the Western European electricity system. To avoid confusion we have termed this strand of the ERI theWestern regional market. Annual electricity consumption in the France, Ireland, and UK electricity REM is about 780 TWh and the region comprises about 30% of the electricity market within the EU. This regional market includes two of the biggest national economies in the union. The broad task of the regional initiative is to achieve greater integration, which will facilitate regional development and accelerate cooperation and coordination at the European level. Following a Stakeholders’ Group meeting on 14 November 2006, workstreams have been established to take forward priority issues. The four regulators are Ofgem (Great Britain), CRE (France), CER (Republic of Ireland), and Ofreg (Northern Ireland). It is led by Ofgem. 3.5.2. Priority issues The regional regulators have published a series of documents and papers on priority issues, some in collaboration with the four TSOs – EirGrid, Réseau de Transport d’Electricité (RTE), National Grid, and System Operator Northern Ireland (SONI). They consider key issues for addressing to create “a balanced market” across the different national trading regimes, being:
EBL
• • • •
compliance with the congestion management guidelines; coordination of interconnector capacity allocation; enhancing reciprocal access to balancing mechanisms; and wholesale market transparency.
The TSOs have written a paper for each of the four priority issues. A cover note accompanies each document in order where relevant to set out the background to the document and to invite comment. The TSO’s first paper, Gap Analysis of Current Compliance with the Congestion Management Guideline,78 concerns an assessment of compliance of present practice on interconnectors with the guideline. The document looks at the impact these guidelines will have on the regional TSOs and the actions they will need to take to fully comply. The TSO’s second paper, Options for Further Development and Coordination of Existing Cross-Border Arrangements,79 builds on the TSO’s first paper and puts forward options for dealing with areas where current congestion management practice in France, the United Kingdom, or Ireland does not meet the requirements of the congestion guideline. It seeks views on what aspects of capacity allocation and coordination require most attention. It 78
www.ergeg.org/portal/page/portal/ERGEG_HOME/ERGEG_RI/ERI/UK_Ireland/Papers%20 and%20Written%20Consultation/20061027_Paper%20_IG2-1CMGuidelineGapanalysis_FINAL.doc 79 www.ergeg.org/portal/page/portal/ERGEG_HOME/ERGEG_RI/ERI/UK_Ireland/Papers%20 and%20Written%20Consultation/20061031_Paper_IG2-2CrossBorderInitiatives_FINAL.doc
134
Competitive Electricity Markets
also considers whether greater use should be made of “use it or lose it” type provisions in conjunction with current interconnector access rights, and whether such mechanisms would facilitate trade. It also explores how intraday trade between national markets can best be facilitated on interconnectors. The group notes that the liberalization of European electricity markets has increased substantially the need for interconnector capacity. It believes greater interconnection is needed to boost competition entailing more efficient use of the existing three regional links (the North–South interconnector in Ireland, the Northern Ireland–Scotland Moyle link, and the Interconnexion France–Angleterre (IFA)). The regulators want better coordination of capacity allocation, particularly for IFA and Moyle. This change will “encourage trade, reflect national market requirements and ensure that market participants can co-ordinate their desire to trade over two or more interconnectors simultaneously.” The TSOs’ third paper, Conceptual Options for achieving Reciprocal Access to Balancing Arrangements across the Region,80 puts forward options for ways in which TSOs and market participants might trade in balancing market services across borders. It looks at current regional TSO mechanisms. Two models are used to show how access may be improved. Both models already exist elsewhere in Europe: the first within the German control block and the second within Nordel. One recommendation here is for further development of intraday arrangements on the IFA. More generally, there is a call for improved balancing activities throughout the whole region and between national markets to increase plant loading efficiency and to reduce balancing costs. The TSOs’ fourth paper, Situation Report on Wholesale Market Transparency,81 makes an assessment of current levels of wholesale market transparency within the territories. It uses the Ergeg draft Guidelines for Good Practice on Information Management and Transparency as an input for this assessment, and seeks views on what issues raised in the guidelines need to be addressed in the region. Regulators have written further papers concerning imbalance pricing, transmission tarification, and efficiency of interconnectors. The regulators’ first paper, Electricity Imbalance Pricing – Comparison of Regimes and Effects across France, GB, Republic of Ireland,82 makes a first assessment of the imbalance rules applying in each territory with a view to understanding if significant differences exist that might tend to affect trading decisions were full reciprocal access to balancing markets to exist. It complements the TSOs’ third paper. It asks whether the paper addresses the correct issues and whether any existing market distortions are properly described. The issue of imbalance energy pricing is studied by way of a comparison of the different regional regimes. Based on various analyses, this document concludes that trade would be more efficient if imbalance pricing rules in adjacent markets were uniform. This situation arises because any differences between territories might affect the “competitive position of market participants, potentially resulting in inefficient trades.”
EBL
80
www.ergeg.org/portal/page/portal/ERGEG_HOME/ERGEG_RI/ERI/UK_Ireland/Papers%20 and%20Written%20Consultation/20061027_Paper_IG2-3%20Balancing_FINAL.doc 81 www.ergeg.org/portal/page/portal/ERGEG_HOME/ERGEG_RI/ERI/UK_Ireland/Papers%20 and%20Written%20Consultation/03112006_Paper%20IG2-4_RTE_Transparency.pdf 82 www.ergeg.org/portal/page/portal/ERGEG_HOME/ERGEG_RI/ERI/UK_Ireland/Papers%20 and%20Written%20Consultation/20061101_Paper_IG2-5%20Imbalance%20Pricing_FINAL_.doc
Achieving Electricity Market Integration in Europe
135
The regulators’ second paper, National Transmission Tarification Systems,83 outlines the current national transmission tarification systems across the four territories together with a first assessment of the extent to which differences in approach might affect cross-border trade. Here, the regulators solicited industry opinion as to whether the systems impact regional trade and, if so, how this can be rectified, possibly by revising or aligning tariffs in adjacent countries. The regulators’ third paper, Analysis of Interconnector Flows on the English Interconnector Angleterre,84 makes a first assessment of the extent to which the electricity interconnector between the markets is used efficiently, and puts forward some hypotheses to explain the observed levels of efficiency. This paper is intended to complement the first and second of the TSOs’ papers. It finds there is room for greater efficiency because there is currently an “irrational” utilization of capacity with some flows occurring in the opposite direction of the price differentials between the two markets. Moreover, the analysis shows that when use of the interconnector has been “rational,” capacity was under-used two-thirds of the time. For this regional market to be successful, the wholesale market will have to be much more transparent in order to facilitate efficient price discovery. Ergeg’s recommendations in this area of information disclosure are based on its draft transparency guidelines. These state that “trade between countries in this region will be best facilitated where the appropriate level of information is made available to market participants.” 3.5.3. Next steps
EBL
These consultations closed in January 2007, and Ergeg and the regional regulators and TSOs are now considering the responses. A detailed project plan was due to be published in March. The focus will be on producing workable proposals for the congestion management, balancing and transparency workstreams, especially development of a model for reciprocal access to balancing markets. The consultations will also inform the further work needed to address the priority issues and to assess what further actions, if any, are needed regarding the three additional topics. 3.6. Conclusions The reform processes to secure electricity market convergence and harmonization in Europe have shown sustained activity over more than a decade. They have in the main been characterized by “more heat than light.” Despite two landmark directives and sustained attempts to impose top-down harmonization, numerous workstreams initially led by technical agencies then by the commission have delivered few tangible or significant results, and the commission’s vision of a single internal market remains some years hence. Probably the most notable success has been achieved by the facilitation route, with the promulgation of guidelines under the important 2003 regulation on cross-border electricity exchanges. Four years on this approach is beginning to see real progress in the areas of the 83
www.ergeg.org/portal/page/portal/ERGEG_HOME/ERGEG_RI/ERI/UK_Ireland/Papers%20 and%20Written%20Consultation/20061101_Paper_IG2-6National%20Tariffication%20Systems_.doc 84 www.ergeg.org/portal/page/portal/ERGEG_HOME/ERGEG_RI/ERI/UK_Ireland/Papers%20 and%20Written%20Consultation/20061106_Paper_IG2-7%20Analysis%20of%20interconnector%20 flows_FI.doc
136
Competitive Electricity Markets
allocation of cross-border electricity interconnector capacity (i.e., congestion management), harmonization of transmission tariffs, and compensation to be paid to each TSO for hosting transmission flows originating in other TSOs’ areas. It is clear that there are real limits on how much progress can be made in building on the regulation in moving quickly to the single market. Recent years have seen a significant change of direction, with a new regional focus and a re-emphasis on structural and commercial rather than technical aspects of market access. The new regional initiatives under the auspices of the pan-European regulatory groups of CEER but especially Ergeg are endeavoring to prompt localized change as a catalyst to wider market integration. The development of regional markets as an interim step toward the establishment of a single European energy market is a sensible and probably the only viable way forward, and the potential for progress is clearly there if the process is supported politically by national governments. However, the scope for electricity transfers between member states remain constrained at less than 15% of consumption, and at the end of 2005 many interconnections remained managed by administrative rules without “market economic bases.”85 Furthermore, there is little early prospect that major new interconnection will change this context. Functional unbundling remains a significant problem especially in the newer accessed states, and the commission is continuing to face sustained resistance to addressing remaining barriers in this area. It has concluded that deeper powers are required by national regulators to address this nexus of issues, but a further directive will be necessary to provide an appropriate legal basis. Against this background, producing a strategic vision paper in 2008 and a route map to a single market, which is what Ergeg has said it intends to do, looks extraordinarily ambitious. It is relatively early days, but the Western regional initiative has begun to make progress by focusing on priority actions in areas that presently distort interaction between markets. It is hard to determine whether other regions enjoy similar levels of commitment as there is limited public information as yet to assess these. This exercise has highlighted the types of issues that arise in considering development of a regional electricity market and the main areas of divergence that presently exist. How those issues will need to be addressed for a particular regional market, including fundamental questions of market design, is dependent on a number of technical, political, geographical, economic, and regulatory factors that are specific to that collection of national markets, and it is too early to say how these factors might impact across regions. However, it is possible to identify the key obstacles to the establishment and operation of a regional market and so provide a checklist of priority actions for further consideration in specific instances. It remains to be seen how and to what degree these priorities are effectively addressed by the ERI, and whether the process will be more successful than those initiatives that preceded it. As for the TSOs, they remain collectively an active participant in the process and the events of November 2006 have served to highlight the need for continuing convergence between physical operators. However, the need to join technical and trading solutions means that the national regulators are now in the driving seat. Further, the Ergeg process is beginning to achieve much wider participation by other stakeholders, including the PXs and representatives of the trader community, which will be essential if enduring solutions are to be identified.
EBL
85
Glachant, J-M. (2005). Implementing the European internal energy market in 2005–09, available at www.grjm.net.
Achieving Electricity Market Integration in Europe
137
What is informative are the areas of focus and the priority actions needed to increase the prospect of regional market convergence based on tackling congestion, intraday market access, and transparency, which should be of note to reformers not just in Europe but outside it. That said, these actions remain modest in scope and do not as yet embrace delivery of balancing arrangements that are transparent, simple, and robust to trading between markets. Further progress toward a single market design remains a long way off, and work in progress suggests that real progress toward this may still be a decade away, and that for the foreseeable future competition is likely, again to quote Glachant, to remain “fractured in national or local blocks.”
EBL
EBL
This page intentionally left blank
Part II Market Performance, Monitoring and Demand Participation
EBL
EBL
This page intentionally left blank
Chapter 4 Transmission Markets, Congestion Management, and Investment HARRY SINGH Federal Energy Regulatory Commission1 , Washington, DC, USA
Summary Nearly a decade has passed since the introduction of transmission open access in the United States under Order 888. During this period the electric utility industry has witnessed significant changes in the transmission business with the development of organized markets operated by Regional Transmission Organizations (RTOs), the continued refinement of the open access rules outside the organized markets, and the development of new transmission companies, such as merchant transmission projects and Independent Transmission Companies (ITCs). Transmission investment has generally lagged generation investment, putting greater emphasis in the United States on the role of price-based congestion management in market design than has occurred elsewhere. However, there is renewed focus on transmission with several initiatives to encourage investment and improve transmission markets. The August 2003 Northeast Blackout also drew attention to transmission operations and served as a catalyst for the development of enforceable reliability standards. This chapter reviews various approaches that have been implemented for transmission organizations in the United States using data from different markets. The chapter also provides an overview of significant regulatory developments related to the Energy Policy Act of 2005.
EBL
4.1. Introduction The development of wholesale electric power markets has been driven largely by the goal of enabling competition in generation. However, connecting generation and load requires access to transmission. The transmission system consists of high voltage transmission lines, transformers, phase shifters, and other devices that enable the transfer of electric energy from generators to loads. This chapter explores the development of approaches to create open access to the transmission system and compares these approaches in terms of 1
The opinions expressed here are those of the author and do not reflect the view of the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission or any other organization that the author may have been affiliated with.
141
142
Competitive Electricity Markets
managing congestion and creating incentives for transmission investment. It also discusses the evolution of transmission organizations in the United States. This section provides background and introduces some major themes. A key development in creating transmission open access in the United States took place over a decade ago when Orders 888 and 889 were introduced by FERC in 1996, marking the first attempt to standardize procedures for obtaining transmission service (FERC, 1996 and FERC, 1996a). Since that time, significant changes have occurred in the structure of the transmission business that include the development of Independent System Operators (ISOs) or Regional Transmission Organizations (RTOs), the continued refinement of the open access rules outside such organized markets, and the introduction of new transmission companies, such as merchant transmission projects and the formation of Independent Transmission Companies (ITCs). The separation of ownership from control of transmission assets in RTOs and ITCs has evolved differently in the United States as compared to other countries or regions where asset ownership and control are more typically combined within the same entity.2 Although pros and cons have been cited for both types of structures, the evolution of each was largely driven by the different starting points and differences in regulatory approaches as well as the intention of the policymakers (e.g., Chandley and Hogan, 2002; Henney and Russel, 2002; Ruff, 2002). A more detailed discussion of European Transmission System Operators (TSOs) can be found in Chapter 3. Section 4.2 of this chapter discusses the evolution of US transmission organizations and structures. In the US context, the evolution of ISOs and RTOs is closely linked to the creation of competition in generation. A useful analogy compares ISOs to air-traffic controllers as entities in charge of ensuring safe and secure operation of the power grid (or airtraffic) and impartially administering the rules of access. Although ISOs and RTOs are known as transmission system operators, they are just as much operators in the generation market.3 Given that vertically integrated utilities in the United States owned and operated both generation and transmission, there were three main options available for ensuring independence in transmission operation. The first was to transfer the operational control of transmission assets to an independent entity such as an ISO or RTO; the second was to maintain control over transmission but offer transmission access and rates subject to the open access requirements; the third was to divest transmission assets to an independent company. As of this writing, approximately two-thirds of the US system has taken the first approach, although the designs of ISOs and RTOs remain works in progress (see Fig. 4.1).4 The remainder of the system continues to take the second approach, which is also being continually refined (e.g., FERC, 2007). While there are ITCs in the United States, they remain embedded in one or the other of these market models. Unlike the UK, no ITC in the United States undertakes congestion management under performance-based regulation. Sections 4.3, 4.3, and 4.5 of the chapter discuss transmission market design issues, such as congestion management, congestion metrics, and transmission rights, both within and outside the organized markets. The nature of RTO markets has evolved over time
EBL
2
Examples of transmission organizations that combine ownership and operations include the National Grid Company in the UK, Statnett in Norway, Red Eléctrica in Spain, and Transpower in New Zealand among others. 3 One ISO, the Independent Electricity System Operator (IESO) in Ontario was initially known as the Independent Electricity Market Operator (IMO) until it changed names in December 2004. 4 Roughly 60 per cent of the summer peak demand in the United States corresponds to regions with RTOs.
Transmission Markets, Congestion Management, and Investment
143
ISO-NE
Northwest NYISO
MISO
Peak load (MW)
PJM
CAISO
160,000 140,000 120,000
Southwest
SPP
100,000 80,000
Southeast
60,000 40,000 20,000
ERCOT
0 ISO-NE NYISO PJM
MISO
SPP ERCOT CAISO
Fig. 4.1. RTO and non-RTO regions. The northwest, southwest, and southeast are non-RTO regions. The projected peak demand for all regions in 2007 is 757 812 MW. RTO record peak loads in 2006. Sources: FERC, and NERC.
but appears to have settled on certain common elements. One such element is the use of auction-based markets for determining generation commitment and dispatch patterns (discussed in further detail in Chapter 5). These markets use a framework for congestion management that is known as Locational Marginal Pricing (LMP) or nodal pricing (the terms will be used interchangeably in this chapter). Along with LMP came allocations and markets for tradable Financial Transmission Rights (FTRs) designed to insulate transmission customers from the price risks created by congestion in an LMP market. Considerable debate ensued in determining the structure of LMP and FTR markets. With a few differences, these issues have largely been settled. For example, in the midand late 1990s, there was substantial concern in the nascent merchant and financial power trading sector that the granularity of prices (i.e., prices set at each individual node instead of by zone) in LMP markets would have a significant adverse impact on market liquidity. However, that did not prove to be the case. An example is the sustained liquidity of financial trading at the PJM–West hub that aggregates individual LMPs at more than a hundred nodes. This experience built confidence in LMP. In contrast, markets that started with zonal pricing (e.g., California and Texas) have transitioned to or are now gradually moving to a nodal approach. However, the FTR model has not been without its problems. For example, FTR prices have been quite volatile every year, reflecting volatility in congestion costs. This makes valuation difficult. Also, multi-year FTRs were difficult to design. Hence, markets for FTRs have seen the evolution of several new products. Section 4.3 discusses approaches for transmission markets while Section 4.5 describes FTR markets in particular. An important feature of the US markets is that the design of ISO and RTO markets varies by region, with major elements summarized in Fig. 4.1. The markets in the northeast, midAtlantic, and to some extent the Midwest are generally considered the most developed organized markets with full implementation of LMP.5 Other regions such as California
EBL
5 All these markets incorporate LMP implementations with day-ahead energy markets and FTRs. However, a majority of the schedules in the MISO day-ahead markets are still based on the commitment and schedule developed in utility control areas. Consequently, MISO is still moving toward implementing some market elements such as an Ancillary Services market.
144
Competitive Electricity Markets
and Texas incorporate varying elements of LMP markets and are in transition, while the Southwest Power Pool (SPP) operates a transmission market under Order 888 paradigm along with an auction-based real-time market.6 As noted, the rest of the country is served under open-access tariffs based on Order 888. PJM was the first US market to implement an LMP-based day-ahead market on April 1, 1998 – one year after it started operating a regional bid-based market. NYISO started operation of an LMP-based market on December 1, 1999 followed by ISO-NE’s implementation of LMP on March 1, 2003. MISO implemented an LMP market on April 1, 2005. California is scheduled to implement an LMP market in 2008. Both PJM and ISO-NE initially started their markets without LMP but transitioned to an LMP approach after their initial experiences with congestion management. Table 4.1 lists key features and milestones in various RTO markets. While the United States has experimented with several kinds of transmission market designs and various regulatory approaches, a major indicator of policy and regulatory success is whether transmission investment has been seen as supportive of market development and improved reliability. These questions are explored in Section 4.6. Certainly the separation of generation from transmission that had historically been linked together in integrated resource planning has introduced new challenges to transmission planning. The further separation of ownership and operations in transmission and the interests of multiple entities have not made transmission planning and investment decisions any simpler. At the same time, the expansion of RTO footprints can make regional transmission planning easier by increased coordination across a wider geographical area. Transmission planning by RTOs is only now reaching a level of maturity that can be used to assess any real improvements. A key metric in transmission expansion decisions is the level of congestion on the grid. Increased price transparency in organized markets has made it easier to measure congestion. However, as discussed in Section 4.4, while several different congestion metrics have been proposed, not all metrics can be directly used as a measure on which to base investment decisions. The Northeast Blackout of August 2003 served as a catalyst for significant action on the reliability front, such as the development of mandatory reliability standards and the creation of an Electric Reliability Organization (ERO). These developments followed the collapse of several merchant generation companies7 and also drew attention to transmission investment that had lagged behind generation investment for some time. Section 4.6 explains that although some merchant transmission projects have been implemented and several others have been proposed, they are unlikely to become the norm given the economies of scale that still exist in the transmission sector. Consequently, incentivebased regulated rates for transmission investments have received attention. Other recent actions such as a federal backstop authority in siting transmission projects and the repeal of the Public Utility Holding Company Act (PUHCA) are also likely to play a positive role in encouraging transmission investment.
EBL
6 Markets such as SPP have sometimes been characterized as “day 1” RTO markets as they largely operate under the Order 888 construct and are perceived as simpler and less expensive to implement. 7 Between January 2001 and January 2003, more than $130 billion was lost in equity value for just eight merchant generators including AES, Aquila, Calpine, Mirant, Dynegy, El Paso, Reliant, and Williams. Several merchant generation companies including Calpine, Mirant, NRG and National Energy & Gas Transmission filed for Chapter 11 bankruptcy protection.
Transmission Markets, Congestion Management, and Investment
145
Table 4.1. RTO Markets RTO
Start Date
Markets
ISO-New England(ISO-NE)
1971 – New England Power Pool formed 1997 – ISO-NE formed 1999 – Initial market operation 2003 – LMP-based markets
LMP-based day-ahead and real-time markets with 8 load zones and 1 trading hub. Installed capacity market under transition to Forward Capacity Market (FCM), forward reserves market, regulation market, and FTR market.
New York ISO (NYISO)
1966 – New York Power Pool formed 1999 – LMP market started 2005 – Major software updated
LMP-based day-ahead and real-time markets with 11 zones. Zone J (New York City) and Zone K (Long Island) are major load pockets. Locational Installed Capacity market, ancillary services market, and FTR market.
PJM
1927 – PJM formed 1997 – PJM ISO formed 1998 – LMP market started 2004–05 – Major expansions
LMP-based day-ahead and real-time markets. Ancillary services market, Installed Capacity market under redesign, FTR market. Active trading hub at PJM–West.
Midwest ISO (MISO)
1998 – MISO formed 2002 – Order 888-based markets 2005 – LMP market started
LMP-based day-ahead and real-time markets. Ancillary services market, FTR market. Major trading hubs are Cinergy and northern Illinois.
Southwest Power Pool (SPP)
1968 1998 2004 2007
Order 888-based transmission markets and auction-based real-time market.
Electric Reliability Council of Texas (ERCOT)
1996 – Initial creation 2001 – Market operation 2009 – Market redesign using LMP
Real-time balancing and ancillary services markets, zonal congestion management with 4 zones, and FTRs.
California ISO (CAISO)
1998 – CAISO formed 2008 – Market redesign based on LMP
Markets for real-time energy, day-ahead transmission, ancillary services, and FTRs.
EBL
– – – –
SPP formed Tariff administration RTO status Real-time LMP market
Source: FERC, 2007.
4.2. Evolution of Transmission Organizations and Structures Vertically integrated utilities have historically operated a large portion of the transmission system across the United States.8 Although analogies are sometimes made between the transmission system and the interstate highway system, historically transmission planning 8 There are almost 450 different transmission owners and approximately 135 control areas or balancing authorities across the country. A complete list of balancing authorities can be found at http://www.nerc.com/∼org/
Competitive Electricity Markets
146
Table 4.2. Major milestones in the US power industry Date
Event
Comments
1935
Federal Power Act
Enacted by US Congress and basis for FERC jurisdiction over interstate transmission and wholesale power rates
1965
Northeast Blackout
Provided impetus for major reliability initiatives including formation of NERC
1968
North American Electric Reliability Council (NERC) formed
Non-profit organization formed by utility industry to promote reliability and adequacy of bulk power supply. In 2006, NERC was certified as the Electric Reliability Organization (ERO)
1978
Public Utility Regulatory Policy Act (PURPA)
Required utilities to purchase power from Qualifying Facilities (QFs) at avoided costs.
1992
Energy Policy Act of 1992 (EPACT 1992)
Created category of non-utility generators and required transmission open access
1996
FERC Orders 888 and 889
Foundation of transmission open access
2000
FERC Order 2000 and creation of RTOs
Proposal for voluntary formation of RTOs
2000–01
California power crisis
Lack of long-term contracts in face of high spot prices led to bankruptcy of PG & E, setback for expansion of competitive markets. Markets stable since then albeit new market design proposed for 2008.
2001
Enron Bankruptcy
Further setback for competitive markets, credit downgrades that followed impacted long-term contracting and trading, banks and financial institutions stepped in later to fill the void left by Enron.
2002
FERC Standard Market Design (SMD)
Intended to avoid repeat of California experience and help address seams issues by standardizing best practices in RTO market design. However, efforts to expand RTOs into new areas led to resistance and SMD was withdrawn in 2005.
2003
August 14 Northeast Blackout
Largest power outage in North America with more than 61 800 MW of lost load affecting an estimated 50 million people.
2005
Energy Policy Act of 2005 (EPACT 2005)
Several initiatives to address reliability, transmission infrastructure, and market manipulation.
2007
Mandatory Reliability Standards
Mandatory standards took effect on June 18, 2007. NERC certified as Electric Reliability Organization (ERO) in 2006.
EBL
was done primarily within the footprints of large vertically integrated utilities with the goal of serving local load. The evolution of the transmission system from isolated standalone systems to regional systems and ultimately to interconnections took place over many decades (Casazza, 1993). This paradigm changed significantly starting in 1978 with the Public Utilities Regulatory Policies Act (PURPA), which was followed by the Energy Policy Act of 1992 (EPACT 1992), and finally by Orders 888 and 889 in 1996. Seeking to promote the use of renewable energy, PURPA opened up the market for independent power producers by requiring
Transmission Markets, Congestion Management, and Investment
147
utilities to purchase power from qualifying facilities (QFs) at avoided costs. EPACT 1992 expanded wholesale power sales to non-utility generators called Exempt Wholesale Generators (EWGs). However, there was little standardization in the procedures for obtaining transmission access until FERC Order 888 (FERC 1996, 1996a) that required utilities to provide open access to the use of their transmission system on the same terms and rates as available to the utility’s native load. Order 888 also required utilities to functionally unbundle their rates for wholesale generation and transmission service. Various ancillary services were unbundled and included as a component of required transmission service. Although this had significant impact on the number and nature of power transactions, there was little structural change in the transmission business itself. Subsequent regulatory initiatives advanced the move toward formation of transmission companies. An important question in this movement was whether ownership and control of transmission needed to stay together. The Federal Power Act (FPA) established by Congress in 1935 has been administered by FERC to ensure that wholesale power rates are “just and reasonable.” The introduction of competition has seen changes in the FPA most recently with the Energy Policy Act of 2005 that enhanced FERC’s authority in several areas such as enforcement of mandatory reliability standards and created a backstop siting authority for transmission. However, the “just and reasonable” standard continues to remain a major component of the FPA despite the transition from cost-of-service ratemaking to competitive markets. Following several years of experience under Order 888, FERC perceived that the continued balkanization of the United States grid under different transmission operators along with concerns about interpretation or possibly manipulation of open access rules was creating market inefficiency. Hence, it established a new requirement, that of Regional Transmission Organizations (FERC, 1999). The intention was to ensure that all US utilities under FERC’s jurisdiction would join large regional RTOs. However, in some regions of the country there was resistance to the RTO concept, and this resistance grew during the California power crisis in 2000–01. The role of regulators then changed quickly and gained increased prominence following the California power crisis. The significance of good risk management and well-designed markets became increasingly evident. The evolution of markets in different regions with different rules also created “seams issues” between different transmission organizations. In 2002, FERC proposed to establish a Standard Market Design (SMD) for all utilities under its jurisdiction in part to address the seams issue and in part to avoid a repeat of the California crisis that was attributed to flawed market rules.9 Perhaps a more significant component of SMD was the goal of advancing RTO
EBL
9 Although the California crisis is often linked to flawed market rules, one of its major factors was the absence of any long-term contracts. In contrast, other market shortcomings such as the lack of a centralized day-ahead market and LMP played only a secondary role. In fact, some of these shortcomings continue to this day in equally tight supply conditions but without any major disruptions due largely to the presence of long-term contracts and improved market oversight and mitigation. It is also noteworthy that the California and Texas wholesale markets shared similar market designs that lacked centralized day-ahead markets and LMP. The characterization of one as a failure and the other as a success was more a consequence of the different fundamentals and levels of long-term contracting in each market. Further details on these markets can be found in Sweeney (2006) and Adib and Zarnikau (2006). While California enjoys a relatively high level of forward contracting today, other states like Maryland and Illinois that are participants in the generally well-regarded PJM market are facing retail rate-shocks due to expiration of buy-back contracts at a time of high wholesale prices, expiration of retail caps, and retail rate design. Even if this is reminiscent of the California experience, the impacts are likely to be less severe given the maturity of the PJM market.
Competitive Electricity Markets
148
participation. However, as with the RTO initiative, regional dissatisfaction with what was perceived to be an overly prescriptive federal approach created strong resistance in many states to adopting SMD. The resistance to further expansion of RTO markets was also aided by the California experience and the Enron bankruptcy. The SMD proposal was eventually withdrawn by FERC in 2005, but it remained influential in promoting the LMP and FTR market design, as discussed in Sections 4.3–4.5. Table 4.2 lists some major milestones in the US power industry.
4.2.1. Transcos, ITCs, and ICTs There are various business structures possible for a transmission company. A transmission company could be a for-profit or a non-profit organization; it could combine ownership and operation of assets or separate them into different entities. Organizationally, RTOs are independent non-profit entities with operational control but no ownership of assets. This is in stark contrast to successful for-profit transmission operators in Europe that both own and operate transmission assets. The non-profit aspect of RTOs was not explicitly required by FERC Order 2000 that initiated their formation; rather it was a consequence of the debate that followed. The characteristics required of an RTO included independence, regional scope, operational control, and regional reliability (see Box 4.1 for characteristics and functions of RTOs as specified in FERC Order 2000). For-profit transmission companies that combined ownership and operation, referred to as Transcos, were proposed as potential RTOs but never implemented in the United States. There have been recent successes with ITCs that consolidate transmission ownership of transmission assets but still operate under RTOs.
EBL
Box 4.1 Main characteristics and functions of RTOs RTO Characteristics (FERC Order 2000) • • • •
Independence Scope and regional configuration Operational authority Short-term reliability
RTO Functions (FERC Order 2000) • • • • • • • •
Tariff administration and design Congestion management Parallel path flow Ancillary services Available Transmission Capability (ATC) Market monitoring Planning and expansion Inter- regional coordination
Transmission Markets, Congestion Management, and Investment
149
Table 4.3. Stand-alone transmission companies Transmission Company
Ownership
Operational Control
Established
Areas
ITC Transmission
Owned by ITC Holdings held by private equity investors. Formerly owned by DTE Energy, the parent company of Detroit Edison.
MISO (2700 miles of high-voltage transmission)
2003
Michigan, parts of Ontario, and other Midwestern states
METC (Michigan Electric Transmission Company)
Owned by ITC Holdings held by private equity investors. Past owners include Trans-Elect and Consumers Power
MISO (5400 miles of high-voltage transmission)
2002
Lower peninsula of Michigan
American Transmission Company ATC
Owned by member utilities, municipals, and cooperatives
MISO (9081 miles of high-voltage transmission)
2001
Eastern Wisconsin and parts of Michigan, Illinois, and Minnesota
Source: ATC, ITC Holdings 2006.
EBL
Table 4.3 lists the various stand-alone transmission companies in operation today. The first independently owned and operated transmission company in the United States began operations in 2003 as the International Transmission Company (ITC Transmission) in southeastern Michigan. Since then ITC Transmission’s parent company, ITC Holdings, acquired additional transmission assets from an adjacent transmission company, Michigan Electric Transmission Company (METC) and recently announced plans to acquire transmission assets from Alliant Energy that would expand the company’s footprint into other Midwestern states including Iowa, Illinois, and Minnesota. The first transmission-only utility in the country also started in the Midwest as American Transmission Company (ATC) in 2001. However, unlike ITC-Holdings which is owned by private equity firms Kohlberg Kravis Roberts (KKR) and Trimaran Fund Management, ATC is owned by the utilities, municipal electric companies, and electric cooperatives that contributed their transmission assets to ATC. Both companies are members of the Midwest ISO. There is also a recent proposal to form an ITC in Kansas (ITC Great Plains) within the SPP footprint. The definition of Transcos and ITCs has continued to evolve since these terms were first used (Box 4.1). More recently, FERC has used the term Transco more broadly to define any stand-alone transmission company that sells transmission services at wholesale and/or on an unbundled retail basis. This definition includes independent transmission companies like International Transmission as well as those affiliated with other market participants like American Transmission Company (FERC, 2006a). The debate on which structure makes most sense has been influenced by legacy and independence considerations in the United States. In some instances, vertically integrated utilities elected to turn over operation of their transmission system to an RTO as it could address independence concerns without having to divest any generation assets. In other
150
Competitive Electricity Markets
instances, for-profit Transcos were proposed on the grounds that they could provide more value and innovation by combining ownership and operation.10 However, such proposals met strong resistance from some stakeholders on their ability to be truly independent on policy decisions between transmission investment and generation or demand response. For example, generators in a load pocket might fear that excessive transmission upgrades may adversely impact their revenues. There were also questions on the market designs for short-term operations under a Transco – e.g., could it implement an LMP-based market like an RTO? Some of these concerns were addressed by ITCs that offered the advantages of horizontal consolidation of transmission assets but would turn over operations to an RTO to address independence concerns. Transco proponents argued that turning over operations to the RTO would dilute the value proposition of a Transco and make the transmission owner passive. However, a transmission owner operating under an RTO may not be any more passive than a generation owner operating under the RTO. Even though a generator receives dispatch instructions from the RTO, one seldom hears of passive generation owners. A more accurate characterization might be that the fewer functions a transmission owner performs, the more limited the options will be for designing incentive regulation proposals. Another more recent development in transmission organizations involves the creation of an Independent Coordinator of Transmission (ICT), by which a transmission owning utility arranges for an independent entity to coordinate the operation of its transmission system. The utility still remains the transmission owner and operator but certain limited functions such as granting or denying transmission service requests, calculating available flowgate or available transfer capacity, processing generator interconnection requests, and operating the OASIS11 website are outsourced to the ICT. The first example of an ICT involves a structure in which SPP will serve as the ICT for Entergy, a utility in the southeastern United States. In contrast with RTOs that operate daily and hourly markets, the Entergy–SPP ICT will operate a weekly procurement process for energy that is intended to allow independent generators to compete with the incumbent utility (Entergy). Other ICT examples involve Duke Energy, where MISO will act as the Independent Entity (IE), and MidAmerican, where TranServ will act as the Transmission Service Coordinator (TSC). Under a similar arrangement, SPP serves as the Independent Transmission Organization (ITO) for Louisville Gas and Electric and Kentucky Utilities. Figure 4.2 illustrates control and ownership of transmission under different organizational structures.
EBL
4.2.2. Incentives for RTOs Given the non-profit structure of RTOs, the question of performance incentives can be important. Incentive regulation plans designed for a for-profit transmission operator do not automatically lend themselves for application to a non-profit entity. However, it is possible to define metrics for measuring the performance of a transmission operator that could be used in setting management compensation. Table 4.4 lists examples of potential metrics that may be considered (Singh, 2005). Increases in RTO costs have in some cases dampened enthusiasm to join RTOs and there have been recent efforts to reduce these costs. For example, the Grid Management 10
The proposal for the Alliance RTO in the Midwest is one example of a Transco that did not materialize. 11 OASIS or Open-Access Same-Time Information System represents the Internet-based system used to obtain transmission service and related information.
Transmission Markets, Congestion Management, and Investment
RTO
Integrated utility
Non-profit entity control of operations no asset ownership
Non-profit entity control of operations no asset ownership
151
Transco For-profit entity transmission owner control of operations
ITC
ICT
For-profit entity consolidates asset ownership limited operational role
Independent entity for-profit or non-profit Performs limited operational functions for utility
Fig. 4.2. Control and ownership under different transmission organizations. All the existing ITCs operate under the umbrella of an RTO that is responsible for system operations. However, ITCs in non-RTO regions may be more akin to a Transco that combines ownership and operations.
Table 4.4. RTO metrics Metrics for measuring RTO performance
EBL
Accuracy of load forecasts Compliance with reliability standards Accuracy of settlements Settlement cycle Frequency of price revisions Frequency of tariff violations
Frequency of tariff changes Magnitude of administrative costs Magnitude of uplifts charges Efficient utilization of grid Accuracy of information Customer focus
Charge (GMC) at the CAISO has decreased after being among the highest of all RTO charges. Overall, the average administrative and operating charges across all RTOs was approximately $0.5/MWh in 2005 amounting to more than $1 billion in annual payments by market participants. Even though this is a significant figure, RTO costs comprise less than one per cent of the overall cost for power and are still small compared to cost overruns in the earlier era of cost of service regulation. Most RTO markets involve commitment of resources to meet the RTO’s load forecast. If the RTO’s forecast is inaccurate, excessive costs may be incurred that are eventually allocated to load as uplift costs. Thus, accuracy in load forecasting would translate to increased efficiency in the operation of an RTO. Similarly, the performance of an RTO as a control area operator or balancing authority can be measured by frequency control metrics such as CPS1 and CPS2 defined by NERC.12 PJM reported improved control performance 12
CPS1 and CPS2 (Control Performance Standards) are reliability standards that measure the performance of a control area with respect to controlling system frequency and area control error. Under the proposed mandatory reliability standards, CPS1 and CPS2 will be replaced by a new standard for Balance of Resources and Demand BAL-007-1.
152
Competitive Electricity Markets
after the introduction of LMP markets but the performance declined somewhat after PJM’s expansion into new regions. Another metric could be the level of demand response in the RTO. Price sensitive demand response can play an effective role in improving market efficiency and considerable cost savings during system peaks.13 The proper integration of demand response with pricing in RTO markets is a significant issue that continues to develop. Further discussion of demand response can be found in Chapter 8. Most RTO markets involve a time lag between the sale/consumption of energy and actual financial settlement due to the time it takes for actual meter reading. This can increase credit risk as well as the collateral requirements for market participants. Efforts have been made by some RTOs to shorten their settlement cycles to address these concerns although there is still not a uniform standard. The early operation of some RTO markets witnessed frequent revisions to published prices that introduced an added dimension of risk to transaction finality. Equally challenging is the continuous change in market rules. For example, the CAISO has had at least 73 amendments to its original tariff. Although market design changes often improve market functioning, frequent changes create regulatory uncertainty that also adds risk. Prices from RTO markets can provide a useful index for use in long-term contracts. Nowhere has this been as evident as in PJM where the volume of financial swaps indexed to the PJM–West hub has increased dramatically. This reflects the confidence of market participants in the published price. In cases where the published price does not reflect certain costs known as uplifts, its usefulness as an index can decrease. The debate on RTO responsiveness has also involved discussion on what form of governance makes the most sense. With the exception of the CAISO during its initial start-up, RTOs have been governed by independent boards. Independent boards have sometimes been criticized as not being completely in touch with the needs of market participants and beholden to RTO management. In contrast, boards that involve representation of market participants or stakeholders can become beholden to commercial interests of member companies. There has been discussion of hybrid board structures, advisory committees, and the need for access to board members to address some of these issues.14
EBL
4.2.3. Reliability In addition to the evolution of transmission business structures, another area of change deals with reliability standards. All transmission organizations must operate in compliance with standards established by NERC. Until recently, these reliability standards have largely been implemented on a voluntary basis through NERC’s member reliability councils. In 2006, the number of reliability councils was reduced from ten to eight when three councils merged to improve consistency of reliability criteria across the region. A new reliability council, called Reliability First, was formed from the merger of East Central Area Coordination Agreement (ECAR), Mid-Atlantic Area Council (MAAC), and MidAmerican Interconnected Network (MAIN). The hierarchy of entities on the reliability 13
On August 2, 2006, PJM experienced a record peak load of 144,796 MW when voluntary reductions in electricity consumption produced savings of $230 million. Total savings from demand response during a 1-week period exceeded $650 million. 14 Governance issues have been an area of focus in a recent strategic initiative by PJM to examine improvements in its markets http://www.pjm.com/documents/strategic-report.html
Transmission Markets, Congestion Management, and Investment
153
QUÉBEC INTERCONNECTION
NERC INTERCONNECTIONS
NPCC MRO
RFC WECC SPP SERC
FRCC WESTERN INTERCONNECTION ERCOT
EASTERN INTERCONNECTION
ERCOT INTERCONNECTION
Fig. 4.3. NERC Interconnections and Reliability Councils. Source: NERC.
EBL
front starts with the interconnections. NERC spans four interconnections in North America of which three are in the United States – the western and eastern interconnections and Texas. Within each interconnection are several regional councils, as shown in Fig. 4.3. There are also several reliability coordinators listed in Table 4.5 as well as multiple balancing authorities. In response to the August 14, 2003 Blackout in the Northeast, EPACT 2005 called for mandatory and enforceable Reliability Standards. In February 2006, FERC issued Order 672 that certified NERC, as the Electric Reliability Organization (ERO) (FERC, 2006b). The ERO is required to develop Reliability Standards, which are subject to FERC review and approval. Since then NERC has proposed 102 standards based largely on its existing practices for certification with FERC. In October 2006, FERC proposed adoption of 83 of these standards as mandatory and enforceable standards (FERC, 2006c, 2007a). The mandatory standards took effect in June 2007.15 The remaining continue to apply on a voluntary basis. The standards span several different categories as shown in Table 4.6. The primary responsibility for enforcing reliability standards rests with the regional councils and the ERO although FERC has ultimate authority. This is in contrast to FERC’s more direct and active role in enforcement of market rules and preventing market manipulation. However, FERC’s enhanced authority under EPACT 2005 to levy civil penalties as high as $1 million/day for each violation of the Federal Power Act applies to both market and reliability rules. In addition to approving mandatory reliability standards, FERC also approved violation risk factors that classify the consequences 15
The standards were initially set to take effect on 4 June 2007 but the effective date was pushed back to 18 June 2007.
Competitive Electricity Markets
154
Table 4.5. NERC Regional Reliability Councils Reliability Council
Description
Electric Reliability Council of Texas (ERCOT)
Single Balancing Authority, covers Texas
Florida Reliability Coordinating Council (FRCC)
Eleven Balancing Authorities, covers Florida
Midwest Reliability Organization (MRO)
Multiple Balancing Authorities in eight US states and two Canadian provinces
Northeast Power Coordinating Council (NPCC)
Covers 20% of load in eastern Interconnection across northeastern US and central and eastern Canada
Reliability First Corporation (RFC)
Twelve Balancing Authorities across multiple US states.
SERC Reliability Corporation (SERC)
Covers sixteen southeastern and central states and contains 5 sub-regions – Southern, Entergy, TVA, VACAR, and Gateway
Southwest Power Pool (SPP)
Covers southwest quadrant, also operates as Reliability Coordinator and RTO, multiple Balancing Authorities
Western Electricity Coordinating Council (WECC)
Largest NERC region, covers entire Western Interconnection
EBL
Source: NERC.
Table 4.6. Categories for reliability standards Group
Description
BAL CIP COM EOP FAC INT IRO MOD PER PRC TOP TPL VAR
Resource and Demand Balancing Critical Infrastructure Protection Communications Emergency Preparedness and Operations Facilities Design, Connections, Maintenance, and Transfer Capabilities Interchange Scheduling and Coordination Interconnection Reliability Operations and Coordination Modeling, Data and Analysis Personnel Performance, Training, and Qualifications Protection and Control Transmission Operations Transmission Planning Voltage and Reactive Control
Source: NERC.
of non-compliance into low, medium, and high risk (FERC, 2007b).16 Violation risk factors together with the severity of the violation will be used by NERC to establish penalties for non-compliance. EPACT 2005 also gave FERC reliability authority over nonjurisdictional entities such as municipals, cooperatives, federal power marketing authori16
FERC proposed modifications to 28 of more than 700 violation risk factors proposed by NERC.
Transmission Markets, Congestion Management, and Investment
155
ties, and utilities in Texas that are normally not within FERC’s jurisdiction. The move to transition voluntary reliability rules into enforceable standards is also receiving attention in Europe.17 4.3. Approaches for Transmission Markets US transmission markets remain divided between the regions outside the organized markets, which will be called “Order 888-based markets” in this chapter, and those with centrally organized markets, most of which follow a design with LMP and FTRs. There are also hybrid markets emerging that share features of both. This section first describes the former type and then the latter, followed by some additional details on LMP. More detail on FTRs follows in Section 4.5. 4.3.1. Order 888-based markets Transmission service can be defined as the right of a customer to inject energy at one or more points on a transmission service provider’s electric grid (“points of receipt”) and withdraw energy at one or more points on the service provider’s electric grid (“points of delivery”). The first attempt to standardize the rules for transmission service came with Order 888. Transmission access under Order 888 is based on a first-come first-served approach to physical access that presents little price risk but can involve risks of curtailment via Transmission Loading Relief (TLR) procedures.18 The key constructs of Order 888 include the availability of point-to-point and network service, varying levels of firmness (e.g., firm or non-firm) and different term-lengths of service (e.g., hourly, monthly, or annual). Under point-to-point service, a transmission user must designate specific points of receipt and delivery. Network service does not require specific points of receipt and delivery but rather the specification of network loads and resources. Figure 4.4 depicts the choices for transmission service under Order 888. In addition to the risk of curtailment under TLRs, questions have been raised about the transparency of Available Transfer Capability (ATC)19 calculations that can be critical in obtaining physical access to the grid and the use of a contract-path paradigm. The development of organized markets operated by RTOs described next can be viewed as an
EBL
17 The Union for the Co-ordination of Transmission of Electricity (UCTE), an association of Transmission System Operators (TSOs) in 23 European countries, adopted a multilateral agreement in June 2005 to make reliability standards binding and enforceable with inter-TSO penalties for damages up to E5 million. The second phase of this effort involves updating and modifying existing standards similar to what is planned in North America. 18 TLRs have been characterized as an un-scheduling procedure that was developed to address inaccuracies in scheduling of transmission service. TLRs have been criticized as not always being efficient (e.g., Rajaraman and Alvarado, 1998). 19 ATC = TTC – ETC – CBM – TRM where TTC is Total Transfer Capability, ETC denotes Existing Transmission Commitments including serving native load, CBM denotes Capacity Benefit Margin, and TRM denotes Transmission Reliability Margin. In addition to the lack of transparency in models defining ATC calculations, assumptions on the various inputs can also influence the calculation. Overly conservative assumptions on ETC, CBM, and TRM can reduce ATC unnecessarily. There are at least three different approaches currently in use to calculate ATC. These include network ATC, network AFC (Available Flowgate Capacity), and contract path approaches. The contract path approach has been largely used in the Western Interconnection.
Competitive Electricity Markets
156
Network integration service
Point to point (PTP)
Non-firm
Monthly weekly daily hourly
Firm
Short term
Long term (LT)
Monthly weekly daily
Annual or longer
Fig. 4.4. Types of transmission service under Order 888.
attempt to address some of the concerns about Order 888. However, after recognizing that the further expansion of RTO markets may not occur, attention was given to less radical improvements to Order 888. FERC recently proposed reforms under Order 890 that retain the underlying first-come first-served construct of Order 888 but attempt to address some of the concerns that have been raised by market participants (FERC, 2007). Major areas of reform in Order 890 include a requirement for increased transparency for ATC calculations, elimination of imbalance penalties, introduction of a new conditionalfirm service that would avoid denying transmission requests that are infeasible for only a short period, further clarity in re-dispatch obligations, and a reform of the rollover rights policy.20 A new product in the form of hourly firm service was initially considered but not adopted in the final version of Order 890. There are also requirements for increased transparency in intra- and inter-regional transmission planning. Criticisms of Order 888 being based on a contract-path approach have more to do with the geographic scope of ATC calculations rather than the underlying construct itself. In this sense, an Order 888based market operated over a large region by an independent entity (e.g., the SPP RTO) can also serve as an example of Order 888 reform as it addresses both the contract path and the independence concerns.
EBL
4.3.2. Transmission access in organized markets Transmission access in most organized RTO markets (with the exception of SPP, as discussed later) is a three-step process in roughly the following sequence: First, an application for transmission service and payment of an access charge (which is used to compensate rate-based transmission assets in the RTO footprint); second, allocation and/or auction of financial transmission rights (FTRs), typically done months or weeks prior to the dispatch 20
Further details on Order 890 can be found at http://ferc.gov/industries/electric/indus-act/ oatt-reform.asp
Transmission Markets, Congestion Management, and Investment
157
day; and third, actual transmission usage, which is subject to marginal congestion and loss charges derived from the day-ahead and real-time energy market LMPs. FTRs are then used to hedge the congestion component of the LMPs. The transmission markets are also open to financial (“virtual”) trading by non-transmission users, whether seeking to purchase FTRs or to take positions in the energy markets. In a sense, the LMP markets are simultaneous auctions of transmission capacity under which offers and bids for energy establish generation and load schedules subject to transmission constraints. Physical access to the grid is ensured under this approach but comes with a higher price risk that can be managed through FTRs. The allocation of transmission capacity in the form of FTRs is conceptually similar to the allocation of the same capacity as physical transmission rights under Order 888, albeit over the larger footprint of an RTO. Currently, FTRs are limited to annual terms but there are efforts underway to offer long-term FTRs that span multiple years. A major difference in the early implementation of RTO markets was the granularity of locational prices. Some markets such as California and Texas initially opted for market designs with prices aggregated across zones. Experiences with uplift costs and the subsequent redefinition of zones have caused these markets to move closer to a full nodal pricing framework similar to the markets in the Northeast and Midwest. In principle, an RTO could follow the Order 888 approach to allocating physical transmission capacity over the territory of its members. This would overcome some of the criticisms of Order 888 markets such as contract-path limitations and independence. Some RTOs, such as SPP and MISO during their initial start-up, have followed such approaches. Figure 4.5 summarizes the different types of RTO and non-RTO markets. Non-RTO markets can sometimes be separated into those that border RTOs and those that do not. There has been recent discussion of RTO benefits accruing to neighboring non-members at a
EBL
Auction based markets 888 markets 888 regions that are RTO neighbors
888 regions that are not RTO neighbors
RTOs-day-ahead & real-time markets
PJM NYISO ISO-NE MISO
RTOs-realtime markets
CAISO ERCOT
RTOs 888 rights
LG&E BPA Entergy TVA MISO
Southern FPL Avista APS
SPP
Fig. 4.5. Different transmission structures in the United States. At one end of the spectrum are RTOs that operate auction-based day-ahead and real-time markets, followed by RTOs that operate auctionbased real-time markets. At the other end are vertically integrated utilities that provide transmission access under Order 888. Somewhere in the middle lie RTOs such as SPP that provide transmission access under Order 888 but also operate auction-based real-time markets. MISO contains both a market footprint with auction-based markets and a larger reliability footprint that also contains Order 888-based markets.
158
Competitive Electricity Markets
lower cost than what is borne by RTO members.21 For example, a utility neighboring an RTO can buy or sell power from the RTO market paying transaction costs only on its net sale or purchase. In contrast, utilities within the RTO pay such costs on their gross demand. This is only one example of the many seams issues between transmission organizations.
4.3.3. Features of locational marginal pricing As noted, two major elements of organized power markets are the use of single price auctions and LMP-based congestion management. In the absence of congestion (and ignoring the impact of losses), power prices in all locations are the same and set by the most expensive resource selected to serve load at a given point in time. This aspect of organized markets is discussed further in Chapter 5. The presence of congestion causes generation to be re-dispatched and power prices to vary by location. In general, prices in LMP-based wholesale power markets vary by location and time and reflect the incremental cost of meeting demand at any location at any point in time. In some implementations such as in New York and the one proposed in California, loads see prices that are averaged across zones. The emphasis on LMPbased markets in the United States speaks to the significance of congestion management in overall market design. A principal benefit of an LMP market is that it provides a transparent means to price and allocate the use of the transmission system. This provides operational benefits as well as visible price signals for new investment and demand response. One operational benefit is fewer instances of administrative curtailment procedures such as TLRs. In terms of impacts on investment, markets without LMP that socialize congestion costs may not create the best incentives for siting new generation in the right locations. High levels of intra-zonal congestion in southern California in 2004 that also raised reliability issues have at least in part been attributed to poor siting decisions by new generators (California ISO, 2004a). While some intra-zonal congestion was subsequently alleviated by transmission upgrades, it could recur unless the underlying problem of price signals is addressed. LMP markets have been accepted as the preferred approach in most organized power markets. The alternative to LMP is the adoption of a single price across the market with transmission congestion cost allocated as a separate uplift charge that is not reflected in the market price. A major drawback of such approaches is that uplift costs can be unpredictable and are difficult to hedge through long-term contracts. Markets such as California and Texas tried zonal approaches but faced problems with congestion causing significant uplift costs and the need to redefine zonal boundaries. An alternative approach was implemented initially by ISO-NE, where the entire market was treated as a single zone and all out-of-merit generation was paid through an uplift. Additionally, non-LMP approaches that do not directly assign the cost of congestion to those who contribute to it can lead to gaming, as was observed during the California power crisis. One such game involved the submission of infeasible schedules that caused
EBL
21
See Louisville Gas and Electric Company, et al., 114 FERC ¶ 61,282 (2006) at p. 64–65 approving the withdrawal of Louisville Gas and Electric Company (LG&E) and Kentucky Utilities (KU) from the Midwest ISO (MISO). MISO had argued that the request should be denied because the utilities “propose to benefit from the ongoing existence of the Midwest ISO, while paying for the services offered by the Midwest ISO only on a selective, as-needed basis.”
Transmission Markets, Congestion Management, and Investment
159
or exacerbated intra-zonal congestion followed by payments for decrementing output to help relieve the same congestion. This so-called “DEC” game was made possible by a combination of market power and the specifics of market rules that were in place at the time.22 Such problems have not been observed in LMP markets. LMP implementations in several organized markets also incorporate marginal loss pricing as a component of LMPs. This means that LMPs can vary across locations even in the absence of congestion. NYISO, ISO-NE, MISO, PJM, and CAISO all either already incorporate marginal losses in LMPs or are moving in that direction. Transmission losses can be approximated as a quadratic function of the power injected into the transmission system (Wood and Wollenberg, 1996). Consequently, the inclusion of marginal losses in LMPs creates surplus revenue that is approximately twice the average cost of losses. Unlike congestion which only occurs when flows on lines reach binding limits, losses are present at all hours of operation. Consequently, the loss surplus can be considerable and even comparable to the congestion surplus. Unlike congestion rents that are used to fund FTRs, the surplus from marginal losses is currently refunded to market participants using different approaches. Loss hedging rights have been proposed but not implemented (e.g., Harvey and Hogan, 2002; Rudkevich et al., 2005). The basics of LMP can be illustrated using a simple example where three locations or nodes are connected by identical transmission lines (Fig. 4.6) (additional examples are found in Chapter 5.). Cheap generation is available at node 1 at $20/MWh. More expensive generation is available at node 2 at $30/MWh. Each generator has a capacity of 400 MW. A fixed load of 450 MW is at node 3. In the absence of any transmission constraints, the
EBL (1/3) x 180 = 60 MW
Unit A 270 MW
Unit B
1
$20/MWh 180 + 60 = 240 MW
2 (1/3) x 270 = 90 MW (2/3) x 270 = 180 MW
180 MW $30/MWh
(2/3) x 180 = 120 MW
3 Optimal dispatch: Unit A = 270 MW Unit B = 180 MW All lines have equal impedance No losses
450 MW
Prices: Node 1: $20/MWh Node 2: $30/MWh Node 3: $40/MWh
Fig. 4.6. LMP calculation in a three-node network.
22
See, e.g., 103 FERC ¶ 61, 265 Order on proposed tariff amendment 50, May 30, 2003 and Opinion of the ISO Department of Market Analysis on the need for alternatives to economic bids for managing intra-zonal congestion in the absence of competitive conditions for re-dispatch, December 20, 1999.
160
Competitive Electricity Markets
cheaper generator at node 1 is dispatched at its maximum capacity of 400 MW and the expensive generator at node 2 supplies the remaining 50 MW. The LMP at any location is defined as the cost of meeting an additional MW of demand at that node. Ignoring transmission constraints, the next MW of supply comes from the expensive generator and consequently the price is $30/MWh at all locations. Next, assume a capacity limit of 240 MW applies from node 1 to node 3. In this case the cheaper generator can no longer operate at its maximum output as that would cause the power-flow in line 1–3 to exceed its limit. The optimal dispatch involves dispatching the cheaper generator at 270 MW and the expensive generator at 180 MW. The output of each generator splits up between the two parallel paths in inverse proportion to the distance involved. Thus, two-thirds of the power from the generator at node 1 flows directly from node 1 to node 3, while the remaining one-third flows through node 2. The LMP at the three nodes under the constrained case is $20, $30, and $40/MWh, respectively. This is easy to interpret for each of the generator nodes as a megawatt of demand would be supplied by local generation. For node 3, an increase in demand involves increasing the output at the expensive generator by 2 MW and reducing the output at the cheaper generator by 1 MW giving the $40/MWh result. This example also illustrates the fact that LMPs can at times exceed the bid caps applied to generators. The overall impact of congestion is to increase LMPs at the load and decrease it at generator node 1. Thus, any loads located in generation pockets or export regions can actually see lower prices due to congestion while loads in load pockets or import regions see increased prices. The alternative to LMP would be to socialize the re-dispatch costs. In this example, Unit A’s output is reduced by 400 − 270 = 130 MW while Unit B’s output is increased by 180 − 50 = 130 MW. The net change in cost is characterized as re-dispatch cost and equals 130 × 30 − 20 = $1300. When spread over total demand in the system, this equals $2.88/MWh above the uncongested price. The difference between the two approaches can become even more significant when load is distributed across many locations. At first glance, it would appear that under LMP the price paid by the load increases. However, this is not necessarily the case once FTRs are considered. In this example, the difference between total payments by the load and total payments to generators equals $7200. These congestion rents can be used to exactly fund FTR allocations. The total FTRs made available must be simultaneously feasible (e.g., 270 MW of FTRs from node 1 to 3 and 180 MW from node 2 to 3). If all FTRs are held by the load, the effective price paid by the load drops to $/24MWh which happens to be the weighted average of the cost of running the two generators at nodes 1 and 2. Ironically, the introduction of LMP with FTRs lowers the price paid by the load to even less than the uncongested case and equal to what might be expected in a pay-asbid auction. This example illustrates that using congestion rents as a metric may overstate the impact that congestion has on actual load payments. It is also interesting that although single price auctions and LMP markets are sometimes criticized for increasing price shocks for customers, the combination of LMP and FTR markets may actually move an organized market closer to a pay-as-bid market. Although FTRs were able to hedge congestion entirely in this example, this is not true in general. For example, if any out-of-merit generation were required at node 3, it would be paid the higher LMP and these payments could not be hedged by FTRs. Nevertheless, the example illustrates how the elimination of congestion may not always lower effective prices seen by consumers which could add yet another challenge to the already complex process of transmission expansion.
EBL
Transmission Markets, Congestion Management, and Investment
161
4.4. Congestion Metrics Under cost-of-service regulation, utilities made transmission and generation investment trade-offs as a part of their integrated resource planning (IRP). Under a market paradigm, generation and transmission investment decisions are often made by different parties that must rely on transparent access to market data and prices. One metric that plays a significant role in transmission investment decisions is the magnitude of transmission congestion. Some of the metrics that have been used to measure congestion are as follows: • • •
Re-dispatch costs, Congestion rents or payments to FTR holders, Unhedgeable congestion costs.
Some metrics are directly observable from published LMPs while others require simulations of counter-factual scenarios as will be explained shortly. The term “re-dispatch” itself can be misleading when the system dispatch established in a day-ahead market already considers transmission constraints. There is inevitably some level of re-dispatch that must be performed in real time to account for constraints or changes in system conditions that were not already established. However, the term re-dispatch cost refers to the difference between the production cost implied by the actual system dispatch considering all transmission constraints and the production cost in a hypothetical scenario where no transmission constraints are binding. Although actual production costs of each generator may not be known, for the purposes of this metric the costs are assumed to equal offer prices submitted by generators. Since published LMPs are only calculated for the actual dispatch and they do not directly reveal offer prices, published market data does not lend itself to an easy calculation of re-dispatch costs. However, re-dispatch costs have traditionally been the metric of choice in transmission upgrade decisions. For example, the NYISO has used offline simulations to calculate re-dispatch costs. In 2003, re-dispatch costs in NYISO were estimated to be $85 million or approximately 1.5 per cent of total load billings. In 2004, the NYISO re-dispatch costs were estimated to be $72 million.23 These figures are smaller than what would be indicated by other metrics such as congestion rents. The congestion rent metric is widely used to report congestion and can be calculated from published market data. Ignoring the effect of losses, congestion rents are simply the difference between payments made by loads and exports and the revenues received by generators and imports. In the absence of congestion, all LMPs would be equal and congestion rents would be zero.24 They can also be calculated by adding up the products of the shadow prices and flows across all congested lines. The shadow price on a line equals the change in dispatch costs for a unit change in the capacity of the line. Ignoring any impact of revenue shortfalls due to transmission derates, congestion rents would also equal the payments made to FTR holders. Figure 4.7 shows congestion rents in a few selected markets. In 2003, congestion rents in NYISO were approximately $688 million, significantly higher than re-dispatch costs.
EBL
23
For more information on the New York ISO’s ongoing analysis of historic congestion costs, see http://www.nyiso.com/public/services/planning/congestion_cost.jsp 24 The incorporation of losses in LMPs would cause prices to vary even in the absence of congestion and result in a surplus similar to congestion rents. Unlike congestion rents that are used to fund FTRs, loss over-collections are refunded to grid users in some manner. Currently, NYISO and ISO-NE incorporate marginal losses in LMPs while PJM, MISO, and CAISO are working to implement them.
Competitive Electricity Markets
162
Total payments by load were approximately $6 billion. In PJM, congestion rents in 2005 were $2.09 billion. Total load billings were approximately $22.63 billion. Although total congestion costs in PJM increased significantly since 2000, they have ranged between 6 and 10 per cent of the total load billings with 2005 representing the peak year. Congestion rents are directly observable from LMPs which can make them a transparent metric that is easy to cite. However, the caveat is that while LMPs and congestion rents can direct attention to where transmission investment is needed, additional information may be required to make actual investment decisions. Unhedgeable congestion refers to the impact of congestion on load that cannot be hedged by FTRs. If FTRs are allocated to load, a part of the increase in LMPs due to congestion can be hedged. However, not all of the price increase can be hedged. For example, load in an import region such as New York City could hedge the price increase due to congestion for all of its imports using FTRs (also known as Transmission Congestion Contracts or TCCs in NYISO). However, it could not use TCCs to hedge the price increase for purchases from local in-city generation. This creates what is characterized as unhedgeable congestion. The greater the presence of out-of-merit local generation in load pockets, the greater the level of unhedgeable congestion. In contrast, if there is no out-of-merit generation in a load pocket, there is no unhedgeable congestion. According to PJM, unhedgeable congestion in 2005 was roughly $103 million, which is significantly smaller than the corresponding congestion rents. PJM’s definition of unhedgeable congestion also assumes any in-merit or economic local generation can serve as a hedge in addition to FTRs (Figs 4.7 and 4.8). At first glance the congestion metrics described above increased from 2000 to 2005 in both PJM and NYISO but the same does not appear to be the case for California. However, a closer examination reveals that the CAISO also reported significant intra-zonal congestion that was addressed using a variety of measures. In 2004, intra-zonal congestion was at its highest at approximately $426 million. It should also be noted that intra-zonal congestion costs are based on a re-dispatch cost metric and should not be compared to the congestion rent metric reported for inter-zonal congestion. Figure 4.9 shows intra-zonal congestion costs incurred under different categories of resources were used to resolve intra-zonal congestion in the CAISO markets. In contrast, inter-zonal congestion in the CAISO markets
EBL
Congestion costs
NYISO
PJM
CAISO
2000
$ (millions)
1500
1000
500
0 2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
Fig. 4.7. Congestion costs using the congestion rent metric across different markets. Increases in PJM congestion were partly attributable to the expansion of PJM’s footprint. Intra-zonal congestion for CAISO can be significant and is shown separately. Sources: NYISO, PJM, and CAISO.
Transmission Markets, Congestion Management, and Investment
163
3.5
PJM congestion costs 3.0
$/MWh
2.5 2.0 1.5 1.0 0.5 0.0 2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
Fig. 4.8. PJM congestion rents on a per unit basis. Source: PJM State of the market reports.
CAISO Intra-zonal congestion 500
MILCC
RMR
RT Redispatch
EBL
400
$ (millions)
103 300
49
200
100
46 27
274
78 0
2003
2004
36
17
72
80
114
119
2005
2006
Fig. 4.9. CAISO intra-zonal congestion costs. Besides real-time re-dispatch, the CAISO also dispatches units under Reliability Must Run (RMR) contracts or under a must-offer requirement that requires paying minimum load cost compensation (MLCC). Source: CAISO.
decreased after expansion of Path 15, a major transmission interface between northern and southern California. Another metric that is sometimes cited as a measure of congestion is the frequency of curtailments made under TLR procedures. TLRs are administrative curtailment procedures used by transmission providers when scheduled transactions cannot be accommodated. According to NERC data, the number of TLRs has increased annually since 1997 (Fig. 4.10). The number of TLRs requiring curtailment of firm transmission flows has also grown, from under 10 before 2001 to 70 in 2006. This increase is consistent with the rise in inter-regional
Competitive Electricity Markets
164 3000 2500 2000 1500 1000 500 0 1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
Fig. 4.10. Level 2 and higher TLRs in the eastern Interconnection. Source: NERC TLR logs.
trade and higher levels of transmission congestion. It may be a little surprising that TLRs continued to increase despite the expansion of organized markets (e.g., PJM, MISO) in the eastern Interconnection. Although TLRs are typically not needed within organized markets due to the availability of sufficient generation dispatch, they are used at the seams of organized markets, where power flows from outside the organized markets may have a substantial impact on particular flowgates. TLRs are not used in the western Interconnection, which uses a similar process known as the Unscheduled Flow Mitigation procedure. The Midwest ISO accounted for a significant percentage of TLRs in 2004. In 2005 after the introduction of LMP, the number of TLRs decreased only slightly but the quantity of curtailment in MWh decreased significantly. While increases in congestion metrics in LMP markets and the increase in TLRs both indicate increases in transmission congestion, the TLR trend is at least a little surprising since regions covered by LMP markets expanded during this period. Some of this increase could be a result of the increasingly complex seams created by expansion of some organized markets.
EBL
4.5. Financial Transmission Rights Presently, there are two major forms of transmission rights that exist in the United States – physical rights under Order 888 and financial rights available in organized markets that incorporate LMP or its variants. As noted, the allocation of transmission capacity via daily auctions in organized markets enables greater certainty in access to the grid. However, this comes at the cost of increased price risk due to the differences in LMPs across locations during congestion. FTRs offer the ability to hedge price risk due to congestion by giving their holders a financial revenue stream that can offset any congestion charges that apply (Hogan, 1992, 2002). In this sense, FTRs complement LMP markets to ensure that transmission service can be firm in both a physical and a financial sense. However, not all LMP markets incorporate FTRs. For example, New Zealand, which was one of the first international markets to implement LMP, has yet to implement any form of FTRs. Several design issues were addressed by stakeholders and FERC in the development of FTR markets. These include the very nature of the rights – e.g., should they be available
Transmission Markets, Congestion Management, and Investment
165
from any point or location in the grid to any other point or should they be restricted to physical interfaces or flowgates? One concern, noted in passing earlier, was that the point-to-point nature of FTRs as initially conceived might prove too illiquid to support a major expansion in forward market trading. An initial attempt to solve this problem was the zonal pricing concept. A second type of proposal focused not on zones but on highly congested transmission facilities, which were called “flowgates.”25 Proponents of flowgate rights argued that if a small set of critical flowgates could be defined, it might allow for more liquid secondary markets that some considered essential for the efficient allocation of FTRs (Chao and Peck, 1996; Chao et al., 2000). The debate was largely settled in favor of point-to-point rights although the simultaneous offering of flowgate rights has been considered a possibility (O’Neill et al., 2002). Two markets that implemented zonal FTRs akin to flowgate rights (because the zones were supposed to be on either “side” of highly congested paths) were California and Texas. Both markets are currently under redesign and will include point-to-point rights in the future.26 As noted, one concern expressed by market participants about point-to-point rights was that they could not be traded as easily in secondary markets. Such liquidity concerns were partially addressed by the development of trading hubs and zones. For example, FTRs can be purchased from a given generator in PJM to the PJM–West Hub. Similarly, FTRs can be purchased from one zone to another zone in NYISO. A significant design feature of FTR markets is the manner in which FTRs are initially made available to market participants. The two main approaches are (a) to first auction FTRs and then disburse the auction proceeds to some subset of market participants (e.g., to reduce access charges for all grid users), or (b) to first directly allocate auction revenue rights (ARRs) or FTRs to Load Serving Entities (LSEs), and then hold an auction to allow for valuation of the rights and reassignment. The approach of holding the auction first has been used at NYISO, ERCOT, and CAISO although that is changing under the market redesign.27 Figures 4.11 and 4.12 illustrate CAISO FTR auction results. In many instances revenues generated in FTR auctions far exceed the actual congestion or the revenues received by FTR holders. This has also been observed in FTR auctions in NYISO (Siddiqui et al., 2003). In some cases, firms purchasing FTRs also receive FTR auction revenues by virtue of being transmission owners. This needs to be considered in evaluating FTR auction results as a meaningful indicator of congestion. The hybrid approach that incorporates elements of auctions and direct allocations has become popular and its variants are in use at PJM, MISO, and ISO-NE. Under the hybrid approach, auction revenues are allocated to the LSEs that are holders of ARRs. Assuming that an LSE is allocated the appropriate set of ARRs, it can convert them into FTRs without worrying about the FTR auction price. The rules for allocating ARRs can vary across markets. In some markets such as MISO and PJM, the ARRs that an entity can request are linked to its historical loads and resources. In ISO-NE, an LSE may request an ARR that is linked not only to its load but also to every generator rather than a specific set of historical supply sources for that LSE. Such administrative rules for ARR allocation are
EBL
25
Note that this definition of flowgates is not the same as the NERC definition used for purposes of monitoring facilities over which TLRs may be called. 26 The CAISO is expected to introduce LMP markets under its MRTU (Market Redesign Technology Update) program in 2008. 27 Under MRTU, the CAISO will directly allocate Congestion Revenue Rights (CRRs) to load serving entities based on their peak demand and historical supply sources.
Competitive Electricity Markets
166
FTR auction
CAISO FTR auctions
Congestion
200 Each year is April 1 - March 31 2006–07 congestion data is thru Sept
$ (millions)
150
100
50
0 2000–01
2001–02
2002–03
2003–04
2004–05
2005–06
2006–07
Fig. 4.11. CAISO FTR auction revenues and payments to FTR holders. With the exception of the initial auction, payments for purchasing FTRs have been less than congestion revenues. In some cases FTR auction prices may be unreliable as companies that bid for FTRs end up receiving FTR revenues as transmission owners. Source: CAISO.
2004 FTR auction revenue ($) 68,925 23,769,646
2004 FTR auction MW 355 Utilities
EBL
Merchants, Traders and retailers Munis
5,592
Utilities 5,544
Merchants, Traders and retailers Munis
77,499,873
Fig. 4.12. Distribution of CAISO FTR in 2004. Utilities in California still serve a majority of the load but hold roughly half the auctioned quantity of FTRs. However, utilities account for a much higher percentage of revenues paid in the FTR auctions. Source: CAISO.
necessary to preclude every market participant from requesting the same set of ARRs on a transmission path that is deemed valuable. However, even with administrative allocation rules, not all ARR requests between specific resources and loads may be feasible due to excessive nominations on congested transmission paths and some degree of pro-rationing on such paths may be necessary. Market participants that were accustomed to physical rights under Order 888 did not always adapt easily to the financial rights approach in organized markets. One feature of physical rights that has been cited as useful was their “use it or lose it” property. In other words, holding a right that is not used does not cost anything although it may not be worth anything either. In contrast, FTRs provide revenues even if transmission service is not actually taken or does not actually match the FTR. However, FTRs can also become obligations if the direction of congestion changes. This has caused market participants to express a desire for option FTRs (Hogan, 2002). Figure 4.13 illustrates the properties of obligation and option FTRs. In general, issuing option FTRs reduces the total number of FTRs that can be awarded. Additionally, there are differences in the properties of the two types of FTRs. For example, an obligation FTR from node A to node B can be broken up
Transmission Markets, Congestion Management, and Investment
Payoff
167
Payoff {pb − pa}
max{0, pb − pa}
Pb-Pa
Obligations (pb − pa) = (phub − pa) + (pb − phub) (pb − pa) = −(pa − pb)
Pb-Pa
Options max(0, pb − pa) ≠ max(0, phub − pa) + max(0, pb − phub) max(0, pb − pa) = −max(0, pa − pb)
Fig. 4.13. Payoffs for obligations and option FTRs.
into an obligation FTR from node A to a hub and an obligation FTR from the hub to node B. This is not the case for option FTRs. Some markets such as PJM offer both option and obligation FTRs. Although the initial allocation of FTRs is done by ensuring that they are simultaneously feasible, there can be instances when subsequent derates in the transmission system cause some FTRs to be infeasible. In such instances, payouts for FTRs can be reduced or, alternatively, an uplift charge can be collected to ensure FTRs are fully funded once they have been allocated. Some markets such as PJM have yet to implement fully funded FTRs while others such as NYISO already do so. Assuming FTRs are fully funded, the allocation of uplifts to cover shortfalls and ensure full funding can become a contentious issue. One approach allocates the shortfall to transmission owners responsible for managing transmission outages. Critics of this approach argue that causes of the shortfall may extend beyond the responsibilities of the transmission owner. Figures 4.14 and 4.15 illustrate the magnitude of shortfalls in PJM and NYISO. With the exception of NYISO, FTR implementations have thus far been limited to annual rights. While congestion patterns and the contractual obligations of market participants change, the ability to readjust FTR positions annually is not necessarily a negative. However, uncertainty in being able to procure the desired quantities of FTRs has raised concerns about the lack of long-term FTRs. With a renewed focus on long-term contracting, attention has turned to making long-term FTRs available in all organized markets. The issue gained such prominence that there was a specific provision in EPACT 2005 that specifically required FERC to make long-term FTRs available in organized markets.28 FERC’s Order 681 specifies a set of guidelines that must be met in implementing longterm FTRs (FERC, 2006b). In addition to requiring that the long-term FTRs have a sufficient
EBL
28
Under EPACT 2005, a new Section 217(b)(4) of the Federal Power Act provides: “The Commission shall exercise the authority of the Commission under this Act in a manner that facilitates the planning and expansion of transmission facilities to meet the reasonable needs of load-serving entities to satisfy the service obligations of the load-serving entities to secure firm transmission rights (or equivalent tradable and financial rights) on a long-term basis for long-term power supply arrangements made, or planned, to meet such needs.”
Competitive Electricity Markets
168 100.0%
80.0%
60.0%
40.0%
FTR Credit Percentage Planning Pd Percent 2003–04 97.7% 2004–05 100.0% 2005–06 90.7% 2006–07* 100.0%
Note: The monthly percentages include distribution of Excess Charges and may change for months in the 2006/07 planning period if excess charges are collected in the remainder of the planning period.
* through November 2006
20.0%
0.0% Jun- Sep- Dec- Mar- Jun- Sep- Dec- Mar- Jun- Sep- Dec- Mar- Jun- Sep03 03 03 04 04 04 04 05 05 05 05 06 06 06
Fig. 4.14. FTR payouts in PJM. Although there have been some months where the payouts for FTR holders have been reduced significantly, the annual average payout has remained above 90 per cent. Source: PJM.
NYISO TCC Revenue shortfall 8000
TCC Payments
DA Congestion rents
EBL
7000
$ (millions)
6000 5000 4000 3500 2000 100 0 2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
Fig. 4.15. TCC payouts in NYISO. The difference between congestion rents and TCC payouts is collected using an uplift charge. Source: NYISO.
term to satisfy the needs of long-term contracting, the guidelines also touch upon many of the policy debates that occurred in designing annual FTRs. For example, long-term FTRs must be point-to-point, fully funded and available to LSEs without participating in an auction and be reassignable as load shifts between LSEs. The guidelines also require that long-term FTRs be made available for upgrades although this is one feature that is already available in most organized markets.
Transmission Markets, Congestion Management, and Investment
169
4.6. Transmission Investment Transmission can be both a complement to and a substitute for generation, i.e., transmission is necessary to serve load from distant generation but can also sometimes be substituted by building local generation. There are several major differences between transmission and generation. For example, a major driver behind the transition to competitive markets in generation was the argument that generation is no longer a natural monopoly with large economies of scale that requires construction of large power plants. In contrast, much of the transmission sector is still considered a natural monopoly with significant economies of scale. There are some exceptions particularly with Flexible AC Transmission Systems (FACTS) and High Voltage DC (HVDC) technology that can lend themselves to merchant transmission projects. Another difference between transmission and generation is that transmission contributes a relatively smaller portion of retail electric bills compared to generation. This means that even significant transmission investment may only amount to a relatively small increase in the ultimate cost to the retail customer and may lower the cost of generation resulting in a net saving.29 This has sometimes been used as an argument to build up the high-voltage transmission system much like the interstate highway system was. However, siting new transmission projects is not easy due to regulatory and environmental concerns. 4.6.1. Trends in transmission investment There are a few different dimensions to the issue of transmission investment. Perhaps the most significant is the question of overall investment in transmission. Considerable attention has been given to declining investment in transmission infrastructure (Hirst, 2004; Joskow, 2005). As shown in Fig. 4.16, normalized transmission capacity in terms of MWmile per MW demand across all regions declined from 1989 through 2002. According to a survey by the Edison Electric Institute (EEI), overall transmission investment declined from 1975 to 1999 but has been increasing in recent years for both vertically integrated utilities and ITCs (EEI, 2005). Figure 4.17 illustrates in the increase in transmission investment based on an EEI survey of vertically integrated and stand-alone transmission companies. From 2000 through 2005, approximately $28 billion were invested in the US transmission system. From 2006 through 2009, an additional $31 billion is planned, representing a 60 per cent increase over the prior three-year period. More than 70 per cent of the roughly 150,000 miles of high-voltage transmission lines are estimated to be older than 25 years (Anderson et al., 2006). Declines in transmission investment have been attributed to several factors. These include a higher focus on generation with the creation of markets, challenges in transmission siting and obtaining rights of way, regulatory uncertainty, possible over-investment in earlier periods, and location of smaller generating units closer to load centers. At the same time, inter-regional usage of transmission and congestion has undoubtedly increased, putting greater pressure on the grid. One factor that may have contributed to declines in transmission investment was the focus on generation as that sector of the business was transitioning to a market paradigm. The higher pace of investment in generation relative to transmission was particularly
EBL
29
According to an FERC study on transmission congestion in 2001, transmission costs are roughly 6 per cent in contrast to generation costs of 74 per cent and distribution costs of 20 per cent in the average retail bill.
Competitive Electricity Markets
170
Normalized transmission capacity 250 200 150 100
2002
2001
2000
1999
1998
1997
1996
1995
1994
1993
1992
1991
0
1990
50
1989
MW-mi/MW demand
300
Fig. 4.16. Normalized transmission capacity across all NERC regions. Source: NERC, Hirst 2004.
7000
Transmission investment 6000
(2005$)millions
5000
EBL
4000 3000 2000 1000 0 2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
Fig. 4.17. Actual transmission investment from 2000 to 2005. Source: EEI (2006).
evident during the generation boom period shown in Fig. 4.18. The potential of high unregulated returns on generation investments seemed more attractive than investing in regulated transmission, particularly when there were uncertainties on the structure of the transmission business. However, since the merchant generation meltdown and bankruptcies of many unregulated generation companies, investments in regulated transmission at incentive rates may not appear as unattractive for the levels of risk involved. Another factor in play was the regulatory uncertainty with respect to transmission which has since improved with greater clarity on transmission structures. From a fundamental’s perspective, even though inter-regional trade has increased significantly with the creation of markets, new smaller generating plants can now be located closer to load centers than older larger base-load units. The availability of adequate transmission can sometimes make generation markets more competitive and has been cited as a factor that
Transmission Markets, Congestion Management, and Investment
171
Percent change over year end 1998 20%
Percent
15%
Generation plant construction (MW)
10%
Transmission investment ($)
5%
0% 1999
2000
2001
2002
Fig. 4.18. Difference between generation and transmission investment.
should be considered in expansion decisions (California ISO, 2004). All these factors need to be considered together in determining the optimal level of transmission investment going forward. As explained earlier in the chapter, simply quoting congestion rent metrics in LMP markets may not always be the right predictor of new transmission needs. In some cases, transmission cost allocation methodologies can also create opposition to transmission expansion proposals. For example, the expansion of a transmission bottleneck may increase prices in an exporting region. If costs of the expansion are allocated on a regional basis, customers in the exporting region may feel they have to pay for price increases. Investment trends in transmission may be further differentiated between ITCs and vertically integrated utilities. Proponents of ITCs present several arguments as to why ITCs may be better positioned than vertically integrated utilities when it comes to transmission investment. For example, an ITC has a singular focus on transmission, which eliminates competition between generation and transmission. They argue that an ITC does not have the perverse incentive to maintain congestion for protecting generation market share. According to the International Transmission Company, the Midwest ISO’s most recent transmission expansion plan has ITCs accounting for approximately 54 per cent of the $2.9 billion of transmission investment projected through 2009. The average ITC investment is at about seven times that for a non-ITC in MISO. Proponents of ITCs offer this statistic as evidence of their arguments on why ITCs may be better positioned than vertically integrated utilities to focus on transmission investment. Transmission planning has also witnessed significant changes in the transition to competitive markets. Historically, transmission and generation investment were often considered substitutes and lumped together under integrated resource planning by utilities. The separation of transmission and generation ownership has made this task more challenging. At the same time, there have also been positive changes as the larger footprints of RTOs and ITCs make the task of regional transmission planning easier. Some degree of coordination between generation and transmission investment is also captured in the generator interconnection procedures used by transmission organizations. For example, any new generator in PJM needs to satisfy certain deliverability criteria and
EBL
172
Competitive Electricity Markets
is responsible for transmission upgrades that may be needed to satisfy this requirement.30 Such efforts are only now beginning to reach a level of maturity that can make it possible to accurately assess how well they are functioning (California ISO, 2006; PJM, 2006; ISO-NE, 2004 ISO-NE, 2006; NYISO, 2006).
4.6.2. The merchant transmission model Although most transmission investments to date have been made under a regulated cost of service approach, there are also so-called merchant or market-based transmission projects (Rotger and Felder, 2001). Merchant transmission projects rely on market rates for transmission service negotiated directly with purchasers of their capacity, and assume (along with the purchasers of their capacity) all of the market risk for their facilities. Transmission projects can often be lumpy and exhibit large economies of scale that do not always lend themselves to a merchant investment model, though there are exceptions such as FACTS and HVDC technology. Some AC projects using variable frequency transformers may also qualify. While it is typical for merchant transmission projects to involve an open season for their capacity, in theory a project could also be truly merchant and simply offer its capacity to users at market-based rates. In organized RTO markets that use financial rights, FTRs or ARRs are created by a merchant project and some analysts thought initially that such rights would provide a significant component of the project’s forecast revenue stream (with the remainder coming from bilateral contracts to reserve capacity on the transmission facility). However, in case of a lumpy investment, the award of FTRs may have little value if congestion is entirely eliminated. In principle, transmission merchant transmission capacity could be treated as dispatchable in the same manner as generation is dispatchable, i.e., portions of a merchant transmission line would become available only if the price spread across the line exceeds an offer price (O’Neill et al., 2005). The dispatchable transmission paradigm can also be used to relax normal line ratings for short periods under emergency conditions (e.g., it may be less expensive to temporarily expand a line rating and compensate its owner for a short interval instead of re-dispatching more expensive generation). However, reasonable rules for market power mitigation could prove a challenge before any such proposals are implemented. In addition to price signals and incentives for transmission investment, there are other factors that influence transmission investment decisions. These factors include transmission pricing and cost allocation, inter-regional planning, and challenges in siting and obtaining rights of way. Despite the presence of these various factors that make a direct correlation between LMP implementation and transmission investment difficult, there are several instances where market prices have played a role in encouraging transmission projects. Specific examples in the northeast are the Neptune and Cross-sound cable projects that have helped expand the transmission capability into Long Island in
EBL
30
PJM determines the sufficiency of network transfer capability through a series of “deliverability tests.” This includes the Capacity Emergency Transfer Objective (CETO) and Capacity Emergency Transfer Limit (CETL) tests to check if energy from the aggregate of PJM resources can be delivered to capacity deficient sub-regions within PJM. CETO represents the amount of energy a sub-area must be able to import in order to comply with reliability standards. The test is passed if the actual CETL exceeds the CETO. Generators must satisfy the deliverability test in order to be classified as “capacity resources.” PJM’s Reliability Pricing Model (RPM) has taken further steps to make generation capacity planning assumptions consistent with those used in transmission planning.
Transmission Markets, Congestion Management, and Investment
173
Table 4.7. Merchant transmission projects Project
Description
Expected completion
Neptune
600 MW HVDC submarine cable linking New Jersey (PJM) and Long Island (NYISO)
Completed in summer 2007
Cross Sound Cable
330 MW HVDC submarine cable linking Connecticut (ISO-NE) and Long Island (NYISO)
Completed in 2002, first operated in 2003
Montana-Alberta Tie
300 MW, 230 kV line linking Lethbridge, Alberta and Great Falls, Montana
Open season in 2005
Seabreeze Power
550 MW HVDC submarine cable linking Vancouver Island and Port Angeles, WA.
Open season in 2005
Northern Lights
Three 3000 MW HVDC links connecting Alberta to Pacific northwest and Wyoming/Montana to the southwest
Proposed in 2005, expected to be fully committed in 2009
Linden Variable Frequency Three 100 MW VFTs connecting generation at Successful open season Transformer Linden in PJM to the Goethals substation in results in 2007, Staten Island in New York City operation expected in December 2009
New York.31 Although the CAISO has yet to implement full LMP, it has had zonal prices since 1998 that reflected significant congestion and influenced the expansion of a major transmission bottleneck called Path 15.32 Another example of merchant transmission investments includes the Sea Breeze proposal to build a 550 MW undersea cable between Vancouver Island and Port Angeles, Washington State. Table 4.7 lists major merchant projects that have been proposed or implemented so far.
EBL
31
The Neptune Project involves the installation of an approximately 600 MW (500 kV) fully controllable high-voltage, 65-mile direct current (HVDC) submarine electric transmission cable connecting power generation resources in New Jersey to electricity consumers in Long Island. Construction began in 2005 and the project was completed in summer 2007. The Cross Sound Cable (CSC) is a 24-mile, 330 MW high-voltage direct current (HVDC) submarine transmission system linking the electricity grids of New England and Long Island. The project was completed in 2002 but operations started only after the August 14, 2003 Blackout on an emergency basis, stopped again after protests by the Connecticut Attorney General and finally started after an agreement was reached in 2004. The CSC is currently owned by Babcock and Brown Infrastructure, an infrastructure investment fund based in Australia. The entire capacity for both projects is under contract to the Long Island Power Authority (LIPA). 32 Path 15 is a system of three 500 kV transmission lines that narrows down to two lines for an 83-mile stretch through California’s Central Valley. The Path 15 upgrade project added a third line to that segment and upgrades several major transmission substations that are part of Path 15. Completed in December 2004, the upgrades added 1500 MW of transmission capacity to the existing 3950 MW capacity between southern and northern California. The project involved a consortium between independent transmission entity Trans-elect, Pacific Gas and Electric (PG&E) and the Western Area Power Administration. The California energy crisis highlighted the need to relieve congestion caused by Path 15 (estimated by the CAISO at $221.7 million in additional energy costs for consumers between September 1, 1999 and December 31, 2000.) In May 2001, Secretary of Energy Spencer Abraham directed Western to explore an upgrade and to determine whether non-Federal parties would be interested in helping finance and co-own the system additions. The partnership with Trans-elect and PG&E resulted from this effort.
174
Competitive Electricity Markets
4.6.3. Factors influencing regulated transmission investment and other developments Cost allocation for non-merchant transmission projects can also be important in investment decisions. The approaches range from postage stamp to license plate, rolled-in socialization to more targeted allocations based on benefits of projects and hybrid approaches that socialize costs of high-voltage facilities but use more targeted approaches for local investments.33 Cost allocation for transmission needed for renewable resources such as wind are also evolving.34 The challenges in transmission investment were recognized by Congress in EPACT 2005 and there are several new initiatives underway to address this issue (the major elements are listed in Box 4.2) These include backstop siting authority for FERC, the designation of National Interest Electric Transmission (NIET) Corridors, and new incentives for transmission under a recently issued FERC rule. The US Department of Energy completed an initial study in October 2006 that found two areas of critical congestion – southern California and the Atlantic coast from New York City to northern Virginia. These areas were the basis for formal designation of two NIET corridors in April 2007. The two areas are the Mid-Atlantic area corridor and the southwest area corridor.35 EPACT 2005 created for the first time federal eminent domain for electric transmission although this authority is supplemental to and does not preempt state law except in four narrow situations. FERC can permit and condemn right-of-way for construction of an electric transmission line provided that: •
the state where the line is to be located lacks siting authority or state law prohibits siting to achieve interstate benefits; • the permit applicant is not eligible for site approval because it does not provide retail service in the state; • the state with siting authority fails to act on an application within one year; or • the state siting body attaches conditions that will prevent congestion reduction or make the new line economically infeasible.
EBL
Procedures for permitting construction of transmission lines in NIET corridors are described in Order 689 (FERC, 2006d). Section 1241 of EPACT 2005 added a new section 219 to the Federal Power Act that required FERC to establish incentive-based rate treatments that promote capital investment in transmission of electric energy in interstate commerce, regardless of the ownership of the facilities; provide a return on equity (ROE) that attracts new investment in transmission facilities (including related transmission technologies); encourage deployment of transmission technologies and other measures to increase the capacity and efficiency of existing transmission facilities and improve the operation of the facilities. Order 679 modified by Order 679A fulfills that directive (FERC, 2006a). Order 679 establishes a higher incentive-based ROE for investments that enhance reliability and/or reduce congestion. The rule also offers incentive-based rate treatments to encourage ITC/Transco formation and membership in RTOs/ISOs or other approved transmission organizations. 33
See, e.g., 119 FERC ¶ 61,063 Opinion No. 494, PJM Interconnection, L.L.C. Docket Nos. EL05-121-000 and EL05-121-002, 19 April 2007. 34 See 119 FERC ¶ 61,061 California ISO, Docket EL07-33-000, Order granting petition for declaratory order, April 19, 2007. 35 Further details on the NIET corridors can be found at http://nietc.anl.gov/indexnew.cfm
Transmission Markets, Congestion Management, and Investment
175
Box 4.2 Elements of Energy Policy Act of 2005 Major elements of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 related to Transmission • • • • • •
Creation of Incentives for Transmission Investment – FERC Order 679 Creation of long-term transmission rights in organized markets – FERC Order 681 Repeal of Public Utility Holding Company Act (PUHCA) Designation of National Interest Electric Transmission Corridors Federal backstop siting authority for electric transmission – FERC Order 689 Mandatory Standards for Reliability
The rule also contains other incentives such as allowing 100 per cent Construction Work in Progress (CWIP) in rate-base, recognizing the long lead times involved in transmission projects. The rule does not dismiss the recovery of acquisition premiums in incentive rates but suggests a case-by-case approach to evaluate such proposals. Order 679A reaffirmed the proposals in Order 679 but added certain clarifications. For example, the review process for a project must specifically show that the project is needed for reliability or reduces congestion. FERC would also not routinely grant incentive rates at the top end of the zone of reasonableness and applicants would need to justify a higher ROE. The major elements of Order 679 are listed in Box 4.3.36
EBL
Box 4.3 Key Provisions of FERC Order 679 Key provisions of FERC Transmission Incentives Rule Order 679 • • • • • • • •
Incentive rates of return on equity for new transmission investment Full recovery of prudently incurred construction work in progress Full recovery of prudently incurred pre-operations costs Full recovery of prudently incurred costs of abandoned transmission facilities Use of hypothetical capital structures Accumulated deferred income taxes for stand-alone transmission companies Accelerated depreciation Deferred cost recovery for utilities that cannot pass-through costs of new transmission investments due to retail rate freezes • Higher rates of return on equity for utilities that join and/or continue to be members of transmission organizations, including (but not limited to) RTOs and ISOs
36
Several transmission projects have been granted incentive rates under Order 679, see e.g., Baltimore Gas and Electric Docket No ER07-576-000, 121 FERC 61, 167 and Southern California Edison, Docket No EL07-62-000, 121 FERC 61, 168 November 17, 2007.
176
Competitive Electricity Markets
Finally, the Public Utility Holding Company Act (PUHCA) of 1935 was enacted by Congress in response to the collapse of a few large companies that controlled significant generation and transmission assets during the Great Depression. PUHCA split up the companies and imposed restrictions on utilities operating in more than one state. It limited US electric utilities to a single geographic region in which integrated operation was feasible and prohibited utility ownership of businesses that were not reasonably incidental or functionally related to the utility business. PUHCA was viewed by many as impeding investment in transmission companies in more than one region. Under PUHCA, mergers and acquisitions by holding companies were confined to interconnected areas or regions although “virtual interconnection” arguments have been used at times to justify mergers of companies not physically contiguous. The geographic requirement of PUHCA was considered counter-intuitive with respect to addressing generation market power by encouraging mergers between adjacent markets. PUHCA also restricted non-utilities from directly owning and controlling utilities. With its repeal, private equity and other financial investors are expected to enter the sector more easily. This is a significant development given the increasingly active role played by private equity.
4.7. Conclusions After a decade of transmission open access, transmission markets in the United States appear to have reached a certain level of maturity. Two distinct models co-exist in different parts of the country: Order 888-based markets and organized RTO markets. Although organized RTO markets were initially seen as an evolution of the older Order 888 regime, there is recognition that the two are likely to continue to co-exist for some time. Consequently, there have been efforts to further reform Order 888-based markets within that paradigm. There are also some RTO markets that have chosen to operate Order 888 markets. There is recognition that despite the many advantages that organized markets might offer, they too have room for improvement such as the development of long-term transmission rights. On the structural and investment front, the early debate on whether for-profit or nonprofit grid operators made more sense has been largely replaced by the question of independent transmission companies versus vertically integrated utilities. Overall investment in transmission, which suffered in comparison to generation for many years, appears to have turned a corner. The growth of RTO footprints and maturity in planning processes and incentives in EPACT are all likely to be positive influences in this area. Investments under the merchant transmission model have been somewhat limited. There have been significant increases in transparent market data on congestion albeit there are many different metrics in use across regions. Even though there is some degree of consensus that transmission investment has not kept pace with the growth in generation and demand, using the wrong congestion metric can artificially inflate the levels of transmission investment that may be required.
EBL
4.8. Acknowledgment The author would like to thank Udi Helman and Perry Sioshansi for providing useful comments.
Transmission Markets, Congestion Management, and Investment
177
References Anderson, K., Furey, D., and Omar, K. (2006). Frayed wires: US transmission system shows its age. Fitch Rat., Special Report, 25 October. Adib, P. and Zarnikau, J. (2006). Texas: The most robust competitive market in North America. In Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective (F.P. Sioshansi and W. Pfaffenberger, eds). Elsevier. California ISO (2004). Transmission Economic Assessment Methodology (TEAM), June. California ISO (2004a). Annual Report on Market Performance, 2005. California ISO (2006). 2005 Annual Report on Market Performance, April 2006. Casazza, J. (1993). The Development of Electric Power Transmission. IEEE Press. Chandley, J.D. and Hogan, W.W. (2002). Independent transmission companies in a regional transmission organization. Harvard University, Cambridge, MA, 8 January. Chao, H. and Peck, S. (1996). A Market mechanism for electric power transmission. J. of Reg. Econ., 10(1), 25–60. Chao, H., Peck, S., Oren, S., and Wilson, R. (2000). Flow-based transmission rights and congestion management. Elec. J., October, 38–58. Department of Energy (DOE) (2006). National Electric Transmission Congestion Study Report, August. Edison Electric Institute (EEI) (2005). EEI Survey of Transmission Investment, May. Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) (1996). Promoting Wholesale Competition through Open Access Non-discriminatory Transmission Services by Public Utilities; Recovery of Stranded Costs by Public Utilities and Transmitting Utilities. Order No. 888, 61 FR 21540, 10 May. Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) (1996a). Open Access Same-Time Information System. Order No. 889, 61 FR 21, 737, 10 May. Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) (1999). Regional Transmission Organizations. Order No. 2000, Docket RM-99-2-000, FERC ¶ 61,285, 20 December. Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) (2006). Promoting Investment Through Pricing Reform. Order 679, Docket No. RM06-4-001, FERC ¶ 31,222, 31 July. Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) (2006a). Long-Term Firm Transmission Rights in Organized Electricity Markets. Order No. 681, Docket No. RM06-8-001, FERC ¶ 31,226, 1 August. Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) (2006b). Rules Concerning Certification of the Electric Reliability Organization; Procedures for the Establishment, Approval and Enforcement of Electric Reliability Standards. Order No. 672, 71 FR 8662, 17 February. Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) (2006c). Mandatory Reliability Standards for the Bulk Power System. (Docket No. RM06-16-000), 20 October. Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) (2006d). Regulations for Filing Applications for Permits to Site Interstate Electric Transmission Facilities. (Docket No. RM06-12-000), 16 November. Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) (2007). Preventing Undue Discrimination and Preference in Transmission Service. Order No. 890, Docket Nos. RM05-25-000 and RM05-17-000, 16 February. Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) (2007a). Mandatory Reliability Standards for the Bulk Power System. Order No. 693, Docket No. RM06-16-000, 17 March. Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) (2007b). Order on Violation Risk Factors. Docket No. RR07-9-000 and RR07-10-000, 18 May. Harvey, S. and Hogan, W. (2002). Loss hedging financial transmission rights. In School of Government (J.F. Kennedy ed.) Harvard University, Cambridge, MA, 15 January. Henney, A. and Russell, T. (2002). Lessons From The Institutional Framework Of Transmission, System Operation, and Energy Markets In Most West European Countries and Some Other Countries – The Case for Transcos. Docket No. RM 01-12-00, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission. Hirst, E. (2004). U.S. Transmission Capacity: Present Status and Future Prospects. Edison Electric Institute, June. Hogan, W.W. (1992). Contract networks for electric power transmission. J. of Reg. Econ., 4(3), 211–42. Hogan, W.W. (2002). Financial Transmission Right Formulations Report. Harvard University, Cambridge, MA, March 2002. ISO-New England (2004). Regional Transmission Expansion Plan (RTEP04) Technical report, 21 October.
EBL
178
Competitive Electricity Markets
ISO-New England (2006). 2006 Regional System Plan. October. Joskow, P. (2005). Patterns of transmission investment. MIT, March. NERC (2006). Long Term Reliability Assessment. http://www.nerc.com/∼filez/rasreports.html NYISO (2006). Comprehensive Reliability Plan. August. O’Neill, R., Helman, U., Hobbs, B., Benjamin, F., Stewart, Jr., W.R., and Rothkopf, M.H. (2002). A joint energy and transmission rights auction: Proposal and properties. IEEE Trans. on Pow. Sys., 17(4), 1058–67. O’Neill, R., Baldick, R., Helman, U., Rothkopf, M., and Stewart, Jr., W.R., (2005). Dispatchable transmission in RTO markets. IEEE Trans. on Pow. Sys., 20(1), 171–9. PJM (2006). Regional Transmission Expansion Plan. February. PJM (2006a). Annual State of the Markets Report, April. Rajaraman, R. and Alvarado, F. (1998). Inefficiencies of NERC’s transmission loading relief procedures. Elec. J., October. Rotger, J. and Felder, F., (2001). Promoting efficient transmission investment: The role of the market in expanding transmission infrastructure. November 2001. Rudkevich, A, Hausman, E., Tabors, R., Bagnall, J., and Kopel, C. (2005). Loss hedging rights: A final piece in the LMP Puzzle. Proceedings of the 38th Hawaii International Conference on System Sciences. Ruff, L. (2002). Defining and allocating RTO functions. FERC Technical Conference on RTO Functions and Characteristics, Washington DC, 19 February. Ruff, L. (2006). The missing markets: What they are (not) and what (if anything) to do about it. Harvard Electricity Policy Group, La Jolla, California, 2 March. Siddiqui, A.S., Bartholomew, E., Marnay, C., and Oren, S.S. (2003). On the efficiency of the New York Independent System Operator market for transmission congestion contracts. Working Paper, University of California, Berkeley. Singh, H. (2005). Incentives for transmission. RTO Governance Conference, Washington DC, 31 March. Sweeney, J. (2006). California electricity restructuring, the crisis, and its aftermath. In Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective (F.P. Sioshansi and W. Pfaffenberger, eds). Elsevier. Wood, A.J. and Wollenberg, B. (1996). Power Generation, Operation and Control. New York: John Wiley and Sons.
EBL
Chapter 5 The Design of US Wholesale Energy and Ancillary Service Auction Markets: Theory and Practice UDI HELMAN,1 BENJAMIN F. HOBBS,2 AND RICHARD P. O’NEILL1 1
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, Washington, DC, USA; Department of Geography and Environmental Engineering, The Johns Hopkins University, Baltimore, MD, USA
2
Summary
EBL
In the United States, after about a decade of experience with market design, wholesale spot markets operated by Independent System Operators (ISOs) around the country have largely converged on core design elements. This chapter provides a detailed description of how these markets operate. In particular, most of these markets have day-ahead and real-time auction markets for energy and certain ancillary services, typically regulation and operating reserves. The energy auctions can accommodate both physical and virtual supply offers and demand bids. In the regulation and reserve auctions, only physical offers are currently allowed, including those from dispatchable demand. With the submitted day-ahead offers, bids, and non-price schedules, the ISO conducts a security-constrained unit commitment auction, which selects the generation units that will run for every hour of the day subject to all relevant unit and transmission network constraints. For the energy markets, the auction outcome is two sets of prices that together clear the market: locational marginal prices (LMPs) for energy, which include congestion and loss components, and separate payments to ensure revenue sufficiency for any offer or bid costs, such as generation start-up costs, not recovered through LMPs. The real-time energy markets have also progressively incorporated most elements of this design, although auction procedures are somewhat different from the day-ahead market. Integrated into the day-ahead and real-time energy markets are markets for regulation and operating reserves, co-optimized with energy. Market prices for these ancillary services typically incorporate an opportunity cost payment with respect to any foregone energy sales as well as availability payments, if needed. As with energy, revenue sufficiency is guaranteed through additional payments. To provide insight into each stage of the market and into the principles of locational marginal pricing, the chapter provides 179
180
Competitive Electricity Markets
a simple numerical example of an energy auction on an electricity network. Finally, the chapter briefly explores other key design issues, such as refunds of surplus marginal congestion and loss payments, market power monitoring and mitigation, addressing continuing market seams, software development, and extensions of the market design.
5.1. Introduction In the UNITED STATES, wholesale markets for electric power have evolved along two basic organizational approaches, both consistent with the open access transmission regime established by the US Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) in 1996 (FERC, 1996a). In the first type of market, electric utilities and non-utility generators contract bilaterally among themselves for energy on a forward basis. The utilities that own the transmission facilities determine the available quantity and price of transmission access and physical scheduling rights, subject to open access rules. While private power exchanges may form to facilitate forward energy contracting, there is no co-ordinated spot energy market that encompasses the territory of multiple utilities and heretofore no price-based congestion management. In the second type of market, an independent third-party entity, which for purposes of this chapter will be called an Independent System Operator (ISO), operates organized regional bid-based auction markets for spot energy, various types of ancillary services, and possibly capacity, and allocates all transmission capacity and transmission property rights in an efficient and non-discriminatory fashion. Spot transmission usage is subject to charges for congestion and losses. These ISO markets are the subject of this chapter. The chapter will focus on the design of the daily energy, regulation, and operating reserves markets. The chapter will not review ISO market performance, except on occasion to explain a design decision.1
EBL
5.1.1. Overview of Market Design The ISO market designs that have arisen in different regions of the United States have similarities and differences, resulting from the fairly high degree of regional decisionmaking in the regulatory reform of the US electricity sector.2 In general, the ISO operates a day-ahead market and a real-time, or dispatch, market. These are organized as sealedbid, multiple-unit auction markets. The day-ahead market is a forward market in which accepted offers or bids can choose not to perform in real-time (i.e., go to physical delivery) as long as they buy back or sell back their positions. Put another way, the real-time market determines the prices of “deviations” from the day-ahead schedule. Due both to financial incentives and certain administrative rules discussed below, most accepted day-ahead offers and bids that reflect physical supply and demand do go to physical delivery and hence the two markets collectively can be thought of as the “spot” market. In both markets, suppliers submit offers prior to a trading deadline (usually the prior morning for the day-ahead market and about 1 hour before the real-time market). These 1 Market performance is discussed extensively in the US ISO annual state of the markets reports, e.g., PJM 2006a, Potomac Economics 2003–2006 (for New York ISO). In addition, there is a large research literature on this subject. 2 The evolution of US federal rulemaking, including the failed effort to standardize the market designs, is discussed in O’Neill et al. (2006) and O’Neill and Helman (2007).
Design of US Wholesale Energy and Ancillary Service Auction Markets
181
offers must usually specify the minimum and maximum MW that can be produced by the generator, the price of energy ($/MWh) over the range of its available output, a start-up cost ($), a no-load cost ($), and a number of physical characteristics, such as how rapidly the generator can increase or decrease output (called the “ramp rate” and measured in MW/minute). For operating reserves and regulation, suppliers typically provide additional price offers and physical parameters to define capability. Both the day-ahead and real-time auctions conduct “security constrained unit commitment,” in that they specify exactly which generation units should be turned on in each hour, their level of output, and the length of time they should run over the day, based on start-up and energy offer prices and the other financial and physical parameters and transmission network constraints. In the day-ahead market, the unit commitment decision is integrated into the auction. In real-time, unit commitment is conducted through a parallel pre-auction program that “looks-ahead” based on a forecast to determine which units to commit or decommit, while the auction function only adjusts the output of already committed units on a 5–15 minute basis. In addition, because energy, regulation, and reserves can be either or both complementary and substitute uses of a generator, establishing the correct auction constraints to reflect these possible relationships, both day-ahead and real-time, has proven to be important for purposes of economic efficiency. For both day-ahead and real-time markets, the auction result is a market clearing with uniform energy prices at each specified commercial location (nodes or buses) on the transmission network, called “locational marginal prices” (LMPs). Buyers pay the LMPs at their locations (which to date have typically been zonal prices comprised of a load-weighted average of the LMPs in the zone) and sellers are paid the LMPs at their locations. A key function of the energy auctions with LMP is to put a market price on marginal transmission usage, including congestion and losses. In the day-ahead market, congestion is managed instantaneously as part of the auction optimization, which respects most relevant transmission constraints. In the real-time market, the system operators manage congestion on a minute-to-minute basis in part through auction prices and in part through non-market operating decisions. Regulation and operating reserve prices are calculated slightly differently, typically incorporating an opportunity cost payment and an availability price offer into the calculation of market clearing prices, which are determined for pre-defined zones. Additional “pay-as-bid” payments are made to accepted offers and bids in any of these markets if their auction revenues do not fulfill their offer or bid terms (e.g., if a generator is started up but then does not run for sufficient hours to cover the sum of its offer prices for start-up, no-load, energy, regulation, or reserves). These vast regional wholesale spot markets, several consisting of tens of thousands of simultaneously determined prices at locations on the grid, are one of the signal technological achievements to date of the regulatory reform of the US electricity industry. The ISO market designs are also serving as models for other countries’ attempts at market development. At one level, they operate very well, allowing for the regional market operator to capture efficiencies made possible through large-scale optimization. Buyers can schedule their own resources (owned or contracted) or buy spot. Sellers can optimize whether to fulfill their forward contracts with their own resources or through the spot market and can offer any residual capacity into the spot market. The record of the first decade of energy and ancillary service market design in the US ISOs suggests that while some conceptual design issues have largely been resolved, and there have been many technological innovations and advances in auction design, there remain many design and implementation challenges. First, these markets remain “incomplete” in the sense that they do not price adequately all generator services and
EBL
182
Competitive Electricity Markets
physical requirements associated with power transactions (transmission markets present other types of incompleteness). Moreover, while sellers have sufficient flexibility to offer their true costs, buyers are not sufficiently price responsive, due primarily to regulatory and technological barriers. Second, the ISO markets, while fairly unconcentrated in the aggregate, are not perfectly competitive at all locations and at all times due to transmission constraints. The primary method to control intermittent market power in the ISO markets has been through supply offer price caps. But offer caps suppress market prices and sometimes hinder investment. As a result of these two problems, additional pricing rules, such as the “scarcity pricing” discussed in this chapter, and additional markets established through regulatory requirement, such as capacity (or resource adequacy) markets, have been perceived as necessary to support both power system reliability and economic efficiency. Some of these design features can be removed (or become irrelevant) as technology evolves and the markets become more complete. With respect to several design elements, no definitive best practice has yet emerged. To illustrate this, in several sections of the chapter, the rules and procedures in two US ISO markets, PJM and New York, are discussed. These markets were picked because they offer useful comparisons on several design choices in the auction market rules, the integration of market and system operations, and market power mitigation. Nevertheless, the differences, while worthy of consideration, should not obscure the convergence of the US ISO markets over time on important common design elements. 5.1.2. Chapter organization
EBL
In an earlier survey (O’Neill et al., 2006), electricity market design principles were discussed at a relatively high level and US ISO market features were reviewed. The complementary purpose of this chapter is to provide an in-depth description of the sequence of the daily ISO auction markets for energy and certain ancillary services. There is sufficient detail to allow the reader to track most of the market rules and computational procedures that affect the ultimate price of wholesale power transacted through such markets. The chapter is organized as follows. Section 5.2 provides an overview of electricity market design choices and options for market power mitigation. Sections 5.3–5.5 discuss the auction sequence of the day-ahead market, the reliability unit commitment, and the real-time market. A numerical example is introduced in Section 5.3 to motivate the auction description, and continues in most subsequent sections. A mathematical statement of the auction model used in the example is provided in Appendix 5A. Section 5.6 examines revenue sufficiency guarantees that support efficient market behavior in each step of the auction sequence. Section 5.7 explains how surplus spot energy payments collected by the ISO due to pricing of congestion and losses are refunded to market participants. Section 5.8 discusses market power monitoring and mitigation in these auctions. Section 5.9 collects several additional topics in ISO market design and implementation, including the ISO’s longer-term markets and operational functions. Section 5.10 discusses possible next stages in the design of these markets. Section 5.11 presents conclusions. 5.2. The Development of Wholesale Energy Auction Market Designs The designs of the wholesale auctions for energy and ancillary services described in this chapter emerged over a decade of research and experience in the United States and elsewhere and continue to be modified and refined [see, e.g., the surveys in O’Neill et al. (2006); FERC (2002); Stoft (2002); Wilson (2002)]. This section briefly reviews
Design of US Wholesale Energy and Ancillary Service Auction Markets
183
some of the alternative designs that were considered in that period and explains why certain choices appeared desirable for theoretical, practical, and regulatory reasons. These include • • •
definition of the market products, functions of the ISO, choices in electricity auction design, including the question of uniform versus discriminatory pricing, • sequencing of markets and reliability functions, • market power monitoring and mitigation, and • scarcity pricing.
5.2.1. Definition of market products A first step in designing markets is to define the products, including the time and location at which the transaction takes place. While in most commodity markets, product definition is a matter for private firms to determine, in the electricity spot markets operated by ISOs, the nature of the technology in real-time (e.g., balancing requirements and lack of storage) and the presence of reliability requirements has led to a strong regulatory role in product definition (e.g., in FERC, 1996a), although ISOs have had latitude to adjust some definitions and parameters to fit their systems. Energy is the primary wholesale product traded in the ISO electricity markets (as measured in terms of quantities and monetary value), and it is defined straightforwardly as mega-watt-hours (MWh) injected or withdrawn at a location or locations (e.g., hub or zone) on the transmission network in one of the hourly markets (day-ahead or realtime). For purposes of spot energy market design, sales of energy are typically limited to generator output between a unit’s minimum and maximum operating levels. Price offers for energy are typically required to be linear (see Table 5.7). Generator “start-up,” i.e., the short-term fixed costs associated with accepting a generator offer that requires a unit to start-up, is in a sense treated as a separate, discrete product with its own pricing rules (under the revenue sufficiency payment), as is operating the generator at the minimum or “no-load” level. A parallel construction is found on the demand side, in which the demand may bid to consume MWh along with short-term fixed costs associated with implementing a demand curtailment offer. The pricing and settlement rules are discussed further in this section as well as extensively in Sections 5.3–5.6. The ancillary services are reliability services offered by eligible suppliers or responsive demand. As summarized in Table 5.1, these include regulation and different types of operating reserves, measured both as energy and as capacity (MW) made available at locations on the transmission network in one of the hourly markets (day-ahead or realtime). The spatial aspect of regulation and reserve product definitions is typically slightly different from that of energy. The ISOs define locations for these products on a zonal basis. These products share the characteristic that they are difficult to disaggregate among each buyer on the system, so they are currently procured by the ISO on behalf of buyers, who pay a load-weighted average price. Because regulation and spinning reserves are complementary or substitute uses of generator providing energy (or a load consuming energy), their definition typically incorporates an energy component. The implications for auction design are discussed below.
EBL
184
Competitive Electricity Markets
Table 5.1. Definitions and characteristics of market-based ancillary services in the US ISOs currently in operation or under consideration Type of ancillary service
Description
US ISOs with markets
Regulation (or automatic generation control, AGC)
The ability to increase or decrease energy output on a second-by-second basis for energy balancing Reserves available (MW) within 10 minutes from generators synchronized with the grid or demand response Reserves available (MW) within 10 minutes from generators not synchronized with the grid or demand response Reserves available (MW) within 30 minutes or more from generators either synchronized or not synchronized with the grid or demand response A product of generators and types of transmission elements that essentially supports the voltages that must be controlled for reliability
New York ISO, ISO New England, PJM, California ISO
Ten-minute spinning (or synchronous) reserve
Ten-minute non-spinning or non-synchronous reserve Thirty-minute or supplemental reserves
Reactive power
New York ISO, ISO New England, PJM, California ISO
New York ISO, ISO New England, California ISO
New York ISO, ISO New England, California ISO
Currently cost-based procurement; markets under consideration (see, e.g., FERC, 2005).
EBL 5.2.2. Functions of the ISO A major market design question in the mid-1990s concerned the relationship between the transmission system operator and the operator of the spot markets. This issue takes on different forms in different countries, due to the requirements of their regulatory systems and the history of the electric industry. For example, in some countries (such as England and Wales), the transmission system operator is a single firm under performance-based regulation (see, e.g., Chapter 4). In the United States, there was no such opportunity to merge the ownership of national or regional transmission operations at the start of restructuring. Instead, there has been an ongoing experimentation on a regional basis with different organizational approaches to the implementation of transmission open access and management of transmission usage. And as a result, options for designing the energy and ancillary service markets also take different forms in different regions of the United States. As noted in Section 5.1, there are currently basically two organizational approaches to transmission system operations in the United States: individual utility operations and ISOs. To understand the purpose behind the ISO market, it is worth beginning with a description of markets where the grid is operated by individual utilities. In such markets, all energy transactions (long-term and short-term) are made by individual buyers and sellers (i.e., bilaterally) but there is no central trading point that co-ordinates transmission usage. Hence, before or after an energy contract is in hand, the buyer or seller must arrange a transmission contract for a pre-specified period that matches the energy contract’s source point(s) and sink point(s), and contains other characteristics such as the priority given to the transmission reservation (sometimes called the “firmness” of
Design of US Wholesale Energy and Ancillary Service Auction Markets
185
the transmission reservation).3 Ancillary services, including balancing energy, are bought under cost-based rates (FERC, 1996a). This type of market has supported an increase in wholesale energy transactions, especially with the advent of the Internet (FERC, 1996b). Its main limiting factors as a market design are the following: •
The lack of co-ordinated transmission operations to efficiently utilize transmission capacity across multiple utilities, especially when there is congestion (FERC, 1999b, 2002). • The lack of a centralized exchange or auction to facilitate spot trading of energy or ancillary services (FERC, 2002). A higher degree of market organization, as offered by an ISO, is thus generally desirable to support market efficiency and expand market scope. Turning first to organization of transmission operations, market improvements can be achieved in several ways, with different implications for market efficiency. First, individual (transmission-owning) utilities can retain control of their transmission systems, but can establish an independent entity (sometimes called a “Day 1 ISO”) to facilitate information exchange and transmission capacity reservation by parties seeking to buy transmission. This type of organization can improve transmission scheduling to facilitate energy trading.4 Second, individual utilities can cede full scheduling control over their transmission systems to an ISO, which will simultaneously operate the entire transmission network collectively along with real-time energy and certain ancillary service markets. Whether the ISO also operates energy and ancillary service markets prior to real-time, such as day-ahead markets, has been another design decision. Whichever type of centralized transmission operations is chosen, an organized market for electricity can be developed along several different formats. If that market is going to be organized at a central location, then it is likely to be either an exchange or an auction. An exchange is a common format for commodity forward and futures trading. This is typically an “open” market in that buyers and sellers are known to each other. The most common pricing rule is the “bid-ask” method characteristic of futures exchanges. In an auction, a third party known as an auctioneer matches buyers’ and sellers’ following a pricing rule. Either an exchange or an auction could be used to organize spot electricity markets, but for reasons discussed next, an exchange is more compatible with pre-dayahead forward markets while an auction is best suited to the day-ahead and real-time spot markets operated by ISOs.
EBL
5.2.3. Choices in electricity auction design The electricity markets described in this chapter are all auction markets. To expand on the description given above, Table 5.2 summarizes some common auction designs (see, e.g., Klemperer, 1999; Krishna, 2002). In general, the choice among the designs depends 3 In the US context, firmness designates the physical priority of a point-to-point transmission contract in the event that reliability concerns, such as unmanaged congestion, prompt the system operator to scale back (“curtail”) transmission usage. Typically “non-firm” contracts, which are usually shorterterm, are curtailed before “firm” ones. In the United States, this arrangement prevails only outside the ISO markets, which use price-based congestion management rather than physical priorities. See also discussion in Chapter 4. 4 The Midwest ISO operated as such a transmission scheduler from 1997 to 2005, when it began operating a market with the design described in this chapter.
Table 5.2. Comparison of some alternative auction designs
SingleUnit Auctions
Auction type
Description
Revenue adequacy
Incentive compatibility
Open ascending price (“English”)
A one-sided auction in which the auctioneer raises the price of the unit being sold until there is one remaining bidder. The selling price is the winning bid. A one-sided auction in which the auctioneer lowers the price of the unit being sold until one bidder is willing to purchase. The selling price is the winning bid. A one-sided auction with sealed bids in which the selling price is the highest bid price.
Yes
Sealed-bid second price
A one-sided auction with sealed bids in which the highest bid wins the auction, but pays the bid of the next highest bid.
Yes
Yes. The bidder with the highest valuation would remains until all other stop bidding. The winner pays the valuation of the next highest bidder. The bidder with the highest valuation for the item would have the incentive to wait past where its value is in order to receive a lower price. No. The bidder with the highest valuation would want to shave its bid to receive a lower price and thus could lose out on winning the auction Yes. Each bidder would have the incentive to submit its own valuation.
Sealed-bid uniform price
A one- or two-sided auction with sealed bids in which the market clearing price for all units is the highest bid price for any unit. A one-sided auction with sealed bids in which each seller that clears the auction is paid its offer price for any individual unit.
Yes
Open descending price (“Dutch”)
Sealed-bid first price
MultipleUnit Auctions
Sealed-bid discriminatory (pay-as-bid) Sealed-bid Vickrey
Open auctions (English or Dutch)
EBL
Yes
Yes
Yes
No
These are similar in design to the single-unit English and Dutch auctions.
Sources: Krishna, 2002; Hobbs et al., 2000.
Similar to single unit auctions.
Not completely. If the bidder can influence the price, it would have the incentive to buy less in order to lower the price for the amount it buys No, the bidder would have the incentive to guess what the clearing price would be. Yes, each bidder would pay the opportunity cost imposed on the other players if the bidder had not been in the market, and as such would have the incentive to bid its true valuation. Similar to single-unit auctions.
Design of US Wholesale Energy and Ancillary Service Auction Markets
187
on a number of factors, including the characteristics of the product being auctioned and the revenue and efficiency properties of each auction type. The typology in Table 5.2 divides auctions into either “single-unit,” in which buyers and sellers are trading single items or single bundles of items (such as a single MW or a “strip” of MW over multiple hours), or “multiple-unit,” in which multiple units are traded simultaneously.5 As noted, these types of auctions can then be further divided into open or sealed bid formats. Under the sealed bid format, buyers and/or sellers submit bids and offers that are not known to others. The anonymity of a sealed bid auction is further compounded in the spot electricity auction, in which buyers do not know which seller they are buying from. Within the multiple-unit, sealed-bid auction framework, the two major choices for pricing are discriminatory, or “pay-as-bid,” prices or uniform clearing prices. Because auction designs must fit the commodity being traded, not all the auction designs shown in Table 5.2 are applicable or desirable for the electricity commodities discussed in this chapter. The product definitions and the technological characteristics of wholesale electricity vary in the different stages of the market: the pre-day-ahead forward markets that take place outside the ISO markets, where trading is primarily for multi-day/multihour strips of power; the day-ahead markets, where trading is on an hourly basis; and the real-time spot markets where power goes to physical production and delivery and trades takes place within the hour itself. The clearest way to describe how auctions can be designed around these forward and spot markets is to begin with the ISO’s real-time market and work backwards in time. The real-time market has a number of characteristics that greatly narrow the alternatives for auction design, at least with current power system technology. In real-time, the system operator is balancing supply and demand on a time-frame of seconds and minutes, largely by directing the output of generators on the system over such time-frames (and some aspects of the transmission facilities). Because of the nature of power flows, the injections and withdrawals of power on the system must be balanced simultaneously; i.e., individual injection and withdrawal combinations cannot be evaluated independently. Hence, there are no physical “bilateral” transactions involving matching between buyers and sellers in real-time: all purchases are either via the ISO market or self-provided.6 The real-time dispatch of generators must also account for inter-temporal constraints, such as ramp rates, that create interdependencies across hours. Moreover, demand in real-time can be price-responsive, but typically not on a time-frame of minutes or seconds; hence, such demand will inevitably remain largely price-inelastic until technology provides greater responsiveness and the number of units of electricity (e.g., MW) consumed will fluctuate from minute to minute. These factors inevitably require that a real-time auction is multiple-unit and sealed-bid and that the market be simultaneously cleared with all relevant transmission and generation constraints taken into account. That is, it is simply not possible to have a single-unit electricity auction in real-time, even for multi-hour strips (although that can be done in the forward markets) and it is hard to conceive of an open auction format that can meet the time-frames necessary. Essentially, real-time electricity auctions as they currently function in the United States are simply least-cost (“economic”) security constrained dispatch
EBL
5 Multiple-unit auctions do not have to take place simultaneously, but could instead take place in a sequence of single-unit auctions (Krishna, 2002); however, this latter format is not consistent with the physical characteristics of electricity. 6 Prior to the formation of ISOs, individual utilities provided other parties that were using their transmission facilities with “energy balancing,” typically priced on an average basis.
188
Competitive Electricity Markets
using market-based supply offers and demand bids to determine prices. These auctions will be described in more detail below. Whether the pricing rule should be uniform or discriminatory will also be discussed in the next section. In the forward, but short-term, electricity markets, more auction design alternatives become possible, including some simplifications of commodity pricing, although still constrained by their proximity to the physical requirements of the operating day. For close to real-time auctions, such as hour-ahead or day-ahead auctions, deviations from the auction design for the real-time market are possible, such as relaxing some of the physical constraints on the network, but consideration must be given to implications of such designs for reliability and economic efficiency. Economic efficiency will be adversely affected if the forward auction schedule – i.e., the scheduled output of generators going into the operating day – is substantially different from the real-time dispatch, and if the resulting adjustments for dispatch feasibility incur otherwise avoidable costs or if such costs are assigned on a basis that undermines efficient price signals. For example, in the early phases of ISO auction design in the United States, some parties preferred day-ahead auctions or exchanges that did not meet the requirement of simultaneous feasibility of the resulting day-ahead schedule using an actual network. Instead, they argued for a zonal approximation of the network to facilitate day-ahead trading. This was the design choice adopted in the first phase of the California market (1998–2001), in which there was a separate day-ahead market operated by the California Power Exchange (PX) and a real-time market operated by the California ISO. To facilitate the PX market, California was divided into two transmission zones that largely, but not exactly, corresponded to the major transmission constraints on the system. The PX operated a single market in each zone using a multi-unit auction with a single zonal clearing price (see, e.g., Sweeney, 2006). The resulting schedule was then passed to the ISO, which could aim to adjust it to the limits on inter-zonal transmission through adjustments offers and bids available from the PX, but which could not enforce an efficient schedule by altering the scheduled output of generators on the basis of their supply offers. In real-time, the ISO would have to make any final scheduling adjustments on both an inter-zonal and an intra-zonal basis using real-time energy and regulation offers. In concept, the PX was to be joined over time by other competing day-ahead exchanges which could all operate their own auction markets or exchanges under whatever design suited them. The ISO would thus have been collecting many day-ahead schedules and attempting to impose feasibility on them in a similar fashion. Over time, evidence collected that, along with creating cross-subsidies on an intra-zonal basis, such zonal pricing did not provide appropriate locational signals for investment in generation, transmission, and demand response. California ISO will shortly revise the market design to adopt the day-ahead and real-time auction with locational marginal pricing described in this chapter. Like energy used for balancing, the real-time markets for regulation and operating reserves are most compatible with the sealed-bid, multi-unit auction design with all network constraints represented and uniform prices. Again, day-ahead markets for these services could use other auction designs but, as with energy, potentially resulting in market inefficiency. For these products, the primary design issues have been (i) the sequence in which the energy, regulation, and reserves markets are cleared; (ii) whether they are co-optimized or not; (iii) how complementarities and substitutions between them are captured in the auction pricing algorithm; and (iv) the components of the supply offers. These design issues have been reviewed in FERC (1999a, 2002), Stoft (2002), and O’Neill
EBL
Design of US Wholesale Energy and Ancillary Service Auction Markets
189
et al. (2006), among others. The US ISOs that offer these ancillary services through auctions have largely converged on a design that incorporates co-optimization and represents a hierarchical substitution that supports an efficient use of generators and any demand resources that can provide them. More detail on these auctions follows in Sections 5.3 and 5.5. 5.2.3.1. Uniform versus discriminatory (pay-as-bid) pricing As noted, within the multiple-unit, sealed-bid auction format, there are two primary pricing alternatives: uniform or discriminatory, also known as pay-as-bid (Klemperer, 1999; Krishna, 2002). At present, there is no theoretical consensus on the revenue and incentive compatibility properties of these rules as applied to electricity auctions (see, e.g., Kahn et al., 2001; Fabra et al., 2004). However, there is agreement on their implications for market transparency and also market power mitigation, as described later. Those implications have made the uniform pricing rule more attractive in the US ISO markets (although the pay-as-bid rule is currently used in the England and Wales spot market). There are also variations within each type of pricing rule that have implications for market efficiency. Under uniform pricing, all sellers are paid the price offered by either the last unit (MWh) chosen by the auction or the next (incremental) unit that is not chosen (the exception to this rule in some ISOs is in periods of scarcity pricing, as discussed shortly, during which the market price is set through a demand curve). For example, if a $40/MWh offer is accepted and the next offer in the offer stack that is not accepted is for $50/MWh, then the clearing price for all sales is set at either $40/MWh or $50/MWh. In the real-time market for energy, the choice between these alternative uniform pricing rules has to do with how the ISO seeks to control the output of the marginal generator(s) through a combination of price signals and quantity instructions. The choice also has an impact on long-term pricing signals. For example, if due to generation constraints, such as generator ramp rates (and assuming no transmission congestion), the ISO has to turn on a $50/MWh unit while a $40/MWh unit is operating at below its economic maximum output, but that the next available MWh is at the $40 price, then the choice of pricing rules has clear incentive properties:
EBL
•
If the market price is set at $50/MWh, then the $40/MW unit may have an incentive to increase its output. If this creates reliability problems for the system operator to manage, then it will have to control the output of the $40/MWh unit through dispatch instructions and penalties for deviations (as is done in many ISOs). • If the market price is set at $40/MWh, then the $40/MWh unit has no incentive to increase output (assuming that its offer is reflective of its marginal cost), but an alternative pricing rule has to be established to pay the $50/MWh unit to turn on. Typically, the unit is paid its bid and the ISO collects the revenues from buyers. On an electrical network with nodal congestion pricing, this auction pricing rule results in uniform clearing prices at each location and is called locational marginal pricing. A more detailed example of this pricing rule is provided in the numerical example that begins in Section 5.4. In pay-as-bid designs, the supply offer is typically conceived as a bundled offer for energy, start-up, and no-load (sometimes called a “one-part” offer). For example, if a supplier makes an offer of $20/MWh and is cleared through the auction, then the offer
190
Competitive Electricity Markets
is paid $20/MWh, no more or less. Under most proposed formats, buyers in the auction would pay an averaged price based on the total accepted MWh. Hence, while a locational pricing result could be sustained for sellers, it would be difficult to sustain for buyers, except on an aggregate basis, such as in a zone. Advocates of pay-as-bid pricing have different motivations, depending on whether they are sellers or buyers. Sellers may believe that the combination of one-part offers with payas-bid provides the seller greater transparency over the auction result than markets with three-part offers and locational marginal pricing and additional payments to guarantee recovery of start-up and no-load offer costs. Buyers may believe that a pay-as-bid rule will result in a lower market clearing price. This belief is sometimes based on the perception that in a competitive pay-as-bid auction, a unit with a $20/MWh marginal cost will always offer at that price, even if other units are clearing at a higher price. This argument is incorrect. As long as there is sufficient market price transparency, then a supplier will always seek to obtain the price that clears the market to maximize profit. Hence, in a pay-as-bid market, the unit with a $20/MWh marginal cost will raise its offer price to its estimate of the price offer of the most expensive unit cleared in the same auction time period. This incentive raises the following concerns with pay-as-bid auctions. First, the need for sellers to estimate the hourly market clearing price could lead to many incorrect guesses, which even in a competitive market will lead to inefficiency (e.g., when a lower-cost unit overestimates the price, letting a higher-cost unit clear the market). Second, from the perspective of the market operator, efficient control of the power system will become less transparent as all offers for a particular hour will cluster around the market clearing price. There is the argument that a low-price unit will be risk-averse in a pay-as-bid auction and rather than attempt to clear at the estimated market price will persistently shave its offer to ensure that it is scheduled. That is, a $20/MWh unit will offer at $50/MWh rather than at $60/MWh, which is the price of the most expensive unit chosen. Such risk aversion would lower the price to buyers. However, over time, it will also send the wrong price signal for investment, resulting in higher-cost plants being built. Hence, a short-term lowering of market prices may result in an increase in prices over the long term (Cramton and Stoft, 2006). Finally, because all offers will likely cluster around the estimate of the market-clearing price in each auction period, if there is the need for ex ante or ex post market power monitoring and mitigation, the regulator will have more difficulty reconstructing which units have been raising their offers above marginal cost in an attempt to manipulate price levels. This is discussed later in this section and in Section 5.9. For all these reasons, US regulators have preferred the uniform clearing price rule to the pay-as-bid rule. However, in at least one other country (England and Wales), regulators have actually redesigned the spot market to move away from uniform pricing rules, adopting pay-as-bid pricing.
EBL
5.2.4. Sequencing of markets and reliability functions As noted earlier, the basic design choices for real-time electricity auctions are highly constrained by the characteristics of power system operations. Reliability requirements, timelines for operational decisions in the hours prior to real-time, and representation of generation and transmission capacity constraints all further shape the forward market designs by adding mathematical constraints to the auction solution and requiring specific
Design of US Wholesale Energy and Ancillary Service Auction Markets
191
market and “out-of-market” procedures. Over the decade of ISO auction market development, two major questions stand out in this regard: •
If there are forward energy or ancillary service auctions conducted by an ISO or any entity able to offer into an ISO market, how far forward in time should system reliability and operational constraints be applied? Put another way, how should the interface between forward and real-time markets be designed? • How should the physical constraints of power system operations be reflected in the ISO day-ahead and real-time auction pricing rules? Both of these questions were central in the market design discussions that took place in the United States in the mid-1990s (see, e.g., Stoft, 2002; Wilson, 2002; O’Neill et al., 2006). With regard to the first question, an initial debate placed those who believed that system operations could be a primarily real-time function, with forward markets operating separately under their own rules until just a few hours or less before real-time, against those who argued for a full integration of short-term (day-ahead and real-time) market and system operations. The second question concerned issues such as the choice of zonal pricing versus locational marginal pricing in transmission usage pricing and whether supply offers into the auctions should give generators the choice to represent details of their short-term marginal costs, such as start-up costs. The FERC standard market design proposal (FERC, 2002) sought to settle as many of these design debates as possible. As it proposed, and is now done in most of the ISO markets, the sequence of short-term auction markets and reliability actions incorporates all relevant reliability procedures and physical constraints and provides sufficient offer and bid detail to provide an efficient auction result. As the remainder of the chapter will explain, this sequence has the following structure: •
EBL
First, the ISO undertakes a series of pre-day-ahead procedures and out-of-market actions to account for changes in system conditions as well as demand (load) forecasting and scheduling of generators with longer than one-day start-up or shutdown requirements. • Second, the ISO operates a day-ahead market that includes an auction with “securityconstrained unit commitment,” i.e., consideration of the full set of known transmission security and generation unit constraints, within the limitations of the auction optimization. • Third, the ISO takes several types of additional actions after the day-ahead market clears to ensure reliability prior to real-time. Most notably, all ISOs undertake variations on what can be called reliability unit commitment, commitments of additional generation to replace physical units displaced by virtual supply and to meet forecasts of actual load if such forecasts are different from the amount of demand that is cleared day-ahead. In addition, the ISO collects data on generation cleared day-ahead to determine changes in actual availability. • Finally, in the real-time market, as discussed earlier, the ISO operates the power system through a security constrained economic dispatch (complemented by unit commitments) using offers and bids to determine auction market prices and supported also by physical dispatch instructions that may occasionally differ from the market result for reliability reasons. 5.2.5. Market power monitoring and mitigation Market power in the electricity auction markets is defined as the ability of a buyer or seller to significantly and sustainably alter the market price from the competitive price. Most
192
Competitive Electricity Markets
economists interpret the competitive price as the market price that results when sellers are willing to offer power at their marginal opportunity cost and buyers bid for power at their true willingness to pay. The general economic principle is that the larger the number of sellers and buyers, the more likely that market prices and quantities will be competitive. This principle is measured through indices of market concentration or by market price simulations.7 Since there are currently few price-responsive buyers in electricity spot markets, the auction price is usually set by sellers (except when administrative scarcity pricing is enforced). Hence, the competitive price is typically estimated or simulated based on known production costs of the marginal unit delivering to a location, primarily fuel costs, and, if possible, adjusted to account for short-term fixed costs (such as start-up) and inter-temporal opportunity costs (for limited energy plants, such as hydro or emissions-constrained facilities). When the market price is above this competitive price, which it usually is, then some degree of supplier market power is being exerted. In economic terms, consumer surplus is being transferred to producers and the total producer surplus is being shifted among suppliers. The task of the regulator is to determine whether and how to manage such market power such that a reasonable approximation of competitive market prices and quantities prevails. The legal and regulatory methods for doing so vary between countries and supra-national organizations, such as the European Union. In the United States, FERC has the statutory obligation and authority to mitigate the market power of sellers and buyers in the wholesale electricity markets under its jurisdiction.8 Although there have been occasional concerns with buyer market power, the primary regulatory concern in the United States has been with seller market power.9 In general, there are essentially four types of measures through which seller market power in an ISO auction market (or other electricity markets) could be mitigated. First, ex ante structural measures can be taken to enhance the competitiveness of the auction market prior to the market start. For example, if regulators find that the market is too concentrated, ownership of generation assets can be restructured, through divestiture, to diminish the market power of sellers. In the United States, FERC has not required any utility to divest generation prior to selling wholesale power; instead, FERC can selectively prevent suppliers with excessive market power from selling wholesale power at market prices by approving sales only at regulated cost-based rates.10 In practice, this procedure has not
EBL
7
Most ISOs now include such measurements of market power in their annual state of the market reports. 8 In the United States, the Federal Power Act requires that generation and transmission market prices are “just and reasonable.” This standard has been interpreted by the courts as giving FERC the authority to monitor and mitigate market power in the electricity markets. See discussion in O’Neill et al. (2006) and Helman (2006). 9 With respect to buyer market power, a notable design decision was taken in the first phase of the California wholesale market design to require the incumbent vertically integrated utilities to purchase all their wholesale power through the daily markets in part to suppress their buyer market power. See, e.g., discussion in Sweeney (2006), p. 338. 10 FERC screens prospective sellers, individually or collectively (e.g., as market participants in an ISO), for generation market power using various measures of market share and market concentration. Only sellers that pass the screens are automatically granted the right to sell at market prices (called “market-based rates”); those that fail must either prove their lack of market power using additional information or sell at a regulated cost-based rate or some other negotiated rate. See, e.g., Helman (2006).
Design of US Wholesale Energy and Ancillary Service Auction Markets
193
been used to screen individual market participants in ISO markets. Rather, sellers are allowed to participate in the ISO auctions subject to the ISO’s market power mitigation rules. The ISO market power rules are predicated on the assumption that while the market is structurally competitive in the aggregate, some sellers have market power on an intermittent basis, such as when transmission constraints subdivide the market or during peak hours when most or all generators must run. This has led to a second type of market power mitigation: the application of ex ante behavioral measures. These usually take the form of offer caps that limit the price that a supplier can offer into the auction. The ISO auction markets have relied primarily on such offer caps, as discussed in Section 5.8. These caps can apply at all times to all bidders (as the $1000/MWh offer caps do in the eastern US ISOs), or they can be selectively imposed if there is evidence that offer prices are raised significantly above competitive levels and also would affect market prices. Third, the regulator and the ISOs can apply ex post measures, such as penalties for certain types of behavior or refunds to buyers if the auction market prices are found to be in excess of competitive levels, within some margin of error. FERC has the legal authority to apply such ex post measures, as it did, e.g., in requiring refunds following the California market crisis (see, e.g., Sweeney, 2006). It is a policy decision how to strike a balance between ex post and ex ante measures. In general, ex ante measures provide for less market uncertainty than ex post measures. For example, offer caps can be seamlessly integrated into the auction pricing rules, as discussed in Section 5.8. Finally, there are auction designs that mitigate market power without the need for structural or behavioral measures. These are called Vickrey–Clarke–Grove mechanisms, and they provide incentives for truthful bidding and, thus, efficient operation (Hobbs et al., 2000). Such an auction design could in theory be applied to electricity markets, but poses a number of practical issues. Perhaps the most serious issue is that such a mechanism would not be revenue neutral; in general, the auctioneer would pay more to suppliers (in a sense, to pay off their market power) than they would receive from market buyers. Hence, the preference of ISO market designers has been to retain the auction design with sealed bids and uniform price clearing, but apply various methods of ex ante and ex post market power mitigation.
EBL
5.2.6. Scarcity pricing The advent of supply offer caps for purposes of market power mitigation and the lack of demand bids has created a new design issue for the electricity auctions, namely that spot market prices cannot always reach levels sufficient to reflect the true scarcity of supply or the true willingness-to-pay of demand. In markets without such economic regulation or market incompleteness, there is no distinct feature called “scarcity pricing.” Rather, prices rise and fall largely in response to the supply–demand balance. Under scarcity conditions, supply is short and prices are high relative to historical norms, so consumers voluntarily or involuntarily reduce their consumption of the commodity in question. In the US electricity markets, empirical evidence emerged that some existing generators in ISO markets were not revenue sufficient due to offer caps (and were seeking to return to regulated status under types of cost-based contracts) and that investment in both generation and demandresponse capability was not adequate. Largely because the electricity markets are not considered sufficiently competitive in all market conditions to remove or greatly relax the
194
Competitive Electricity Markets
offer caps, FERC and market operators have turned recently to administrative scarcity pricing as a means to complete the market design.11 As of this writing, various scarcity pricing rules are being implemented, and some proposed, in the ISO markets. The first design issue is to define a scarcity condition in the market. In the current electricity markets, with largely price inelastic short-term demand, scarcity is clearly indicated when demand is either voluntarily or involuntarily curtailed. From a system operational perspective, operating reserve shortages are the first indicator to the market operator that demand curtailments are more likely. Hence, most ISOs are using, or considering using, operating reserve shortages as a trigger for scarcity pricing. The second design issue is to determine what the scarcity price should be and how it should be set. The general proposed approach is to raise the price above the highest offer cap incrementally, corresponding to the degree of reserve shortage or demand curtailment. One approach is to create a “demand curve” that begins to automatically set the price as soon as reserves are short.12 The market price is determined by the intersection of the available reserve quantity and the demand curve, with the highest price being reached when reserves are at a minimum allowable level. A simpler method is to raise the price to a single high pricing point when reserves are short to create an adder to the energy market price. Most analysts would prefer that the scarcity pricing curve be related to a measure of the value of lost load (VOLL) (see, e.g., Stoft, 2002, 154–64). However, there is no consensus on how to determine VOLL exactly, and high VOLL prices may be politically unacceptable. Hence, as will be discussed further below, while different ISOs have reached their own conclusions, there is as yet no consensus on the parameterization of scarcity pricing curves. With this background on how auction design decisions have been made and how regulatory, technological and administrative factors have motivated modifications to the auction designs and pricing rules, the chapter turns next to the details of the spot electricity auctions, beginning with the day-ahead market.
EBL
5.3. The Day-Ahead Market The day-ahead market begins the sequence of short-term market-driven and operational procedures that lead to the daily efficient and reliable functioning of the regional power system under ISO control. The day-ahead market encompasses a day-ahead auction market for energy as well as regulation and operating reserves that follows the basic auction format described in Section 5.2, along with many other details that will be described here. The day-ahead market also includes non-price schedules that are included as constraints in the auction market clearing. These schedules include generation and load self-schedules, bilateral schedules, and import and export schedules. As currently designed, the day-ahead market is best described as a forward market subject to all the physical and reliability power system constraints that are known at the time to affect the next-day (real-time) dispatch. It is a forward market because sales or purchases cleared at the day-ahead price that are not subsequently converted into a physical position in real-time must be “sold back” or “bought back” at the real-time market 11
The initial expectation in most ISO markets was that the $1000/MWh offer cap would to allow suppliers to set a sufficient scarcity price using their offers (see, e.g., FERC, 2002). 12 Under scarcity pricing the price is set by the administratively determined demand function.
Design of US Wholesale Energy and Ancillary Service Auction Markets
195
price.13 This design principle generally applies to any generation product sold in the dayahead market, whether energy, regulation, or operating reserve (although as discussed below, in practice ISOs may not fully implement this principle for reserves). It also applies to energy purchased in the day-ahead market, but not to regulation or reserves (which the ISO procures on behalf of buyers). This sequence of financial settlement generally creates an inducement to transact in the day-ahead market based on a forecast of the next-day supply–demand balance. The “physical” aspect of the day-ahead market is that the auction financial offers, along with any submitted schedules, are subject to a number of physical constraints on market clearing, including generator constraints, such as ramp rates and minimum and maximum output levels, and transmission network constraints. As noted above, With the inclusion of offers to start-up generation units, this is called security-constrained unit commitment. The initial objective of market designers was that security-constrained unit commitment, in concert with the financial incentives noted above, would shape the day-ahead schedule into a reasonable approximation of a feasible real-time dispatch. This would give the ISO power system operators time to evaluate system conditions in the spot markets, under which suppliers are no longer necessarily dedicated to particular buyers, before the operating day began. However, with the introduction of “virtual” sellers and buyers (defined in the next section), which can displace physical offers and bids, the day-ahead schedule has become less physical and more financial. To address this, ISOs introduced additional reliability unit commitments following the day-ahead market, as described in Section 5.4. Hence, the day-ahead market, taking into account all relevant system constraints, in concert with the reliability unit commitment allows the ISO to reduce scheduling uncertainty about the next-day dispatch.
EBL
5.3.1. Market procedures The day-ahead market trading rules are fairly consistent across the ISOs. Offers and bids in the day-ahead market, along with non-price schedules, are due typically by midday of the prior day, although as shown in Table 5.3 some ISO markets open and close earlier in the day. Offers and bids for energy and ancillary services are divided into price offer components and physical parameters. These are summarized for two ISO markets, PJM and New York ISO, in Table 5.7. As noted already, in each day-ahead ISO market there are three price components for energy suppliers, which also support the provision of regulation and reserves: start-up ($), no-load ($/MWh), and energy, sometimes called “incremental” energy ($/MWh). The energy offer represents the seller’s minimum dollar value that it is willing to accept to supply energy. A negative energy offer represents the seller’s maximum willingness to pay to produce power at a particular level of output (usually the minimum physical load level of the generation unit). The markets for regulation and operating reserve may include an additional offer component ($/MW) to represent costs associated with providing those services. The remaining generation offer components are physical parameters, which include upper and lower operating limits, both under normal and emergency conditions, ramp rates, minimum run times, maximum starts per day, and other parameters. Demand bids for energy may also have multiple components. In general, the core feature of demand bid is a MW block with a $/MWh reflecting the buyer’s 13
In US regulatory jargon, this is sometimes called a “two-settlement system,” referring to the dayahead (first) settlement and the real-time (second) settlement.
Competitive Electricity Markets
196
Table 5.3. Scheduling, pricing, and settlement timelines for day-ahead and real-time energy in the US ISOs PJM
New York
New England
MISO
Day-ahead market offer period closes (prior day) Day-ahead market results posted (prior day) Reliability unit commitment opens for offers (prior day) Reliability unit commitment offer period closes (prior day) Reliability unit commitment results posted (prior day) Real-time market opens for offers Real-time market offer period closes
12:00
05:00
12:00
11:00
16:00
11:00
16:00
16:00
16:00
17:00
18:00
Integrated with day-ahead market 05:00
18:00
18:00
by unit
11:00
by unit
20:00
Real-time market preliminary results posted
During hour (Integrated 5 minute LMPs)
16:00 (prior day) 18:00 (prior day)
75 minutes prior to the (dispatch) hour 30 minutes prior to the (dispatch) hour
EBL
16:00 (prior day) 18:00 (prior day) During hour (Integrated 5 minute LMPs)
30 minutes prior to the (dispatch) hour During dispatch hour (integrated 5 minute LMPs)
Sources: ISO and RTO technical manuals (see references).
maximum willingness to pay to consume power. Demand bids may also submit fixed cost components, such as an additional cost to shut down a particular piece of equipment. As Table 5.7 illustrates, ISO vary in the periodicity of day-ahead offers and bids and the frequency with which they can be changed. The implications of these differences will be discussed below. Beginning in 2000, the eastern US ISOs began to introduce virtual supply offers and demand bids into the day-ahead markets. These are purely financial positions in the forward market that will not be converted into a physical position and must be re-settled at the real-time market price. An accepted virtual supply offer that “sells” energy at a day-ahead LMP has to “buy back” that energy at the real-time price at the same location. Similarly, an accepted virtual demand bid that “buys” energy day-ahead has to “sell” it back in real-time. There are a number of purposes for such virtual transactions. A common use by purely financial entities (i.e., those that have no physical positions) is to arbitrage the price spread between the day-ahead and real-time markets. Hence, a virtual seller seeks to sell day-ahead energy at a higher price than it will have to buy the energy back in realtime; a virtual buyer has the opposite objective (see the numerical examples in Sections 5.3 and 5.5). With entry into the virtual trading market, competition between virtual traders for arbitrage rents causes greater price convergence between day-ahead and real-time.
Design of US Wholesale Energy and Ancillary Service Auction Markets
197
There are other uses for virtual transactions. For example, if an entity holds financial transmission rights, it can use such virtual positions to shift settlement of the transmission rights from day-ahead to real-time, if that is seen as financially advantageous.14
5.3.2. Market pricing and settlement The day-ahead auctions basically follow the uniform-price pricing rule discussed in Section 5.2.3 for energy, but with additional features to pay other offer components and with many other pricing rules. Prices are determined as follows: The auction is conducted by inserting the supply offers and demand bids into a dynamic optimization program that minimizes the cost of meeting demand (or maximizes social welfare, measured as the sum of consumer and producer surplus) for energy and ancillary services in each hour of the operating day subject to generation and transmission constraints. The generator constraints are represented in the auction model both through discrete, or integer, variables, such as the start-up decision, and continuous variables, such as the generator energy offer (represented as a stepwise or piecewise linear function over the range of output). The dayahead auction result is an hourly schedule of LMPs and non-binding dispatch instructions for each generator, indicating its output level and respecting its start-up costs, energy offers, ramp rates, and other constraints on output, such as minimum and maximum operating limits. The market price for energy is calculated by the auction algorithm as the shadow price associated with the energy balance constraint for each node (typically a bus on the network) in the high-voltage transmission network (see Appendix 5A). That is, LMPs can be calculated for each network location where energy is injected or withdrawn and also for transshipment nodes. ISOs will typically limit the number of LMPs calculated to nodes that have commercial purposes. The LMP is a composite of the accepted offer prices of all generators that would supply the next, or incremental, MW at that location. ISOs typically disaggregate LMPs into three components: energy, losses, and congestion (Schweppe et al., 1988). For computational reasons discussed in Section 5.7, the energy component is the same for all buses within an ISO’s network, while the loss and congestion components differ if there are losses and congestion. The ISO will generally collect surplus revenues when there are losses and congestion. Because the ISO is revenue neutral, these surpluses are returned to market participants through financial transmission rights and loss refunds. One reason for disaggregating the LMP is that the financial transmission rights issued by ISOs typically only cover differences in the congestion component, and not the loss component. Hence, the ISOs
EBL
14 A financial transmission right as currently specified in the ISO markets is a contract to receive the difference in price between two locations on the transmission network for a particular quantity (MW) at a particular time. Financial transmission rights are cashed out in the day-ahead market. An entity holding a financial transmission right can take an equivalent virtual position to create the exact opposite of the locations and MW specified in the right for settlement purposes. That is, it would bid to buy equivalent MW at the location where it was to withdraw the MW specified in the transmission right and offer to sell at the location where it was to inject the MW specified in the transmission right. This would exactly cancel its financial transmission right position day-ahead, but would require it to cash out the equivalent position in real-time due to the virtuals. So the result would be that it buys back at the injection location and sells back at the withdrawal location at their respective real-time prices.
198
Competitive Electricity Markets
need to calculate how much surplus is generated by each component. There are various ways to calculate these components and the corresponding auction surpluses, which will be discussed in the numerical example that begins in this section as well as in Section 5.7. While the day-ahead LMPs will always provide a generator accepted through the auction with sufficient revenues to cover its energy offer price over the hours that it operates, those prices may not cover its start-up and no-load costs. The numerical example that begins in this section illustrates this possible outcome. The ISO ensures that such offer costs will be recovered through a revenue sufficiency guarantee. This is an additional payment that takes place at the end of the day-ahead market, the real-time market, or both markets. This payment is discussed in more detail in Section 5.6. In general, all generators that provide a price offer for energy and all price-responsive demand bids that are “dispatchable” and all virtual offers and bids are eligible to set dayahead LMPs. A dispatchable generator or demand resource is one that the ISO can dispatch up or down based on its offered supply function. In addition, some ISOs let congestion bids (i.e., offers for a maximum price difference between two nodes) set locational energy prices. However, dispatchable generators in some situations are not allowed to set the price. There is usually a straightforward operational and/or economic incentive reason for such a restriction. For example, generators that are scheduled at their minimum load level for some hours are not eligible to set the locational price. The reason for this rule has to do with incentives: if the generator could set the price in the hours scheduled for minimum output, it may try to produce energy to increase its revenues. This would undermine the ISO’s attempt to establish an efficient schedule that respects inter-temporal constraints. In both the day-ahead and the real-time markets, most ISOs have instituted various ex post aggregations of LMPs for settlement purposes. One such aggregation is called “hub” pricing, in which a location-weighted price is calculated for a set of nodes where spot energy is sourced. Another such aggregation is “zonal” locational pricing for demand, in which a load-weighted average price is calculated for the territory of particular utilities that have retail customers. In some cases, such zonal pricing is used to settle the purchases of multiple utilities, thus embodying some level of cross-subsidy. Some of these zonal pricing subsidies reflect regional agreements among utilities and state regulators. However, such zonal pricing also inhibits the development of demand response, as the actual nodal price is not known by buyers and higher prices will be hidden by the averaging process. Transmission usage charges apply to any market participant that has withdrawals in the market. This pertains both to spot transactions and to non-price schedules. With respect to the latter, a buyer with a bilateral contract or a utility that remains vertically integrated and desires to operate its own generators has no requirement to purchase energy through the day-ahead (or real-time) market. However, there is a requirement by such schedulers to pay for marginal transmission usage, as measured by differences in spot LMPs between points of injection and withdrawal. As discussed in more detail in Section 5.7, the congestion component of such usage charges for any particular MW schedule are hedged by financial transmission rights between those points for the equivalent MW schedule, while any surplus marginal loss charge payments are refunded by the ISO on some basis independent of particular schedules.
EBL
5.3.3. Markets for regulation and reserves As noted in Section 5.2.3, some day-ahead markets now incorporate co-optimized regulation and operating reserves markets, although others have only real-time markets for these
Design of US Wholesale Energy and Ancillary Service Auction Markets
199
products. Details on this procedure are provided in Section 5.3.7.15 The design principles for day-ahead auctions of these products generally follow the sequence of financial settlement obligations described earlier. Eligible generators and responsive demand make offers for these services into the day-ahead market. ISOs also allow “self-supply” of regulation and operating reserves, whether from a utility’s own resources or via contract. In general, to ensure reliability, the ISOs require that these schedules are offered through the auction at a zero price. Unlike energy, buyers do not make specific bids for these products into these markets, which are procured on their behalf by the ISO. The quantities that clear in the day-ahead market are then transferred to the real-time market and deviations are priced at real-time prices.
5.3.4. Scarcity pricing As discussed in Section 5.2.6, ISOs are experimenting with alternative types of scarcity pricing that set market prices during operating reserve shortages. In general, the demand curves or price adders/caps used to determine scarcity pricing in the day-ahead market should be the same as those used in the real-time market, to avoid providing incentives to market participants to alter behavior in one market so as to affect the prices in the other. However, there is a practical difference in the triggering mechanism. Day-ahead, an administrative scarcity price will be determined instantaneously as part of a day-ahead market solution. In real-time, as discussed below, system operators may be taking nonmarket steps to maintain reliability, and hence the declaration of an operating reserve shortage will be subject to manual decision-making within the operating hour. Some specific scarcity pricing rules are discussed below.
EBL
5.3.5. Congestion management Because congestion management is a slightly different procedure in the day-ahead market than in real-time, the day-ahead procedure is described briefly here. Essentially, congestion in ISOs with LMP is managed day-ahead “implicitly” through the auction market optimization. Put simply, the day-ahead market result is a schedule for each hour of the day that includes the effects of congestion and in which the congestion “charge” between any two nodes or buses on the system is the difference between the LMPs at those locations. In contrast, in real-time, congestion management is an ongoing process that requires the system operator to make operational adjustments from minute to minute and which may involve non-market decisions. That procedure will be discussed in Section 5.6.
5.3.6. Numerical example This section begins a numerical example of market pricing and settlements that will continue through several sections of the chapter to illustrate the different stages of the ISO energy auctions. The example is developed in the simplest fashion possible to demonstrate realistic characteristics of an auction market with locational marginal pricing, while 15
Co-optimization is less cumbersome day-ahead than in real time, because the real-time procedure requires constant updating of generator set points and available regulation or reserve capacity. Realtime co-optimization is described in Section 5.5.7.
Competitive Electricity Markets
200
allowing the reader to replicate and track auction results. The mathematical details of this example are provided in Appendix 5A. The example assumes a transmission network with three transmission lines connecting three buses, or nodes, as shown in Fig. 5.1. A bus is represented by a thick vertical line while a transmission line is the thin line or lines connecting the buses. The network has characteristics that allow for the calculation of both the marginal congestion and the marginal loss components of LMPs. The transmission line connecting buses 1 and 2 has a capacity limit of 350 MW in both directions (1→2, 2→1); the other lines do not have capacity limits that will affect the examples. To simplify the presentation of power flows on this network, a DC approximation of the AC load flow is used, in a version with quadratic line losses (Schweppe et al., 1988). This means that for any 1 MW injected at one bus and withdrawn at another bus, the percentage of that 1 MW that is withdrawn is a decreasing, non-linear (quadratic) function of the total MW flowing on the line (the line “loadings”). As noted, all the US ISOs calculate the loss component of LMPs, so while adding losses to the example makes it somewhat less intuitive, it is reflective of how the actual prices are calculated. The power flow equations that are being used in these examples are shown in Appendix 5A. All the demand in this example is located at bus 3; this simplifies the presentation, as all power will flow to this location in each example. The 24 hours of the day-ahead market are compressed here into three demand blocks: an off-peak demand of 950 MW, an intermediate demand of 1300 MW, and a peak demand of 1600 MW. To further simplify, these demands are price-inelastic. Virtual demand bids are not considered, but would be represented as price-sensitive demand blocks (as would any price-sensitive physical demand). There are five potential suppliers, whose parameters and financial offers are found in Table 5.4. The location of the suppliers is shown in Fig. 5.1; physical generators are represented as the circles connected by a solid line to each bus, while the one virtual supplier is represented as a circle connected by a dashed line. A cheap “base-load” generator “A” is located at bus 1. The offer price of this generator is $15.00/MWh and its capacity is 1500 MW. A more expensive “intermediate” load generator “B” is located at bus 2. The offer price of this generator is $20.00/MWh and its capacity is 250 MW. Both of these generators have start-up costs. The base-load generator has a very high start-up cost but because it is assumed to be operating for most hours of the year, and hence is already running in hour 1 of the day-ahead market, the auction algorithm does not need to consider its start-up
EBL
Bus 1
Bus 3
D E
A
C Demand
B Bus 2 Fig. 5.1. Three bus, five supplier electrical network.
Design of US Wholesale Energy and Ancillary Service Auction Markets
201
Table 5.4. Supply parameters and offer prices
Generator Generator Generator Generator Virtual E
A B C D
Bus
Capacity (MW)
Energy offer ($/MWh)
Start-up price ($)
1 2 3 3 3
1500 250 200 300 200
15 20 40 50 41
Not applicable 1000 2000 100 0
Table 5.5. Results of day-ahead market simulations Scenario
Off-peak Intermediate Peak
Demand (MWh)
950 1300 1600
Supply (MWh) A
B
1018 1227 1288
190 250
Price at bus ($/MWh) C
D
E
1
15.00 15.00 197 15.00
2
3
16.13 20.00 54.49
17.31 20.36 41.00
cost. The intermediate generator has a start-up cost of $1000. At node 3, there are two peaking generators, “C” and “D,” with similar capacity, but different offer prices, as well as one virtual offer, “E.” Peaking unit C has an energy offer price of $40.00/MWh and a start-up price of $2000; peaking unit D has a higher energy offer price of $50.00/MWh, but a lower start-up price of $100. The virtual offer E is priced at $41.00/MWh to exploit the price gap between the peaking units. Virtual supply offers could also exploit other jumps in the supply function in this example. The results of each demand scenario are summarized in Table 5.5 and in the Figs 5.2a–c. Beginning with the off-peak demand scenario depicted in Fig. 5.2a, the base-load generator at node 1 can supply all the power needed to meet demand of 950 MWh. The transmission capacity constraint on line 1 ↔ 2 does not bind, i.e., does not create congestion. However, the quadratic line losses require the base-load generator to inject 1018 MWh to meet the load (meaning that approximately 68 MWh are lost due to line losses) and the losses also establish differences in the LMPs. The prices at buses 1, 2, and 3 are $15.00/MWh, $16.13/MWh, and $17.31/MWh, respectively. At the LMPs for the off-peak scenario, the ISO auction charges demand $17.31/MWh × 950 MWh = $16 444. The ISO auction pays the base-load generator $15.00/MWh × 1018 MWh = $15 275. The difference between what the ISO collects from demand and what it owes to generators is a transmission usage surplus, which in this case is $1169. In this scenario, because there is no congestion, the surplus is due to charging demand for marginal losses. Since the ISO is revenue-neutral, it must refund this surplus in some fashion, as discussed in Section 5.7. In the intermediate demand scenario depicted in Fig. 5.2b, while the demand of 1300 MWh is lower than the base-load generator’s capacity, the transmission capacity limit of 350 MW on line 1 ↔ 2 now creates congestion that prevents the base-load generator from meeting the demand on its own.16 This requires dispatching generator B at bus 2 to
EBL
16
The base-load generator congests line 1 → 2 when it injects around 1038 MWh.
Competitive Electricity Markets
202
Bus 1 A
$15
Bus 3
D C
$17.31
950 MW
1018 MW
$16.13
B
Bus 2 Fig. 5.2a. Off-peak scenario.
Bus 1 A
$15
Bus 3
D C
$20.36
1300 MW
1227 MW
$20
EBL
B Bus 2
190 MW
Fig. 5.2b. Intermediate scenario.
Bus 1 A
$15
Bus 3 $41
D
E
C
197 MW 1600 MW
1288 MW
$54.49
B 250 MW
Bus 2 Fig. 5.2c. Peak scenario.
provide “counterflow” on line 1 ↔ 2 that can resolve the congestion and also meet the demand at bus 3. In the day-ahead auction, as noted above, this congestion management happens simultaneously in the solution of the auction. The intermediate generator has a start-up cost of $1000 that is considered in the auction’s decision to commit this generator. However, as noted above, this cost does not enter into the calculation of the LMPs. The prices at buses 1, 2, and 3 are $15.00/MWh, $20.00/MWh, and $20.36/MWh, respectively. Using bus 1 as the slack bus for the purpose of calculating LMP components, the energy
Design of US Wholesale Energy and Ancillary Service Auction Markets
203
component of the price is $15.00/MWh, while the loss (congestion) components are $0 ($0), $1.18 ($4.82), and $3.19 ($1.17) per MWh, respectively at the three buses. At these intermediate scenario prices, the ISO auction charges the demand at bus 3 $2036/MWh × 1300 MWh = $26 468. The ISO auction pays the base-load generator $1500/MWh × 1227 MWh = $18 411, and the intermediate generator $2000/MWh × 189 MWh = $3793. The surplus collected by the ISO is now $4264, which is due in this scenario both to marginal loss charges and to marginal congestion charges. Using the above LMP components, the congestion surplus portion of this total surplus is $2163. This means that the loss component is $2101, equaling the sum of the loss LMP components times the net withdrawals ($3857) minus the energy LMP component times the net losses ($1756). However, this division is arbitrary. If the LMP components were instead based on using the load bus as the swing bus, the estimates of the surpluses results would have been different. These calculations are shown in Section 5.7.4.17 In the peak demand scenario in Fig. 5.2c, both the base-load generator and the intermediate generator are operating at the highest output possible given the congestion on the system, but meeting the demand of 1600 MWh requires using one or more peaking units, which in this example are located close to the load at bus 3. Because generator A is still not operating at full output, it remains a marginal generator and the price at its bus remains at $15.00. However, generator B is operating at full output and the price at its bus has risen above its offer price, to $54.49/MWh. This price is the value (in terms of reduced operating cost of the other operating generators) of a hypothetical additional MW (or increment) of power injected at bus 2. The ISO auction has the choice of three supply offers at bus 3, each with different energy and start-up prices. Each of these offers alone is sufficient to meet the demand. The auction unit commitment decision is to pick the generator offer that either (a) minimizes the total offer cost of both energy and start-up if demand is not price responsive or (b) maximizes social welfare defined as the difference between buyer surplus and seller surplus (see Appendix 5A). Mathematically, this is called the auction “objective value.” To illustrate the commitment decision, the results of each choice, including the resulting LMPs, are summarized in Table 5.6. As can be seen, the minimal objective function value is to dispatch the virtual supply offer. This offer has a higher price than generator C, but has no start-up cost. The start-up cost of generator C is high enough that its lower energy offer is not sufficient to yield a lower total cost of energy and start-up. Generator D has a lower start-up cost than generator C, but its higher energy cost results in a higher total supply cost. Note that total payment to sellers is higher than their total offer costs because the LMPs can be higher than the generator offer price at a location. Put another way, some generators are “inframarginal”: in this example, generator B at bus 2. The virtual supply offer is priced in this example to displace Gen C. The expectation of the virtual supplier is that in real-time, Gen C will set the price, allowing the virtual to sell back its position at a lower price than what it has been paid in the day-ahead market. The example is continued in Section 5.5 to show the conditions under which the virtual supply offer makes positive revenues or faces a financial loss.
EBL
17 For example, a 1 MW load increment at bus 1 would be met by decreasing load at the “distributed load slack” (just bus 3) by 0.827 MW; thus, losses would be lowered by 0.173 MW, which at $20.36/MWh is worth $3.52.
204
Competitive Electricity Markets
Table 5.6. Comparison of unit commitment choices for peak demand scenario
Energy offer price ($/MWh) Start-up offer price ($) Nodal price at bus 1 ($/MWh) Nodal price at bus 2 ($/MWh) Nodal price at bus 3 ($/MWh) Total demand payments for Energy + start-up ($) Total supply payments for Energy + start-up ($) Auction objective function value ($)
Commit Gen C
Commit Gen D
Commit Virtual E
40.00 2000 15.00 52.80 40.00 62 000
50.00 100 15.00 69.75 50.00 80 100
41.00 0 15.00 54.50 41.00 65 600
42 395
46 702
41 015
34 196
34 265
32 393
5.3.7. Comparison of PJM and New York ISO market rules The general description of the auction markets given above is largely consistent across the US ISOs. For example, with respect to the day-ahead markets, all the ISOs operate auction markets for energy with security-constrained unit commitment which calculate hourly LMPs. However, there are many minor and several quite significant differences among the ISO market rules and procedures that affect market behavior and market prices. Beginning in this section and continuing in several subsequent sections, some of these differences between PJM and New York ISO will be examined, so as to further illustrate design choices and trade-offs. A thorough examination of the differences between these two markets, many of which stem from the preferences and expectations of the market designers and market participants in each region, is beyond the scope of this chapter. Readers are encouraged to turn to the ISO tariffs, technical manuals, and annual state of the market reports for further comparative analysis.18
EBL
5.3.7.1. General scheduling procedures and energy market rules Turning first to the day-ahead energy markets, some of the basic differences between the auctions in PJM and New York ISO lie in the rules for specifying and submitting energy offers, the components of which are listed in Table 5.7. As this brief survey will suggest, there are some ways in which the PJM offer rules are more restrictive than those in New York ISO, and other ways in which the opposite is true. One notable difference is in the ability to modify offers from hour to hour. PJM requires that a single energy offer, specified as a piecewise linear curve with up to 11 prices, be submitted for the full day (i.e., the same supply function for each hour), whereas New York, which specifies a stepwise linear function with up to 10 steps, allows offer prices to change from hour to hour. In addition, PJM restricts changes in start-up offers to once in every 6 months, whereas New York allows hourly changes. Hence, with respect to variability over time, the PJM offer rules are more restrictive than those in New York. For some generators that have the option to sell into neighboring markets, or potentially to make a bilateral sale within the ISO market, the hourly flexibility to change offers may 18
These are available on the ISO websites.
Table 5.7. Offer and bid components in the PJM and New York ISO short-term markets PJM
A. Supply Offers and Demand Bids Generation Start-Up Price Minimum Generation Energy Block and Price Dispatchable Energy
Demand Shutdown Price (fixed cost) Demand Bid Regulation Capacity Availability Regulation Price Spinning Reserve Price 10-Minute Non-Synchronized Reserve 30-Minute Operating Reserve
New York
Parameters
Variability
Parameters
Variability
$/hour MW, $/hour
Six months
$/hour MW, $/hour
hourly hourly
Piecewise linear function: 10 pieces, $/MWh for the two points of piece, slope of line $/period $/MW MW $/MWh $/MWh n/a n/a
Daily
Stepwise linear function: 11 steps, $/MWh, MW/Step
hourly
$/MW MW $/MW $/MW $/MW $/MW
hourly hourly hourly hourly, day-ahead only hourly, day-ahead only hourly, day-ahead only
EBL Daily Daily Daily Daily Daily n/a n/a
(Continued)
Table 5.7. (Continued) PJM Parameters
New York Variability
B. Physical Generation Characteristics Dispatch Status Start-Up Time Minimum Run Time Minimum Down Time Max. Start-Ups per Day Normal Upper Operating Limit Emergency Upper Operating Limit Temperature-Based Operating Limits
Normal Response Rate Regulation Response Rate Regulation Maximum and Minimum
Emergency Response Rate Reactive Power Capability Physical Minimum Generation Limit
hours, min hours, min hours, min MW MW MW plotted against temperature MW/min MW/min MW
Variability subject to PJM market rules
Parameters
Variability
Whether ISO or self-committed hours, min hours, min hours, min 1–9 MW MW
May vary May vary per commitment period, day-ahead or real-time Static May change over day May change over day
Limited to Combustion Turbines
EBL
Daily; can be increased but not decreased after day-ahead market closes
MW/min MW/min MW
May vary May vary
MW/min MW plotted against MVARs MW
May vary Static Static
Note: Additional details are found in the PJM and NYISO tariffs. Static refers to offer components that remain relatively constant over the life of the offer, but can be changed.
Design of US Wholesale Energy and Ancillary Service Auction Markets
207
reflect changing opportunity costs from hour to hour. In the real-time market, as discussed in Section 5.5, these differences in offer flexibility may have other implications for pricing. Another reason for the differences in offer price flexibility is that the two markets have different market power mitigation rules. These rules will be discussed in more detail in Section 5.8. In short, in PJM, if a generation unit is not transmission constrained, it can generally submit any price offer up to $1000/MWh without any consequence, while in New York, there are offer price screens that may result in an offer being mitigated to a reference price. Hence, in unconstrained areas, PJM appears to permit greater offer pricing flexibility than New York. On the other hand, for units that are in transmission constrained locations, PJM automatically mitigates offers to a pre-submitted marginal cost offer if they fail a market concentration screen (PJM, 2006b), while New York applies offer thresholds according to a formula that becomes progressively more restrictive with the number of congested hours, as summarized in Table 5.13. One of the high-level differences between the market designs in New York and PJM is that the former sought to establish a price basis for as many market features as possible, while the latter retained several physical scheduling features that were more consistent, at least initially, with prior utility practice. For example, PJM allows participants to submit non-price energy schedules, whether bilateral schedules or self-schedules. That is, a generator can simply schedule itself to run in PJM, regardless of market price, as long as the schedule does not cause a reliability concern. Similarly, PJM allows for physical reservations for import schedules on its boundary. In contrast, New York has required that all schedules, including imports, have price offers. A supplier can attempt to guarantee that a generator runs, or that an import is accepted, by reducing its offer prices: the start-up price offer and no-load price offer can be reduced to $0, while the energy price offer can be reduced to $0/MWh or a negative price. However, if a negative price offer is accepted and sets the price, then the generator will be paying to run (NYISO, 2004). In the case of imports, the price offer requirement was an issue for many years due to scheduling difficulties that it created due to software problems; other problems for imports stemmed from lack of co-ordination between the ISO markets (Potomac Economics, 2003, pp. 68–74). The upshot is that scheduling only through financial offers and market prices can occasionally create complications for market functioning, while physical scheduling may result in economic inefficiency. Finding the appropriate balance requires continuing refinement of market rules, software, and inter-ISO co-ordination.
EBL
5.3.7.2. Markets for regulation and reserves New York ISO began market operations in 1999 with auctions for energy, regulation, and three operating reserves. In contrast, PJM operated only an energy market for several years, while procuring ancillary services on a cost basis. PJM introduced a market for regulation in 2000, followed by a market for spinning reserve, called synchronous reserve, in 2002 (see discussion in PJM, 2003). However, the design of its ancillary service markets has been different than the markets in New York, both in the sequence of the markets and in their pricing rules. First, the PJM markets for regulation and synchronized reserve clear in real-time (although price offers have to be submitted on the prior day) and so will be discussed in Section 5.5.6 in the context of the PJM real-time market. New York ISO has both day-ahead and real-time markets for regulation and operating reserves that are simultaneously co-optimized with the energy markets. The rules for these
208
Competitive Electricity Markets
markets are quite complicated and not all the details are covered here (see in particular NYISO, 2006). In New York, day-ahead offers for regulation and reserves are subject to the same submission deadlines as energy (New York ISO, 2001b). Regulation offers must include a regulation response rate (MW/min), which can be no less than 1 MW/min, and a regulation availability price, in $/MW. The three types of operating reserves are 10-minute spinning reserves, 10-minute non-synchronized (non-spinning) reserves, and 30-minute reserves, which can be provided from spinning or non-synchronized units. As shown in Table 5.7, suppliers of operating reserves can submit an “availability” offer ($/MW) for each hour of the day-ahead market and must also provide an emergency response rate that will be used during reserve pickup events. The remainder of the offer consists of physical parameters. The maximum capability for different reserves is a function primarily of the energy output of the unit in relation to its upper operating limit and the unit’s ramp rate.19 New York currently has three locations (zones) for the operating reserve markets: the western zone, which is defined as west of the Central–East transmission path; the eastern zone, which is east of the Central–East transmission path, excluding Long Island; and Long Island. Each of these locations has a reserve requirement, with higher requirements in the east where most of the load is concentrated (NYISO, 2006).20 The pricing of operating reserves is done by zone: there is a different price for each zone described above. Within each zone, the price of each type of reserve under normal operating conditions is done in a fashion that reflects the hierarchical ranking and substitution properties.21 In addition, when operating reserve capacity is less than reliability requirements, prices are set by demand curves described next.
EBL
5.3.7.3. Scarcity pricing When supply is tight, reflecting scarcity, the two ISOs have different procedures for scarcity pricing. PJM essentially allows suppliers to voluntarily raise offer prices, up to the $1000/MWh offer cap, so as to raise market prices. Some suppliers submit “hockey-stick” offers in which a small percentage of the generator’s output is priced at a high price in the event that demand is high enough to require all available generation capacity including 19
In New York, the rules are that spinning reserve MW are calculated as the unit’s emergency response rate multiplied by 10 (minutes); 10-minute and 30-minute non-synchronized reserve MW are the unit’s upper operating limit (normal or emergency), and for synchronized 30-minute reserves, the emergency response rate multiplied by 20 (minutes), which gives the available reserves above the unit’s 10-minute capability. 20 Currently, the most severe contingency in New York state is rated at 1200 MW and the total 10-minute reserve requirement for the system is set at this quantity. Half of this total is required to be 10-minute spinning reserve, with half of the total spinning reserve purchased in the eastern location; the remainder can be either spinning or non-synchronized 10-minute reserves and must all be purchased on the eastern location. The 30-minute reserve is set at 150% of the most severe contingency, equal to 1800 MW, of which 1200 MW is purchased in the eastern location and 600 MW in the western location. 21 Each surplus higher quality reserve offer can fulfill the quantity requirement of a lower quality reserve. The price of 10-minute spinning reserve is equal to the shadow price on the constraint for that reserve in the auction algorithm plus the shadow price for 10-minute non-synchronized reserve plus the shadow price for 30-minute reserve. Similarly, the shadow price for 10-minute non-synchronized reserve is the shadow price for that reserve plus the shadow price for 30-minute reserve. Finally, the price for 30-minute reserve is the shadow price on its constraint.
Design of US Wholesale Energy and Ancillary Service Auction Markets
209
short-term emergency capacity. There is one situation in which PJM will administratively raise prices day-ahead. In the condition of “maximum emergency generation,” the ISO finds that day-ahead bid demand is not met by offered generation at maximum output. The ISO then takes a sequence of steps to balance supply and demand, setting the market energy price after each step to the highest offer price of any generator on-line or demand offer accepted. First, it increases the output of scheduled generation to their maximum emergency output limits. Second, it schedules generators that are designated as only available for such emergencies. Third, it drops any remaining price-sensitive demand bids. Finally, it sheds load. In the final step, the market price is set at the higher of $1000/MWh or the highest offer price of a generator on-line. In contrast, New York has established demand curves for operating reserves that administratively set energy, regulation, and reserve prices during reserve shortages. Until the reserve shortage condition, generators can, as in PJM, attempt to raise the energy price to reflect scarcity by submitting high price offers, including those submitted specifically for output at what is designated as emergency levels (however, unlike PJM, almost all non-emergency supply offers are subject to automatic screening for market power and possible mitigation, as described in Section 5.8). But once the reserve shortage is reached, energy prices are administratively determined through co-optimization with the reserve markets. Currently, there are nine reserve demand curves, some for particular zones.22 In each case, the ISO seeks a target quantity (MW) level for each type of reserve and the demand curve affects the price when the quantity falls below the target level. The curves are simply single price points or stepwise functions when the quantity of reserves reaches a particular level; i.e., they are not negatively sloped. The highest such price in the New York system is $500/MWh for spinning reserve. The lower quality reserves are then priced at lower levels. The prices can go no higher than addition of those demand curve prices, so that even if a high availability offer is submitted in anticipation of a reserve shortage, it cannot further increase the market price of reserves. As the comparison of PJM and New York shows, there are at least two fundamentally different approaches to scarcity pricing currently implemented. Other ISOs have proposed different methods and/or pricing parameters. Hence, there are likely to be many subsequent developments and refinements in this aspect of market design.
EBL
22
The nine demand curves are as follows. For spinning reserves the price is (1) $500/MW for eligible operating reserves at quantities less than or equal to the target level and $0/MW otherwise; (2) $25/MW for eligible operating reserves at quantities less than or equal to the target level for the Eastern region and $0/MW otherwise; or (3) $25/MW for eligible operating reserves at quantities less than or equal to the target level for the Long Island zone and $0/MW otherwise. For total 10-minute reserves (spinning and non-synchronous) (4) $150/MW for eligible operating reserves at quantities less than or equal to the target level and $0/MW otherwise; (5) $500/MW for eligible operating reserves at quantities less than or equal to the target level for the Eastern region and $0/MW otherwise; or (6) $25/MW for eligible operating reserves at quantities less than or equal to the target level for the Long Island zone and $0/MW otherwise. For total 30-minute operating reserves the price is (7) $200/MW for eligible operating reserves at quantities less than or equal to the target level minus 400 MW, $100/MW for eligible operating reserves at quantities less than or equal to the target level minus 200 MW, but greater than the target level minus 400 MW, $500/MW for eligible operating reserves at quantities less than or equal to the target level, but greater than the target level minus 200 MW, and $0/MW otherwise; (8) $25/MW for eligible operating reserves at quantities less than or equal to the target level for the Eastern region and $0/MW otherwise; or (9) $300/MW for eligible operating reserves at quantities less than or equal to the target level for the Long Island zone and $0/MW otherwise.
210
Competitive Electricity Markets
5.4. The Reliability Unit Commitment While the day-ahead market with security-constrained unit commitment is now generally accepted as a design feature that improves the interface between forward markets and reliable system operations in real-time, it still presents the ISO with a few problems in this regard. These problems stem essentially from uncertainty over the physical sufficiency of the supply and demand cleared in the day-ahead market. First, as noted, when virtual supply offers are introduced into the day-ahead market, they can displace physical supply offers, potentially leaving the ISO uncertain as to the location and available capacity of generators that are preparing to operate for the next day. Second, if there is no requirement that demand bid in day-ahead, and, further, the market allows virtual demand to bid, the ISO may be uncertain as to whether the demand cleared in the day-ahead market is overor under-scheduled with respect to the operating day. Most US ISOs have addressed these potential problems by adding an intermediate stage to the sequence of the day-ahead and real-time markets, sometimes called a reliability unit commitment. In the reliability unit commitment, the ISO takes two primary actions. First, the ISO removes accepted virtual supply offers from the day-ahead generation offer stack to determine its prospective post-day-ahead physical supply (although the physical generators do not have to operate in real-time, they at least have a financial inducement to do so). Second, the ISO compares its own next-day load forecast with the demand cleared in the day-ahead market. If the former exceeds the latter, the ISO seeks to ensure that sufficient generation has been started up to meet load. The ISO then commits additional generators to meet its load forecast. In this fashion, the ISO enters the operating day with greater confidence that it has sufficient generation to meet demand. Like some other design features of ISO markets, the reliability unit commitment is best thought of as a market-priced reliability procedure that could eventually be removed in the event that the demand-side of the markets become sufficiently price-responsive. In most ISO markets, it is undertaken after the day-ahead market closes but before the realtime market opens. This means that it is usually conducted in the late afternoon of the prior day, with results made available to market participants over the next few hours. As such, it can also be considered the beginning of the real-time market since, as will be discussed below, any generation committed through the reliability unit commitment will be compensated for any energy produced at real-time prices.
EBL
5.4.1. General procedures and pricing rules As reliability unit commitment designs were introduced into the ISO markets, there was debate over the correct offer and pricing rules. The design decisions were largely focused on two questions: •
Should the reliability unit commitment act as a type of forward market, clearing a market for starting generators as well as energy, or should it simply start generation with sufficient capacity to meet forecast demand while letting the real-time market determine whether to produce energy from those units? • If the reliability unit commitment only starts generators, but does not buy their energy, what is the appropriate pricing for such units? The design direction taken by the ISOs on the first question was not to compute a postday-ahead forward market for energy, but rather to minimize the cost of start-up offers by generators such that sufficient capacity is postured to meet the residual demand between
Design of US Wholesale Energy and Ancillary Service Auction Markets
211
the day-ahead market and the ISO’s next-day load forecast. In this fashion, the ISOs could minimize the expenditures by buyers associated with the reliability commitment. If the generators are started up, but their energy is not actually used, then the ISO has not over-purchased energy that would need to be bought back at real-time prices. Conversely, if the generators are started up and do produce energy in real-time, then they are paid for their energy through the real-time market. In fact, all ISOs reduce the costs of the reliability commitment further by applying the real-time market revenue sufficiency guarantee. That is, generators scheduled in the reliability unit commitment are not paid until the ISO has determined whether they have earned sufficient revenues in the real-time market through energy sales to cover any start-up and no-load costs incurred. The methods for allocating such uplift charges are discussed in Section 5.6. 5.4.2. Numerical example (continued) In this section, the numerical example begun in Section 5.3 is modified to reflect the actions taken by the ISO in the reliability unit commitment. In the example, a new ISO load forecast is substituted for the demand cleared in the day-ahead market auction. These differences in these demands for each time period are shown in Table 5.8. In addition, the ISO removes the accepted virtual supply offer from the peak demand hours. The results are as follows. In the off-peak period, the ISO estimates that demand will be 25 MWh higher than the demand cleared through the day-ahead market. This additional demand is met at lowest cost by the base-load generator that is already scheduled to operate during that hour. Hence, the ISO does not need to make any additional unit commitments for that period. In the intermediate period, the ISO estimates that demand will be 100 MWh higher than the demand cleared day-ahead. Again, this load is met at lowest cost by the two generators already scheduled in the day-ahead market to operate in that period. In neither the off-peak nor the intermediate periods does the ISO need to consider the displacement of physical generation by virtual supply offers. However, in the peak period, the ISO does have to remove an accepted virtual supply offer from the day-ahead market schedule to conduct the reliability commitment. In doing so, the ISO must consider which physical generator offers are available to meet its forecast peak load, which is 10 MWh lower than the peak demand cleared in the day-ahead market, but which is being met day-ahead with the virtual supply. Both peak generators available in this example have sufficient capacity (MW) to meet the ISO’s load forecast, and the ISO only needs the capacity of one of them, so the ISO’s commitment decision is simply to minimize the costs of starting up one of the generators to meet the forecast demand. In this example, it is generator D, which has high energy costs but low start-up costs, that is committed by the ISO in the reliability unit commitment. By scheduling this generator, the ISO is
EBL
Table 5.8. Difference between day-ahead market demand (MWh) and ISO load forecast (MWh)
Day-Ahead Market ISO Load Forecast Difference
Off-peak
Intermediate
Peak
950 975 +25
1300 1400 +100
1600 1590 −10
212
Competitive Electricity Markets
guaranteeing that it will cover the unit’s start-up costs of $100 whether or not it actually produces energy in real-time. This cost now rolls over into the real-time revenue sufficiency guarantee, as discussed in sections 5.5 and 5.6. In turn, generator D is now obligated to start up and be ready to produce energy by the peak period of the real-time market. To simplify the example, assume that generator D is a “quick start” unit that does not have a ramp rate that would require multi-period scheduling.
5.4.3. Comparison of PJM and New York ISO market rules All the US ISOs with a day-ahead market conduct a reliability unit commitment and all procure additional capacity by minimizing start-up and no-load costs. The differences in market rules are relatively minor. PJM begins this procedure, which it calls the “secondary resource commitment,” at 18:00 the prior day. This commitment uses the updated offers via the real-time market and any updated information on resource availability to meet the updated PJM load forecast. Following this initial commitment, PJM will do additional resource commitment prior to the start of the real-time market. Any changes to individual generation schedules are provided to generation owners only. New York ISO undertakes its reliability unit commitment over multiple steps. In contrast to PJM (and the other ISOs), New York integrates its initial reliability unit commitment into its day-ahead market unit commitment. This has been described earlier. In the second pass of the five-pass unit commitment, the ISO clears additional units based on day-ahead offers to meet the ISOs forecast demand. Like the other ISOs, the objective is to minimize start-up and no-load costs. However, because there is no guarantee that sufficient supply will be offered into the energy market day-ahead, following the day-ahead commitment, New York ISO conducts a resource evaluation called “forecast required energy for dispatch.” In this evaluation, it solicits any additional offers that were not submitted to the day-ahead market or represented in day-ahead schedules. At the start of the realtime market, the ISO continues to do supplemental evaluations to ensure that sufficient offers are available for dispatch. Similarly to other reliability unit commitments, units committed are eligible for start-up and no-load payments and for the revenue sufficiency guarantee.
EBL
5.5. Real-Time Market The real-time, or dispatch, market encompasses both an auction market for energy and ancillary services and any submitted MW deviations from day-ahead self-schedules and bilateral schedules. The spot auction is a purely “physical” market in that all sales and price-sensitive demand bids cleared through the market embody requirements to produce or curtail consumption. In the real-time auction market, demand that did not clear in the day-ahead market purchases energy and ancillary services from generators that have been started either through the day-ahead market (and have surplus capacity), the reliability unit commitment or through ongoing real-time commitments. If excess demand cleared through the day-ahead market, then the real-time market calculates the prices at which that demand must be “sold back.” Similarly, if supply clears through the day-ahead market, whether backed by a physical generator or a virtual offer, but does not perform in real-time, its output must be “bought back” at the real-time price. In markets with locational marginal pricing, the real-time market also determines marginal congestion and marginal loss charges for any transactions in real-time. These charges are calculated based
Design of US Wholesale Energy and Ancillary Service Auction Markets
213
on the total dispatch, but settled against deviations from the day-ahead market, as shown in Section 5.8.
5.5.1. Market procedures Offers and bids into the real-time market include those submitted into the day-ahead market but not accepted in that market and new ones submitted subsequent to the dayahead market. ISOs differ over when offers and bids are due, as summarized in Table 5.3. The major difference is between markets that collect all real-time offers and bids the prior day (PJM) and those that allow them to be submitted up to some time just prior to the hourly market in question (all other US ISOs). The price components and physical parameters required for offers into the real-time market are generally the same as the offers into the day-ahead market, as summarized in Table 5.7. The real-time market begins market clearing operations at 00:00 of the operating day and closes at 24:00 of the same day. As with the day-ahead market, by convention it is operated as an hourly market in the US ISOs. Hence, there is a market for each hour (e.g., 12:00–13:00) and typically a single hourly integrated price at each location, even if the dispatch price is calculated on a 5–15 minute‘ basis.
5.5.2. Market pricing There are similarities and differences between the day-ahead market and the real-time market with respect to the calculation of LMPs for energy. The similarity is that once calculated, LMPs clear the energy market. However, the procedure for calculating the prices is quite different. Unlike the day-ahead auction market, the real-time market typically has two parallel programs running to schedule and dispatch generators. The first begins with the day-ahead and reliability commitments and conducts unit commitment and de-commitment over the operating day, with a look-ahead usually of a few hours. This unit commitment typically only has to consider peaking units that were not scheduled by the day-ahead commitment or whose schedules need to be adjusted. The second is the dispatch program, which takes the commitment decisions as given and adjusts generator output on a 5-minute basis to achieve an optimal dispatch and set LMPs. The better the integration between these two scheduling programs, the more efficient is the dispatch. Also unlike the day-ahead market, in real-time, the ISO both sends its computed dispatch prices and outputs to generators every few minutes (often 5 or 10 minutes) for the subsequent time period and then meters the actual output a few minutes after that. There are thus two possible ways to set real-time LMPs: on the basis of the ex ante dispatch results or by using the metered outputs to calculate prices ex post. Ex ante real-time pricing has the advantage that it is reflective of the ISO’s optimal dispatch for the next time period. However, it generally requires penalties for “uninstructed” deviations (i.e., deviations that take place contrary to system operator instructions), because if a generator knows the anticipated price for the next 5–10 minutes, it may choose to over or under-produce in violation of the ISO’s optimal dispatch. Such deviations may cause costs to other parties, by requiring other generators to ramp up or back down (as regulation), or affect reliability. Ex post pricing relies on incentives for generators to follow their dispatch instruction; generally, if a generator over-produces, it lowers the locational price. But because of transmission network effects, some ISOs do not find that ex post pricing offers them sufficient
EBL
214
Competitive Electricity Markets
control over the system and rely on ex ante prices along with penalties to maintain an optimal economic dispatch. Another difference with the day-ahead market is that in real-time, while dispatch instructions and LMPs are calculated on a 5–10 minute basis, for convenience financial settlement takes place against an average hourly price. Hence, some hourly realtime LMPs do not cover the offer price of some units dispatched during the hour. Any difference, as in the day-ahead market, is made up through the revenue sufficiency guarantee.
5.5.3. Markets for regulation and reserves Real-time markets for regulation and reserves cannot be entirely operated in the context of the 5-minute dispatch because they require commitment decisions and re-scheduling based on the dispatch points that generators have moved to over the operating day. Hence, these are operated as hourly markets and typically re-adjusted in each hour based on new offers and the results of the energy dispatch prior hour. The auction market for these products thus runs in parallel to the energy dispatch auction. However, for any energy produced by a generator providing regulation or reserves, the price paid is the real-time energy price.
5.5.4. Scarcity pricing
EBL
Scarcity pricing in the real-time market typically follows similar principles to that in the day-ahead market. Again, because spot demand is largely non-price responsive, and more so in real-time than day-ahead, most ISOs again use a reserve shortage as a proxy for market shortage in real-time (even if no demand curtailments take place). Two significant differences between the two markets are in the trigger for scarcity pricing and financial settlement. In real time, system operators will undertake many non-market measures to avoid running short of reserves. Hence, there can be some ambiguity about when scarcity pricing is triggered. Another difference is that due to the averaging of real-time hourly prices, high scarcity prices for a few minutes during the hour will be averaged over the hour, resulting in a diluted price signal to the market.
5.5.5. Congestion management Unlike the day-ahead market, real-time congestion management requires physical re-dispatch throughout the day. The system operators use LMPs and dispatch instructions to resolve congestion, but can also take numerous non-market actions. For example, in PJM, prior to generation re-dispatch, the operator takes all available “non-cost” measures to resolve congestion, including PAR adjustments, transformer tap adjustments, MVAR adjustments, switching capacitors/reactors in/out-of-service, switching transmission facilities in/out-of-service, and curtailing transactions that have indicated that they are “not-willing-to-pay” congestion. After these non-cost measures are completed, the system operator sets a “threshold” for each individual congested transmission element, usually 95–100% of the facility rating, which must be respected by the unit dispatch software. This threshold is then re-adjusted by the PJM dispatcher as conditions change.
Design of US Wholesale Energy and Ancillary Service Auction Markets
215
5.5.6. Numerical example (continued) As noted, the real-time market is a residual market, in which deviations from day-ahead market schedules are settled at real-time prices. To maintain the simplicity of the numerical example, only the supply offers submitted into the day-ahead market but not accepted in that market or the generator committed in the reliability unit commitment are considered for additional real-time demand. The prices and quantities in their supply offers are assumed not to have changed. What does change in the example is the real-time, or physical, demand. The results of each demand scenario are shown in the Figs 5.3a–c. As shown in Table 5.9, actual demand is 5 MW lower in the off-peak period than the quantity cleared day-ahead, but is 150 MW and 20 MW higher than the latter for the intermediate and peak periods, respectively. As a result, the physical dispatch and nodal prices are different from the day-ahead market. In the off-peak period shown in Fig. 5.3a, the base-load generator is dispatched at a level 5.76 MWh lower than the quantity settled in the day-ahead market. Since the generator remains marginal, the price at its bus remains the same as the day-ahead market off-peak period. Hence, the generator has to “buy back” 576 MW × $15/MWh = $8645. Buying back this forward position does not cause the generator to lose money, since it did not produce any physical power day-ahead. Similarly, the demand at bus 3 bought excess power day-ahead, which it now “sells back” at a slightly lower price than the day-ahead price at its location, 5 MW × $1729/MWh = $8645. The differences in the nodal price at bus 3 between day-ahead and real-time are due to differences in losses. In this case, the ISO remains revenue neutral. In the intermediate period shown in Fig. 5.3b, generator C, which was not dispatched in the day-ahead market due to the virtual supplier, is committed because demand is higher than anticipated by the day-ahead market. Remember that the reliability unit commitment postured generator D to potentially provide energy in the peak period, and in doing so committed to paying its start-up. However, by the intermediate period of the real-time market, using its look-ahead unit commitment software, the ISO is aware that both generators C and D will be needed for the peak period. Hence, it is economic to use generator C rather than generator D for the intermediate period. In fact, had both generators not been needed for the peak period, it would have been economic to “decommit” generator D following the reliability unit commitment and only use generator C due to its lower energy price. That is, the savings due to lower energy prices would have more than offset the higher cost of starting up generator C.
EBL
Table 5.9. Results of real-time market simulations and deviations from the day-ahead market Scenario
Demand (MWh)
Supply (MWh)
Price at bus ($/MWh)
A
B
1013 1288 1288
250 250
47 200
Deviations from the day-ahead market: Off-peak −5 −6 Intermediate +150 +61 Peak +20 0
+60 0
+47 +200
Off-peak Intermediate Peak
945 1450 1620
C
D
E
17
1 1500 1500 0 1500
0 +17
−197
0 0 0
2
3 1613 5280 6975
1729 4000 5000
−002 +3280 +1526
+1964 +900
Competitive Electricity Markets
216
Bus 1 A
$15
Bus 3 $17.29
D C 945 MW (–5 MW)
1013 MW (–6 MW)
$16.13
B
Bus 2 Fig. 5.3a. Off-peak scenario.
Bus 1 A
Bus 3
$15
$40
D C
47 MW 1450 MW (+150 MW)
1288 MW (+60 MW)
$52.80
EBL
B
250 MW Bus 2 (+60 MW)
Fig. 5.3b. Intermediate scenario.
Bus 1 A
$15
Bus 3 $50
17 MW D C
200 MW 1620 MW (+20 MW)
1288 MW
$69.75
B 250 MW
Bus 2 Fig. 5.3c. Peak scenario.
In the peak period shown in Fig. 5.3c, both peaking generators are dispatched, because peak demand is higher than was cleared in the day-ahead market and also higher than the ISO forecast in the reliability unit commitment. As noted, the ISO committed generator D in the reliability commitment, and in doing so was obligated to pay the generator its start-up costs regardless of whether it provided energy. Now that the generator has been
Design of US Wholesale Energy and Ancillary Service Auction Markets
217
dispatched to provide energy, the ISO must calculate whether its revenues are sufficient to cover its start-up costs. These calculations are shown in Section 5.6.1. In addition, the virtual supplier must “buy back” its position in the period in which it sold virtual energy day-ahead but at the real-time price. In this example, the virtual supplier buys back 197 MW at bus 3 at the real-time price of $50.00/MWh. Hence, the virtual supplier owes back $9850, for a net loss between day-ahead and real-time of (-$50 + $40) × 197 MW = -$1970. If the virtual supplier’s forecast that the real-time price would be $41.00/MWh had been correct, then it would have owed back −$7879, for a net profit between day-ahead and real-time of ($41 - $40) × 197 MW = $197. 5.5.7. Comparison of PJM and New York ISO market rules As with the day-ahead markets, the PJM and New York real-time markets both calculate LMPs for energy and zonal prices for several ancillary services. However, there are again some interesting differences in market design and procedures. 5.5.7.1. General dispatch procedures and energy market rules Beginning with the energy markets, the two ISOs have different offer price rules and trading deadlines. In PJM, the real-time market offer period begins immediately following the close of the day-ahead market at 16:00 and closes at 18:00 the prior day. In addition, like the day-ahead market, only a single supply function offer can be submitted for all 24 hours of the real-time market. In New York, offers and bids are only due 75 minutes before the operating day hour, and the offer price can vary for each hour. Unlike the day-ahead auction, the real-time auction schedule is the result of the interaction of market functions with several constantly updated forecasting and system monitoring systems. These are worth examining in some detail. In PJM, with all offers submitted, the system operators begin calculating ex ante dispatch instructions for the operating hour using its unit dispatch system. Data from three software systems feeds into the unit dispatch analysis: the energy management system calculates the load forecast, area control error, steam deviation, constraint data, unit sensitivities, and state estimator output; another software system updates unit outage data; and market systems software provides generator offers and data on dispatchable transactions (PJM, 2007b, d). In addition, as described below, a parallel program clears markets for regulation and spinning reserves using the unit dispatch data. The PJM energy dispatch auction subsequently clears using the most current data from the various software subsystems. The unit dispatch system calculates a dispatch solution including dispatch rates and generator unit MW every 5 minutes for a look-ahead period. The dispatcher must approve the solution before the data is sent to utilities and generators. The ISO then solves for a state estimator solution every 5 minutes to estimate the actual MW injections and withdrawals at buses. Actual schedules for external transactions are then included and the ISO sets real-time prices on an ex post basis. There are no penalties for deviations. In New York, as with the day-ahead market, in the real-time market, energy, regulation, and operating reserves are co-optimized. The calculation of real-time schedules and prices is implemented through two primary commitment and dispatch programs that exchange data with each other: the real-time unit commitment program, which conducts a 2.5-hour look-ahead with commitment decisions made on a 15-minute basis, and the real-time dispatch program, which establishes a 5-minute dispatch and calculates market prices on a 5-minute basis. The real-time unit commitment begins with the day-ahead
EBL
218
Competitive Electricity Markets
schedule and either commits or decommits units from that schedule based on offers submitted following the day-ahead market, changes in resource availability and updated load forecasts. Its commitment schedule is binding for units that need to be started up or moved to a dispatch point over a 30-minute look-ahead and advisory for units committed beyond that horizon. The commitment decisions are then passed to the real-time dispatch program, which can adjust the output of committed generators to determine an optimal dispatch and calculate prices.23 The dispatch produces ex ante binding prices and quantities every 5 minutes for the next 5- minute period and provides four additional advisory prices and quantities spaced over 5–15 minutes up to 50–60 minutes ahead, depending on the initial period. 5.5.7.2. Markets for regulation and reserves To establish the real-time dispatch, the ISOs have different methods for co-optimizing the offers for regulation and operating reserves with those for energy. As noted, the New York ISO operates a two-settlement system for regulation and operating reserve (NYISO, 2006). The basic rules for these markets were described above in the section on the day-ahead market. New York buyers purchase most of their regulation and reserve requirements through the day-ahead market. The ISO commits additional resources to provide these services in real-time if insufficient MW were cleared day-ahead, units that were scheduled day-ahead are not available in real-time, or additional MW are needed over the day-ahead forecast (only for regulation, which is a function of actual load). The offer rules for the New York real-time markets for operating reserves are largely the same as those for the day-ahead market, with the exception that all availability offers into the real-time market are assigned a price of $0/MW, meaning that their payments will be based on opportunity costs relative to their energy offer. In contrast to New York, PJM’s ancillary service markets clear after the day-ahead market, and before the real-time market (PJM, 2007b). PJM operates hourly real-time markets for two ancillary services, regulation and spinning reserve (called synchronous reserve).24 Suppliers include eligible generators and demand resources. Demand resources are currently limited to providing 25% of the regulation requirement. There are two types of spinning reserve resources: Tier 1 and Tier 2. Tier 1 is any incremental spinning reserve that is already available through the energy dispatch; i.e., from a generator that is already operating and has additional capacity available through ramping. Tier 2 is spinning reserve from generators that are synchronized to the grid but which need to be dispatched to a different operating point than they would be through the energy dispatch (including generators started-up to produce reserves). Regulation is procured in two separate zones in PJM,
EBL
23
The dispatch program’s procedure for normal (i.e., non-emergency) time periods is a three-pass approach. The first pass determines an initial set of binding physical schedules for generators that result from co-optimized minimization of the cost of energy, regulation, and operating reserves. This pass assumes that all fixed block units that have been committed by the real-time commitment are at their upper operating limits, whereas all other dispatchable capacity that has not been committed is flexible. The second pass then relaxes the constraint on loading fixed block units and allows them to be flexibly loaded. This pass determines whether the least-cost solution can be found through inflexible or flexible loading of such units. The third pass then calculates LMPs with the optimal mix of inflexible or flexible block loaded units. However, the third pass does not change the physical schedule determined in the first pass. 24 The regulation market began on June 1, 2000; the spinning reserve market began on December 1, 2002.
Design of US Wholesale Energy and Ancillary Service Auction Markets
219
while spinning reserve is procured in four zones, with zonal prices if transmission constraints separate the zones and a single price when they do not.25 Each load-serving entity must buy a pro-rata share of these services. As with energy, buyers can self-schedule using their own generators, contract with a third party, or purchase through the PJM market. Supply offers for regulation and Tier 2 reserve suppliers are due to PJM by 18:00 the prior day and the price cannot vary by hour of the day.26 Also, any units listed as available for these services but without an offer price are entered into the markets as price takers (i.e., with their prices offers set to zero). However, physical parameters can be changed up to 1 or 2 hours before the dispatch hour, as described below. In PJM, the process for scheduling ancillary services and calculating the dispatch similarly begins 1–2 hours prior to the dispatch hour. The first step in real-time market pricing is to calculate the prices for regulation and Tier 2 reserves, which are actually done prior to the real-time energy market and are thus ex ante rather than ex post. Since most units will provide both energy and ancillary services, PJM’s market deadlines for submitting physical parameters for both regulation and spinning reserve are within 1–2 hours of the operating hour. The data on ancillary services (including price offers) is then evaluated by PJM using its unit dispatch system software. For regulation, the final regulation capability (MW) above and below the regulation midpoint and the regulation maximum and minimum values (MW) must be finalized 1 hour prior to the operating hour. For spinning reserves, ramp rates and maximum reserve MW are due 2 hours prior to the dispatch hour. This information is then used to estimate the Tier 1 reserve schedules, which are posted 90 minutes prior to the dispatch hour. Reserve availability and offer quantities for Tier 2 resources are due by 1 hour prior to the dispatch hour. Self-schedules are also due by 1 hour prior, with exceptions for units substituted for others that have become unavailable and for units that have only become available during the dispatch hour. The pricing of ancillary services is then conducted through a co-optimization of forecast energy prices for the hour with the offers and parameters submitted for regulation and spinning reserves. The forecast LMPs are the result of a 1-hour look-ahead provided by PJM’s unit dispatch tool. For regulation, PJM calculates a supply stack that reflects each regulation units offer and any opportunity costs incurred by not producing energy. The highest merit order unit price becomes the regulation market clearing price for the hour. Similarly to regulation, for the Tier 2 reserves, PJM’s objective is to calculate a supply stack that reflects a Tier 2 unit’s offer price for standing by on reserve as well as any opportunity costs that it might incur by not providing energy (a demand resource has an opportunity cost of zero). The formula is as follows:
EBL
Resource merit order price ($/MWh) = Resource synchronized reserve offer + estimated resource opportunity cost per MWh of capability + energy use per MWh of capability.27 25
The PJM regulation requirement is 1% of the PJM peak load for the day. For regulation, this offer restriction was justified on the basis of market power concerns; see discussion in Section 5.8. 27 PJM applies different formulas for the estimated resource opportunity cost. For condensing combustion turbines, this opportunity cost is calculated as the absolute value of the difference between the unit’s energy offer price and the forecast LMP at the unit’s bus multiplied by the unit’s MW capability with this number then divided by the unit’s synchronized reserve capability. For non-condensing units, this opportunity cost is calculated as the absolute value of the difference between the forecast LMP and the price estimated for the unit’s set point to provide its assigned quantity of synchronized 26
220
Competitive Electricity Markets
The price of Tier 2 spinning reserves in each zone is the highest resource merit price for the operating hour. The prices for regulation and spinning reserves are posted no later than 30 minutes prior to the operating hour. Tier 1 reserves are priced not for capacity on reserve but on the basis of actual output in response to a reserve call. The price is a $50 premium over the LMP for energy. In the event that spinning reserve units are called to provide energy and do not perform, Tier 1 units are credited for the MW that they provide but are not penalized otherwise, while Tier 2 units have to repay for any non-performance by providing the MW shortfall for the next 3 consecutive, same peak days.
5.6. The Revenue Sufficiency Guarantee As described above, participants in the ISO markets are subject both to market incentives and to operational instructions that may be required to maintain system reliability. To establish the appropriate incentives for market sellers and buyers to follow both auction schedules and operational instructions, there are two types of rules. First, there is a “revenue sufficiency guarantee” that any multi-part offer accepted by the auction will be fully compensated through additional payments if market revenues are not sufficient to meet its offer requirements. These additional payments are then billed to buyers as an “uplift” – an ex post charge assigned on some averaged basis. This rule will be the subject of this section. There is a second type of rule, related to the first but less frequently needed, which is that any participant that has sold or bought through the markets and is then requested by the ISO to change its schedule or physical position for reliability reasons will not lose money in doing so.28 In the early phases of market design, the question of how to calculate and allocate revenue sufficiency guarantee charges was a quite heavily contested issue.29 The simplest proposition was that such uplift should be paid on a load-weighted share basis by all demand. However, for merchant suppliers that were interested in primarily transacting through the forward contract markets, there was a concern that allocating the uplift to buyers through the spot markets would provide a financial advantage to sellers into the spot markets. That is, a generator seeking to create a short-term bilateral contract would have to incorporate its start-up costs into the forward contract price, whereas spot sellers could have their start-up costs spread out over the buyers in the ISO market. Further, bilateral buyers might thus double-pay if they both paid for start-up via a forward contract and for other spot sellers as part of an uplift charge. Some sellers thus asked that their contracted purchasers be insulated from the market-wide uplift charges. The position taken by the ISOs and supported by FERC (e.g., FERC, 1999) was that generators would be started up to provide both energy and ancillary services, such as regulation and operating reserves; since the latter were reliability services that buyers could not easily dis-aggregate from energy, there was a rationale for allocating the uplift to all buyers on a total demand basis.
EBL
reserve multiplied by the quantity of synchronized reserve provided. Finally, the energy use component of the price is calculated as the forecast LMP multiplied by the MW of energy use divided by the synchronized reserve capability. 28 For example, a generator may be asked to ramp down even though the prior real-time LMP at its bus indicated that it should increase production. These types of problem are often related to difficulties in integrating the market price calculation with the short-term operational decisions. 29 See, e.g., discussion of New York ISO’s rules in FERC (1999), pp. 42–3.
Design of US Wholesale Energy and Ancillary Service Auction Markets
221
Another design issue concerns the assignment of such uplift to virtual transactions. As noted above, a virtual supplier “sells” energy in the day-ahead market and then “buys it back” in the real-time market. The virtual seller may displace some physical generation offers in the day-ahead market that are then re-scheduled through the reliability unit commitment. In theory, the start-up and stand-by of the physical units may embody some costs that are then passed to the revenue sufficiency guarantee uplift, either day-ahead or in real-time.30 In some cases, such virtual positions may cause uplift to be shifted from one party to another.31 Whether such ex post uplift charges should be allocated to the virtual suppliers is a contested design issues in the US ISO markets (see, e.g., Hogan, 2006). There is no simple and accurate way to calculate the actual price impact of virtual sellers on real-time market uplift charges. The most accurate (in a static sense) would be to re-solve the day-ahead and real-time market sequence with and without virtual transactions represented as a means to quantify the difference. This might be a relatively simple analysis for the day-ahead market, requiring one pass of the unit commitment algorithm, but obviously in real-time, it would require re-solving the dispatch algorithm for every 5-minute market clearing to determine which generators were dispatched to a different level due to the removal of the virtual suppliers. The simplest method is to treat all virtual supply MW as effectively demand in the real-time market and to assign uplift charges to such virtual suppliers proportionally to their share of total MW. This approach does not distinguish the impact of virtual suppliers on the uplift. For example, some virtual supply might be accepted day-ahead but not result in any physical generation being scheduled that would not have been otherwise, but would nevertheless face uplift charges on per-MW basis. In the face of such alternatives, another option is to not charge virtuals any uplift on the basis that the economic benefits that result from market price convergence outweigh any cost shifts that they might cause (e.g., as recommended by Hogan, 2006). FERC has generally supported the principle of “cost-causation” – that entities that create costs should be billed for them – and the simple approach of assigning virtual supply uplift charges on a per-MW basis, although it has not precluded the more complicated analysis of calculating virtual supply’s actual impact on uplift and assigning costs appropriately.
EBL
5.6.1. Numerical example (continued) This section applies the principles of revenue sufficiency to the numerical example. In Tables 5.10 and 5.11, the total revenues that each generator earns in the day-ahead and real-time markets are compared to its offer price requirements for energy and start-up 30
Similarly a virtual demand bid that clears the day-ahead market may cause a physical generator to be scheduled that would not have been otherwise. In the reliability unit commitment, the ISO uses its own load forecast so that virtual demand can be removed from the schedule. 31 For example, if there is no charge to virtual suppliers, a vertically integrated utility that is an actual consumer of power, i.e., will have metered energy withdrawal in real time, can also shift uplift charges from day-ahead to real-time, if that is financially advantageous, by taking a virtual seller position. To do so, it substitutes virtual supply for its actual generation day-ahead, thus reducing any revenue sufficiency uplift paid by its day-ahead load. Its physical generators are then scheduled through the reliability unit commitment or in real time, creating revenue sufficiency uplift. However, since its day-ahead load has not deviated, all the uplift is billed to net real-time load.
Table 5.10. Day-ahead market calculation of revenue sufficiency Revenues ($) Off-peak Generator A 15 275 Generator B Virtual E
Offer Requirements ($) Intermediate
Peak
Total
18 411 3 793
19 316 13 623 8 076
53 002 15 275 17 416 8 076
EBL
Off-peak
Revenue Sufficiency
Intermediate
Peak
Start-up
Total
18 411 3 793
19 316 5 000 8 076
– 1 000 0
53 002 9 793 8 076
0 7 623 0
Table 5.11. Real-time market calculation of revenue sufficiency (including reliability unit commitment) Revenues ($) Off-peak Generator Generator Generator Generator
A B C D
−87
Offer Requirements ($) (including reliability unit commitment) Intermediate 905 3186 1879
Peak − − 10 000 849
Total 819 3186 11 879 849
EBL
Off-peak
Intermediate
Peak
Start-up
Total
−87
905 1207 1879
− − 8000 849
− − 2000 100
819 − 11 879 949
Revenue Sufficiency
0 1979 0 −100
224
Competitive Electricity Markets
shown in Table 5.4.32 The total revenues for each generator in each energy market are the generator’s output (MWh) in each period multiplied by the LMP ($/MWh) at its location, and summed over all periods. This revenue is shown in column 5 of Tables 5.10 and 5.11 (the source data is shown in Figs 5.2a–c and 5.3a–c, and Tables 5.5 and 5.9). The total offer requirement for each generator is equal to the generator’s start-up offer price and the sum of the generator’s output in each period multiplied by its offer price ($/MWh). This requirement is shown in column 10 of Tables 5.10 and 5.11. All generator offers and the virtual offer are included in Tables 5.10 and 5.11, although not each of these offers is eligible for the revenue sufficiency guarantee in the example. For example, the base-load generator A is not assumed to have submitted start-up costs to the ISO because it is not starting-up in the period of the daily auction. Similarly, the virtual offer E is not eligible because it has no start-up offer (and is not allowed to submit one). The final column in Tables 5.10 and 5.11 shows whether each offer is revenue sufficient. In the day-ahead market, shown in Table 5.10, each supply offer is revenue sufficient, and generator B makes revenues that exceed its offer requirements. However, in the real-time market, shown in Table 5.11, generator D does not earn sufficient revenues in the energy market to cover its offer prices for energy and start-up. It is thus owed $100 by the ISO. As noted, because the ISO is revenue neutral, this uplift payment is charged to some set of market participants. For example, it could be charged to real-time demand. Table 5.9 shows that in the intermediate and peak periods, 170 MWh of demand was present in real-time that was not cleared day-ahead (ignoring the −5 MWh deviation in the off-peak period). Hence, spreading the $100 over this demand on an averaged basis would result in an approximately $0.59/MWh additional charge to each 1 MWh purchase of energy in real-time. If the −197 MWh deviation caused by the virtual supplier was added to the real-time demand, as it is in some ISOs, then the per MWh uplift would be approximately $0.27/MWh.
EBL
5.6.2. Comparison of PJM and New York ISO market rules The ISOs allocate revenue sufficiency guarantee uplift in roughly the same fashion, but with some differences. PJM collects the uplift for the revenue sufficiency guarantee for energy as a part of its charges for providing operating reserves, presumably because startup and no-load payments are required for units that are turned on to provide reserves (PJM, 2007b; see also discussion in PJM, 2004). PJM calls this payment “operating reserves charges” and applies them in both the day-ahead and real-time markets. PJM allocates such charges day-ahead to the day-ahead demand, including accepted virtual bids (called decrement bids in PJM), and exports; in real-time, any additional charges are allocated to deviations from day-ahead schedules, including virtual supply (called increment bids in PJM) and demand. Similarly to PJM, New York ISO collects this uplift on a pro-rata basis from all wholesale buyers, but through a per unit charge for transmission scheduling. New York ISO also charges virtual supply for any incremental costs that such transactions cause through the real-time revenue sufficiency guarantee (NYISO, 2005). 5.7. Pricing and Settlement of Marginal Congestion and Losses Heretofore, locational marginal pricing of energy has been discussed at a general level, noting that such prices in the ISOs typically reflect the effect of both marginal congestion 32
In the ISO markets, the revenue sufficiency guarantee extends also to the “no-load” component of the energy offer.
Design of US Wholesale Energy and Ancillary Service Auction Markets
225
and marginal losses. In this section, more detail is provided on how the ISOs calculate these components of LMPs and how they collect and dispose of the marginal congestion and marginal loss surplus payments. The computational issue is worth discussing because it relies on certain technical assumptions and the results are sometimes misunderstood. When the transmission constraints that are examined here – capacity limits on transmission facilities and loss factors – affect LMPs, the ISO almost always collects surplus payments through the energy auction. Because the ISO is a revenue neutral organization, it must dispose of that surplus, i.e., refund it to market participants in some fashion. The rules that are devised for such refunds are somewhat different in each ISO. 5.7.1. Computation of marginal congestion and marginal losses As mentioned in Section 5.3.2, an LMP can be disaggregated into three components, using methods discussed below (Schweppe et al., 1988): 1. The price of energy at a slack or reference bus located on the ISO network; 2. The marginal congestion cost associated with delivering energy from the reference bus to another node and; 3. The marginal loss cost associated with delivering energy from the reference bus to another node. The LMP is the sum of these three factors. The difference in the congestion or loss component between two nodes on the system, A and B, equals the marginal congestion or loss charge associated with injecting at A and withdrawing at B (i.e., a bilateral schedule). There are several ways to calculate the LMP components. The following method is the most common. First, the energy component is defined as the LMP at some (arbitrary) “slack” or “reference” bus, or as a weighted sum of LMPs over a set of “distributed” slack buses assuming a fixed set of proportions. The loss component of a bus LMP is the cost of the marginal losses resulting from increasing the load at that bus by 1 MW, assuming that the entire load increase, including incremental losses, are met from the slack bus (or distributed slacks according to the assumed proportions). The loss component may be positive or negative, depending on whether losses or increase or decrease as a result of the load increase. Finally, the congestion component is the difference between the bus’s LMP and the sum of the energy and loss components. Note that these components depend on the arbitrary choice of a slack bus; what is not arbitrary is their sum – the LMP – at each location. In theory, congestion-only payments to financial transmission rights depend on this arbitrary choice of slack. However, ISOs have generally gotten agreement from stakeholders on the definition of the slack buses; for instance, one approach is to use a distributed slack based on the average load distribution (e.g., California ISO, 2005). This is equivalent to assuming that an addition of 1 MW of load at any bus is met by decreasing the original loads at all buses by the same percentage. An advantage of this definition is that the load-weighted value of the loss component is then, in theory, equal to zero. The definition of the LMP components allow for a decomposition of the total surplus earned by the ISO into its loss and congestion components. Multiplying the net withdrawal (load minus generation) at each bus by the congestion component and then summing over all buses yields the congestion surplus; then subtracting this from the total surplus gives an estimate of the loss surplus. Note that the loss surplus will then have two components: the sum of the net withdrawals times the loss component minus the total system losses times the energy component.
EBL
226
Competitive Electricity Markets
An alternative approach for separating the two surpluses is to define the congestion surplus as the sum of the flowgate prices [dual variables for transmission component capacity constraints in the dispatch solution; see Eqs (2) and (3) of Appendix 5A] times the flow, and then the loss surplus is the congestion surplus subtracted from the total surplus. However, the total loss surplus defined in this manner cannot be disaggregated into a bus-by-bus loss component, and so this definition has not been adopted by any ISO.
5.7.2. Disposal of marginal congestion charge surplus By definition, the ISO collects congestion surplus payments from buyers whenever transmission capacity constraints bind in the auction. This is because transmission congestion prevents the cheapest generators from operating at full capacity prior to the dispatch of more expensive units. The surplus occurs when the ISO collects more from buyers than it owes to sellers due to such congestion. Although the total dollar amount that the ISO collects in surplus congestion charges varies over time and among the ISOs, it is generally measured as being under 10% of total market participant expenditures.33 The primary mechanism for refunding these congestion surpluses to ISO market participants is through the assignment of financial transmission (property) rights, subject to the requirement of simultaneous feasibility (which ensures that the ISO will be revenue adequate).34 In general, ISOs either allocate transmission rights directly to certain market participants (in the United States, the allocation is to “load-serving entities,” which is typically defined as the party that has the contract to serve retail demand) or conduct auctions for the rights and then provide the auction revenues to the eligible market participants (again, in the United States, the load-serving entities). However they are obtained, these transmission rights collect most of the congestion surpluses that the ISO collects on an hourly basis in the day-ahead market (see, e.g., PJM, 2007a, p. 266). Any surplus congestion rents remaining after transmission rights are settled represents uses of the grid by parties that do not hold transmission rights but pay congestion charges. If there is any congestion surplus left over at the end of the year (or the period defined in the market rules), each ISO has rules defining how it is disposed. Some of these rules are discussed below.
EBL
5.7.3. Disposal of marginal loss charge surplus The calculation of marginal losses provides the market with a more efficient dispatch than would be the case if locational prices only reflected congestion. However, because losses are usually represented as a quadratic function of line loadings (e.g., Schweppe et al., 1988), the marginal loss charge between two locations will be greater than the average loss charge. The quadratic function implies that the average cost of losses is 33
For example, PJM reports that total congestion costs have ranged between 7 and 10% of total billings between 2002 and 2006 (PJM, 2007a). See also discussion on congestion metrics in Chapter 4. 34 That is, the ISO will collect sufficient congestion charges in each market in which financial transmission rights are settled to pay all the outstanding rights. This rule holds as long as the system topology used in the simultaneous feasibility of the rights remains the same in actual market (see Harvey et al., 1997).
Design of US Wholesale Energy and Ancillary Service Auction Markets
227
roughly one-half the marginal cost. Hence, the ISO will always collect surplus marginal loss payments. The disposal of the marginal loss surplus has been a controversial issue in market design, more for reasons of equity than efficiency. In general, any method for disposal of this surplus will support efficient scheduling by a particular market participant as long as the method leaves the participant indifferent between accepting the ISO schedule or dispatch and undertaking an alternative, inefficient schedule or dispatch to obtain loss refunds (e.g., by changing its supply offers or self-scheduling).35 However, equity would suggest that the refund method is not entirely arbitrary, since it could involve unfair transfers among market participants based on pre-existing historical contracts.36 Market participants concerned about the uncertainty of the relationship between marginal loss charges and their share of their refund often have sought a tradable loss hedging right similar in principle to financial transmission rights for congestion. Because of the non-linearity of line losses, designing such a tradable loss right has not been straightforward. Losses are an example of diseconomies of scale or super-additive costs, such that Ky1 + Ky2 ≥ Ky1 + y2 . Therefore, there is no simple way to decentralize trading of losses, since loss is a function of power flows (unlike transmission capacity, which is assumed to be independent of power flows in the transmission rights model discussed earlier). However, there is less uncertainty about losses than about congestion charges. Therefore, even though average losses through the year can be approximately as costly as transmission congestion, the risks to transactions are less. Therefore, financial transmission rights that cover just congestion costs are likely to cover most of the risks that market participants care about. 5.7.4. Numerical example (continued)
EBL
In the examples given in Sections 5.3.6 and 5.5.5, the total LMP surplus collected by the ISO was calculated as the difference between payments by buyers and payments to sellers. In this section, that total surplus is disaggregated into congestion surpluses and loss surpluses for two of the day-ahead examples: the off-peak and intermediate scenarios (in Section 5.3.6). Changes in the total surplus between day-ahead and real-time are shown in Table 5.12. Turning first to the day-ahead off-peak case shown in Fig. 5.2a, the prices at buses 1, 2, and 3 are $15.00/MWh, $16.13/MWh, and $17.31/MWh, respectively. If the slack bus is assumed to be bus 1, then the LMP price components (using the CAISO, 2005 methodology) are an energy component of $15/MWh; loss components of $0.00, $1.13, 35
For example, consider a buyer that has the choice between scheduling generator A or B to serve load at C. A has a lower energy offer price (and actual marginal cost) than B but a higher loss charge than B associated with deliveries to C, resulting in a higher LMP at the load bus than if B was scheduled. The efficient schedule is to dispatch B. As long as the loss refund method makes the buyer indifferent between accepting the scheduling of A or B, it will result in the efficient scheduling of B. In this simple case, if the loss refund exactly matched the loss charge for scheduling A, then the buyer would have the incentive to self-schedule A inefficiently. 36 In some US regions, notably the Midwest ISO, some generator siting and contractual decisions made prior to the start of the ISO market were not fully reflective of actual losses (implying some cost shifting). In such regions, there was the sense that marginal loss refunds should be related to actual losses in some fashion for some period to reflect those historical decisions, even if not on a transaction basis.
Competitive Electricity Markets
228
Table 5.12. ISO surplus collection in dollars due to congestion and losses Total Surplus Day-ahead market
Off-peak Intermediate Peak Total
1 169 4 264 24 585 30 018
Real-time market
Off-peak Intermediate Peak Total (net)
1 155 (−14) 23 605 (+19 341) 33 398 (+8 813) +28 140
(change from day-ahead)
and $2.31 per MWh, respectively, at the three buses; and zero congestion components. The loss component at, for instance, bus 2 is calculated by incrementing the load by 1 MW; to meet that load, 1.0873 more MW of generation is needed from the slack. The value of the 0.0757 MW of losses, evaluated at the slack’s LMP of $15/MWh, is $1.13/MWh. As shown in Section 5.3.6, the difference between what the ISO collects from demand and what it owes to generators is an auction surplus, which in this case is $1169 (Table 5.12). In the day-ahead intermediate scenario shown in Fig. 5.2b, there are both loss and congestion surpluses due to the binding transmission constraint. The prices at buses 1, 2, and 3 are $15.00/MWh, $20.00/MWh, and $20.36/MWh, respectively. Using bus 1 as the slack bus for the purpose of calculating LMP components, the energy component of the price is $15.00/MWh, while the loss (congestion) components are $0 ($0), $1.18 ($4.82), and $3.19 ($1.17) per MWh, respectively at the three buses. As discussed in Section 5.3.6, the total surplus collected by the ISO is $4264 (Table 5.12). Using the above LMP components, the congestion surplus portion of this total surplus is $2163. This means that the loss component is $2,101, equaling the sum of the loss LMP components times the net withdrawals ($3857) minus the energy LMP component times the net losses ($1756). As noted above, this division is arbitrary. If the LMP components were instead based on using the load bus (bus 3) as the slack bus (as in the CAISO, 2005 methodology), the estimates of the surpluses results would have been different. Then the energy component would be $20.36 (the bus 3 price), and the loss components would have been −$3.52, −$2.20, and $0.00 per MWh at the three respective buses.37 The resulting congestion components would also be negative, being −$1.84, $1.84, and $0.00 per MWh, respectively. The congestion surplus would then be calculated as (−184×−1227 +184×−190) or $1920. Subtracted from the total surplus of $4264, this yields a loss surplus of $2355. Thus, the loss and congestion surpluses based on bus 3 being the slack are each about 10% different from the values based on a bus 1 slack, above. Finally, if the congestion surplus was instead defined based on flowgate shadow prices, it would instead equal $5.39 (the price for the congested flowgate between buses 1 and 2) times 350 MW (the corresponding flow), or $1886; this would imply a total loss surplus of $4264 − $1886 = $2378. These values are close but not identical to the component surpluses
EBL
37
See also discussion in footnote 17.
Design of US Wholesale Energy and Ancillary Service Auction Markets
229
resulting from using the distributed load slack (bus 3) as the slack bus. As noted, this method is not used by ISOs because it does not disaggregate to the bus level. LMPs are calculated both day-ahead and in real-time, and the value of the ISO surpluses may change between the two markets, as shown in Table 5.12. For example, in the off-peak scenarios shown in Figs 5.2a and 5.3a, since there is no congestion, all the surplus collected by the ISO is due to losses. There is less demand off-peak in real-time than day-ahead, so the ISO effectively “owes back” $14 in loss surplus that was assigned to day-ahead buyers after the resettlement of the sellers’ and buyers’ real-time positions (as discussed in Section 5.5.5). In practice, the ISO surpluses are not disbursed or refunded on an hourly basis, but are aggregated for later disbursal. In the intermediate and peak scenarios, there are also congestion surpluses due to the binding transmission constraint. In the day-ahead intermediate market scenario, the congestion and loss surpluses are fairly close in value. However, in the real-time intermediate market scenario, due to the increase in demand that requires the dispatch of the more expensive generator at bus 3 and continued congestion causing an increase in the price differentials between buses 1 and 3 (but also creating a negative differential between buses 2 and 3), the total surplus greatly increases relative to the day-ahead surplus. The ISO thus collects additional surpluses in real-time, which are recovered from real-time buyers. A similar result is seen in the peak scenario. The interpretation of these results must be done carefully. If market participants hold financial transmission rights and are concerned that the settlements of such rights dayahead will not collect sufficient revenues compared to congestion charges in real-time, then they can use virtual bids and offers to effectively shift their congestion hedge to real-time. This was discussed in Section 5.3.1. With regard to changes in marginal loss surpluses between day-ahead and real-time, these surpluses in total are refunded to market participants, regardless of which market they occurred in. Some ISOs have specific rules to account for differences in magnitudes between the day-ahead and real-time loss surplus so as to ensure that these differences do not create inefficient scheduling incentives when the loss refunds are determined.
EBL
5.7.5. Comparison of PJM and New York ISO market rules As with many areas of auction market design, there are some differences in the rules in PJM and New York regarding dispersal of ISO congestion and loss charge surpluses. Beginning with congestion surpluses, in both markets, these are used initially to pay the set of awarded financial transmission rights. Any residual congestion surplus is then subsequently refunded to market participants. As of this writing, in PJM, the existing transmission rights are paid in full only if the ISO collected sufficient congestion revenues to do so; otherwise, payments are pro-rated.38 At the end of each month and over the course of the period covered by annual allocations of financial transmission rights, PJM then distributes any residual congestion surplus in five stages (PJM, 2007b, p. 46). In the first stage, any surplus is allocated to holders of financial transmission rights that were deficient with respect to their target allocation for the month. In the second stage, any remaining surplus is allocated to financial transmission right payment deficiencies in prior months of the year. Third, any remaining surplus (after stages one and two) is carried 38
This rule is due to change in 2008, at which time PJM will pay all transmission rights in full regardless of shortfalls in congestion revenues, through an uplift charge.
230
Competitive Electricity Markets
forward to the subsequent month and distributed in the same fashion. Fourth, at the end of the year, any remaining surplus is used to compensate for any deficiency in payments to auction revenue rights. Finally, any remaining annual surplus is distributed to entities that had paid PJM transmission access charges that year in proportion to their demand charges or MW reserved capacity for transmission service into, out of, or through the transmission system. New York ISO has a different method for settlement of financial transmission rights in the event of a congestion rent shortfall, and hence the rules for disposing of any residual congestion surplus after cashing out the transmission rights are also different. Unlike PJM, in the event of a shortfall in congestion revenues, payments to the financial transmission rights are made wholly by transmission owners in New York via a pass-through to their retail rates (sometimes called “full funding” of the rights). Because of this rule, any residual congestion charge surplus is disbursed to transmission owners. With respect to losses, both PJM and New York ISO implement a marginal loss calculation in locational marginal pricing. New York ISO’s surplus, which it calls the “residual loss payment,” along with surpluses collected in other ways (with the exception of congestion cost surplus), is credited against what transmission customers are billed as aggregate ISO costs, which include operational costs and the costs of implementing certain ISO programs, such as demand response payments (NYISO, 2001a, Rate Schedule 1).
5.8. Market Power Monitoring and Mitigation
EBL
The basic definitions and procedures of market power monitoring and mitigation were introduced in Section 5.2. Here more detail is provided, in particular on the ISO auction rules for economic withholding. ISO markets typically encompass sufficient geographic territory and enough suppliers that generation market concentration is relatively low by most market-wide measures, except in two cases: first, when transmission constraints bind causing ISO market concentration to rise in sub-regions, and second, when supply is scarce and the lack of demand elasticity allows even small suppliers to raise prices. Both of these market conditions are typically intermittent, and their frequency is a factor in creating the mitigation rules. For example, if a transmission constraint causes a persistent, concentrated sub-market to emerge, sometimes called a “load pocket,” then a specific remedy may be required for that sub-market, e.g., requiring some generators to sign cost-based contracts.
5.8.1. Identifying and mitigating exercise of market power In the US ISOs, three actions are typically identified as the exercise of market power: physical withholding, economic withholding, and uneconomic production. Physical withholding refers to any withdrawal of physical generation capacity from the market, including both units that are self-scheduled and those offered into the auction, that could be construed as an attempt to raise the market price. This could result from unscheduled outages that cannot be justified ex post, changes in a generator’s physical parameters in its offer that cause it to reduce its output, and failure to respond to an ISO’s dispatch instructions. Forced outages and scheduled maintenance are obviously not considered physical withholding. Physical withholding is typically simple to detect, but can be difficult to prove as intentional exercise of market power in the absence of clear evidence. Hence,
Design of US Wholesale Energy and Ancillary Service Auction Markets
231
ISOs have adopted certain measures, such as a percentage share of a generator’s available capability withheld or percentage deviation from a dispatch instruction, before physical withholding is identified as a market rule violation. Mitigation measures are ex post, and typically involve either revising the generator’s offer or applying penalties. Economic withholding refers to raising offer prices substantially above marginal cost, including opportunity cost, so as to affect the market clearing price. Typically, an offer that is economically withheld is one that has raised its price sufficiently to not get picked by the auction. However, in electricity markets, short-term demand is largely inelastic – i.e., not price sensitive – in which case there will be times when all offers are picked and any price can theoretically clear the market. One situation in which this could be the case when demand is inelastic is if one or more suppliers are “pivotal,” meaning that if they withdraw all their available capability the market could not clear. Most ISOs have implemented a threefold approach to mitigation of economic withholding in the energy market. The first component is an absolute offer cap on day-ahead and real-time energy, which currently stands at $400/MWh in California and $1000/MWh in the eastern US ISOs. No offer can exceed this cap, but a locational market price can be higher than the cap due to network effects. A second component, present in some ISO markets but not in others, is offer caps outside the transmission constrained area that are below the absolute cap. In some ISOs, such as New York ISO as described later, these have been implemented in a two-step fashion sometimes called a “conduct-impact test.” In the first step (the conduct test), an offer is screened to determined whether it has violated a percentage increase, or absolute dollar amount increase, from a “reference” accepted offer price. The reference offer is typically an average of prior accepted offers and is understood to be a proxy for a competitive market offer. In the second step (the impact test), the ISO determines whether offers that violated the first step also increased the LMPs by some additional threshold. An offer that violates both steps is mitigated to its reference offer price and the auction is re-run. The third component is offer caps for persistently transmission constrained locations, where presumably generation market power is more prevalent. These tend to be more restrictive than the offer caps for locations that are less frequently transmission constrained. They are also strict caps rather than the screens discussed above. ISOs have adopted different approaches to monitoring and mitigating the price offers for start-up and no-load. In some ISOs, these are restricted to being modified infrequently, while in other ISOs, where they can change daily, they can be subject to similar offer caps to energy. There are also offer caps in the ancillary services markets; in some cases, where there is administrative scarcity pricing for operating reserves, those prices effectively set the reserves market price and through simultaneous co-optimization of energy and reserves also set the energy LMPs.
EBL
5.8.2. Contractual remedies There are typically a number of generators in ISO markets that have locational market power because they are needed to operate for reliability purposes or persistently to resolve congestion. Some such generators were built to provide transmission support. Others are older generators that are only intermittently used for peak hours but which cannot recover fixed costs through the market. For such units, which are sometimes called “reliability must run” units, a contractual solution may be required. Such contracts may be cost-based or pay the higher of a market price or a contract price.
232
Competitive Electricity Markets
5.8.3. Comparison of PJM and New York ISO market rules PJM and New York ISO have a number of differences in their market power monitoring and mitigation rules, stemming from their regulatory histories and aspects of their subsequent market development. The most prominent difference is that PJM uses mandatory cost-based offers as a basis for mitigating transmission constrained supply offers (if needed), while New York ISO has a quite different approach under which the system is subdivided into pre-specified “constrained areas” in which there are formulas for offer caps that depend on the frequency of congestion and areas outside the constrained areas, where a conduct-impact test is applied. These differences will be explained below. PJM began its centralized auction market for energy in April 1998 and operated it for a full year with all supply offers capped at marginal costs.39 When the bid-based energy market was begun in April 1999, PJM continued this method of mitigating supply offers when an energy offer was from a generator’s whose output was altered due to transmission congestion, called an “out-of-merit” generator. Subsequently to beginning its markets, PJM also tightened the rules for start-up and no-load. Currently, a generator can choose between cost-based and price-based offers for these offer components. If it chooses cost-based offers, these can be adjusted daily. However, if it chooses price-based offers, these can only be adjusted twice a year, during enrollment periods (a generator can also switch between cost- and price-based offers in these enrollment periods). Other rules have addressed physical offer parameters, which can provide a generator with market power with additional means to affect market clearing prices. For example, in PJM, the market monitor found in the summer of 1999 that during peak demand hours when the ISO requested all generators to produce on an emergency basis (called “maximum generation emergency alert” in PJM), certain generators anticipated the shortage and increased their minimum run times to the full day. This allowed them to get paid their offer price (including start-up) in hours of the day when the market price had subsided below their offer. The market rule change to address this issue required that a generator’s total offer, including payments for start-up and no-load, could not exceed $1000/MWh during the specific hours of the emergency. In any other hours that the generator would operate due to its minimum run time, it would be a price-taker in the market and would not be eligible for additional revenue sufficiency payments (FERC, 2000). Sometimes, market power rules are overly restrictive. In PJM, for generators subject to offer caps due to being out-of-merit, concern grew that particularly for persistently offer-capped units, energy market prices were not sufficient for such units to recover long-term variable costs. In PJM, this lead to a reduced application of offer caps through two measures. First, PJM developed a new test, called the “three pivotal supplier test,” to determine when a transmission constraint was creating a truly uncompetitive market behind the constraint. The offer cap is not applied to a generator that affects a particular constrained transmission path if there are three or fewer suppliers that are jointly pivotal with respect to the constraint and if the owner of the generator when combined with
EBL
39
This was because FERC rejected PJM’s first market proposal in 1997 which did not provide sufficient information about generation market power to satisfy regulatory requirements (FERC, 1997). However, while PJM undertook its market power analysis, FERC allowed it to start market operations in April 1998 with the condition that market power was mitigated in the interim using offers capped at marginal cost. The market with liberalized supply offers began one year later.
Design of US Wholesale Energy and Ancillary Service Auction Markets
233
the two largest other suppliers affecting the constraint is not pivotal (PJM Tariff, Section 5.6.4). Second, PJM allows generators that are frequently mitigated to recover a greater percentage over and above their incremental cost offer cap.40 PJM has also established market power mitigation rules for its regulation and reserves markets. At the start of the regulation market in 2000, PJM expressed some concern about the market concentration (i.e., the low number of potential sellers) and as a result was allowed to establish the requirement that regulation price offers cannot vary by hour and later also that they would be subject to a $100/MWh cap. Moreover, due to market concentration some generators in PJM can only submit cost-based offers for regulation. In the spinning reserve market, several zones have caps based on cost-based rates. New York ISO initially began its markets in November 1999 with generation offer restrictions only within New York City, an obvious load pocket, called a “constrained area.” FERC approved this approach based on New York ISO’s demonstration that the market outside the constrained area was sufficiently un-concentrated. However, in 2000, New York ISO and its external market monitor developed the “conduct-impact” approach to screening supply offers described above, which has subsequently been adopted directly or in modified form by the other ISO markets, with the exception of PJM. As a component of this method, New York developed a market-based approach to measuring a benchmark competitive offer (and hence to avoid requiring generators to submit marginal cost offers, as in PJM). The basic method is to use the average of a generator’s accepted offers in the prior 90 days as a reference price. If there is not a sufficient history of accepted offers, then there are other methods for setting reference prices. The offer caps under this rule are shown in Table 5.13. As in PJM, the rules differ between constrained areas and those in largely unconstrained areas. This is not surprising since a market-based reference offer would reflect the market concentration in the constrained area. Hence, as shown in Table 5.13, the New York ISO resorts to offer caps that are a declining function of the average price in the constrained areas and the number of hours that the area is congested. Like PJM, New York ISO has also had some experience with overly restrictive mitigation rules. Generators in New York City was initially subject almost continuously to offer caps set roughly at the level of their variable production costs. In 2004, these rules were revised to conform to the conduct-impact approach used in other parts of the system (Potomac Economics, 2005). This reduced the frequency of mitigation and allowed prices to rise to levels more reflective of scarcity within the area.
EBL
5.9. Other Topics in ISO Market Design and Implementation This section reviews several other topics in ISO market design and implementation that have been prominent in the United States in the period under review. The first of these is the interaction between the daily energy auction markets and longer-term markets and other functions undertaken by the ISO. The second is the continued existence of market “seams” that include boundaries of market operations that do not conform to natural 40
Specifically, for units that are offer capped for (a) between 60% and 70% of their run hours, the offer cap is either incremental cost plus 10% or incremental cost plus $20/MWh; (b) between 70% and 80% of their run hours, the offer cap is either incremental cost plus 15% or incremental cost plus $30/MWh, and (c) 80% or more of their run hours, the offer cap is either incremental cost plus 10%, incremental cost plus $40/MWh, or unit-specific going forward costs in agreement with the ISO.
234
Competitive Electricity Markets
Table 5.13. Thresholds for identifying conduct that may lead to economic withholding in New York ISO Offer Components
Outside Constrained Area
Within Constrained Area (excluding New York City)
Energy and minimum generation offers: Day-ahead market
Lower of 300% or $100/MWh increase; Offers below $25/MWh excluded.
When constraint binds, lower of (a) thresholds for outside Constrained Area, or (b) a threshold calculated as follows: (2% × Average Price × 8760)/Constrained Hours, where Average Price is the average day-ahead market price in the Constrained Area over the prior 12 months (adjusted for fuel price changes) and Constrained Hours is the total number of hours in the day-ahead market over the prior 12 months in which any transmission interface or facility leading into the Constrained Area where the generator is located had a shadow price > 0 in any interval.
Energy and minimum generation offers: real-time market
Lower of 300% or $100/MWh increase; Offers below $25/MWh excluded.
Same as day-ahead calculation, with the Average Price and Constrained Hours calculation being made using real-time market data. The Average Price is also adjusted for out-of-merit generation dispatch as feasible and appropriate.
Start-up price offer
Increase of 200%.
Regulation and operating reserves offers
Lower of 300% or $50/MWh increase; offers below $5/MWh excluded.
Lower of 300% or $50/MWh increase; offers below $5/MWh excluded.
Time-based offer parameters (including start-up times, minimum run times, minimum down times)
Increase of 3 hours or increase of 6 hours for multiple time-based bid parameters.
Increase of 3 hours or increase of 6 hours for multiple time-based bid parameters.
Offer parameters in units other than time or dollars (including ramp rates and maximum stops)
Increase of 100% for parameters that are minimum values; 50% decrease for parameters that are maximum values.
Increase of 100% for parameters that are minimum values; 50% decrease for parameters that are maximum values.
EBL
Increase of 50%.
Source: New York ISO Market Services Tariff, Attachment H. Available at: www.nyiso.com
operational boundaries as well as differences in market design and other factors that may result in economic inefficiency. The third is the important role of software design and development in expanding the scope of the auction markets and capturing opportunities for efficiency.
Design of US Wholesale Energy and Ancillary Service Auction Markets
235
5.9.1. Longer-term ISO markets and operational/planning functions In addition to the energy and ancillary service markets described in this chapter, which take place on a daily and hourly basis, the ISO also operates markets and undertakes reliability, operational, and planning functions that take place on longer time-frames, from several days to several years. With respect to markets, these include most notably auctions for generation installed capacity and financial transmission property rights. Table 5.14 lists several of these market and other functions and their respective time-frames. The design of these longer-term ISO markets is discussed in several chapters in this volume and will not be reviewed here. Notably, none of the ISOs currently operate forward energy auction markets on a longer time-frame than the day-ahead period discussed in this chapter. These longer-term markets and functions have interactions with the daily markets, both intended and unintended. For example, the capacity product is the operable MW of a generator and is sold separately from forward or spot energy. In the ISO markets, there is no need to purchase energy and capacity from the same generator. However, most of the capacity products are designed implicitly or explicitly as options for the ISO to call on energy from a generator in the event of shortages. If a capacity generator is called on for energy by the ISO, then it must curtail any sales outside the ISO market and provide real-time energy to the zone for which it has been designated as a capacity resource.41 As ISOs have found out, it is important to design capacity markets that have sufficient incentives or penalties to enforce this call option. Another type of possible linkage, this time unintended, between forward and spot markets is between holdings of financial transmission rights and energy market behavior. A market participant that both owns generation and can collect congestion revenues from its transmission rights may have the
EBL
Table 5.14. Longer-term ISO markets and operational/planning functions Time-frame
Market Functions and Operations
Reliability and Planning Functions
Multi-year
Forward markets for installed capacity Allocation and auction of multi-year financial transmission rights
Regional planning and expansion (transmission, generation, and demand response)
Annual, monthly
Allocation and auction of annual, seasonal and monthly financial transmission rights
Co-ordination of planned transmission and generation maintenance
Weekly
Scheduling of generation with more than one-day start-up times
Load forecasting
41
Hence, under current designs, a capacity contract is not equivalent to a forward energy contract – i.e., physically linked to a particular buyer of power – because the ISOs are not equipped to implement a priority ranking among wholesale buyers in the event of a load curtailment. Instead, the capacity product is defined zonally, as an option to deliver power from a generator to a zone. For example, PJM conducts a “deliverability test” for generators requesting to be capacity resources using a power flow model that evaluates how the power from that generator will diffuse in a region of the market. When transmission constraints limit the flow of the generator in this test, it must pay for upgrades to fully qualify as a capacity resource. Once it meets the eligibility requirements, a capacity resource is then invested with energy market obligations in exchange for capacity payments, as noted earlier.
236
Competitive Electricity Markets
incentive to alter its output so as to maximize the revenues from both energy and its transmission right revenues. This would result in an inefficient dispatch. Such activity has been observed in the markets, but is generally rare. 5.9.2. Market seams A market “seam” refers to differences between methods of power system operations, market designs, and rules for crossing market boundaries (i.e., as an importer or exporter of power) that create transactions costs or externalities across the boundary. In the United States, the ISO markets can have seams with other ISO markets or with the regions that do not have organized markets. In each case, the primary issue across the seam is transmission scheduling, congestion management, and unscheduled flows (such as “loop flows”). FERC has sought to reduce or eliminate these market seams over the years. In late 1999, it issued a rule that encouraged and provided incentives for all utilities in the United States to join large Regional Transmission Organizations (RTOs) on a voluntary basis (FERC, 1999). A subsequent FERC initiative to merge PJM, New York, and New England on the basis that they already shared a similar market organization failed in this period due to regional differences. In 2002, with RTO formation lagging, FERC proposed a “standard market design” for all utilities in the country that largely followed the basic ISO design described in this chapter (FERC, 2002). However, this proposal met strong political and industry resistance in some regions of the country and was formally revoked in 2005. Hence, for the period covered by this chapter, market seams, both between ISO markets and between the ISO markets and the purely bilateral markets, have remained salient concerns from both an operational and economic perspective. Had the standard market design rule been implemented, many of these seams problems would have been resolved.
EBL
5.9.3. Developments in market software In practice, software has been a limiting factor in the development of efficient market designs. The existing ISO software and data systems are a result of market start-up decisions as well as patches resulting from continual change and improvement. Consequently, changes to a single software system may require changes to many software and data systems. Currently, there is a significant backlog of improvements in each ISO. In part the backlog is due to the extensive testing and changes necessary to install new software modules. Hence, there are still significant efficiencies to be gained from the standardization of data systems so that when improved software is developed in one area it can be easily tested and put into production elsewhere. Nevertheless, in some areas, ISOs and commercial vendors have been able to introduce innovations that demonstrate the value of their investment in software and growing technological expertise. These innovations have produced economic benefits. One example is the search for faster solution times and closer to optimal solutions for the unit commitment auctions that take place day-ahead and then over the operating day. In the past, the Lagrangian relaxation solution algorithm used by utilities and then by the ISOs was known to reach sub-optimal solutions, but the size of the problems that it could solve and its solution times had been reduced over the years. In theory, mixed integer programs could achieve an optimal solution but had difficulties with solution speed for large problems. In recent years, these solution time issues have been reduced such that ISOs can
Design of US Wholesale Energy and Ancillary Service Auction Markets
237
now deploy mixed integer programs for the auction markets (Johnson et al., 1997; Hobbs et al., 2001; Guan et al., 2003). In addition, mixed integer programs allows a much more detailed and full specification of the unit commitment problem and relieves the market co-ordinator of many of the simplifying assumptions that are necessary using Lagrangian relaxation.42 These advantages and the tractability of mixed integer programming algorithms have led several ISOs to introduce or test mixed integer program-based implementations over Lagrangian relaxation. Due to the computational complexity of unit commitment problems, ISOs which implement mixed integer program based algorithms tend not to solve their unit commitment problems to optimality due to limitations on solution times.43 Streiffert et al. (2005) note that the enhanced modeling capabilities of mixed integer program allows the ISO to deal directly with a number of constraints that were very difficult to model in Lagrangian relaxation. PJM has implemented mixed integer programming for its day-ahead market with estimated savings of $54 million per year due to efficiency improvements in the auction solution. While savings from the more precise solutions provided by mixed integer programs may be a small percentage of total generation costs, i.e., 1–4%, a 1% savings in generation costs translates into a $1–$2 billion annual cost saving in the United States alone. 5.10. Extensions of the Market Design The US ISOs have been operating spot energy auctions with locational marginal pricing since 1998, and regulation and operating reserves markets with various designs for almost as long. As discussed in this chapter, market designs and software are continuously being refined in response to various factors, including incomplete markets, the introduction of new technologies and software, and also due to the greater penetration of some existing technologies that create new operational requirements, such as demand response and wind energy. The auction designs described in this chapter should be adaptable, such that the basic organizational and pricing principles will remain appropriate as technological changes take place. Among the near-term design challenges relevant to this chapter is more “complete” pricing of ancillary services, such as reactive power. Currently, many systems are dispatched without using a full AC optimal power flow, and impose overly restrictive voltage levels. Reactive power is not priced or is priced inappropriately. The design question is whether ISOs should sign long-term contracts for reactive power that include obligations
EBL
42
Even if the mixed integer program algorithm times out before finding an optimum, one is still left with a primal-feasible solution and a bound on the optimality gap. These intermediate solutions are often found within the same amount of time a Lagrangian relaxation-based algorithm takes, and typically have optimality gaps of the same size or smaller than Lagrangian relaxation commitments. Furthermore, a mixed integer program-based solution algorithm allows ISOs to easily introduce new types of unit-operating and system constraints to the formulation of the problem, whereas Lagrangian relaxation-based techniques generally require extensive reprogramming of the feasibility heuristics to ensure that the unit commitment satisfies all the necessary conditions. 43 PJM, for instance, allows its mixed integer program optimizer to run within a certain period of time or until the optimality gap is below some maximal threshold and uses whatever intermediate integer-feasible solution the solver has found. If an ISO is left to rely on an intermediate integerfeasible but sub-optimal solution, the same issues of generator payoffs, energy pricing, and inequity of the resulting dispatch arise as with sub-optimal Lagrangian relaxation commitments.
238
Competitive Electricity Markets
to perform or whether spot markets for reactive power can elicit a more efficient outcome and overcome concerns about locational market power (Hogan, 1993; Kahn and Baldick, 1994; FERC, 2005). To implement such markets, optimal power flow software needs to be improved and integrated with unit commitment models. Another line of inquiry concerns the more active participation of “dispatchable” transmission elements in the energy spot markets (O’Neill et al., 2005). That is, with sufficient regulatory oversight, both merchant and regulated transmission owners could offer some or all of their transmission capacity into the ISO markets at a price. Another aspect of this development could be the unit commitment of transmission elements; e.g., the ability to decouple a transmission line if that leads to a reduction in the auction objective function.
5.11. Conclusions The US ISO markets, many encompassing multiple states and reaching a geographic scope that was not anticipated just a few years earlier, are a major achievement of electricity regulatory reform. The auction market designs for energy and ancillary services have developed on the basis of both theoretical principles and practical decisions. In some cases, design mistakes were made, but equally the ISOs and their stakeholders have worked to refine the designs and learn from experience, with FERC oversight. This has led to a high degree of convergence on key elements of the designs, such as day-ahead and real-time markets with locational marginal pricing, the reliability unit commitment, and the co-optimization of regulation and reserves; although as this chapter has shown, there remain many design differences between the ISO markets. A lesson of the first decade of the ISO markets is that an efficient spot market for electric power that respects economic principles and reliability requirements ends up being rather complicated. There are many products and their pricing and financial settlement rules are often difficult for market participants to understand and analyze. This chapter has sought to provide a step-by-step review of many of these market rules and procedures and to explain why design choices were made. More recently, concerns about the costbenefit ratio of implementing such markets have been raised. Among other things, this has prompted calls for simplification of the market designs. Although simplification where possible (and increased standardization) of market rules in the United States should be a design objective, observers should also note that the complicated design of the daily auction markets is in part because so much of the power system has been exposed to transparent market pricing and procedures. What in prior years were system operational decisions whose costs were internalized by utilities, often inefficiently, are now integrated into daily market auctions and generally priced efficiently. Transmission usage is priced on the margin and optimized over large regions, resulting in much more efficient use of transmission capacity. Extensions of these locational pricing principles and the application of unit commitment to transmission elements could yet result in even further gains in utilization of the existing grid. However, as discussed, there are several aspects of market pricing that do continue to rely for practical reasons on types of average pricing. Most notably, most ISOs still charge buyers load-weighted average LMPs on a zonal basis rather than the LMPs at their nodes. The current market designs will continue to evolve with refinement of the market rules, changes in technology, and shifting regulatory requirements. The markets will function better if technology and consumer interest (or regulation) allow a robust demand response to emerge. At least some of the regulatory and reliability aspects of the market designs,
EBL
Design of US Wholesale Energy and Ancillary Service Auction Markets
239
such as supply offer caps and reliability unit commitments, could become less important if that takes place. Finally, this chapter has focused on the short-term, daily markets. As discussed in other chapters of this book, there is still evolution in the design of other elements of electricity market design to support investment decisions, such as resource adequacy or capacity markets and long-term financial transmission rights. Because of the interactions between these different design elements, all aspects of the ISO market designs must be carefully integrated and calibrated [see, e.g., Stoft (2002) and O’Neill et al. (2006) for discussion].
5A. Appendix: Mathematical Formulation of the Auction Examples The auction examples given in several sections of this chapter employ a simplified version of the ISO auction designs, but with many of the main features of those markets, including realistic network power flows including congestion and losses and including both start-up and energy offers by generators. In this appendix, the mathematical formulation of the auction model used in the examples is given, with some additional explanation. There are different ways to write this auction mathematically; the approach taken here is intended to improve the intuition of the model. For a more detailed mathematical description of the ISO auction on transmission networks, see, e.g., O’Neill et al. (2002) and the ISO auction manuals. A single period version of the auction model is as follows. Max
mi BIDmi dmi −
subject to
−yi +
EBL
mih STARTmih zmih + OFFERmih gmih
mh gmih − yi
fk+
≤
Fk+ max
=
m dmi
∀k k−
(3)
+ + + + − − − − k Dik fk − fk + fk Lki fk + fk Lki fk +
(1) (2)
∀k
fk− ≤ Fk− max
∀i i
k+ ≤ 0
∀i
−
Rf − f = 0 gmih ≤ Gmih zmih
∀m i h
(4) (5) (6)
dmi gmih fk+ fk− ≥ 0 zmih ∈ 0 1 where the notation is defined as follows. Index sets H is the set of generators and virtual offers, h = 1 nH . I is the set of buses, i = 1 nI , in the transmission system. K is the set of transmission facilities, k = 1 nK . M is the set of participants in the auction market, m = 1 nM , whether as sellers or buyers (physical and virtual). Variables dmi is the quantity of energy bought by market participant m at bus i.
240
Competitive Electricity Markets
fk+ fk− represent the flow on transmission element k in the positive and negative direction respectively (defined arbitrarily). The net real power flow on transmission element k could thus be defined as fk , where fk = fk+ − fk− . f + f − are the vectors of these flows. gmih is the quantity of energy, physical, or virtual, sold by market participant m at bus i from generator or virtual offer h. yi is the amount of real power injected at node i (withdrawn at node i if yi < 0) that is induced by the d bids and g offers that were awarded through the auction. zmih is the commitment decision associated with the offer for generator h submitted by market participant m at bus i. It is either 0 (uncommitted) or 1 (committed). In a dynamic model, separate variables would be defined for the start-up decision (1 signaling a start-up occurs in a given hour) and commitment (1 indicating that the generator is operating in that period). i k+ k− are Lagrange multipliers associated with selected sets of primal constraints in the auction. Parameters and operators BIDmi is the bid price ($/MWh) submitted by market participant m at node i associated with a demand quantity dmi . In this context, “bid” means a bid to buy energy. OFFERmih is the offer price ($/MWh) submitted by market participant m for generator or virtual supply h at node i associated with quantity gmih . In this context, “offer” means a offer to sell energy. STARTmih is the start-up price ($) submitted by market participant m for generator h at node i. For all physical generators, this quantity is non-negative. Note that for all virtual offers, it is exactly zero. D is the arc incidence matrix, {Dki }. Dki = 1 if fk+ − fk− represents a MW flow out of bus i through transmission line k in a positive direction; Dki = −1 if the flow through k is in a negative direction; and Dki = 0 otherwise. Fk+ max Fk− max are transmission capacity constraints – thermal, stability, or contingency limits – associated with a transmission element k in the positive and negative directions. Gmih is the upper bound on the capacity offered by market participant m for generator or virtual supply offer h at node i. + L− ki Lki represent resistance loss coefficients (decrease in imports to bus i) due to a negative and positive flow, respectively, through transmission line k. R = rvk are line reactances used in Kirchhoff’s Voltage Law analogues. rvk is the value of reactance for transmission line k that appears in voltage loop v. rvk = +Rk or −Rk if line k occurs in loop v, depending on whether a positive fk+ − fk− is in the same or opposite sense of flow around v. rvk = 0 if link k does not occur in loop v. Consistent with the linearized DC model of load flow (Schweppe et al., 1988), the number of independent loops v must be equal to K − N + 1, where K is the number of lines considered and N is the number of buses.
EBL
The objective function maximizes social welfare, defined as the sum of consumer surplus and producer surplus. This is the same as the integral of the demand curve (sum of accepted demand bids) minus as-bid production costs. Production costs include commitment costs, which are incurred if a generator is operating (i.e., zmih = 1), along with variable generation costs. More general versions include start-up and min run costs as separate terms in the objective. Constraint (1) is a net energy balance requirement for each
Design of US Wholesale Energy and Ancillary Service Auction Markets
241
bus on the network, whose dual variable is the LMP. Equations (2) and (3) are transmission capacity constraints on each transmission element. Their dual variables are the so-called “flowgate prices.” Equations (4) and (5) are DC analogues to Kirchhoff’s Current and Voltage Laws. Equation (6) is the generation upper operating limit; if the unit is not committed (i.e., zmih = 0), then this constraint forces MW generation to be zero. Lower operating limits (“min run constraints”) and ramp rate constraints are not shown, but could be introduced. The numerical example takes place on the three-bus network in Fig. 5.1, in which the arrows show the direction of flow for an injection at bus 1 and a withdrawal at bus 3 (note that the arrows do not correspond to the direction of the flowgates). In the equations that follow, the three transmission lines indexed k above are labeled for the two buses to which they are connected in the “positive” direction. Hence, the line from bus 1 to bus 2 is labeled “12,” the line from bus 1 to 3 is labeled “13,” and the line from bus 2 to 3 is labeled “23.” All loss factors on all lines = 0.00001 [MW/MW2 ]. All reactances, Rk = 1. Then (4) for each bus becomes + + − − − 2 − 2 KCL1 −y1 + f12 − f12 + f13 − f13 + 00001f12 + 00001f13 ≤ 0 + + + 2 − − − 2 − f12 + f23 − f23 + 00001f12 + 00001f23 ≤ 0 KCL2 −y2 − f12 + + − − − 2 − 2 − f23 − f13 − f13 + 00001f23 + 00001f13 ≤ 0 KCL3 −y3 − f23
and (5) becomes + + + − − − KVL f12 − f12 + f23 − f23 − f13 − f13 = 0
EBL
With these simplifications, the auction examples can be replicated using commercially available software, such as GAMS. Acknowledgment The authors would like to thank David Mead, Partha Malvadkar, and Harry Singh for useful comments, and Perry Sioshansi for editorial advice and great patience. References44 California ISO (2005). Locational Marginal Pricing (LMP) Study 3C, Analysis of Market-Based Price Differentials, Description of Methodology, Appendix A, Disaggregation of LMP Components. 19 November. Available at http://www.caiso.com/14cd/14cd6d735cf60.pdf. Cramton, P. and Stoft, S. (2006). Uniform-Price auctions in electricity markets. Working Paper, University of Maryland, 20 March. Fabra, N., von der Fehr, N., and Harbord, D. (2004). Designing electricity auctions. Center for the Study of Energy Markets, University of California, Berkeley, CSEM WP-122, February. Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) (1996a). Promoting Wholesale Competition Through Open Access Non-Discriminatory Transmission Services by Public Utilities; Recovery of Stranded Costs by Public Utilities and Transmitting Utilities. Order No. 888, FERC Stats. & Regs. 31,036, 24 April.
44 The technical manuals referenced below were all current as this chapter was being written. Such manuals are periodically updated to reflect market rule changes. The websites of the ISOs whose materials are cited are as follows: PJM, www.pjm.com; New York ISO, www.nyiso.org; ISO-New England, www.iso-ne.com; Midwest ISO, www.midwest.org
242
Competitive Electricity Markets
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) (1996b). Open Access Same-Time Information System (formerly Real-Time Information Networks) and Standards of Conduct. Order No. 889, 75 FERC 61,078, 24 April. Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) (1997). PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., et al., Order Conditionally Accepting Open Access Transmission Tariff and Power Pool Agreements, Conditionally Authorizing Establishment of An Independent System Operator and Disposition of Control over Jurisdictional Facilities, and Denying Rehearing. 81 FERC 61,257, 25 November. Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) (1999a). Central Hudson Gas & Electric Corporation et al., Order Conditionally Accepting Tariff and Market Rules, Approving Market-Based Rates, and Establishing Hearing and Settlement Judge Procedures, 86 FERC 61,062, 27 January. Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) (1999b). Regional Transmission Organizations. Order No. 2000, 89 FERC 61,285, 20 December. Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) (2000). PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., Order Accepting Tariff Sheets as Clarified. 92 FERC 61, 013, 7 July. Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) (2002). Standard Market Design and Structure, Notice of Proposed Rulemaking. 18 CFR Part 35, Docket Number RM01-12-000, September. Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) (2005). Principles for Efficient and Reliable Reactive Power Supply and Consumption. FERC Staff Report, AD05-1-000, 4 February. Guan, X., Zhai, Q., and Papalexopoulos, A. (2003). Optimization based methods for unit commitment: Lagrangian relaxation versus general mixed integer programming. Power Engineering Society General Meeting, IEEE. Harvey, S.M., Hogan, W.W., and Pope, S. (1997). Transmission Capacity Reservations and Transmission Congestion Contracts. John F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University, Cambridge, MA. June 6, 1996. revised 8 March. Helman, U. (2006). Market power monitoring and mitigation in the US wholesale power markets. Energy, 31(6–7), 877–904. Hobbs B.F., Rothkopf, M., Hyde, L., and O’Neill, R.P. (2000). Evaluation of a truthful revelation auction in the context of energy markets with nonconcave benefits. J. Reg. Econ., 18(1), 5–32. Hobbs, B.F., Stewart, W.R. Jr., Bixby, R.E., et al. (2001). Why this book?: New capabilities and new needs for unit commitment modeling. In The Next Generation of Electric Power Unit Commitment Models (B.F. Hobbs, M.H. Rothkopf, R.P. O’Neill, and H-P. Chao, eds). Boston: Kluwer Academic Press, pp. 1–14. Hogan, W.W. (1993). Markets in real electric networks require reactive prices. Energ. J., 14(3), 171–200. Hogan, W.W. (2006). Resource sufficiency guarantees and cost allocation. Comments submitted to the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, Docket No. ER04-691-065, 25 May. Available at http://ksghome.harvard.edu/˜whogan/. Johnson, R.B., Oren, S.S., and Svoboda, A.J. (1997). Equity and efficiency of unit commitment in competitive electricity markets. Util. Pol., 6, 9. Kahn, A.P., Cramton, P., Porter, R., and Tabors, R. (2001). Pricing in the California Power Exchange electricity market: Should California switch from uniform pricing to pay-as-bid pricing? Blue Ribbon Panel Report, Prepared for the California Power Exchange, January. Kahn, E. and Baldick, R. (1994). Reactive power is a cheap constraint. Energ. J., 15(4), 191–202. Klemperer, P. (1999). Auction theory: A guide to the literature. J. of Econ. Surv., 13(3), 227–86. Krishna, V. (2002). Auction Theory. San Diego, Calif.: Academic Press. New York ISO (1999). Transmission and Dispatching Operations Manual, Manual 12, September. New York ISO (2001a). Market Services Tariff. Issued on 16 January. New York ISO (2001b). Day-Ahead Scheduling Manual, Manual 11, June. New York ISO (2004). Subject: Scheduling a “Must-Run” Generator, Technical Bulletin 026, 10 November. New York ISO (2005). Subject: Allocation of Uplift Costs to Load and Other Entities Associated with Virtual Trading, Technical Bulletin 082, 5 November, 2001; updated 4 November, 2005. New York ISO (2006). Ancillary Services Manual, Manual 2, May. O’Neill, R.P., Baldick, R., Helman, U., Rothkopf, M.H., and Stewart, W.R. (2005). Dispatchable transmission in RTO markets. IEEE Trans. on Pow. Sys., 20(1), 171–9.
EBL
Design of US Wholesale Energy and Ancillary Service Auction Markets
243
O’Neill, R.P. and Helman, U. (2007). Regulatory reform of the U.S. wholesale electricity markets. In Creating Competitive Markets: The Politics of Regulatory Reform (M.K. Landy, M.A. Levin, and M. Shapiro, eds). Brookings Press. O’Neill, R., Helman, U., Hobbs, B.F., and Baldick, R. (2006). Independent system operators in the USA: History, lessons learned, and prospects. In Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective (F. Sioshansi and W. Pfaffenberger, eds). Amsterdam: Elsevier. O’Neill, R.P., Helman, U., Hobbs, B.F., et al. (2002). A joint energy and transmission rights auction: proposal and properties. IEEE Trans. Pow. Sys., 17(4), 1058–67. O’Neill, R.P., Sotkiewicz, P.M., Hobbs, B.F., et al. (2005). Efficient market-clearing prices in markets with nonconvexities. Eur. J. Op. Res., 164, 269–85. PJM (2000). State of the Market Report, 1999. Market Monitoring Unit, PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., June. PJM (2001). State of the Market Report, 2000. Market Monitoring Unit, PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., June. PJM (2002). State of the Market Report, 2001. Market Monitoring Unit, PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., June. PJM (2003). State of the Market Report, 2002. Market Monitoring Unit, PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., 5 March. PJM (2004). State of the Market Report, 2003. Market Monitoring Unit, PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., 4 March. PJM (2005). State of the Market Report, 2004. Market Monitoring Unit, PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., 8 March. PJM (2006a). State of the Market Report, 2005. Market Monitoring Unit, PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., 8 March. PJM (2006b) PJM Manual 15: Cost Development Guidelines. PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., Revision 07, Effective Date: 3 August. PJM (2007a). State of the Market Report, 2006. Market Monitoring Unit, PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., 8 March. PJM (2007b). PJM Manual 11: Scheduling Operations. PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., Revision 30, Effective Date: 20 March. PJM (2007c). PJM Manual 6: Financial Transmission Rights. PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., Revision 9, Effective Date: 4 April. PJM (2007d). PJM Manual 12: Balancing Operations. PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., Revision 15, Effective Date: 15 May. PJM News (2004). PJM’S New Generation-Scheduling Software to Save Customers Estimated $56 Million: Unit Commitment System Uses First of its Kind Technique. Valley Forge, Pa., 24 June. Potomac Economics, Ltd. (2003). 2002 State of the Market Report, New York ISO. Independent Market Advisor to the New York ISO, June. Potomac Economics, Ltd. (2004). 2003 State of the Market Report, New York ISO. Independent Market Advisor to the New York ISO, May. Potomac Economics, Ltd. (2005). 2004 State of the Market Report, New York ISO. Independent Market Advisor to the New York ISO, July. Potomac Economics, Ltd. (2006). 2005 State of the Market Report, New York ISO. Independent Market Advisor to the New York ISO, August. Schweppe, F. C., Caramanis, M. C., Tabors, R. D., and Bohn, R.E. (1988). Spot Pricing of Electricity. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers. Stoft, S. (2002). Power System Economics. New York: IEEE Press. Streiffert, D., Philbrick, R., and Ott, A. (2005). A mixed integer programming solution for market clearing and reliability analysis I. In Power Engineering Society General Meeting, 2005, IEEE, San Francisco, CA. Sweeney, J.L. (2006). California electricity restructuring, the crisis and its aftermath. In Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective (F. Sioshansi and W. Pfaffenberger, eds). Amserdam: Elsevier. Wilson, R. (2002). Architecture of power markets. Econometrica, 70(4), 1299–340.
EBL
EBL
This page intentionally left blank
Chapter 6 The Cost of Anarchy in Self-Commitment-Based Electricity Markets RAMTEEN SIOSHANSI1 , SHMUEL OREN1 , AND RICHARD O’NEILL2 University of California, Berkeley, USA; 2 Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, USA
1
Summary
EBL
With the advent of restructured electricity markets a contentious market design issue has been whether unit commitment decisions should be made centrally by the system operator or by individual generators. Although a centrally committed market can, in theory, determine the most efficient commitment, they have been shown to suffer some equity and incentive problems. A self-committed market can overcome some of these incentive issues, but will generally suffer efficiency losses from not properly coordinating commitment and dispatch decisions between individual generators. This chapter examines the issue of dispatch efficiency raised by the design of markets based on central versus self-commitment by determining a set of “competitive benchmarks” for the two market designs. Comparing the total commitment and dispatch costs of the two markets provides a bound on the productive efficiency losses of a self-committed market. 6.1. Introduction The introduction of competition in the electric supply industry has led to a number of important questions regarding the need for organized markets to efficiently and reliably coordinate the power system and the desirable features and scope of those markets. Complicating electricity market design, power systems are subject to a number of “network” constraints, in that these constraints depend on the actions of every market participant and each participant can impose an externality on others using the power system. That is, the ability of customer A to purchase power from generator B can depend on the actions of generator C or of consumer D. These complexities have called into question the ability of decentralized markets to efficiently and feasibly commit and dispatch units 245
246
Competitive Electricity Markets
while respecting power system constraints and the market design rules for any centralized markets operated by a system operator (SO). While a centralized market can, in theory, find the most efficient dispatch of the generators, the market designs suffer equity and incentive problems. Decentralized designs can overcome some of these issues but will suffer efficiency losses due to the loss of coordination between market participants. As electricity markets in various countries have been restructured and evolved, different approaches have been used with varying degrees of success. In the United States, e.g., the move toward standard market design has led to heavy reliance on open and transparent centralized markets. The British market, by contrast, started with a centralized market in the original Electricity Pool and moved to a more decentralized design under the New Electricity Trading Arrangements (NETA) and subsequent reforms under the British Electricity Trading and Transmission Agreements (BETTA), which were meant to overcome some of the problems experienced under the original centralized pool design. Although these design differences are driven by realities of the market such as asset ownership, generation mix, and system infrastructure, different “philosophies” regarding the proper role of centralized markets have also played a role in determining the scope of any centralized markets. Two of the chapters in this volume, Chapter 5 and Chapter 11, e.g., advocate centralized versus decentralized markets, respectively, based on these philosophies and experiences in different markets. This chapter revisits the issue of dispatch efficiency raised by the design of markets based on centralized versus decentralized dispatch. Using actual market data from an SO, a set of “competitive benchmarks” for a centralized and decentralized market are computed and compared. These competitive benchmarks assume that generators do not behave strategically in manipulating their offers in the two markets. Comparing the total commitment and dispatch cost of the two market designs shows the extent of productive efficiency losses from a decentralized market, which are small but non-trivial. Comparing total settlements costs of the two designs shows that generators can extract significantly higher payoffs from consumers under a decentralized design, suggesting that this design may be the wrong approach if the goal of restructuring is to reduce consumer costs. These higher prices under a decentralized design would further result in allocative efficiency losses in markets with demand response.1 The remainder of this chapter is organized as follows. Section 6.2 provides the context on the debate regarding the scope of centralized markets. Sections 6.3.1 and 6.3.2 further describe centrally and self-committed markets and the market models used in the simulations, while Section 6.3.3 provides the results and comparison of the two designs. Section 6.4 provides conclusions. The Appendix 6A outlines the formulations and algorithms used in the simulations and analysis.
EBL
6.2. Centralized versus Decentralized Markets Unlike other commodities, electricity has a number of technical constraints, which must be obeyed to ensure feasible and reliable service. Complicating electricity market design, power systems are subject to physical constraints, which make markets for electricity inherently incomplete. This incompleteness is due in part to costly storage of electricity, 1 As in any market with price-elastic demand, prices which are above the competitive level will result in higher producer profits at the cost of consumer welfare losses.
Cost of Anarchy in Self-Commitment-Based Electricity Markets
247
complex power flows within the transmission network, extremely price-inelastic short-run demand for energy, and the need to constantly balance supply and load in real-time. Injections and withdrawals of electricity cannot be directed along a specified path within a transmission network, rather power flows along each line in inverse proportion to the line’s impedance. Flows on lines within the network are constrained by physical limitations and environmental factors. Moreover, allowing an injection of power, which will flow in a constrained (also known as congested) direction along a path, may be contingent upon another injection, which provides “counterflows” to relieve congestion on that path. These characteristics of power systems mean that use of the transmission network for injection and withdrawal of energy must be properly coordinated, otherwise the resulting dispatch may not be simultaneously feasible or optimal. Generating units are constrained in the time it takes them to start up or shut down, and the rate at which they can adjust their output. Thermal units have non-zero minimum generating constraints and “forbidden zones,” in which they cannot operate stably when they are online. Other types of generating units, such as combined-cycle gas turbines (CCGT) and cascaded watershed hydroelectric systems, tend to have complex constraints restricting their operation. Due to the stochastic nature of demand fluctuations, generators must be able to adjust their real and reactive power outputs in real-time to ensure constant load balance. Other random contingencies such as transmission equipment failures or forced generator outages may also require generators to adjust their outputs within a short period of time to maintain system reliability. Thus, efficient and reliable operation of the system requires having a sufficient number of generators online and available to react to variations in load and other contingencies at least cost. These physical realities of power systems have given rise to a debate about whether competitive pressures in a decentralized or bilateral market can lead to efficiency and reliability of the system, or if we must rely on centrally organized markets. Whatever market design is ultimately adopted, there are several objectives it should address, including the following:2
EBL
•
Efficient dispatch: The market should ensure that generators within the system are efficiently dispatched to meet system load at least cost, while satisfying the requisite operational constraints. • Network feasibility: The pattern of injections and withdrawals within the transmission network and the resulting power flows must be feasible. • System reliability: The market must ensure that there is sufficient excess generating capacity online and available (known as ancillary services) to react to contingencies such as load fluctuations, or generator or transmission outages within a sufficiently short amount of time to ensure reliability. This market design debate has often been framed as being between the two extremes of the bilateral versus Poolco model, as described by Hogan (1994). The bilateral model emphasizes direct transactions between buyers and sellers. It argues that competitive forces in the marketplace will resolve any infeasibilities in dispatches and schedules and deliver efficient and reliable electric service, without the need to design or impose new market institutions. Technical difficulties such as load balance, power flow constraints, and ancillary services would be resolved by market transactions. According 2 Joskow and Schmalensee (1983) and Hunt (2002) provide a more thorough discussion of important considerations in electricity market design.
248
Competitive Electricity Markets
to proponents of the bilateral model, competitive forces would minimize costs while capturing any potential efficiency gains, desirable features that may be hampered by the rigidities of centralized markets. The Poolco model, on the other hand, emphasizes the need for tight coordination of the power system to ensure efficient, feasible, and reliable service. This model has influenced the Standard Market Design (SMD), “blessed” by the Federal Regulatory Energy Commission in the US, and variants of this model have been implemented (or implementation is underway) in about 50% of US states. Proponents of the Poolco model have argued that power balance, provision of ancillary services, and feasible power flows and counterflows within the transmission network may not be easily achieved through bilateral transactions. Moreover, the system must be in continuous real-time balance to ensure reliable operation, meaning the bilateral model may have to rely on a series of short-run minute-by-minute bilateral transactions to constantly adjust schedules and ensure system feasibility. Hogan (1994), e.g., paints an extreme picture of a “strict bilateral market,” in which the market is completely reliant on bilateral transactions without any centralized markets. His example envisions that consumers3 must contract with generators to provide energy and other essential services, and manage these contracts in real-time, independently of one another. In his example, each customer and generator would have to track changes in one another’s output and consumption and make adjustments to their own generation and load or make spot bilateral transactions to correct load imbalances. Furthermore, the two parties would have to adjust their portfolio of transmission capacity rights to enable the actual real-time power flows. Much of this debate originally centered on use of the transmission system. Ruff (1994) advocates development of organized spot markets, in which energy and transmission are traded in an integrated fashion, as opposed to relying on bilateral trading between the incumbent utilities and new entrants. He argues that in the absence of organized spot markets the industry may fall back on traditional wheeling agreements, which are ad hoc trades that were used by vertically integrated utilities under the regulated industry paradigm to handle a few incremental trades with other utilities. These wheeling agreements would be, in his opinion, inadequate to deliver all the potential efficiency gains and cost savings from trading in a restructured wholesale market. Hogan (1995) further advocates a centralized Poolco model. He argues that the physical realities of power flows would make the allocation of physical transmission rights to parties difficult, and as such a bilateral approach may not fully realize efficient trade. In his opinion, only a centralized market which cooptimizes generation and transmission flows will achieve least-cost dispatch. Although much of the debate initially focused on use of the transmission network, another important facet of this market design issue is how the commitment (on/off) status of generators should be determined. Under the traditional regulated monopoly paradigm, utilities would determine unit commitments to minimize total costs while meeting load, ancillary service, transmission, and generator operational constraints over a fixed planning period, typically between 24 and 168 hours. One of the difficulties that has plagued the solution of unit commitment problems is their computational complexity. Because commitment decisions are binary (i.e., a generator is either on or off in a given hour),
EBL
3 The term “consumer” is used throughout this chapter to encompass any entity purchasing in the wholesale market. This includes both large customers purchasing electricity for themselves and loadserving entities.
Cost of Anarchy in Self-Commitment-Based Electricity Markets
249
they must be formulated as mixed-integer programs (MIPs), which are computationally demanding, as shown by Guan et al. (2003) and others. As such, utilities have had to rely on approximation algorithms such as Lagrangian relaxation (LR) to find a near- (but sub-) optimal feasible solution within a reasonable amount of time, so the utility can follow the least-cost commitment.4 In a competitive setting, the market must provide for this unit commitment planning. The Poolco model typically envisions unit commitments being determined in a centralized manner by the SO. The SO solicits generation offers from generators, which specify their operating constraints and cost structure,5 and combines these with hourly load forecasts to determine a least-cost commitment and dispatch, which satisfies the requisite generator and system constraints. Ancillary service constraints are normally based on possible generator and transmission contingencies. For instance, it is typical to ensure that there is sufficient excess generating capacity available to react to the forced outage of the largest and second largest generators within a set number of minutes. This unit commitment process is typically done day-ahead, meaning commitments are determined for the following day and an advisory schedule is given to each generator specifying their generation in each hour.6 Once the commitments are fixed, on the following day, the SO will redispatch generators in real-time to meet the actual load and obey real-time system constraints. This allows the dispatch to react to contingencies such as load shocks, forced generator outages, or changes in transmission network topology. Because most generators incur fixed costs when starting up and when online, the cost offers generators submit to the SO typically consist of three parts:7 • •
EBL
A start-up cost, which is incurred whenever the unit is started from an offline state. A no-load cost, which is the spinning cost a generator incurs from being online, regardless of its actual generation. • Its actual variable generation costs, which are typically expressed as a nondecreasing step- or piecewise linear-function. The bilateral model, by contrast, leaves these commitment decisions to individual generators. In a purely bilateral market, generators will contract to deliver energy to consumers. This contracted energy will then, in real-time, be supplied by some combination of producing energy from its own generating assets or contracting with another party to deliver the energy. To produce energy itself, a generator will have to determine the commitment status of its own units to ensure it can deliver the energy. Similarly, consumers can contract with generators to hold excess generating capacity for ancillary services to ensure its demand can be reliably served under different system conditions, which will again 4
Muckstadt and Koenig (1977) provided one of the first formulations of unit commitment problems and proposed the use of the LR algorithm in their solution. Hobbs et al. (2001) and O’Neill et al. (Chapter 5) provide more recent treatments of unit commitment. 5 Although some authors use the term “bid” to describe the cost and operating constraint data provided to the SO by a generator, this chapter calls them “offers,” which distinguishes a generator’s offer to generate energy from a consumer’s bid to purchase energy. 6 Some markets with centralized unit commitment have longer planning horizons. The new market design put forth by the California ISO, e.g., has a separate unit commitment for the second day out, which is used to advise units with long start times to have themselves ready to be online. 7 Some SOs also allow generators to specify a shutdown cost, which is incurred whenever the unit is halted from an online state. Generators operating in markets which do not accept shutdown costs can roll these shutdown costs into the unit’s start-up cost.
250
Competitive Electricity Markets
factor into a generator’s unit commitment decisions. If generators are liable for damages from not serving a customer’s load, the generator may include its own ancillary service requirements in its commitment decision. Alternately, some bilateral designs call for the SO or another entity to operate energy and ancillary service markets into which generators can offer their generation. These markets are typically operated day-ahead, and in many cases hour-ahead or markets with other timeframes are operated. Although the assignment of generators to generate or provide ancillary services is done in a centralized manner in such a market, generators individually decide whether to commit themselves in expectation of revenues from the market. Wilson (1997), for instance, suggested the use of such a market in the original restructured California market. In a strictly bilateral market, real-time load imbalances would have to be resolved directly between contract counterparties, for instance, as described by Hogan (1994). Otherwise, some bilateral markets have real-time balancing service markets in which imbalance energy (both incremental and decremental) can be traded. Besides philosophical differences regarding the extent to which transactions in the market should be standardized and centralized within the SO’s purview, there are also incentive and efficiency issues arising from the two designs. The clear advantage of having the SO make commitment decisions in a centralized manner is that a centralized market will, in theory, find the most efficient commitment and dispatch of units. Generators acting independently of one another may not be able to achieve this, because the non-convex nature of generator operating constraints and costs mean there are efficiencies to be gained from coordination amongst generators.8 Moreover, a centrally committed market could easily find a feasible schedule, while this may prove more difficult in a decentralized paradigm. Centrally committed markets do, however, suffer from incentive issues, which call into question the efficiency of the underlying commitment. For one, the auction into which generators submit their operating constraints and costs is not strategy-proof, meaning generators may find it profitable to misstate their parameters. Oren and Ross (2005) demonstrate, by studying simple examples, that generators can profitably misstate their ramping constraints. Because these parameters are then used by the SO in determining the commitment of units, this type of misrepresentation on the part of generators can result in productive efficiency losses. That is, the SO could find a commitment which appears to be least-cost on the basis of the parameters given to it by generators, but which is sub-optimal because these parameters are misstated. Furthermore, Johnson et al. (1997) highlight other equity, incentive, and efficiency issues with centralized unit commitment. They demonstrate that if the SO solves for a commitment using an LR algorithm and makes binding commitment and dispatch decisions on the basis of this solution, different near-optimal solutions which are the same in terms of total commitment costs can result in vastly different payoffs to individual generators. Thus, seemingly benign programming parameters and heuristics used in the LR algorithm could arbitrarily determine which generators are “winners” and “losers” in being committed and receiving energy payments. Generators, knowing the nature of the LR commitments, may be further inclined to misstate their constraint and cost parameters to increase their likelihood of being committed and dispatched, which would again
EBL
8 Non-convexities imply that an efficient Walrasian equilibrium with linear prices may not exist. See O’Neill et al. (2005) for a more detailed discussion.
Cost of Anarchy in Self-Commitment-Based Electricity Markets
251
call into question the efficiency of the solution due to incorrect data in the underlying problem. Although recent advances in computational capabilities and optimization software now make it tractable to solve the MIP formulation of a commercial-scale SO unit commitment problem, Sioshansi et al. (2007) show that eliminating the issues with LR solutions raised by Johnson et al. (1997) requires solving the MIP to complete (as opposed to near-) optimality. They demonstrate that otherwise, if the algorithm used to solve the MIP must be stopped by the SO prematurely, the sub-optimal solution can yield generator payoffs which are different from the optimum. They further demonstrate that because energy prices are determined by the marginal cost of generation in each hour, which is in turn determined by the set of units committed in each hour, these energy prices can deviate significantly from the optimum as well. Moreover, they show that the relative size of these payoff and energy price deviations do not necessarily decrease as the commitment gets closer to optimal – meaning the only way to completely eliminate the issues raised by Johnson et al. (1997) is to solve the MIP to complete optimality. Although some SOs with central commitment have adopted MIP (as opposed to LR) in the solution of their unit commitment problems, none of these SOs are able to solve their unit commitment to complete optimality within the limited timeframe they have to determine the next day’s commitments and advise generators, implying the issues raised by Johnson et al. (1997) have not been alleviated in these markets. The issues raised by Johnson et al. (1997) have been used to champion simpler market designs in which unit commitment decisions are made in a decentralized fashion by individual generators. Advocates of decentralized commitment claim it will reduce incentive compatibility issues since generators must internalize their operating constraints while minimizing production costs. Furthermore, if generators are making commitment decisions to maximize profits in expectation of energy prices, this process is similar to solving a centralized unit commitment by means of an LR algorithm.9 Wilson (1997) proposed a market design with self-commitment and a multi-round energy auction in which generators and loads would iteratively submit one-part offers specifying prices at which they would be willing to supply and consume energy. The offers would be iteratively updated, subject to some proposed activity rules,10 until the prices and dispatch converged. His proposal was geared toward the original California market design, and while
EBL
9 When an LR algorithm is used to solve a central SO unit commitment problem, it works by relaxing load balance and ancillary service constraints and penalizing these in the objective function. The problem then decouples in the sense that there are no longer any constraints linking the decision variables of the individual generators, and each can be solved independently of the others. The algorithm then works to find coefficients for the penalty terms which incent sufficient generation and reserves to satisfy the relaxed constraints. These coefficients can, in turn, be thought of as energy and ancillary service prices, and each generator’s decoupled problem can be rewritten as a profitmaximization problem, which would be equivalent to a market with decentralized commitment. The important distinction, however, is that because a centralized unit commitment problem typically has a duality gap, heuristics must be used to ensure primal-feasibility of the dual solution. This heuristic process can commit a unit at a net profit loss, meaning that the final feasible centralized solution can differ from the decentralized in terms of some near-marginal commitments and dispatches. See Wolsey (1998) for a further discussion of the LR algorithm. 10 The purpose of the activity rules is to ensure early price discovery, fast convergence, and to prevent large generators and consumers from manipulating the auction by withholding themselves from the market until the final round of bidding.
252
Competitive Electricity Markets
some of the elements were used, the design eventually settled on a simpler single-round auction. Given these divergent philosophies on the fundamentals of market designs and the pros and cons of centralized versus decentralized markets, different jurisdictions have implemented a variety of designs spanning the spectrum between the bilateral and Poolco models. Britain, which was one of the first markets to restructure, originally established the centralized Electricity Pool, which was a mandatory market through which all energy was transacted.11 The pool operated as a day-ahead market which accepted generation offers consisting of three-part costs and unit operation constraints, and determined a least-cost commitment and dispatch of the system. The pool relied on the same software program, GOAL, which was used by the vertically integrated monopolies prior to restructuring to determine these commitments. Because generators had access to the GOAL software, they were able to manipulate and misstate the cost and constraint parameters in their offers in such a way to maximize profits, as opposed to submitting the true values. A review of the pool, conducted by Offer (1998), further criticized the GOAL software as being opaque in its pricing (due to various heuristics employed in the feasibility phase of the LR algorithm12 ) and using scheduling algorithms that are more appropriate for a vertically integrated utility than for a competitive market. The British market was eventually restructured under NETA, which established a series of overlapping voluntary markets, that rely primarily on bilateral and long-term contracting between generators and consumers. NETA has a minimal balancing market based on a pay-as-bid auction three and a half hours prior to physical delivery. NETA was further reformed under BETTA, but still maintained a decentralized design with self-commitment. The market in Texas, established in 2001, is based almost entirely on individual bilateral transactions that rely on generators to commit their units individually.13 The bulk of energy and ancillary services (typically 95–98%) are traded and contracted on a long-term basis between generators and consumers, with the SO operating markets for imbalance energy and to acquire ancillary services as a provider of last resort. Day-ahead, generators, and consumers submit schedules to the SO, specifying expected injections and withdrawals of energy and ancillary service schedules. Originally, market rules required consumers to submit balanced schedules – meaning scheduled injections had to cover expected loads. This balanced schedule requirement was meant to encourage consumers to contract for their expected load as opposed to relying on the balancing market for procurement of base load energy. Eventually, in mid-2002, the balanced schedule requirement was dropped, yet the balancing market still accounted for only a small fraction of energy trades.14 Due to the inaccuracy of load forecasts and because of random events, such as generator or transmission outages, generators and consumers would have to have a means of
EBL
11
Newbery (2006) provides a more detailed description of the history and structure of the British electricity market. 12 A Branch and Bound approach, on the other hand, guarantees feasibility of the solution but nontheless would require some heuristics to decide when to terminate the search since running the algorithm to completion is typically unrealistic in a practical setting. 13 The Texas market is currently undergoing a major reform which among other things will establish a voluntary day-ahead market with centralized unit commitment-based three-part offers. See Adib and Zarnikau (2006) for a more detailed discussion of the Texas market. 14 See Hortaçsu and Puller (2005) for a discussion of the implications of the balanced schedule requirement.
Cost of Anarchy in Self-Commitment-Based Electricity Markets
253
making real-time adjustments to their schedules. As opposed to requiring generators and consumers to make these adjustments individually, the SO operates a balancing energy services (BES) market. Generators can submit offers for both incremental and decremental energy, which is then dispatched in real-time to ensure load balance, but the offers are simple one-part energy-only offers specifying a price at which a generator is willing to increase or decrease its generation from its schedule. The BES market is further used by the SO to purchase imbalance energy in order to relieve congestion on transmission lines. Because of the highly decentralized nature of the Texas market (with the exception of the pool-like BES market), there is no centralized mechanism by which commitment decisions are made. Rather, generators individually determine commitments for their units in order to meet their contractual obligations and any imbalance or ancillary service15 sales they expect to make. The two examples presented are meant to be illustrative of centrally16 versus selfcommitted markets, with other markets falling between these two examples. Table 6.1 summarizes where other major restructured markets fall with regard to determining unit commitments. The Australian National Electricity Market, original California market, and NordPool are further examples of self-committed markets. The original California market is slightly unique in that it is a hybrid of a Poolco model with self-commitment. Generators would make commitment decisions individually, but nearly all energy was traded
Table 6.1. Examples of centralized versus decentralized unit commitment in selected electricity markets
EBL
Market Australian National Electricity Market Brazil British California Chile Columbia ISO New England Midwest ISO New York New Zealand NordPool PJM Texas ∗
Electricity Pool NETA/BETTA Original design MRTU∗ redesign
Current design Texas Nodal redesign
Commitment
Source
Self
Moran (2006)
Self Central Self Self Central Self Self Central Central Central Self Self Central Self Central
Dyner et al. (2006) Newbery (2006) Sweeney (2006) and California ISO (2007) Raineri (2006) Dyner et al. (2006) ISO New England (2007) Midwest ISO (2005) New York ISO (2001) Bertram (2006) Amundsen et al. (2006) Bowring (2006) Adib and Zarnikau (2006)
Market Reform and Technology Update
15
The ancillary service market operates similarly to the BES, into which generators submit offers specifying prices at which they are willing to be held in reserve for different qualities (i.e., reaction times) of ancillary services. 16 Most centrally committed markets do allow for self-commitment.
254
Competitive Electricity Markets
day-ahead in a mandatory central power pool. The three large incumbent utilities were initially prevented, by regulatory mandate, from contracting for energy on a long-term forward basis.17 This restriction was later relaxed but the utility had no incentive to contract since the regulator would not guarantee that the contract cost would be considered “prudent” if it turned out to be higher than the average spot price on the central power exchange. ISO New England, PJM, the proposed California market redesign, and the Texas market redesign are examples of centrally committed markets.
6.3. Comparison of Centrally and Self-Committed Markets Clearly, centrally and self-committed markets present tradeoffs, which must be evaluated in addressing market design issues. Centrally committed markets strive for the least-cost commitment and dispatch of generators by solving for a commitment which minimizes the SO’s cost objective. Theoretical studies and empirical observations have demonstrated incentive and equity issues with centralized unit commitment, which call into question the efficiency of the central solution, however. Self-commitment has been offered as a viable alternative, which addresses and reduces some of the issues with centrally committed markets. Self-commitment will, however, suffer from some loss of coordination amongst generators, resulting in efficiency losses. Thus, central and self-commitment are two imperfect market models with inherent shortcomings.18 To compare the two designs, this section describes and analyzes models of the two markets. The models assume that the markets are competitive – thereby eliminating the incentive issues and focusing instead on the relative efficiency losses and settlement costs of relying on self- as opposed to central commitment. Unit commitment refers to determining a short-term schedule of the on/off status of generating units to ensure sufficient resources are available to serve load while satisfying transmission network and contingency constraints at least cost. In many restructured markets commitments are determined day-ahead (i.e., the day before the commitments are to take place) with a planning horizon of 24 single-hour periods. Some markets have different planning horizons or period lengths in their commitment process. The proposed market redesign for the California ISO will consist of a day-ahead unit commitment and a separate one-day commitment for the second day out. The purpose of this second unit commitment is to give advanced warning to units with extremely long start times that they will be needed to be online. The Electricity Pool in the original British market had a single-day planning horizon, but the commitment model consisted of 48 half-hour-long periods. The simulations and discussion in this section will assume the more standard planning horizon of 24 single-hour periods.
EBL
17
The one exception to this was a short-lived and highly illiquid block-forward market which the California Power Exchange (the entity which administered the day-ahead spot market) operated. 18 In theory, a Vickery–Clarke–Groves (VCG) mechanism (assuming the SO’s unit commitment problem could be solved to complete optimality) would address both the incentive and efficiency issues. This suffers the obvious shortcoming that the SO unit commitment cannot be solved to optimality. In fact, the VCG mechanism requires solving the unit commitment problem multiple times – once for each generation firm in the market. Moreover, VCG payments are discriminatory, complicated, and not budget balanced, making the mechanism an unrealistic option. See Mas-Colell, Whinston, and Green (1995) for a discussion of mechanism design and the VCG auction.
Cost of Anarchy in Self-Commitment-Based Electricity Markets
255
6.3.1. Centrally committed model In centrally committed markets, the SO typically forecasts transmission network constraints for the following day, solicits demand bids from consumers,19 self-schedules,20 and virtual bids,21 and generation offers consisting of costs and operating constraints. For ease of problem formulation, an SO which centrally commits units accepts costs and operating constraints as a set of standardized parameters. Most SOs accepts three-part costs, consisting of start-up, no-load, and marginal generating costs. Start-up costs can usually be declared as being time-dependent with, for instance, a different start-up cost when a unit is in a hot, intermediate, or cold state, with the state being dependent on how long a unit has been offline. Marginal generating costs are normally submitted as non-decreasing stepwise- or piecewise-linear functions. Operating constraints are similarly given as a set of parameters. For example, a ramp rate indicating the maximum allowable hourly change in a unit’s output, minimum and maximum output when online, minimum up and down times when a unit is started of stopped, etc. Although most unit costs and constraints can be parameterized in this manner, some SO commitment models are too rigid to fully capture unit characteristics. Combined-cycle gas turbines, for instance, have “sawtooth”-shaped cost functions because they can switch between different operating modes as their output changes. Cascaded hydroelectric systems have constraints linking the reservoirs within the watershed, which some SOs cannot fully capture in their standardized constraint parameters.22 Given these inputs, the SO then determines a least-cost commitment and dispatch of the units to serve load while satisfying all operating, security, and ancillary service constraints. The SO will typically settle the market based on a uniform marginal energy price for each hour in the planning horizon at each location in the transmission network. These hourly locational marginal prices (LMPs) are paid to each unit that is dispatched to generate
EBL
19
In some markets, the SO uses its own load forecasts instead of soliciting bids from consumers in order to ensure a sufficient set of units is committed. Many markets which do commit units on the basis of submitted demand bids have a separate reliability unit commitment process into which the SO substitutes its own load forecast and solves to find if additional units (beyond those selected in the initial unit commitment) must be started to ensure its load forecast can be satisfied. 20 Some centrally committed SOs give generators the option to self-commit their units and submit self-schedules and one-part energy offers as opposed to having the SO make commitment decisions for them. Most generators in such markets have tended to use the centralized commitment with multipart offers, instead. One possible reason for this behavior is that a generator which self-schedules a unit must recover all of its variable generating and fixed start-up and no-load costs through energy payments and will have to roll these fixed costs into its one-part energy offers. Units which are centrally committed by the SO, by contrast, are given supplemental “make-whole” payments if energy payments do not cover all of their costs. This different treatment of self-scheduled and centrally committed units can serve to make a self-committed unit less attractive in the SO’s dispatch, since the energy cost of the unit will seem higher. Make-whole payments are described further later in this section. 21 SOs which include virtual bids in computing the unit commitment will often remove these bids in computing the reliability unit commitment, since virtual bids do not generally require actual physical delivery of energy. This is to ensure that there are sufficient units available when the virtual bids are netted out in real-time. 22 Streiffert et al. (2005) further note that because the SO’s commitment problem does not decouple when the load balance and ancillary service constraints are relaxed, unit commitment problems solved by an LR algorithm cannot easily model combined-cycle gas turbines or cascaded hydroelectric systems. Instead, they must often rely on other approximation algorithms.
256
Competitive Electricity Markets
in that period. Because most units incur fixed startup and no-load costs, these linear energy-only payments can be confiscatory – meaning that inframarginal energy rents may not ensure that a generator recovers its full costs. Since such confiscation could incent generators to withhold themselves from the commitment process or to misstate costs or operating constraint parameters in their offers, potentially affecting the efficiency of the resulting commitment, centrally committed markets typically include a supplemental “make-whole” provision. This make-whole provision pays any revenue shortfall over the course of the planning horizon to ensure committed units recover their stated costs. Units which receive energy payments in excess of their fixed and generating costs do not receive any supplemental make-whole payments. Although the make-whole provision ensures units recover their stated costs over the course of the day, a unit may still be run at a loss in a single hour. This could occur, e.g., if a unit is kept online and generating at its minimum load (for instance, because of a minimum up-time constraint), in which case it would not set the LMP and could be running at a marginal loss.23 As such, units which do not lose money over the course of the day may be forced to cross-subsidize between individual hours. For ease of analysis and discussion the unit commitment formulation used in the simulations is a simplification of a commercial SO model. It includes stepped marginal costs and fixed (not time-dependent) start-up and no-load costs for each unit. Demand is priceinelastic; there are no network flow constraints, virtual bids, self-schedules, or ancillary service requirements. Appendix 6A discusses in further detail the exact formulation studied. The computations assume the centrally committed market settles with a uniform hourly energy price – specifically the dual variable associated with the hourly load balance constraints.24 As noted before, because linear energy-only payments can be confiscatory, the analysis further assumes that the SO includes a make-whole provision, which pays each unit the difference between its total costs incurred in the commitment and dispatch (calculated on the basis of costs stated in its offer) and the total energy payments received over the course of 24 hours, if that difference is positive. These payments ensure that total net profits (on the basis of stated costs) are always non-negative.
EBL
6.3.2. Self-committed model In a self-committed market, generators are left to make commitment decisions individually, as opposed to the SO making binding commitment decisions for them. The exact format and means of energy trade in self-committed markets varies, however. The current 23
A unit can also run at a marginal loss if it has any binding intertemporal (e.g., ramping) constraints and is the highest marginal cost unit, in which case it may not set the LMP. However, the LMPs used by the SO are typically computed from a separate optimal power flow (OPF) problem, which determines the optimal dispatch of the units given the fixed commitments from the unit commitment. Because these OPFs are solved separately for each hour, they do not include intertemporal constraints; thus a unit will only run at a marginal loss if it is held at minimum load. 24 As noted before, some SOs use LMPs based on the load balance constraint dual variables from the OPF, which can be different from the prices from the unit commitment load balance constraint dual variables. When there are no network flow constraints, the OPF LMPs will simply be set by the highest marginal cost unit, which is not running at minimum load. The unit commitment prices, on the other hand, will “smooth out” prices when high-cost units have binding intertemporal ramping constraints, and can in general be different. Because the two sets of prices are nearly identical in these simulations, the analysis uses only the unit commitment prices.
Cost of Anarchy in Self-Commitment-Based Electricity Markets
257
Texas market, for instance, is based almost exclusively on bilateral transactions between generators and consumers. The original California market operated as a day-ahead energyonly market into which generators would offer their generation and are given energy payments only for their actual generation. The California market made dispatch decisions solely on the basis of the generators’ energy offers by aggregating them into a supply curve and intersecting them with demand, without any regard for operating constraints or start-up or no-load costs. These constraints and fixed costs were meant to be internalized by generators, which would be compensated for energy generated only.25 The model analyzed assumes that energy is traded through an energy-only market, such as the original California market design. To compute a competitive benchmark, the market is modeled as a competitive auction in which the auctioneer26 announces a set of hourly energy prices, and price-taking generators individually determine their hourly commitments and output level to maximize profits and submit offers to the auctioneer indicating how many MWh they are willing to supply in each hour. The auctioneer then iteratively adjusts the hourly energy prices until it finds a set of prices which incent sufficient generation to serve the load. This iterative price-updating process is meant to mimic Wilson’s (1997) proposal for a self-committed market with two important differences. One is that loads are fixed in each hour as opposed to being price-elastic. Thus, the market is assumed not to accept demand bids but rather solicit sufficient generation at any price to serve a fixed hourly load. The other is that under Wilson’s proposal, generators are assumed to submit offers consisting of quantity/price pairs. Because the model analyzed in this section assumes generators to behave competitively, generators are modeled as price-takers, which take the auction prices as fixed and decide their commitments and generation offers to maximize profits individually, as opposed to strategically adjusting their energy offers to raise energy prices. Although the model assumes that energy is traded through a centralized energy market, it can be thought of as solving for a competitive equilibrium of direct bilateral trade between generators and consumers a la a Walrasian auction model. The model further assumes that the auctioneer starts with a set of prices which incent sufficient generation to serve the load, and iteratively adjust prices until finding a set of supporting minimal prices – which is a set of prices such that generators offer sufficient energy to serve the load, but would no longer do so if any of the energy prices were reduced. As the energy prices are dropped, higher-cost units will no longer find it profitable to commit themselves and the total quantity offered for generation will be driven toward the system load. One difficulty with finding a set of supporting minimal prices is that the binary nature of the generators’ commitment decisions means that a set of supporting minimal prices will generally not be market-clearing, meaning generators will offer more total generation than there is load to serve, yet reducing any of the energy prices will cause a unit to de-commit itself leaving insufficient energy to serve the load.27 One solution is to assume that the auction uses some type of rationing rule to determine how the load is divided amongst generators willing to commit themselves. Our model assumes, instead, that because highercost generators drop out of the commitment as prices are iteratively reduced, if there is
EBL
25
Generators could also offer capacity into separate ancillary service markets in which they could be paid for committed reserve capacity. 26 The auction can be thought of as being operated by the SO, or it can be a separate outside market. 27 This stems from the fact that if the SO unit commitment problem is solved using an LR algorithm, the dual solution will have a non-zero duality gap.
258
Competitive Electricity Markets
excess generation offered and multiple units are competing for the same load, the one with the lowest average cost over the course of the day will prevail. In modeling generators’ profit-maximizing behavior, they are assumed to perfectly rationally expect the behavior of other generators and take into account the “winner determination assumption” in making their own commitment decisions. This is to preclude the possibility that a unit may commit itself in expectation of being dispatched but finds that it does not, resulting in a net profit loss. This assumption is enforced algorithmically and described along with the formulation and solution algorithm in further detail in Appendix 6A. Finally, the model assumes that each generator acts independently in making its commitment decisions, as opposed to making commitment decisions for portfolios of generators being owned by generating firms. This assumption is made because the dataset used does not have unit ownership information, although the technique and results would translate to a setting with generator asset portfolios. 6.3.3. Market simulations The simulations are based on actual market data from an ISO New England (ISONE) unit commitment problem in February 2005, consisting of 276 dispatchable units. This dataset is used because of availability of the data and is meant to be an illustrative example of the
EBL
Fig. 6.1. ISO New England system map.
Cost of Anarchy in Self-Commitment-Based Electricity Markets
259
relative efficiency losses and settlement costs between the two market designs. Fig. 6.1 shows the ISONE system map and the nine major pricing zones. The ISONE system covers approximately 6.5 million retails customers, includes more than 350 generators with 31 000 MW of installed capacity, an all-time peak load of 28 127 MWh, and $11 billion of annual energy trade. The operating costs and constraint parameters used in the market simulations are those that were submitted by generators to ISONE. The competitive benchmark assumption takes these generator-offered parameters as reflecting actual costs and unit operating constraints – thereby assuming away any incentive compatibility issues. The computation of the central commitment assumes generators will offer these actual cost and constraint parameters to the SO for use in its commitment problem, as opposed to strategically misstating them to increase profits. The computation of the self-commitment assumes that generators behave as price-takers and maximize profits with the same cost and constraint parameters. Table 6.2 compares the total settlements paid to generators, commitment costs, and profits of the generators in the simulations of the two market designs. Although the centrally committed market is assumed to include a make-whole provision, the dataset is such that each generator receives sufficient inframarginal rents to recover all its costs and no supplemental payments are required. Nonetheless, Fig. 6.2 shows that the set of supporting minimal prices found in the self-committed market far exceed the energy prices paid in the central unit commitment. Indeed, a critical assumption underlying a centrally committed market is that the SO can force cross subsidies of “losing” hours by profits from other hours and has means of preventing generators from making adjustments to their assigned schedules. Fig. 6.3 shows the resulting load imbalances which would occur if generators could individually adjust their outputs to maximize profits against the hourly energy prices – known as uninstructed deviations. Due to the potential for such deviations, SOs penalize such deviations in generation by requiring generators to buy or sell back their insufficient or excess generation at the LMP, thereby removing any incentive for such deviations. This enforcement mechanism can be problematic, however, in multiple-settlement systems in which the SO computes different sets of LMPs at different intervals in real-time. Because there can be differences between the prices at which an uninstructed deviation is paid and penalized, a generator may be inclined to change its output if these price differences are predictable. Alternatively, O’Neill et al. (2005) propose a two-part nonlinear tariff, which prevents such deviations. Their proposed scheme pays the same uniform LMPs28
EBL
Table 6.2. Cost and profit comparison of centrally and self-committed market designs Market design
Energy payments
Make-whole payments
Total settlements
Commitment costs
Total unit profits
Central
$16 075 121
$0.00
$16 075 121
$5 758 201
$10 316 920
Self
$25 060 666
$25 060 666
$6 003 274
$19 057 392
55.90%
4.16%
84.72%
%-difference
28
Importantly, these LMPs must be the prices from the unit commitment problem, not from the associated OPFs. Moreover, the pricing scheme enforces the unit commitment dispatch, not that from the OPF. If the SO dispatches according to the OPF, then those OPF constraints must be incorporated into the unit commitment formulation.
Competitive Electricity Markets
260
15000
160
Load Central commitment energy price Self commitment energy price Self commitment marginal average cost
140
14000
Load (MWh)
100 12000 80 11000 60 10000
40
9000
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24
20
Hour Fig. 6.2. Central- and self-commitment prices of ISONE market simulations.
EBL 80 Load Imbalance
60 40
MWh
20 0 −20 −40 −60 −80
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24
Hour Fig. 6.3. Load imbalance from uninstructed deviation in centrally committed market.
Price ($/MWh)
120 13000
Cost of Anarchy in Self-Commitment-Based Electricity Markets
261
and a set of discriminatory payments on each of the commitment variables.29 O’Neill et al. demonstrate that such a pricing scheme will ensure that profit-maximizing generators will follow the same centrally determined commitment and schedule if they could adjust their outputs, without the need for any additional penalty or enforcement mechanism.30 Inclusion of such a provision in our simulation would increase total settlement costs of the centrally committed market by approximately $219 017, which is a relatively small sum compared to the total simulated settlement costs of the market of approximately $16 million. More importantly, the simulation demonstrates that a self-committed market requires higher energy prices than a centrally committed one. Because the model assumes that demand is fixed and inelastic, these higher prices are simply a wealth transfer from consumers to generators, without any efficiency losses. In a more realistic setting with demand response,31 the higher prices could result in allocative distortions. Table 6.2. also shows that a self-committed market will generally suffer productive efficiency losses, as demonstrated by the more than 4% increase in total commitment and dispatch costs. These efficiency losses are not the result of units committing themselves under a self-committed market when they would not be committed under the central commitment. Rather, these losses stem from the fact that a central commitment gives the most efficient coordination of generator dispatches, which are lost when generators dispatch themselves independently. Of the 276 units, 108 are committed in at least 1 hour under the central unit commitment solution. Of these 108, 73 follow the same commitment and dispatch schedule under the self-committed market as under the central unit commitment, with some shuffling of generation amongst the remaining 35. 6.4. Conclusions
EBL
This chapter has revisited one of the key issues surrounding the proper role of the SO in the design of competitive electricity markets. An SO with broad economic authority can, in theory, determine the most efficient commitment to meet forecasted demand. However, centrally committed markets, are not strategy-proof and are prone to incentive compatibility issues, meaning that generators can profitably manipulate their offers to increase profits. This has both been shown through simple examples and was one criticism of the original Electricity Pool in the British market. Proponents claim that a decentralized energy-only market in which generators individually determine their commitments can reduce the incentive issues of a central unit commitment while minimizing efficiency losses. The simulation of a competitive benchmark conducted in this chapter provides a bound on the productive efficiency losses from a self- as opposed to centrally committed market design. While these losses were relatively small, around 4.25% in the case examined here, this would nonetheless represent a significant welfare loss in absolute terms considering that ISO markets typically trade energy worth billions of dollars on an annual basis. The efficiency loss in the market simulations would amount to an annual loss of nearly 29
These commitment variable payments are found by solving the unit commitment problem to optimality, adding constraints to fix the values of the commitment variables, solving the linear programming relaxation of the unit commitment problem, and using the dual variables on the constraints fixing the commitment variables. 30 Their results apply much more broadly to any market with integer variables or other nonconvexities. 31 See Chapter 8 for a discussion of demand response.
Competitive Electricity Markets
262
$90 million for the ISONE system, if the results are typical of most days.32 Moreover, the total efficiency losses would be significantly higher in the presence of demand response since the energy prices under self-commitment will generally be higher than under central commitment. These higher prices could cause self-committed markets to be more prone to allocative efficiency losses in the presence of demand response, which may be an important consideration as these programs are slowly becoming more prevalent. Although these simulations are based on a dataset from a single SO for a specific period of time, the results are nonetheless instructive for estimating the relative size of the efficiency losses between the two market designs. The issue of unit commitment is an important and often overlooked one. Many authors have been quick to advocate one market design or another, all the while suppressing these important technical realities of power systems. The discussion and analysis of this chapter and the issues raised would be relevant to any market that is evaluating the options of centralized versus decentralized design of day-ahead markets. In some sense, the options available to policy makers and market engineers is between two imperfect systems, since centralized markets will be fraught with incentive problems and decentralized markets with coordination losses. 6A. Appendix This section describes the specific formulations and algorithms used in modeling of the centrally and self-committed market. 6A.1. Central Commitment Model
EBL
To describe the formulation, the following notation is used: Problem Parameters • • • • • • • • • • • • •
I: generator index set T: number of planning periods B: number of steps in generators’ marginal cost SUi : stated start-up cost of unit i Ni : stated no-load cost of unit i MCbi : stated marginal generating cost of step b of unit i’s marginal cost curve bi : stated maximum generating capacity of step b of unit i’s marginal cost curve − Kit : stated minimum generating capacity of unit i in period t + Kit : stated maximum generating capacity of unit i in period t Ri : stated maximum ramp rate of unit i ni : stated minimum up time of unit i fi : stated minimum down time of unit i Di : load forecast in period t
Decision Variables • • • • 32
b qit : generation provided from step b of unit i in period t uit : binary variable indicating if unit i is up in period t sit : binary variable indicating if unit i is started in period t and hit : binary variable indicating if unit i is stopped in period t.
This may likely be a lower-bound on the annual losses, since more energy would presumably be traded during summer peak periods.
Cost of Anarchy in Self-Commitment-Based Electricity Markets
263
+ − , Kit , Ri, ni , and fi , are The generator cost and constraint parameters, SUi , Ni , MCbi ,bi , Kit assumed to be given by each generator to the SO in the generator’s offers. Given these offers, and the load forecast, the SO’s unit commitment problem is then formulated as follows: b MCbi qit + Ni uit + SUi sit minimize total costs min qush
s.t.
it
ib
b
b qit
= lt
∀t
load balance
∀i t
unit generating capacity
∀i t b
unit segment capacity
∀i t
ramping limit
si ≤ uit
∀i t
minimum uptime
hi ≤ 1 − uit
∀i t
minimum downtime
∀i t
startup transition
− uit ≤ Kit
b
+ b qit ≤ Kit uit
b ≤ bi qit
−Ri ≤
t =t−ni +1 t =t−fi +1
b
b b qit − qit−1 ≤ Ri
sit ≥ uit − uit=1 hit ≥ uit−1 − uit uit sit hit ∈ 0 1 b ≥0 qit
EBL
∀i t
shutdown transition
∀i t
integrality
∀i t b
non - negativity
6A.2. Self-commitment model The self-commitment model assumes that the market operates as an iterative energy-only auction. The auctioneer announces a set of hourly energy prices, given by pt . Generators then individually determine their profit-maximizing commitments and dispatches and submit to the auctioneer a set of offers indicating how many MWh of energy they are willing to generate in each of the hours. The auctioneer then iteratively adjusts the prices until reaching a set of supporting minimal prices. The “winner determination rule,” which states that if two or more generators are contending for the same dispatch the one with the lowest average cost will prevail, is enforced algorithmically. The model assumes that generators, in making their commitment and dispatch decision, will be perfectly rational in predicting other generators’ behavior and the winner determination rule outcome. This is to preclude the possibility that a generator commits itself thinking that it will be dispatched, but finding that it is not because of the commitment decision of another unit with a lower average cost. This is enforced in each generator’s profit-maximization problem by restricting each generator to produce no more than the available load in each hour, where the available load in each hour is the total load in that hour less the dispatch of lower average cost units. As units are accepted for dispatch in order of average cost, the available load is updated, and the profit-maximization problem of the remaining generators are iteratively resolved.
Competitive Electricity Markets
264
Using the same notation as from Appendix 6A.1, define pt to be the hourly energy prices announced by the auctioneer and alt to be the available load in each hour. Generator i’s profit-maximization problem is then formulated as follows: b − Ni uit − SUi sit maximize profits pt − MCbi qit Pt max qush t
s.t.
b
∀t
available balance
∀t
unit generating capacity
∀t b
unit segment capacity
∀t
ramping limit
sit ≤ uit
∀t
minimum uptime
hit ≤ 1 − uit
∀t
minimum downtime
sit ≥ uit − uit=1
∀t
startup transition
hit ≥ uit−1 − uit
∀t
shutdown transition
∀t
integrality
∀t b
non-negativity
it
b qit ≤ alt
− uit ≤ Kit
b
+ b qit ≤ Kit uit
b ≤ bi qit
−Ri ≤
t =t−ni +1 t =t−fi +1
b
b b qit − qit−1 ≤ Ri
uit sit hit ∈ 0 1
EBL
b ≥0 qit
Given a set of energy prices, pt , the resulting dispatch is found using the following algorithm: initialize alt ← Dt ∀ t = 1 T # initialize available load in each hour to be total load in that hour dispatchi ← 0 ∀i ∈ I # initialize each generator’s status to not being dispatched repeat ∀i s.t. dispatchi = 0 solve Pi # solve each undispatched unit’s profit-maximization problem b b MCi qit + Ni ui + SUi sit t b ∀i s.t. dispatchi = 0 let avgcosti ← b qit tb
Cost of Anarchy in Self-Commitment-Based Electricity Markets
265
# calculate each undispatched unit’s average cost b Let j ← arg minavgcosti dispatchi = 0 qit > 0 i
tb
# find undispatched unit with positive generation offer and lowest average cost. Denote this unit as unit j Fix commitment and dispatch of unit j Let dispatchj ← 1 # set generator j’s status to being dispatched b ∀t = 1 T Let alt ← alt − qjt b
# update available load in each hour to be previous available load, less generation offer of unit j until alt = 0 ∀t = 1 T or dispatchi = 1∀i ∈ I # repeat until available load in each hour is zero or all units have been dispatched
The algorithm is designed to find a set of profit-maximizing commitments and dispatches, while also ensuring that generators properly take into account how much load will be available for them to supply in each hour given the behavior of other generators and the winner determination assumption. It does so by iteratively accepting generators one at a time in order of their average costs, updating the load available in each hour based on the dispatch of the accepted units and resolving the profit-maximization problems of the uncommitted units. The process continues until all the load is served, in which case the energy prices are called a feasible set of supporting prices, or until no other generators wish to commit themselves, in which case the energy prices do not incent sufficient commitment to serve the load. To find a set of supporting minimal prices, the auction begins with a set of supporting prices that will induce oversupply. The prices are then iteratively updated to be pt ← pt + 1 − t , where t is the highest average cost of the units dispatched to generate in period t and ∈ 0 1is a step-size parameter. In doing so, the auction aims to drive the energy price in each hour toward the marginal average cost. Once the prices cannot be feasibly updated in this manner, the auction decreases the energy price in each period individually so as to minimize the total settlement costs paid by the SO.
EBL
References Adib, P. and Zarnikau, J. (2006). Texas: The most robust competitive market in North America. In Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective (F.P. Sioshansi and W. Pfaffenberger, eds). Amsterdam: Elsevier. Amundsen, E.S., Bergman, L., and Von Der Fehr, N.-H.M. (2006). The Nordic electricity market: Robust by design? In Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective (F.P. Sioshansi and W. Pfaffenberger, eds). Amsterdam: Elsevier. Bertram, G. (2006). Restructuring the New Zealand electricity sector 1984–2005. In Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective (F.P. Sioshansi and W. Pfaffenberger, eds). Amsterdam: Elsevier.
266
Competitive Electricity Markets
Bowring, J. (2006). The PJM market. In Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective (F.P. Sioshansi and W. Pfaffenberger, eds). Amsterdam: Elsevier. California ISO (2007). Business Practice Manual for Market Operations. http://www.caiso.com/ Dyner, I., Arango, S., and Larsen, E.R. (2006). Understanding the Argentinean and Colombian electricity markets. In Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective (F.P. Sioshansi and W. Pfaffenberger, eds). Amsterdam: Elsevier. Guan, X., Zhai, Q., and Papalexopoulos, A. (2003). Optimization based methods for unit commitment: Lagrangian relaxation versus general mixed integer programming. In Proceedings of IEEE Power Engineering Society General Meeting. Hobbs, B.F., Rothkopf, M.H., O’Neill, R.P., and Chao, H-P. (eds) (2001). The Next Generation of Electric Power Unit Commitment Models. Norwell, MA: Kluwer. Hogan, W. (1994). An efficient bilateral market needs a pool. Testimony before the California Public Utilities Commission. Hogan, W. (1995). Coordination for competition in an electricity market. Working Paper. Hortaçsu, A. and Puller S.L. (2005). Testing Models of Strategic Bidding in Auctions: A case study of the Texas Electricity Spot Market. UCEI CSEM Working Paper 125. Hunt, S. (2002). Making Competition Work in Electricity. New York: John Wiley & Sons. ISO New England (2007). Manual for Market Operations. http://www.iso-ne.com/ Johnson, R.B., Oren, S.S., and Svoboda, A.J. (1997). Equity and efficiency of unit commitment in competitive electricity markets. Uti. Pol., 6, 9–19. Joskow, P.L. and Schmalensee, R. (1983). Markets for Power: An Analysis of Electric Utility Deregulation. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press. Mas-Colell, A., Whinston, M., and Green, J. (1995). Microeconomic Theory. New York: Oxford University Press. Midwest ISO (2005). Business practice manual for energy markets. Moran, A. (2006). The electricity industry in Australia: Problems along the way to a national electricity market. In Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective (F.P. Sioshansi and W. Pfaffenberger, eds). Amsterdam: Elsevier. Muckstadt, J.A. and Koenig, S.A. (1977). An application of Lagrangian Relaxation to scheduling in power-generation systems, Op. Res., 25, 387–403. New York ISO (2001). Manual 11: Day-ahead scheduling manual. Newbery, D.M. (2006). Electricity liberalization in Britain and the evolution of market design. In Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective (F.P. Sioshansi and W. Pfaffenberger, eds). Amsterdam: Elsevier. In Press O’Neill, R.P., Sotkiewicz, P.M., Hobbs, B.F., et al. (2005). Efficient market-clearing prices in markets with nonconvexities. Eur. J. Op. Res., 164, 269–85. OFFER (1998). Review of electricity trading arrangements. Office of Electricity Regulation. Oren, S.S. and Ross, A.M. (2005). Can we prevent the gaming of ramp constraints? Dec. Supp. Sys., 40, 461–71. Raineri, R. (2006). Chile: Where it all started. In Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective (F.P. Sioshansi and W. Pfaffenberger, eds). Amsterdam: Elsevier. Ruff, L.E. (1994). Stop wheeling and start dealing: resolving the transmission dilemma, Elec. J., 7, 24–43. Sioshansi, R., O’Neill, R.P., and Oren, S.S. (2007). Economics consequences of alternative solutions methods for centralized unit commitment in day-ahead electricity markets. Forthcoming in IEEE Transactions on Power Systems. Streiffert, D., Philbrick, R., and Ott, A. (2005). A mixed integer programming solution for market clearing and reliability analysis. In Proceedings of IEEE Power Engineering Society General Meeting, San Francisco, CA. Sweeney, J.L. (2006). California electricity restructuring, rhe crisis, and its aftermath. In Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective (F.P. Sioshansi and W. Pfaffenberger, eds.). Amsterdam: Elsevier. Wilson, R. (1997). Activity rules for a power exchange. In Proceedings of the 2nd Annual POWER Conference of the University of California Energy Institute, Berkeley, California. Wilson, R. (2002). Architecture of power markets. Econometrica, 70, 1299–340. Wolsey, L.A. (1998). Integer Programming. New York: Wiley-Interscience.
EBL
Chapter 7 Market Power and Market Monitoring PARVIZ ADIB1 , AND DAVID HURLBUT2 Automated Power Exchange, Santa Clara, California, USA; 2 National Renewable Energy Laboratory in Golden, Colorado, USA
1
Summary Competitive electricity markets are prone to abuse of market power by dominant generators or firms with strategic assets under a number of circumstances. Experience suggests that when these conditions are present and a vigilant watchdog is absent, firms may be tempted to exercise their market power to manipulate prices in a number of ways, harming consumers and other market participants in the process. This chapter provides an overview of how market power can be exercised and how effective market monitoring can prevent abusing practices.
EBL
7.1. Introduction Competition is good public policy as it encourages efficiency and price transparency. While proper market design is important, the success of competitive electricity markets depends first and foremost on structural conditions that do not distort market outcomes. One of the important conditions is that structural market power must be eliminated or effectively mitigated.1 Other structural conditions such as demand response are related to market power. The ability of customers to respond to high prices by reducing consumption can greatly limit suppliers’ ability to influence prices. Unfortunately, in most restructured electricity markets today, some degree of market power continues to exist. Demand response is still in its infancy, which means that customers have little ability to defend themselves when a dominant supplier engages in the exercise of market power.2 1 Structural market power refers to high concentration of ownership. Some wonder why market power abuse seems more prevalent in the United States than in Australia. One important difference between, for example, the Texas market and the Australian market is the high concentration of ownership in Texas, where TXU owns 22.4% of ERCOT-wide generation and 44.4% of generation in the transmission constrained North zone, versus the dispersion of ownership in Australia where the largest generation company has a 14% market share. See Moran and Skinner, Chapter 11, this volume. 2 See Chapter 8 by Jay Zarnikau in this volume for a detailed discussion of demand response in restructured electricity markets.
267
268
Competitive Electricity Markets
Until demand response matures, market monitors have a crucial role in detecting and reporting market power abuses. See Mark Armstrong and David Sappington (2006). Wholesale electricity markets have characteristics not normally encountered in antitrust law. Section 7.2 of this chapter elaborates on what market power means in the particular context of wholesale electricity markets. The section provides a review of the reasons why antitrust law is not always applicable to restructured electricity markets and why it cannot effectively address some of the market power problems encountered in those markets. The different types of market power and the different ways a monopolist can withhold production to affect market prices are described, and the tools available to market monitors to detect market power abuses and mitigate their impact are discussed. Section 7.3 provides a description of the role and function of market monitoring units (MMUs) that have been created in the United States and elsewhere. Section 7.4 provides conclusions. 7.2. Market Power in Electricity Markets Structural market power exists where a single player or a group of colluding players is large enough to control market outcomes. In wholesale power markets, a player is said to have market power if it is pivotal; which means that it is so large relative to the pool of other suppliers and to demand that, without it, supply would be physically less than demand and the market would not clear. There are no potential substitutes for electricity at least in the short run, resulting in what could be aptly termed the “Don Corleone Equilibrium”: the largest player can make the market an offer it can’t refuse. An important distinction is often made between having market power and abusing or exercising it. For example, a particularity of Texas law relating to the opening of a competitive electricity market is that it makes such a distinction between having and abusing market power. The Texas law defines market power abuse as “practices by persons possessing market power that are unreasonably discriminatory or tend to unreasonably restrict, impair, or reduce the level of competition.” Texas Public Utility Regulatory Act (2005): (Emphasis added.) This distinction means that abusively exercising market power is a practice that is illegal in Texas, whereas merely having market power is tolerated. In contrast, there are jurisdictions where the statutes address not only the practice but also the possession of market power. In such markets, effective structural remedies to address market power such as divestiture have been implemented. Thus, in California, New York, and New England, regulators have either required large vertically integrated utilities to divest their generation assets before the implementation of deregulated markets or provided strong incentives such as predicating stranded investment recovery upon asset sales. Divestiture of assets is the most efficient method of mitigating the natural tendency of a monopoly company to use its market power to influence market prices and eliminate competitors. Whereas vertical divestiture is called for to separate the generation part of the former utility from the wires company and the retail branch, horizontal divestiture ensures the breakdown of large generation fleets and their acquisition by multiple new owners.3
EBL
3 California’s three investor-owned utilities sold their generation assets to two or more buyers, which ensured better mitigation of their generation monopoly. In New England, however, regulators did not impose a limit on the maximum amount of generation that could be purchased by any single entity, and almost all of NEES non-nuclear generation (4000 MW) was acquired by a single buyer, PG&E, so that the potential for horizontal market power in that market remained strong.
Market Power and Market Monitoring
269
In electricity markets where one or more generation companies continue to have market power, the regulator’s and market monitor’s most challenging task is to protect customers from the high prices induced when market power is exercised. This section examines the specificities of horizontal market power when it is exercised in electricity markets and is organized into the following: • •
A discussion of the limitations of antitrust law when applied to electricity markets. A discussion of the distinction between high prices caused by a shortage of supply compared to the demand, referred to as scarcity prices, and excessive prices that result from the exercise of market power. • An examination of the different ways an entity with market power can withhold resources to control prices. 7.2.1. Antitrust law and electricity markets While antitrust case law contains a number of definitions of market power that have passed judicial muster, many have been tailored to the facts of the specific case being litigated. Antitrust and wholesale electric market oversight share the same principles: genuine competition is desirable, market power is not. These shared principles are rooted in fundamental market economics, in which a fair market environment engenders creative tension among economic actors. With respect to the specific problems associated with competitive electricity markets, however, antitrust offers few useful precedents. One expert in antitrust law observed that:
EBL
Experience over the last 15 years reveals that both regulation and antitrust may be hobbled in their ability to effectively deal with the competitive issues dealt out by restructuring. Antitrust may be limited because it cannot (by design) address certain problems; regulation, because it uses an inadequate set of policy tools.4 Generation owners usually advocate a verbatim adoption of the definition of market power used by the US Department of Justice (DOJ) and the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) in these agencies’ Merger Guidelines (DOJ and FTC 1997). Yet DOJ legal experts have said informally that they themselves do not apply the Merger Guidelines’ definition in such a way – as the title plainly states, they are guidelines, not laws or court rulings. They are designed to evaluate mergers, not market power issues that do not involve mergers. The DOJ document is therefore highly instructive, but by no means definitive outside the realm of mergers. The Merger Guidelines define market power as “the ability profitably to maintain prices above competitive levels for a significant period of time.”5 However, the element of time renders part of this definition less meaningful for the wholesale electricity market.6 The main question for antitrust is whether a merger, which is a discrete and easily observable change, causes a competitive market to become measurably less competitive. In this context, “significant period of time” is meaningful, because time is easily divided into “before” and “after” the merger. On the other hand, there is no discrete dividing line between “before” and “after” in a newly restructured electricity market, because the market has no history before the day the 4
Moss (2005), February, p. 3. DOJ and FTC (1997), p. 2. 6 For a concise discussion of why the time element is problematic, see Stoft (2002), pp. 365–8. 5
270
Competitive Electricity Markets
market opens to competition. Market power may have been present from the beginning, but the tools for detecting it and measuring it need to evolve.7 Time also has a different meaning in markets in which customers have the ability to see prices when they make consumption decisions and to defer consumption accordingly, and where consumers and suppliers have the ability to store products for future use or sale. In contrast, a large majority of electricity customers are blind to price fluctuations and cannot respond to them, are unable to defer or forego consumption at least in the short run, and cannot store electricity for future use. Hence relying on the Merger Guidelines to address market power in electricity markets would most assuredly cause an agency charged with market oversight to overlook the existence of market power. In short, while antitrust law may provide philosophical guidance, there is no basis for being bound to its precedents.8 Where market power exists, the challenge for a regulatory authority charged with protecting the public is to adopt a definition of market power that recognizes the complexities of electricity markets. It may be a highly generic definition taken from antitrust law that addresses the fundamental concerns, such as “the ability to control prices or exclude competition in a relevant market.”9 This definition of market power does not include the element of time found in the DOJ and the FTC definition mentioned above, nor does it require the market monitor to demonstrate that a company was able “profitably to maintain prices above competitive levels.”10 A general definition, however, places the burden on market monitors and enforcement authorities to defend in court the tests and criteria they use to measure “the ability to control prices” if such tests are not included in the definition.
EBL
7.2.2. Scarcity prices versus high prices induced by market power In a well-functioning competitive market, scarcity puts pressure on prices, and the resulting high prices provide a signal for resource allocation decisions that bring about adjustments in demand and, over time, new investment in generation. It does not follow, however, that any high price is a scarcity price. High prices can occur from the exercise of market power in the absence of true scarcity. Unlike scarcity prices, prices that rise due solely to the willful effort of one or more dominant players do not send rational signals for resource allocation and for that reason can be harmful to the market. Marginal costs and long-term fixed costs can vary widely with the type of generation. In a uniform pricing auction where generators tend to bid in their marginal costs, generators with the lowest marginal costs are selected first and those with the highest marginal costs are selected last. In most auctions, the marginal unit sets the market-clearing price or MCP. The marginal unit is the most expensive unit selected, and the MCP is the price at which 7
Moss (2005), pp. 33–4. This standard was applied by the court to the Texas Commission’s enforcement rule, Subst. R. 25.503. TXU Generation Co. v. Public Utility Commission, 165 S.W.3d 821 (Tex. App. – Austin 2005, writ denied). 9 This definition is drawn from the seminal US Supreme Court decision in U.S. v. E.I. duPont de Nemours & Co., 351 U.S. 377, 76 S.Ct. 994 L.Ed.2d 1264 (1956). It was adopted by the Public Utility Commission of Texas (25 TAC Sec. 504), with the intent that specific indicators of market power and their validity be considered in the context of specific cases as they arise. 10 DOJ and FTC (1997), Horizontal Merger Guidelines. “For more background on how DOJ and FTC employ these concepts in an investigation, see DOJ, commentary on the horizontal merger guidelines,” March 2006. 8
Market Power and Market Monitoring
271
all suppliers are paid.11 Under this pricing mechanism, all generators except the marginal unit receive a price that is higher than their marginal cost. This difference is known as the inframarginal profit. Since marginal costs cover only short-term production costs, additional revenues are needed to cover the generator’s long-term fixed costs and ensure ongoing investments in generation. Thus, for the business to be viable, the inframarginal profit must provide the revenues necessary to cover both the short-term and long-term costs of electricity production. Scarcity refers to a situation where the amount of generation capacity needed to serve the load and to maintain a minimum reserve margin approaches existing capacity, putting pressure on prices. High MCPs lead to high inframarginal profits, which, in turn, lead to investment in additional resources. The new plants entering the market tend to have low marginal costs compared to the existing fleet. Once the older, more expensive units that had been setting the MCP are displaced by the new efficient units, the next-most-expensive unit in the stack will set the price, with the effect that over time prices will come down. As long as the new price setters have marginal costs sufficiently higher than the new units, however, the new generator will be profitable and long-term sustainability will be achieved. The previous paragraphs describe how price signals are expected to work in a wellfunctioning competitive market. However, when prices are driven by the exercise of market power rather than by scarcity of supply, the price signal is corrupted. Lenders and investors may be uncertain about whether to build or finance new plants if they see an incongruity between high prices and seemingly abundant supply. Prices that are higher and more volatile than the fundamentals of supply and demand would suggest can also be a significant risk factor for new retail suppliers in the electricity market. In addition, if consumers cannot respond to high prices by reducing their demand, excess wealth flows from consumers to producers. Market power also makes it more difficult for intermediaries such as power marketers to arbitrage risk. Consider, for example, the different risk values placed on long-term contracts by a typical generator and by a typical retailer. For the generator, a 3-year contract to provide power reduces risk because it assures some amount of future revenue. The retailer, on the other hand, may not know what its customer base will be 3 years into the future, and thus may prefer short-term supply arrangements. Consequently, there is a natural economic role for a power marketer to arbitrage risk between the two market players, to the advantage of all involved. For power marketers to effectively perform this function, they must have confidence that prices change in response to legitimate market mechanisms and will continue to do so. If the prices paid by the retailer and received by the generator respond to the normal forces of supply and demand, power marketers can safely base their market decisions on informed predictions about future prices. If price fluctuations are instead the result of market power abuse, the prices do not follow a predictable course, the associated risk is difficult to arbitrage, and the market operates less efficiently. Unfortunately, there is no simple test to distinguish a legitimate $1000 scarcity price from a $1000 price resulting solely from the exercise of market power. Sometimes both scarcity and market power may be at work. The data for supply, demand, market share,
EBL
11
Uniform pricing, as compared to pay-as-bid pricing, is the dominant pricing mechanism used in most restructured wholesale electricity markets, particularly, in the United States. For a good discussion of these two pricing mechanisms, see Kahn et al. (2001).
272
Competitive Electricity Markets
and prices may suggest that market power is what drives prices, but the difficulty comes in proving that a specific action by a specific market entity constitutes an exercise of market power. To compound the problem, if a large supplier controls the market, it need not break any established market rules to exclude competition or manipulate prices. This is why structurally competitive markets – i.e., markets that exhibit ease of entry and where no supplier or group of suppliers can control prices – are generally better at disciplining market participants, protecting consumers and producing efficient pricing, output, and investment than is reliance on behavioral rules. Absent the best solution of genuine competition, the regulators and MMUs who must protect consumers against unjust prices have a difficult challenge.
7.2.3. The different types of market power Wholesale electricity market exhibits market power in three ways. Ideally, each type should be addressed differently when developing legislation prior to deregulation, when designing the market and developing the market rules, and when developing mitigation plans or penalties for anti-competitive behavior. This section provides a discussion of the distinction between pervasive market power, temporal market power, and local market power, and of the difficulties in concretely delimiting each type. 7.2.3.1. Pervasive market power If a supplier is pivotal all the time, that entity’s market power is called pervasive. This is the classic kind of market power that is described in economic textbooks and discussed in antitrust literature. Pervasive market power can be difficult to address. Take, for example, a market in which auctions to purchase and sell energy are conducted every hour. The largest supplier may be pivotal half the hours, but only close to being pivotal the rest of the hours. How “close” is too close? Are half of all hours enough to be significant? The second, third, and fourth largest suppliers may also be pivotal, but only for a handful of hours. Does that mean these middle-sized players have market power too? If the largest supplier is pivotal only because all the old, inefficient, and expensive units have not been turned on, is that entity considered to have market power? These are some of the issues the market monitors face when attempting to determine whether large generation companies, in a given market, have been exercising market power. The Electric Reliability Council of Texas (ERCOT)12 provides an instructive case study of the challenges. In the fall of 2004, the largest generation owner in the ERCOT market stated its intention to begin pricing the energy it offered into the balancing energy market at well above marginal cost, so that it could recover both marginal cost and its own estimation of the long-term fixed costs associated with its gas turbine units. The supplier was pivotal in the balancing energy market significantly more often than even the second-largest supplier. A subsequent investigation by the Public Utility Commission of Texas’s (PUCT’s) market monitoring consultant concluded that the supplier’s pricing strategy was not consistent with competition and contributed to a significant increase in balancing energy prices
EBL
12
The ERCOT accounts for about 85% of Texas. The Public Utility Commission of Texas (PUCT) has regulatory jurisdiction over ERCOT wholesale electricity market. In contrast, the FERC has jurisdiction over wholesale electricity markets in all other states within the United States.
Market Power and Market Monitoring
273
during the period studied.13 Nevertheless, two factors prevented investigators from stating that market power had been exercised: •
First, other suppliers had excess spinning capacity that they could have offered into the market but did not. Had all of that capacity been offered at its marginal cost, the investigators concluded, prices would have remained normal. • Second, at the time the PUCT had adopted no particular definition of market power. The investigators, acting on their own judgment, used the DOJ/FTC definition previously mentioned, which requires proving that the entity had the “ability profitably to maintain prices above competitive levels for a significant period of time.” The analysis could not demonstrate that the company profited overall during the study period by the higher prices, even though it could show that the supplier’s strategy caused prices to be significantly higher.14 No punitive action was taken at that time. However, a few months later in the summer of 2005, the company again started offering large amounts of balancing energy well in excess of marginal costs over a period of 4 months. A new investigation was launched. The supplier was found to be pivotal in about 84% of the price spike intervals, and it was again found that its pricing strategy was inconsistent with competition. This time, however, the investigator found that the company had profited by close to $20 million over the 4 month period while raising prices by approximately $70 million in the balancing energy market, and concluded that the company had engaged in economic withholding and abused its market power.15 Thus, although the company engaged in the same pricing strategy in the two periods, based on the market power definition adopted, a determination of market power abuse could not be made conclusively in the first investigation. This example illustrates the importance of establishing an operational definition of market power that is suited to wholesale electricity markets. Texas is not the only market where market monitors have been unable to demonstrate that market power has been exercised until recently. None of the MMUs that are members of the Energy Intermarket Surveillance Group (EISG)16 have reported any success in investigating and documenting market power abuses. As Leveque (2006) concluded recently, “The potential for market power in electricity and gas is high but extremely difficult to determine.”17
EBL
13
Potomac Economics (2005). The reason was that the period of analysis was too short to make such a determination. During a small number of intervals the supplier had scheduled too little energy overall and ended up having to purchase balancing energy at the high price it had set. Over the short period of analysis, the magnitude of these few losses offset the majority of intervals during which the supplier received higher balancing energy revenues. 15 See Potomac Economics (2007). Investigation of the Wholesale Market Activities of TXU from June 1 to September 30, 2005. Independent Market Monitor, March. The report was further revised in September 2007 to reflect lower figures for profit for $19 million and rising prices in balancing energy market by $57 million. The IMM report is available on the Texas PUC website: http://www.puc.state.tx.us or can be directly accessed at the Potomac Economics website at http://www.potomaceconomics.com/ercot/2005%20TXU%20Investigation%20(Final%20%20REDACTED).pdf. A Notice of Violation issued to TXU by the PUCT can be found on the website under Docket No. 34061. Interested readers may follow the progress of this case on the PUCT website under that docket number. 16 The EISG is a non-profit, voluntary professional organization of market monitors from electricity markets around the world that was established in 2000. 17 See Levegue (2006), p. 31. 14
274
Competitive Electricity Markets
Market power often exists in degrees. Deciding how much is too much will necessarily involve subjective policy decisions that no amount of economic analysis alone can answer. What we can say without hesitation, however, is that competition is threatened when market power is so pervasive that certain suppliers can control prices even when reserve margins are high and there is no sign of scarcity. 7.2.3.2. Temporal market power Temporal market power is market power caused by a tightness of supply. In some contexts, the theory of contestable markets and the limitations on antitrust enforcement have supported the notion of allowing some level of market power to exist, as long as it is not accompanied by abusive behavior on the part of the monopolist.18 Under this theory, high prices, whether they are the result of scarcity or market power, will induce market entry that will correct the underlying deficiency and lower prices. In a practical sense, however, this low level of market power is barely distinguishable from scarcity. If market power does not exist or is of limited scale without scarcity, then the real issue is resource adequacy and not market power.19 The economic issue is not necessarily the resulting high prices, but rather the suppliers’ response to those prices. The types of market power abuse for which market monitors should be especially vigilant are activities by current suppliers that prevent new suppliers from entering the market. 7.2.3.3. Local market power Local market power is a common problem in electricity markets because of transmission bottlenecks, which are common in many markets today. Some states judged it prudent to direct former monopolies to divest their generation assets prior to opening the electricity market to competition. However, even after the former utilities divested their generation, these markets continued to experience local market power.20 Local market power arises from limitations on the transmission system. Line limits may make it impossible to import enough power into a load pocket to meet local demand, even if the system outside the load pocket has abundant generation resources. Under these conditions, a lone generator inside the load pocket may well be in a position to dictate its price with respect to the residual demand21 in the load pocket. Local demand cannot be served through imports entirely, and as a result, the local generator is in no danger of being replaced by low-cost competitors outside the load pocket. The “market” in which market power exists in this case is difficult to define; it often has no geographic boundaries, but is rather delineated by a complex combination of power flow relationships. Addressing local market power requires imposing mitigation safeguards. For example, it may be ruled that generators inside load pockets can only be paid their generic costs when conditions do not allow enough power to be imported into
EBL
18
See Baumol (1982). Also see Shepherd (1984) for a strong criticism of the theory of contestable markets. See Falk (2004) for an application of this argument to wholesale electricity markets. 19 For a more extensive discussion of scarcity and resource adequacy, see Adib, Schubert, and Oren, Chapter 9, this volume. 20 California is a good example. The state was successful in achieving both vertical and horizontal divestiture of its three largest utilities, yet the California electricity market was plagued by local market power problems caused by its severe transmission bottlenecks. 21 Residual demand is the difference between total demand for a given time period minus total offers by all other suppliers that should be served by the generator in question.
Market Power and Market Monitoring
275
the local area. The challenge comes from having to regulate prices only within the limits where local market power is likely to exist, without affecting other areas. Complicated modeling is often required to decide how to draw the lines and where to enforce the mitigation rules. Even then, any lines drawn are bound to be wrong some time or another. The question then, is whether to err on the side of too much mitigation or of too little: is it better to impose price limits when competition would otherwise be sufficient, or to allow unrestrained pricing when in fact the market is not competitive? Generators are naturally predisposed to lobby for the latter, as it would provide occasional opportunity to reap a windfall by raising prices beyond competitive levels. However, erring on the side of too much mitigation has the least price impact on the market. Ideally, mitigation would be designed to make suppliers behave as though they faced competition. When that is possible, mitigation results in prices that are close to competitive prices and is least intrusive. A Texas example illustrates how market rules can attempt to mitigate local market power, but not always successfully. When local congestion occurs in ERCOT, a generator that is strategically located can submit a high premium bid22 knowing that the ISO has no other choice to resolve the congestion. To mitigate this problem, ERCOT protocols initially defined a market solution as three unaffiliated resources capable of solving a circumstance of local congestion, when no one bidder is essential to solving the congestion. Under this rule, when a market solution exists, each generator selected to resolve the congestion is paid the premium bid it submitted in the auction process, but when a market solution does not exist, each generator is paid at generic cost. This seemed at the time like a reasonable hands-off solution that would allow congestion constraints to be resolved by competitive forces when the condition for competition existed. However, market participants did not respond to competitive pressures as expected in situations where at least three non-affiliated competitors were offering their generation.23 Subsequently, the “market solution” provision was removed and it was decided that all generators called on to relieve local congestion would be paid at generic costs, with no exception.
EBL
7.2.4. Different ways to withhold resources Withholding of production is the most common method of exercising market power in a wholesale electricity market. Production may be withheld economically, which is referred to as economic withholding, by pricing it significantly in excess of marginal cost. Or it can be physically withheld, which is referred to as physical withholding, by not offering it at all. All else being equal, however, and assuming no collusion, withholding is profitable only if the supplier has market power, and only then does it become a concern. From the supplier’s point of view, market power greatly amplifies the motive to withhold. Comparing inframarginal profits demonstrates why. Inframarginal profit is the difference between revenues and operating costs summed for all units in a supplier’s portfolio given a single MCP. Suppose a small supplier had a single 100-MW unit with 22
The premium bid was used by the ERCOT ISO to provide Balancing Energy Service when no Market Solution existed for resolving congestion. See 2003 version of the ERCOT Protocols §§ 2.1 and 6.1.11. 23 See Project No. 25937, PUC Investigation into Possible Market Manipulation of the ERCOT Market, “Settlement Agreement with Commission Staff,” 21 August 2003 and Memorandum to PUCT Commissioners, 21 August 2003.
Competitive Electricity Markets
276
a cost of $99/MWh, and that it was dispatched for all 100 MW. If the MCP were raised to $100/MWh, this supplier would profit by only $100 ($1/MWh times 100 MWh). Now let’s assume a supplier with two units – one 50-MW unit with a cost of $99/MWh and a 50-MW unit with a cost of $20/MWh. This second supplier would profit by $4050 if dispatched for that same 100 MW for an hour when the MCP is raised from $99 to $100. The larger and more diversified the portfolio is, the larger a supplier’s inframarginal profit can be when prices are high. For a small supplier lacking the ability to control the MCP, maintaining such a high-cost unit would be risky. If prices were not high enough, the small supplier, if acting rationally, would eventually retire or sell the unit.24 On the other hand, a large supplier controlling a similar unit could, through withholding other units in its portfolio, make the price clear high enough to cover the unit’s operating cost, thereby significantly increasing the profits on all its other units. The large supplier, therefore, has the opposite incentive from the small supplier. Instead of retiring a unit that would be uneconomical in a competitive market, it would keep the expensive unit online as a potential price-setting tool. Figures 7.1 and 7.2 illustrate the two types of withholding, using a hypothetical market with 1200 MW of demand, 2000 MW of supply, and a large market participant that controls 50% of the supply. For ease of illustration, these examples assume that the large supplier’s cost curve is the same as that of the rest of the market. 7.2.4.1. Physical withholding In Fig. 7.1, the hypothetical large supplier significantly increases its total revenues by taking three-fourths of its supply off the market. The overall supply shrinks, causing the market to clear at $325/MWh rather than $95/MWh. The large supplier sells all of the 250 MW it offered, but foregoes payment on 350 MW it would have sold had it not withheld. But because the price is more than three times higher, its total revenues are in fact greater.
EBL
Large supplier’s offer
Overall supply market
$750
$750
$500
$500
$250
$250
$0
Price increase due to withholding
$0 –
200
400 600 MW offered
800 1,000
Available MW offered Available MW not offered
–
500
1,000 1,500 MW offered
2,000
Supply, no physical withholding Supply with physical withholding MW required
Fig. 7.1. Physical withholding.
24 After enough retirements, competitive prices would eventually rise given tightness in the market through normal supply and demand, signaling new entry into the market.
Market Power and Market Monitoring Large supplier’s offer
277
Overall supply market
$750
$750
$500
$500 Price increase due to withholding
$250
$250
$0
$0 –
200
400 600 MW offered
800 1,000
Incremental cost Economic withholding offer
–
500
1,000 1,500 MW offered
2,000
Supply, no economic withholding Supply with economic withholding MW required
Fig. 7.2. Economic withholding.
(Its revenue under the withholding scenario is $81 250, rather than $57 000 under the no-withholding scenario. In addition, its costs would be lower under the withholding scenario, since it would be operating only 250 MW, rather than 600 MW.) Had a non-pivotal supplier with only 100 MW of supply attempted the same strategy, the effect on the clearing price would have been negligible. The supplier itself would have ended up worse off, having lost most of its potential revenue and most of the profit it would have enjoyed had it priced its offer near its marginal cost. Hence the MMU does not have to be concerned with non-pivotal suppliers submitting offers at prices substantially above marginal costs.
EBL
7.2.4.2. Economic withholding In Fig. 7.2, the hypothetical large supplier doubles its revenues by pricing nearly all of its offers at $600/MWh. No other supplier has offered any amount priced higher than $500/MWh, so all 1000 MW offered by other suppliers are taken. Another 200 MW are required, however, and the large supplier is the only one who has it. The large supplier can name its price, and need not take its actual costs into consideration. Even though the large supplier sells a smaller quantity, it enjoys a much larger profit on what it does sell due to the fact that its total revenue in this hypothetical scenario is $120 000 on total costs of $6500 for its least-expensive 200 MW. As in the example of physical withholding, if a small supplier were to increase its offer to $600/MWh, the impact on the MCP would be zero. The smaller supplier would simply price itself out of the market, giving up all the revenue and profit it would have received had it offered at marginal cost. As these two examples illustrate, neither physical withholding nor economic withholding matters in the absence of market power. It is only when these activities are done by a large supplier with market power that the clearing price is significantly affected. Consequently, the key element in a legal case involving market power abuse is not necessarily proving what the supplier did, but establishing that it has market power and that, therefore, what the supplier did led to an outcome that would not have occurred under competitive conditions.
Competitive Electricity Markets
278 7.2.5. Detecting market power
Market monitors screen for potential market power and possible market power abuse in two general ways: traditional methods that measure market concentration, and newer methods that test market outcomes. The traditional approaches, such as the Herfindahl– Hirschman Index (HHI) and the Delivered Price Test (DPT), are familiar to antitrust law. The outcome approach, however, has encountered rough waters in the courtroom despite its grounding in economic theory. This section briefly reviews five methods of analysis that are widely used by market monitors to detect market power. The HHI and the DPT as well as the Pivotal Supplier Test (PST) indicate whether an entity has market power, but do not by themselves indicate whether the entity is abusing its market power. In contrast, the output gap test, the impact test, and scenario analysis provide information that indicates whether an entity with market power may actually be engaged in anticompetitive practices.
7.2.5.1. Concentration measures: HHI and DPT The HHI sums up the squared values of each supplier’s market share. For example, a market in which four suppliers each have 25% of the market would have an HHI of 2500 (25 squared, times four suppliers, where market share is measured as the number of percentage points). The DOJ uses the HHI to measure how market concentration might change as a result of a merger between two suppliers. Continuing with the above example, if two of the suppliers merged, the HHI would be 3750 (50 squared, plus 25 squared times the other two original suppliers). DOJ considers a market to be un-concentrated if the resulting HHI is less than 1000, and highly concentrated if the HHI is greater than 1800.25 The DPT as specified by federal statute is the HHI applied to a more explicitly delineated market.26 It evaluates the amount of capacity that can reasonably be expected to serve a market at a competitive MCP defined to present 105% of that market’s prevailing price to attract additional potential supply, taking into account imports and native load obligations. When used to evaluate the market power effects of a merger or acquisition, the capacity identified by the DPT is then compared to the amount of capacity the entity will hold as a result of the merger or acquisition. The analyst is then able to assess if the amount of capacity held by the new merged entity will reach an unacceptable level as a percentage of the total capacity available to serve the market.
EBL
7.2.5.2. Pivotal supplier test As discussed earlier, a supplier is considered “pivotal” if it controls an amount of capacity that is so large relative to the demand and the pooled capacity of all other suppliers that the market cannot clear without it. Mathematically, a supplier is pivotal if the following equation holds: Qallsuppliers − Qpivotalsupplier < Demand 25 26
DOJ and FTC (1997), Horizontal Merger Guidelines, Section 1.51. See Title 18, Code of Federal Regulations, §33.3(c)(4).
Market Power and Market Monitoring
279
where Qallsuppliers represents the total amount of capacity offered to the market by all suppliers, and Qpivotalsupplier represents the amount of capacity offered by the entity being tested. If the total amount of capacity minus the capacity of the single supplier being tested is less than the demand, the single supplier is pivotal. This formula is the basis of the PST.27 A supplier that triggers the PST can unambiguously be said to have market power. It is important to note, however, that the supplier has market power at the time of the test and in the market where it is tested. Because the PST is calculated ex post, however, it might not be apparent that a supplier is pivotal until after the market clears and the opportunity to exercise market power has passed. Therefore, it is important, when conducting an analysis based on the PST, to assess how frequently and how predictably a large supplier might trigger the test. Each peak season will typically have a dozen or so hours when demand is so high that some moderate-sized suppliers may be found to be pivotal when applying the PST. In most cases, this is likely to be an example of temporal market power. These extraordinary periods are more indicative of thin reserve margins and true scarcity than of pervasive market power. A PST, therefore, should exclude these periods from the analysis up front or the analysis should give little weight to whether a supplier was pivotal during super-peak periods. A PST may be conducted on a system-wide basis by comparing real-time load against the generators that are online and capable of providing energy. It can also be applied to a specific market, as long as substitution with products outside the market is not reasonably possible. In the market operated by ERCOT, for example, market monitors have applied a PST to the balancing energy service (BES) market. Balancing energy is energy procured in real-time by the ISO to keep scheduled load and scheduled generation in balance. Generators offer into the BES market their excess spinning capacity (that which is not dedicated to serving load or other contractual obligation).
EBL
7.2.5.3. Output gap analysis The “output gap” measures the capacity of profitable resources that are not offered into the market or are offered into the market at prices that are substantially above their marginal cost. For example, if a supplier were suspected of engaging in physical withholding, the market monitor would evaluate the amount of capacity this supplier had online but did not dispatch or offer into the market even though the marginal cost was significantly less than the MCP. This amount of capacity constitutes the output gap. As discussed earlier, strategically keeping economic capacity off the market will shrink the supply of generation available to meet demand, forcing the ISO to procure higher-cost offers and thus increasing the MCP. The output gap analysis is useful as an initial screen for detecting possible withholding activities, but is not by itself conclusive evidence that strategic withholding has occurred. Many other factors can affect whether or not a unit is deployed. A full determination of market power abuse requires investigating and excluding each instance where a plausible, legitimate reason exists for not offering capacity, and a determination of how persistently the potential withholding occurred. 27 The results of a PST are sometimes presented as a residual supply index (RSI). The index can measure how frequently the market has a pivotal supplier, or how frequently any given supplier is pivotal.
280
Competitive Electricity Markets
7.2.5.4. Impact tests and scenario analysis Impact tests measure how market prices change as a result of behavior that fails a screen. The New York ISO, New England ISO, Midwest ISO, and PJM (Pennsylvania–Jersey– Maryland) ISO use some form of conduct and impact tests. A supplier fails the screen when it offers a generator’s capacity into the market at a very high price compared to an established reference price for that generator. When that happens, the bid price is administratively reset at the calculated reference price. However, these mitigation provisions are only implemented if the conduct has an impact on market prices, to ensure that seemingly high offers do not trigger price mitigation if they in fact have no impact on prices. Establishing reference prices for a particular generator requires an estimation of the generator’s marginal cost of production. The reference price is based primarily on fuel costs and incremental operating costs. When triggering conditions are met, i.e., when an offer is significantly above its reference price, the security-constrained economic dispatch market pricing model can be re-run and the target generator’s offer is reset at its reference price. This allows the analyst to simulate the market outcome and price that would be in effect in the absence of anti-competitive behavior. The simulation indicates whether a supplier that behaved as though it had market power, i.e., priced well in excess of its marginal cost, actually affected the resulting market prices through its behavior. In practice, there are two ways price mitigation can be implemented. In one alternative, if the simulation provides evidence of market power abuse, bid prices can be reset ex ante, meaning that the bid price of a particular generator is administratively changed to the reference price before the results of the auction. Ex ante price mitigations are in effect in the New York and New England markets. Alternatively, if the results of the simulation show that the bidding behavior affects prices in excess of a threshold the prices obtained from the simulated run are used to clear the market. Although this approach may seem objective and data-driven, it in fact requires some subjective judgment. Most significantly, there is little in the way of economic theory or legal precedent that can guide the selection of a threshold. Wherever it is set implicitly denotes an acceptable range of market power. For example, say a market participant failed an impact test with a $300 offer, but would not have failed had that same offer been $299. It would be difficult for a market monitor to prove how a $1 price difference would constitute a material difference in the market participant’s ability to influence price outcomes. An example taken from the New England market illustrates another weakness of this approach in the calculation of a generator’s reference price. The New England ISO calculates a generator’s reference price by taking a rolling average of the bids submitted over time for this generator. The reasoning is that the bid price will reflect the generator’s marginal costs most of the time, except in certain situations when the supplier anticipates a shortage due to weather extremes or transmission or generation outages, or other similar event. As explained earlier, in the case when a generator’s bid price is significantly above its reference price, the ISO either resets the bid price or replaces the MCP with a market price obtained by running a simulation model. In the spring of 2005, the New England ISO found that the reference prices calculated for certain non-competitive generation units that are frequently run out of economic merit to relieve transmission congestion were well above their marginal costs. These generators were never under competitive pressure to bid their marginal costs. The result was that their reference prices were well above their
EBL
Market Power and Market Monitoring
281
marginal costs. Once aware of the situation, the ISO in this case changed the rules and the way the reference price was calculated.28 7.3. Market monitoring Section 7.2 described the most important reason why electricity markets need close monitoring. The California crisis of 2000–0129 provided costly proof of how vulnerable consumers can be to market power abuse.30 Strategically located generation units resulted in local market power in areas where transmission constraints existed, and consumers could not respond effectively when prices soared. These structural problems were compounded by rules that prevented utilities from hedging against spot market volatility through longterm contracts, and by loopholes in rules that were intended to ensure reliability yet opened up unforeseen opportunities for gaming.31 32 The California crisis also illustrated how, when an MMU lacks coordination and close cooperation with the relevant enforcement agency, market power abuse can run unchecked, resulting in the failure of electric restructuring efforts.33 This section explores the status of market monitoring today and draws on the experience MMUs have accumulated with market power and market manipulations issues in California and elsewhere. The section is organized into: •
A discussion of the objectives of an MMU and of the ingredients necessary for meeting these objectives. • A review of the different ways MMUs have been organized in the United States and abroad, and of the extent to which organizational factors can affect the independence of an MMU and the resources it has available. • A review of how market monitoring has evolved since the beginning of restructured electricity markets, and of the adjustments that are being made to the structure and organization of MMUs to improve their effectiveness. • A summary of examples of conduct by market participants or the system operators that resulted in harm to the market.
EBL
7.3.1. Objectives of MMUs An MMU has three main objectives: identification of market design flaws, monitoring and reporting, and prevention. To meet these objectives, the MMU carries out the following functions. 28
For more details, see the following link: http://www.iso-ne.com/regulatory/ferc/orders/2005/ may/er05-767_5-6-05.doc. 29 See Borenstein (2002) and Borenstein et al. (2002) . For a description of gaming strategies, see Market Oversight Division(2002a). 30 Statistics collected by the California market monitor show that total electricity costs, which include energy and ancillary services costs at the wholesale level, increased from $5.5 billion in 1998 and $7.4 billion in 1999 to $27.6 billions in 2000. On a per unit basis, total costs went from $33 per MWh in 1998 and 1999 to $116 in 2000. 31 For a description of some of the gaming opportunities see Market Oversight Division (2002b). The two documents listed under this and the previous footnote were prepared by the authors of this chapter and other members of the Market Oversight Division, including Richard Greffe, Julie Gauldin, Tony Grasso, and Drs Eric Schubert and Sam Zhou. 32 See Sweeney (2006). 33 For an excellent discussion regarding market monitoring, see Wolak (2004).
282
Competitive Electricity Markets
Identification of market design or operational flaws: Poorly designed market rules and protocols can create unanticipated inefficiencies or gaming opportunities. One function of the MMU is to identify such inefficiencies and recommend changes to market rules to address them. The MMU also monitors ISO operations and evaluates the impact of the practices and procedures followed by the ISO on market outcomes and market efficiency. Monitoring and reporting on overall market performance: The MMU acts as a troubleshooter that identifies trends that call for corrective action before a serious market failure occurs. It must detect market anomalies such as price excursions and determine if they are the result of market power manipulations or genuine scarcity. Prevention of harmful market activities: The market monitor can prevent market rule violations by identifying perverse incentives and recommending that they be changed. A market monitor that calls on market participants when they step outside legal limits can encourage compliance with market rules by simply letting it be known that someone is watching. Some of these harmful activities will be briefly described later when real life examples of MMU investigations are discussed. It is not always easy to determine whether an event is the result of market manipulations or legitimate activities. The MMU will devote a lot of its resources to fact-finding activities and analyses of abnormal events before concluding that a potential violation has occurred. Communication with market participants is essential at this point, as what may appear to be a violation can often be explained by special circumstances or complex situations. Finally, the MMU may conclude that a certain behavior may have violated market rules, or may have been anti-competitive. If it does not have enforcement authority itself, it may, at that time, refer the case to the relevant enforcement agency. When that is the case, the MMU may act in a supporting role to help in the investigation phase, the negotiation phase, and the litigation phase as applicable.
EBL
7.3.2. Effective market monitoring To achieve the objectives described in the previous discussion, an effective MMU needs independence from stakeholders; appropriate skills, tools, and experience; adequate financial resources; and access to both market data and individual market participants’ information. The independence of the market monitor will be discussed separately in the MMU organization discussion. The other ingredients to effective market monitoring are discussed below. The level of staffing and budget of an MMU will vary depending on organizational factors. Some MMUs may rely on ISO staff for supporting activities related to information technology resources, human resources, and clerical support. The ERCOT Independent Market Monitor (IMM) has five full-time employees dedicated primarily to real-time market monitoring, market data analysis, investigations, report writing, or similar activities, but does not have enforcement authority and, therefore, does not have any legal staff. The IMM first year budget is approximately $2 million. This level of staffing and budgeting is considered at this time to be the minimum to conduct meaningful market monitoring in a market the size of ERCOT, but may have to be revised in future years if it is found that additional resources are necessary. Skills, tools, experience, and technical knowledge of system operations: Market monitoring requires extensive knowledge of economics, transmission operation, and system engineering. Tasks may also require sophisticated quantitative tools34 and computer 34
Quantitative tools are used to develop automated indices, screens, and reports (ISRs).
Market Power and Market Monitoring
283
models35 to replicate market operations and network topology and to allow scenario analysis. To be effective, the monitoring team needs expertise in economics, engineering, statistics, and operations research – preferably with several years of working experience. Frequently, market monitors will need to interpret and analyze massive amounts of market data. While some of the requisite knowledge may be obtained through education and work experience, most of the technical and operational experience can only be acquired through constant interaction with system operators. Financial resources: Many of the skills and experience needed for good market monitoring are also sought by market participants and are in short supply. The MMU therefore will have to offer high salaries to be competitive with the private sector. In addition, the MMU must budget for high-level consulting services, as the highly technical skills required for some monitoring and investigative activities will not always be available in-house. If the MMU is part of a governmental entity charged with market monitoring functions, budget restrictions may interfere with the ability to secure the required resources. While there are advantages to a market monitor located within a governmental enforcement agency, as will be discussed below, the inherent budgetary limitations are likely to severely impact the MMU’s effectiveness. Access to relevant market data and information: The market monitor can only function if it has access to all market and operational data. Therefore the market monitor has to have the authority to request all relevant information from the market participants whose behaviors are under investigation. Market participants will sometimes try to argue that they should not be required to provide sensitive market information for competitive reasons. An arrangement can and should always be made to accommodate the need for confidentiality, and the MMU should be able to guaranty that the information provided will remain strictly confidential, so this hurdle should not be difficult to resolve. Timeliness is another important factor and the MMU must be able to place deadlines on its information requests, which can be negotiated so as not to impose an unreasonable burden on the market participant. Finally, it is essential that market participants’ data be archived for several years, as an investigation will often require looking into previous years’ activities. ISOs process thousands of pieces of market information all day long. Resource schedules and offers change hourly, there are new arrays of clearing prices every 5 to 15 minutes, regulation deployment every few seconds, and information regarding load forecast, generator outages, or tripped lines pours in all day long. Each time the market-clearing engine is run, the inputs are different and the outcome changes. This massive amount of data is where the evidence of market manipulations and market power abuse resides. The only practical way to examine this amount of data day to day is through computer-aided triage: automated tools and software routines that provide a user-friendly first-cut analysis and flag events that deviate significantly from the norm. Such tools may include:
EBL
•
Market condition e-mail alerts (such as prices above a certain threshold level) and other frequently generated reports • Market statistics (price levels, congestion costs, outages, etc.) • Preliminary tests of market power and abnormal behavior (pivotal supplier, withholding, etc.) 35
Computer models may include statistical and econometric models as well as mathematical models, such as MCP engine, which allows MMUs to test specific behavioral changes by various market participants and evaluate how the market outcome might have been affected.
Competitive Electricity Markets
284
An MMU conducts day-to-day monitoring as well as long-term analyses, primarily examining the activities of market participants but also evaluating the ISO’s performance with respect to market operations, congestion management, and reliability. Table 7.1 provides a summary of these activities.36 7.3.3. Organization of MMUs The way an MMU is organized will often affect whether it can secure the necessary resources previously described, but also how independent it will be from market Table 7.1. Market monitoring activities Day-to-day • • • • • •
Real-time market monitoring through reliance on automated indices and screens Assessment of generation adequacy to meet forecast demand in various markets Review of abnormal events (weather, congestion, outages, etc.) Identification of price abnormalities and conducting preliminary analysis Review of ex ante price mitigation and compliance Identification of violations of market rules and procedures
Communication with market participants regarding abnormal outcomes and identifying market outcomes requiring further investigation • • • •
Daily reports preparation Databases and computer models maintenance Tracking of emerging market issues Dissemination of useful market information
EBL
Long-term • • • • • •
Identification of market design flaws and remedies Investigation of market power abuses and anti-competitive behavior Assessment of demand growth, generation and transmission adequacy, and system reliability Resolution of complaints and disputes regarding anti-competitive behavior Assessment of market competitiveness Preparation of regular reports (annual state-of-the-market reviews, monthly summaries, etc.) and reports on specific special issues and events
Monitoring of market operator* • • • • • ∗
Assessment of ISO compliance with market rules and operating guides and procedures, particularly those governing market operations and congestion management Detection of operational procedures and practices that create market inefficiencies or otherwise adversely impact market outcomes Determination of ISO’s short-term load forecast accuracy Evaluation of amount of ISO procured ancillary services Evaluation of ISO long-term planning process to identify demand growth and possible shortcomings in transmission system
Discussion by Adib (2006).
36
See also PUCT Substantive Rule §25.365 for a description of the market monitor’s role and responsibilities in Texas.
Market Power and Market Monitoring
285
participants and the market operator. Organizational factors therefore influence the effectiveness of the MMU and its ability to detect and prevent market abuses. They will also affect the effectiveness of enforcement activities following an investigation. These issues are examined next as the general ways in which markets monitors have been organized is described. There are more than 20 MMUs operating worldwide, most of which are listed in Table 7.2. A Market Monitors’ professional organization, the EISG, was formed to share market monitoring experiences and exchange information and ideas.37 An MMU may be established • • •
within an ISO: the MMU answers to the board of directors of the ISO; outside the ISO: the MMU in this case reports to a regulatory authority; or within a governmental agency that has full oversight and enforcement authority.
MMU established within the ISO: This model is followed by early restructured electricity markets in the United States,38 and more recently by the Southwest Power Pool (SPP). It was also initially adopted in the Canadian provinces of Ontario and Alberta, and in New Zealand.39 The US Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC,) as part of its Standard Market Design in its Order 2000, required the creation of MMUs in each of the newly deregulated markets in the United States and emphasized the need for these units to be independent.40 All aspects of market monitoring are conducted by either the ISO or the Regional Transmission Organization (RTO) through these MMUs. The market monitor communicates with market participants, advises the board of directors, and reports to the board all suspicious activities and findings of market manipulation. The board may consist of members affiliated with market participants, or independent members, or a combination. The board may also have an independent market-monitoring advisor to assist its deliberations and decisions regarding issues identified by the MMU. In US markets under FERC jurisdiction, when the MMU identifies a potential market manipulation or market power abuse, it is required to refer the case to FERC for further investigation. These MMUs have limited enforcement authority, but they can require that the market participant under investigation cease its potentially illegal or harmful activities. If the request is unsuccessful, FERC takes over the case as the agency that has full enforcement authority. One advantage of this model is that the MMU is more likely to operate with adequate resources and has immediate access to market operational data. The MMU staff can readily discuss market problems with ISO operators as they occur, which makes this the best model to ensure that the MMU has a good understanding of market operations and of the causes of market failures. The disadvantage of the model is that the MMU is less likely to be completely independent from the market participants or the ISO. Where the ISO’s
EBL
37 The EISG was created in 2000 and its members meet twice a year. The United Kingdom Office of Gas and Electricity Markets’s (Ofgem’s) and the Scandinavian electricity market’s (NordPool’s) monitoring units are not member of the group at this time. A description of Ofgem can be found at: http://www.ofgem.gov.uk/ofgem/index.jsp. For a description of NordPool see: http://www.nordpool.com/ 38 These states are California, PJM, New York, and New England. 39 The Alberta and New Zealand markets have changed course and their MMUs are now outside the ISO and answer to government agencies or government appointed commissions. 40 See Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, Order 2000, (1999). Market monitoring was identified among eight core functions of newly established RTOs.
Competitive Electricity Markets
286
Table 7.2. Existing market monitoring units MMU within ISO, limited enforcement authority 1. Pennsylvania–New Jersey–Maryland (PJM)∗ 2. New York Independent System Operator (NYISO)† 3. Independent System Operator for New England (ISO–NE)‡ 4. California Independent System Operator (CAISO)§ with its Market Surveillance Committee (MSC)∗∗ 5. Southwest Power Pool (SPP)†† IMM outside of ISO 1. Midwest Independent System Operator (MISO)‡‡ 2. Market Surveillance Administrator, Alberta, in Canada§§ Government MMUs 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. 8. 9. 10. 11. 12. ∗
Wholesale Market Oversight (WMO)∗∗∗ of the PUCT with its IMM located in ERCOT Australia Energy Regulator††† France Energy Regulation Commission‡‡‡ Japan Electric Power Exchange, Inc.§§§ Korea Electricity Commission∗∗∗∗ The Netherlands†††† The NordPool (Denmark, Finland, Norway, and Sweden)‡‡‡‡ Electricity Commission of New Zealand§§§§ Philippines Energy Regulatory Commission∗∗∗∗∗ Singapore Energy Market Company Pte. Ltd††††† United Kingdom Office of Gas and Electricity Markets (Ofgem)‡‡‡‡‡ Independent Electricity System Operator (IESO)§§§§§ , Ontario, in Canada
EBL
Link to PJM Interconnection: http://www.pjm.com/about/pjm-links.html Link to NYISO: http://www.nyiso.com/public/index.jsp ‡ Link to ISO-NE: http://www.iso-ne.com/industry_links.html § Link to CAISO: http://www.caiso.com/surveillance/index.html ∗∗ Link to CAISO MSC: http://www.caiso.com/docs/2005/10/04/20051004104917266.html †† Link to SPP: http://www.spp.org/section.asp?pageID=17 ‡‡ Link to MISO: http://www.midwestiso.org/home §§ Link to Alberta Market Surveillance Administrator (MSA): www.albertamsa.ca ∗∗∗ Link to PUC WMO: http://www.puc.state.tx.us/wmo/about/aboutwmo.cfm ††† Link to Australia Energy Regulator: http://www.aer.gov.au/content/index.phtml/itemId/673322/fromItemId/651437 ‡‡‡ Link to France Energy Regulation Commission: http://www.cre.fr/marches/elec_gros.jsp §§§ Link to Japan Electric Power Exchange: http://www.jepx.org/ ∗∗∗∗ Link to South Korea Electricity Commission: http://english.mocie.go.kr/index.jsp and Power Exchange: http://210.223.85.230/english/ †††† Link to the Netherlands Office of Energy Regulation: http://www.dte.nl/engels/about_dte/Links/Links.asp ‡‡‡‡ Link to Nord Pool: http://www.nordpool.com/ §§§§ Link to Electricity Commission of New Zealand: http://www.electricitycommission.govt.nz/rulesandregs/compliance ∗∗∗∗∗ Link to Philippines Energy Regulatory Commission: http://www.erc.gov.ph/ ††††† Link to Singapore Energy Market Company: http://www.emcsg.com/grids/emc_template_aq.asp?id=278&area=5¤tsection=27079 ‡‡‡‡‡ Link to United Kingdom Ofgem: http://www.ofgem.gov.uk/ofgem/index.jsp §§§§§ Link to Canada IESO: http://www.oeb.gov.on.ca/html/en/industryrelations/msp.htm †
Market Power and Market Monitoring
287
board of directors is a stakeholder board, the influence of the entities that are the subject of the MMU’s monitoring is more likely to be felt than where there is an independent board. MMU established outside the ISO: In the United States, this model has been adopted by the Midwest Independent System Operator (MISO). In MISO, all aspects of market monitoring are conducted by the MMU and are funded through the ISO budget subject to government approval. The MMU is selected in a competitive process conducted by the ISO and overseen by the local regulatory authority. While the MMU freely communicates with market participants, the ISO staff, and the members of the ISO’s board of directors, it does not answer to the board. All suspicious activities and findings of market manipulation are referred directly to the governmental authority for further investigation and enforcement. Compared to the previous model, the MMU similarly has limited enforcement authority but is independent from the ISO board. In Australia, the National Electricity Code Administration (NECA), which had market monitoring and enforcement authority until recently, was initially established by several states participating in the national electricity market as a completely separate entity from the ISO with its own board. In 2005, NECA was abolished and its market monitoring functions were taken over by a new government agency, the Australian Energy Regulator, which now places the Australian MMU in the next class. In Alberta, the Market Surveillance Administrator (MSA), which conducts market monitoring in that market, answered to the ISO board of directors until 2003. It became clear that there was a conflict of interest when the MSA had to investigate the behavior of the ISO. The MSA was then set up as an independent entity appointed by the government. At this time, the Alberta MSA is an independent entity with surveillance and investigative authority. The adjudicative and enforcement authority is placed with an independent hearing panel that is separate from the Energy and Utilities Board, the agency with all other energy-related regulatory responsibilities in the Province. In France, the Commission for the Regulation of Energy (CRE) has recently been charged with monitoring the wholesale electricity and gas markets by the French Parliament. When created in 2000, the CRE was given a structure that was intended to ensure complete independence from the market players as well as from the government. The budget of the CRE is a line item in the State’s budget and is approved by the Parliament. The agency has six government-appointed commissioners representing various sectors of the economy, an appointed president, and two appointed vice-presidents. To ensure their independence, CRE commissioners serve a 3- to 5-year term, cannot be dismissed, and are not eligible for a second term. The agency has full authority to collect and analyze market data and reports finding of potential violations to another independent government entity, the Competitive Council, vested with investigative and enforcement authority. The CRE is a fully independent entity that reports only to the French Parliament and the European Commission. Government MMUs: Market monitoring in this model is conducted from within a government agency with full investigation and enforcement authority. This appears to be a preferred model in many countries outside the United States, including New Zealand and Australia since 2005, and several European and Asian electricity markets. New Zealand started off with its MMU integrated within the ISO or market administrator as it is called in that country, but governmental authorities decided to switch the market surveillance team to a more independent setting. In 2003, the Electricity Commission was created to oversee the electricity market, and in 2004 the surveillance and compliance functions were entrusted to a Market Governance team that answers to the Commission. The six Commission members are appointed by the government.
EBL
288
Competitive Electricity Markets
A similar change occurred in Ontario where the market monitoring authority, the Market Surveillance Panel, was transferred in 2005 from being a panel of the ISO Board of Directors to become a panel of the provincial regulator, the Ontario Energy Board. This change was made to bolster the independence of the Panel; however, the importance of direct access to ISO data and operational expertise was recognized and the existing market oversight business unit within the ISO was contracted to continue to provide monitoring and analytic services to the Panel.41 ERCOT is in this class. The PUCT, which is the government agency responsible for market oversight and monitoring in Texas, has contracted with an entity to act as the IMM and conduct monitoring of the wholesale electricity market from offices located within the ISO facilities. The market monitoring functions in this case are funded by a fee charged to electricity customers and collected by the ISO, but the market monitor answers to the PUCT and refers all cases of possible market abuse and market rule violations to the PUCT for investigation and enforcement. This model has the potential to provide a high degree of independence from market participants and from the ISO. It offers the best opportunity for good coordination and a close working relationship between the monitoring and investigative arm and the enforcement arm of an agency with market monitoring responsibilities. However, in several markets where this general model is followed, large market players have launched lobbying efforts to influence legislators’ and regulatory bodies’ rulings, threatening the independence of investigations and enforcement decisions. Potential shortcomings of this model include the adequacy of resources and skills needed for effective market monitoring42 and reduced opportunity for interaction and coordination with the ISO operators. Thus, organizational factors can subject a market monitor to more or less pressure from the market actors whose behavior and operations it must scrutinize and report. Regardless of the type of organization selected, opportunities for a market participant to influence the outcome of an investigation exist, and the market monitor should be subject to strict ethics standards that address possible conflicts of interest. For example, an employee of the market monitor should not have a financial interest in a power company that operates in the market it monitors, and should not accept employment with the company, or an affiliated company, or with the ISO, until a reasonable period of time after leaving employment with the MMU. Gifts or invitations should not be accepted. Market participant influence can also be exercised, sometimes in a subtle way, if there is unrestricted communication with the market monitor. MMU communication with market participants should be encouraged to the extent that the market monitor conducting an investigation needs access to market participant information and explanations of the facts. However, it should be structured to ensure no pressure is exercised, and no accidental disclosure of strategic information to the market participant occurs once the investigation becomes formal. Communication between the market monitor and the investigating and
EBL
41
This business unit, ring-fenced within the ISO, is also responsible for the enforcement of compliance with the market rules, a role unrelated to market power except for the specialized provisions related to the recovery of inappropriate congestion payments to market participants. 42 The experience in ERCOT and the Canadian Province of Alberta demonstrates that it is possible to effectively address this concern by establishing a funding mechanism, subject to government approval and control, in which an adequate portion of ISO-generated fees is used to fund market-monitoring activities.
Market Power and Market Monitoring
289
enforcement teams, on the other hand, should be encouraged and made as easy and unobstructed as possible. 7.3.4. MMU Objectiveness and Independence Not all the models described above have the necessary features to support the MMU’s goals of objectiveness and independence. It is clear that the market monitor must not be influenced by market participants, but it must also be independent from the market administrator or ISO. MMUs established within the ISO are more likely to experience interference from the organization they are supposed to monitor and evaluate if they have to report to the management of that organization, and if their budget is controlled by that organization. The Alberta MSA was reorganized and separated from the ISO when it found itself in the position of critically analyzing the behavior of the ISO. A more recent example of conflicting interests involving an MMU within an ISO was provided when the head of the PJM MMU reported to FERC that PJM management had interfered with his work and taken actions toward the MMU because of its dissatisfaction with the MMU’s analyses and conclusions.43 The Alberta solution was to set up the MMU as a stand-alone entity appointed by the government but not held to report to the ISO, the Utilities Board, a Board of Directors, or to the government, and with its own surveillance and investigative authority. In contrast, the PJM ISO has announced that it is considering disbanding its MMU and outsourcing the function, and it appears that the ISO would negotiate and administer the contract with the external MMU. This is not the case in Alberta where the MMU funding is also totally independent from the ISO, thereby leaving the MMU with no need to be wary of their treatment of the ISO in order to ensure a contract renewal. Entrusting the market monitoring function to an outside consulting firm raises some additional issues. Will the selected firm be influenced by its financial relationship with energy companies that may operate or have parent companies that operate in the market being monitored? Will the staff assigned to market monitoring duties also work on unrelated projects for other companies, rather than devote its full attention to the task? Can a consultant working on a time-limited contract be as engaged in the work as a permanent staff member? How is continuity assured? Can an external firm working offsite acquire an intimate knowledge of the market’s operations necessary to understand the very subtle ways in which the market can be gamed? These issues, however, can be addressed to a large extent if a number of requirements are specified. For example, when the PUCT hired a consulting firm to perform the function of market monitor for ERCOT’s wholesale markets, the commission required that the director and its staff be dedicated to working uniquely as the ERCOT MMU, located onsite with their offices within the ISO, and reporting directly to the commission. The more fundamental issues that affect independence and objectivity are:
EBL
• • • 43
Who controls the budget of the MMU? Who has hiring and firing authority over the director of the MMU? To whom is the MMU accountable?
See Electricity grid monitor claims interference. Wall Street Journal, 6 April (2007) More details about the charges are provided in PJM Market Monitor Joseph Bowring’s Prepared Statement presented at FERC’s technical conference on the Review of Market Monitoring Policies, Docket No. AD07-8-000, on April 5, 2007. Interested readers may follow the progress of this case at FERC.
290
Competitive Electricity Markets
The entity identified in response to these three questions must be as removed from the market participants and the market administrator the MMU evaluates as possible, and its decisions must not be influenced by them. The Alberta model of a stand-alone organization, which closely meets this description, seems to provide the best insurance for an objective and efficient MMU that will effectively protect the competitiveness of the market. However, recent developments there indicate that it does not satisfy everyone. Financial stakes are high, and market participants that have been under investigation have been dissatisfied with a market monitor that they think has too much discretion and leaves them little opportunity for appealing enforcement decisions. As a result, a discussion is currently under way to bring more clarity to the standards of behavior the Alberta MSA uses as bases for its evaluations and compliance measures, as well as minimize the ability of the MSA to negotiate behavioral change. Such tradeoffs are not easy to make: overall these changes, if adopted, would reduce the level of discretion left to the MSA and may also reduce its effectiveness as a market monitor. 7.3.5. Evolution in market monitoring The role of MMUs has changed significantly since wholesale power markets were first open to competition.44 When MMUs first took charge of their market monitoring responsibilities, there was no established way of conducting market monitoring, and the laws and rules of the market for the most part still had to be developed. More importantly, MMUs had no clear authority to investigate market manipulations, market power abuses, or other violations, and there was no case history. At that early stage, MMUs were often in a position to observe suspicious market activities but were not empowered to act on the undesirable behaviors they witnessed. MMUs have now entered a new phase. Rules and procedures are under development or have been developed with considerable input from stakeholders. The MMUs’ responsibilities are better defined, and so are enforcement procedures. Most of the restructured electricity markets have put in place market participants’ behavior rules and have spelled out penalties for a range of prohibited activities.45 Over time, these rules have been refined and expanded to reflect lessons learned. As a result, market participants have a better perception of the boundaries of acceptable behavior and they know what to expect if they step over those boundaries. MMUs, too, have a better sense of direction. The lines of responsibility between those who monitor and report market abuses, those who investigate, and those who enforce have been made clearer. The recent investigation of a large generation company in ERCOT and the market monitor’s finding that the company exercised its market power in violation of Texas laws and market rules are a good example of this evolution. The investigation took less than 3 months to finalize, and the PUCT staff was quick to issue a recommendation to levy a hefty fine against the company based on the IMM’s investigation results. These recent developments provide a good example of the effectiveness that can be achieved when a market monitor is free of influence from market participants and works in full cooperation with enforcement authorities.
EBL
44
See Adib (2006). The Texas commission adopted an enforcement rule that spells out the duties and responsibilities of wholesale market participants and the procedures for an investigation. See PUCT Substantive Rule §25.503. 45
Market Power and Market Monitoring
291
Over time, electricity markets abroad have increasingly opted to establish their MMUs outside the market operator and in many instances within governmental agencies that have investigative and enforcement authority. Alberta in 2003, New Zealand in 2004, Ontario in 2005, and France in 2006 moved in that direction. In the United States, where the first electricity markets to open to competition established their MMUs as part of the ISO, the MMU budget is still controlled by the ISO and MMU members are employees of the ISO. Even though the trend changed with MISO and ERCOT, where the separation between the ISO and the MMU became more prevalent, the first US electricity markets to open to competition are showing increasing signs of conflictual relationships between MMUs and ISO management. Recent testimony presented at FERC by the head of the PJM MMU regarding the alleged PJM ISO interference with the work of the MMU shows that the issue of the market monitor’s independence has reached a critical point and public pressure is building up for FERC to address and correct such situations. However, it is desirable that any changes that bring about more market monitoring independence do so without sacrificing access to crucial data sources. On the one hand, the monitoring function of the MMUs must remain within, or in close proximity to, the market operator, as the MMU’s work benefits from close interactions with the market operator. On the other hand, the investigative, reporting, and enforcement functions of the MMUs must be insulated from possible interference not only from market participants, but also from pressures that may be exercised by the market operator or by a government. Establishing an MMU as a stand-alone organization is the organizational structure that is most likely to result in effective market monitoring. Placing an MMU within a government agency is also a positive development, but only to the extent that such agency is able to offer guaranties of independence in its investigations and enforcement decisions. Such organizational decisions are crucial in winning the public’s trust in electricity markets and achieving true competitiveness in those markets.
EBL
7.3.6. Examples of behavior leading to harmful market outcomes Market monitors are concerned with any action that causes a market price to be different than if market forces had prevailed. Some of the examples of market manipulation are the exercise of market power to affect prices, anti-competitive behavior affecting other market participants, strategic manipulation of schedules, and inadequate resource information that causes the ISO to make sub-optimal operational decisions in real-time. Further examples of harm to the market dealt with by MMUs across the world are briefly presented in the Appendix 7A to this chapter. Market manipulation does not always involve an explicit rule violation. Operating guides and market rules cannot be exhaustively specific, and a market participant may be able to take advantage of flaws in rules at the detriment of the market. Examples of gaming activities that do not necessarily violate market rules include scheduling resources in a way that increases the congestion payments received by an entity, and bidding strategies that pose no risk to the supplier but significantly increase risk or costs for the rest of the market. In any case, the MMU must be on guard against any behavior that results in prices inconsistent with what would obtain under competitive conditions, regardless of whether the behavior was expressly prohibited or not.
292
Competitive Electricity Markets
7.4. Conclusions Market power is a fundamental problem that affects most electricity markets in transition from a regime of regulated monopolies to competition. Left unaddressed, restructuring will leave consumers at the mercy of unregulated monopolists. The problem is best addressed when legislators and regulators require structural changes and the large vertically integrated power companies inherited from the past divest their generation assets. If divestiture is not required, the market monitor could very well be the best bulwark against market power abuse and a pivotal defender of competition. If one or more generators participating in the newly deregulated market are so large that they can control prices in the absence of scarcity, regulators and market monitors will have the difficult task of protecting electricity markets against market power abuses. To be effective, MMUs must preserve their independence. Organizational factors are important in determining whether market actors can exercise undue influence on the market monitor and the outcome of its investigations, and they can also help or hinder the market monitor’s access to the extensive and time-sensitive market information it needs to perform its duties. These factors have played out, lessons have been learned, and market monitoring has evolved over time. Around the world, MMUs are now better organized, and are receiving clearer directions. However, power companies have also stepped up their efforts to influence the political processes that affect market monitors. The burden is on legislative and regulatory authorities to ensure that market monitors are empowered to do their job effectively, that their independence is protected, and that the information they gather is utilized fairly but firmly to police electricity markets in transition to competition.
Acknowledgment
EBL
Parviz Adib and David Hurlbut were on the Wholesale Market Oversight staff of the Public Utility Commission of Texas from 2000 to 2007, and from 2002 to 2006, respectively. The opinions expressed in this chapter are those of the authors and do not represent the opinion of the Public Utility Commission of Texas. The authors especially would like to thank Danielle Jaussaud, Director of Market Analysis at the Public utility Commission of Texas for her invaluable feedback on various versions of this chapter. Our appreciation also goes to Dr Perry Sioshansi, President of Menlo Energy Economics, Keith Casey, Manager of Market Analysis & Mitigation, California Independent System Operator, Wayne Silk, Vice-President and COO, Alberta Market Surveillance Administrator, Harry Chandler, Director of Market Assessment and Compliance, Ontario Independent Electricity System Operator, and Nicolas Beaulaton, Aurelien Lecaille, and Marie Dufourg of the French Energy Regulation Commission for their excellent comments and suggestions. Finally, we would like to thanks Jess Totten, Director of Competition Division, Public Utility Commission of Texas, for reviewing an earlier version of this chapter.
7A. Appendix 7A.1. Some examples of harm to the market addressed by MMUS across the world Most of the forensic economics performed by market monitors falls into one of three categories: market power abuse, market manipulation, and market design inefficiencies. The first involves suppliers that have market power, and their ability to control market outcomes. The second involves opportunistic behavior that does not necessarily require
Market Power and Market Monitoring
293
the ability to control prices. The third involves noncompliance with ISO rules in a way that is economically rational to the market players but poses reliability problems or leads to inefficient market outcomes. While the following are real life examples, an attempt was made to avoid disclosing the names of markets or players involved in the behavior.46
7A.2. Market power abuse Examples of market power abuse fall under several categories: •
Price spikes. Every price spike – even those that occur when scarcity is evident – raises the specter of potential market power abuse. Market monitors are the “first responders” called upon by regulators, market participants, and the public to investigate price excursions. Virtually every MMU has been called upon to investigate the price shocks resulting from a hurricane, an ice storm, a heat wave, or some other unusual event. • Economic withholding. A large supplier uses its market power to drive wholesale prices high. The supplier offers some energy at prices significantly higher than the marginal cost of its units, and on many occasions these offers cause market prices to clear higher than they would have had the energy been offered closer to marginal cost. • Physical withholding. A supplier with most of its generating capacity located inside or near a load pocket decides to retire a number of older units. In one instance, the market monitor was called on to investigate whether the proposed plant retirements were economically justifiable, or whether they would increase the ability of the supplier to control prices in the load pocket. • Price mitigation. In some wholesale power markets, energy offers are mitigated when they fail the conduct and impact test. Market monitors may have to pay special attention to offers from suppliers that have market power due to the fact that their units must be committed to maintain reliability. In some markets, offers from such units are mitigated after the market monitor determines that there is economic withholding.
EBL
7A.3. Market manipulation Examples include: •
Local market power. A generation owner schedules its units day-ahead in such a way that it causes the market operator to forecast local congestion for the next operating day. To resolve the congestion, the ISO pays start-up costs for a unit owned by the same supplier and that is not scheduled to run. In this case, the supplier artificially creates congestion, then receives start-up payments for a unit that it would have run anyway. • Suspension of operations at power plants. Market protocols often require power plant owners to notify the market operator if it intends to cease operations at the plant. Failure to notify the ISO resulted in financial penalties in at least one market. 46
For a description of specific gaming strategies and market manipulation in California and in Texas, see Market Oversight Division (2002a,b).
Competitive Electricity Markets
294 •
•
•
•
•
•
•
Failure to meet ancillary service obligations. One of the most common violations is the failure to meet ancillary service obligations. Generators receive payment to maintain spinning reserves, but then sell the associated energy when balancing energy prices rise. Such violations can cause reliability problems when the operator needs to deploy the reserves to maintain frequency. Insider trading. A market participant has information about the timing of a plant outage and uses that information to enter into financial trades before news of the outage is released to the market. Price chasing. A generator puts un-scheduled energy into the grid when prices rise. The market monitor must determine whether the act is deliberate and has a financial or reliability impact. Schedule manipulation. In one instance, several wind farm operators were receiving compensation for curtailing false generation schedules when the wind was not even blowing and there was no actual output to curtail. Failure to satisfy technical requirements. When a large generating company fails to meet the technical requirements for generator performance, it may result in a reliability event. In one market, two companies were fined for such violations. Failure to justify unit inflexibility. A generating company declares that its resources’ higher operating limits are equal to its lower operating limits without a proper justification, making the unit unavailable to be dispatched by the market operator for reliability purposes. Invalid gate closures. A generator changes its offer after the market closes without proper justification. In one market, the market monitor found that a number of breaches of that nature were committed within a short period of time, and that procedures that could have prevented the breaches from occurring were not in place.
EBL
7A.4. Market design deficiencies •
Reference price creep. In markets that use price or offer mitigation tools based on reference prices such as the Automatic Mitigation Procedure (AMD) of the New York and New England markets, the methodology used for calculating reference prices can over time yield results that diverge significantly from marginal costs. In one case, the market monitor found that resources that do not face competition, such as units located in load pockets, resources needed to solve transmission congestion, or reliability-must-run resources skewed the reference prices, requiring a change in the reference price calculation methodology. • Morning and evening ramps. At the beginning and at the end of the standard 16-hour peak period each day, a large number of generators simultaneously ramping up in the morning and ramping down in the evening can result in frequency deviations requiring large deployments of regulation reserves to maintain power balance. Market monitors’ recommendations to smooth out these ramping problems have not been easily accepted by the market. • Imputed value for out-of-merit actions. When a market operator relies on out-of-market actions to create additional operating reserves for reliability purposes, these actions have a market impact that is not recognized. Market monitors have suggested that the market operator impute a value for these actions that would be reflected in the energy price.
Market Power and Market Monitoring
295
7A.5. Improvements in system operators’ performance •
Improvement in ISO load forecast. An evaluation of the ISO’s load forecast methodology by the market monitor may be useful in improving load forecast accuracy and reducing the balancing energy and regulation deployments caused by flawed load forecasting methodologies. • Improvement in ISO procurement practices. One market monitor conducted an investigation into the practices of the market operator in the procurement of reliabilitymust-run services and concluded that the market operator had abused its position as monopoly buyer in its negotiations with transmission service providers. The market monitor’s recommendations resulted in improved procurement procedures and a clarification of the ISO’s authority relative to its procurement requirements. No financial penalties were applied but the ISO’s procurement practices were improved going forward.
References Adib, P. (2006). Discussion by Parviz Adib Restructuring Today, Market Monitoring: Is the Focus changing? Audio Conference, Washington, D.C., 28 July. Armstrong, M. and Sappington, D. (2006). Regulation, competition, and liberalization. J. of Econ. Lit., 44(2), 325–66. Baumol, W.J. (1982). Contestable markets: An uprising in the theory of industry structure. Am. Econ. Rev., 72, 1–15. Borenstein, B. (2002). The trouble with electricity markets: Understanding California’s restructuring disaster. J. of Econ. Pers., 16, 191–212. Borenstein, B., Bushnell, J., and Wolak, F. (2002). Measuring market inefficiencies in California’s restructured wholesale electricity market. Am. Econ. Rev., 92, 1376–1405. Falk, J. (2004). The social benefit of the limited exercise of local market power. Elec. J., 12–23. Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (1999). Commission acts to assure independence of PJM market monitoring. New release. 20 September Kahn, A., Cramton, P.C., Porter, R.H., and Tabors, R.D. (2001). Uniform pricing or pay-as-bid pricing: A dilemma for California and beyond. The Elec. J., 14, 70–9. Leveque, F. (2006). Antitrust enforcement in the electricity and gas industries: Problems and solutions for the EU. The Elec. J., 19, 27–34. Market Oversight Division (2002a). Enron’s wholesale power trading strategies in California: How did they work? Can they happen in the Electric Reliability Council of Texas? Prepared for the Texas Legislative Oversight Committee, Public Utility Commission of Texas, 18 June, Austin, Texas. Market Oversight Division (2002b). Mitigation measures for gaming opportunities in ERCOT wholesale electricity market. A Presentation to the Texas Legislative Oversight Committee, Public Utility Commission of Texas, 18 June, Austin, Texas. Moss, D. (2005). Electricity and market power: Current issues for restructuring markets (a survey). American Antitrust Institute working paper No. 05-01, February. Potomac Economics (2005). Investigation into the causes for the shortages of energy in the ERCOT balancing energy market and into the wholesale market activities of TXU from October 27 to December 8, 2004, April, Austin, Texas. Potomac Economics (2007). Investigation of the Wholesale Market Activities of TXU from June 1 to September 30, 2005. Independent Market Monitor, March. The report was futher revised in September 2007. Restructuring Today (2006). Market monitoring: Is the focus changing? Audio Conference, Washington, D.C., 28 July. Shepherd, W.G. (1984). Contestability vs. competition. Am. Econ. Rev., 74, 572–87. Stoft, S. (2002). Power System Economics. New York: John Wiley & Sons.
EBL
296
Competitive Electricity Markets
Sweeney, J.L. (2006). California electricity restructuring, the crisis, and its aftermath. In Electricity Market Reform: An International Perspective (F.P. Sioshansi and W. Pfaffenberger, eds). Elsevier. Texas Public Utility Regulatory Act (2005). Texas Public Utility Regulatory Act, as amended in 2005, Title II, Texas Utilities Code. US Department of Justice and US Federal Trade Commission (1997). Horizontal merger guidelines, revised in 1997. US Department of Justice (2006). Commentary on the horizontal merger guidelines, March. Wolak, F. (2004). Lessons from international experience with electricity market monitoring. Center for the Study of Energy Markets, University of California Energy Institute, CSEM WP 134, June. Available at: http://www.ucei.berkeley.edu/PDF/csemwp134.pdf.
EBL
Chapter 8 Demand Participation in Restructured Markets JAY ZARNIKAU Frontier Associates LLC and LBJ School of Public Affairs, The University of Texas at Austin, Texas, USA
Summary1 Demand response is of particular importance in restructured markets that face some unique challenges in maintaining resource adequacy and preventing market power abuse. By responding to prices, by providing an ancillary service, or by offering to curtail usage in response to an interruption request, the participation of consumers or loads can contribute to the efficient operation of an electricity market. Establishing the policies and market structure that will enable demand participation has proven difficult to date. Nonetheless, advances in technology and reductions in infrastructure costs hold the potential to raise demand participation to new heights.
EBL
8.1. Why Demand-Side Participation is Important in Restructured Markets In most markets, there is little need to make demand more elastic. In competitive markets for most goods and services, retail prices adjust to reflect the relative abundance or scarcity of the good or service and changes in the cost of providing it to the market, and consumers adjust their purchasing behavior accordingly. But inelastic demand has been and remains a feature of electricity markets. In the 1980s and 1990s, the establishment of real-time pricing programs sought to address this problem by providing consumers with prices designed to mimic competitive prices that would reflect short-run marginal costs (Barbose et al., 2004). More recently, critical peak pricing programs became a popular means of eliciting a response from consumers by providing strong price signals in a limited number of high-cost or high-demand periods. Yet, aside from these exceptions, regulated retail prices seldom reflected the frequent changes in the value of electricity generated, transmitted, and distributed by the utility 1 Fereidoon P. Sioshansi, Parviz Adib, Alison Silverstein, Charles Goldman, and Nat Treadway provided valuable comments on earlier drafts of this chapter.
297
298
Competitive Electricity Markets
system and sold to an ultimate retail customer. Tariffs reflected the long-term average cost of providing electricity to a class of consumers. For smaller electricity consumers, the costs of metering energy usage at less than monthly intervals thwarted pricing schemes to reflect changes in the value of electricity in retail prices in hourly or 15 minute intervals on a wide-scale basis (see, e.g., Zarnikau et al., 1990; O’Sheasy, 2003). Load management programs and other types of “peak clipping” or “load shifting” demand-side management sought to elicit responses from consumers in situations where pricing programs might not prove effective. This includes situations where the costs of metering and settling smaller loads based on real-time prices might outweigh the benefits. While demand-side participation is important in regulated markets, the response of consumers or “loads” to price signals is even more crucial to the efficient operation of restructured power markets. As noted by US Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC): “Demand response is essential in competitive markets, to assure the efficient interaction of supply and demand, as a check on supplier and locational market power, and as an opportunity for choice by wholesale and end-use customers” (Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, 2002). The National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) has called for regulatory commissions to accommodate demand-side resources and “remove any unnecessary barriers to customer responses to such wholesale market price signals” (NARUC, 2000). Through the Energy Policy Act of 2005, the US Congress affirmed the importance of expanding demand response opportunities as a matter of national policy, stating: It is the policy of the United States that time-based pricing and other forms of demand response, whereby electricity customers are provided with electricity price signals and the ability to benefit by responding to them, shall be encouraged, the deployment of such technology and devices that enable electricity customers to participate in such pricing and demand response systems shall be facilitated, and unnecessary barriers to demand response participation in energy, capacity and ancillary service markets shall be eliminated (Energy Policy Act of 2005, Section 1252(f); see also US Department of Energy, 2006).
EBL
One factor cited as responsible for the collapse of California’s competitive electricity market in 2000–01 was an absence or inadequacy of demand response (Faruqui et al., 2001; see also Sweeney, 2006). Demand response encompasses changes in consumer electricity consumption decisions in response to changes in the price of electricity as well as programs that require consumers to curtail their usage at the request of an independent system operator (ISO), utility, or other authority in return for a price discount or payment. The US Demand Response Coordinating Council offers a formal definition: Providing electricity customers in both retail and wholesale markets with a choice whereby they can respond to dynamic or time-based prices or other types of incentives by reducing and/or shifting usage, particularly during peak periods, such that these demand modifications can address issues such as pricing, reliability, emergency response, and infrastructure planning, operation, and deferral.2
2
http://www.demandresponseinfo.org/id46.htm
Demand Participation in Restructured Markets
299
The US Department of Energy (DOE) similarly defines demand response as: Changes in electric usage by end-use customers from their normal consumption patterns in response to changes in the price of electricity over time, or to incentive payments designed to induce lower electricity use at time of high wholesale market prices or when system reliability is jeopardized (US DOE, 2006). Many of these definitions of demand response encompass the load management and innovative pricing concepts that attained popularity under regulation. In markets with relaxed regulatory oversight, demand response can restrain prices to economically efficient levels (Rosenzweig et al., 2003). A small amount of demand response can yield significant reductions in short-term wholesale electricity prices (Caves et al., 2000; Faruqui and George, 2002). For example, recent analyses by the staff of the New England ISO suggests that a 500 MW increase in demand response participation would reduce wholesale costs by $32 million annually (ISO-New England, 2006). A 3% load reduction in the top 100 hours in five mid-Atlantic zones could yield total annual benefits of from $138 to $281 million (Brattle Group, 2007). Demand response becomes all the more important when it is recognized that most restructured electricity markets are far from “perfectly competitive.” Thus a reduction in demand in response to a price spike is crucial to constrain the ability of suppliers to raise prices to inefficient levels (i.e., price levels inconsistent with consumer willingness or ability to pay), due to the exercise of market power or other anticompetitive behaviors. Insufficient demand response is sometimes used as a justification for wholesale price caps (which in turn may dampen or jeopardize price response. In markets where an “energy-only” approach is adopted to maintain resource adequacy, demand response may play an important role in maintaining a balance between supply and demand. This is particularly important in light of the cyclical nature of power plant construction activity. During the periods when a market is left with inadequate reserve margins, demand response can provide an important backstop (Parviz et al., this volume-b). It is sometimes argued that demand-side resources can be used to defer or displace transmission investments in either a regulated or a competitive market. There have been few situations in which this potential benefit has been successfully exploited (FERC, 2006). However, some encouraging programs have been launched in California, New York, and the Pacific Northwest region of the United States.3 Carefully crafted demand response programs can be used to foster reliability in realtime system operations. High wholesale prices or participation in programs through which loads curtail in response to instructions from a system operator in return for some financial compensation can assist the system operator in balancing supply and demand in real-time and in managing reliability during emergency conditions. Finally, when viewed as a call option, demand response may provide a variety of risk management benefits to an ISO or load-serving entity in a competitive market.4 As electricity markets are redesigned to facilitate wholesale and/or retail competition, stakeholders and policymakers face the challenge of ensuring that consumers are presented with accurate price or curtailment signals and the appropriate incentives to react to those signals. Yet, responses by retail energy consumers to price changes and the introduction of demand-side resources (e.g., interruptible or curtailable loads) into competitive markets
EBL
3 4
See FERC (2006), pp. 115–7. See FERC (2006), pp. 11–2.
300
Competitive Electricity Markets
primarily designed for power plants pose certain technical and economic challenges. Key policy questions include the following: •
•
• •
• • • • •
Must demand-side participation be fostered with special programs, or can a means of promoting demand-side participation through a competitive market structure be found? To what extent can demand response be relied upon to match supply and demand, especially in markets that plan to rely upon “energy-only” resource adequacy mechanisms? How will changes in consumption in reaction to wholesale prices affect the need for generation and ancillary services? How should a consumer’s need for sufficient time to respond to prices be balanced against an ISO’s desire to reduce forecast errors (to increase the accuracy of prices) in near-real-time operations? Can demand-side resources provide the same types of ancillary services as supplyside resources (generators)? What metering policies are needed in order to facilitate beneficial demand response? Will new technologies come to the rescue? Can demand-side resources play a role in markets for transmission rights? Is a “quasi-LMP” market structure, in which power plants face nodal prices and loads face a different set of zonal prices, sustainable?
While these policy questions are difficult, the stakes are high, and the opportunities to improve electricity markets through effective demand response efforts are enormous. Indeed, efficient demand response can contribute to resolving many of the problems associated with market power, resource adequacy, and reliability discussed in other chapters of this volume. This chapter reviews the challenges associated with facilitating demand-side participation in competitive markets for power, provides a summary of various demand-side initiatives in restructured markets in North America, and contributes a case study describing some of the problems faced in promoting demand-side participation in the Electric Reliability Council of Texas (ERCOT) market, often cited as the most successful of North America’s restructured retail markets.
EBL
8.2. Barriers and Opportunities In any electrical network – regulated or restructured – the costs associated with energy generation, transmission, distribution, and meeting various operational constraints change continuously over time. The costs associated with serving customers in different areas of a network may vary greatly. Yet, electricity consumers have traditionally faced flat systemwide rates, which seldom varied over time or space within a utility service area. Economic efficiency requires that prices bear some relationship to marginal costs, a condition that was seldom satisfied under traditional ratemaking. Successful demand response requires a correct combination of customer characteristics, economic incentives, metering and communications technology, market design, and policy. Fundamentally, consumers need the motivation and means to respond to price signals or indicators of reliability problems (Hirst, 2002, p. 2). Certain loads (e.g., municipal wastewater pumping, pipelines, and steel mills) tend to possess considerable flexibility in their operations and are natural candidates for nearly any demand response initiative. Production at such facilities may be delayed during a high-price period at relatively little
Demand Participation in Restructured Markets
301
economic loss to the facility. Similarly, water heating can be deferred for a few hours with no noticeable loss of comfort to a residential consumer. Technologies capable of enabling demand response may include backup generation, control systems, load monitoring equipment, and energy storage devices. High penalties for failure to comply with curtailment requests and uncertain payments tend to discourage participation in voluntary curtailment programs (Neenan et al., 2002). Response may be affected by incentive levels, notice periods, the importance of energy costs to the consumer, the communications infrastructure, the customer’s sophistication in energy consumption decisions, and a multitude of other customer-specific factors. In a regulated market, a vertically integrated utility may realize a variety of benefits from the ability to control or reduce loads. The cost of operating expensive peaking capacity may be reduced. Generating capacity additions may be deferred. In some rare situations, transmission or distribution capacity additions could be deferred. Overall system reliability may benefit. In regulated markets, demand-side participation can be fostered by utilities and regulatory authorities through the establishment of interruptible tariffs and demandside management (e.g., load management) programs.5 However, in an unbundled market, there are some unique economic challenges associated with demand-side participation. Different entities may receive value from different segmented benefits. For example, a retailer could benefit from lower purchased power costs or the ability to better manage power procurement risks, a transmission and distribution services provider might be the beneficiary of deferred transmission or distribution improvements, and the ISO might benefit from an additional tool to maintain reliability. But, no single entity (i.e., the retailer, wires provider, or ISO) is likely to derive sufficient benefits within its own sphere of operations to justify the establishment of a program. The “value chain” has been severed and economies of scale and scope may be lost.6 In competitive markets, the design of the market rules must be crafted to accommodate and facilitate demand-side participation. Alternatively, special demand response programs may be grafted onto the competitive market. For a retailer, the possibility of stranded costs, which may result if the customer later switches suppliers, may discourage investments in metering, control technologies, and technical assistance necessary to implement a successful program. This is particularly true for residential direct load control, where program equipment infrastructure costs can be quite significant relative to the economic value of the demand reduction that can be realized. While third-party demand reduction aggregators can play a valuable role in facilitating demand response in competitive markets, they face a number of barriers. Access to the meter may be an obstacle. Who owns the meter? Is it just a “cash register” for the retailer, or can it also be used by a third party who is developing a demand response program? In some markets, retailers are concerned about energy services companies (ESCOs) and demand aggregators “interfering” with their relationship with their customer, particularly if demand response may have an impact on the retailer’s procurement of generation. Settlement procedures may be complicated when one entity is selling generation to a retail consumer while another entity curtails or shifts the temporal pattern of the electricity that is consumed. Reliable real-time communications between system operators and retail customers pose another obstacle. It has been noted that currently “the protocols for sending the signal that
EBL
5 It is sometimes argued that load management programs are not true demand response if their deployment is not sufficiently driven by prices or market conditions. 6 An excellent discussion of this is provided in Spine (2002).
302
Competitive Electricity Markets
capacity is tight and voluntary load shedding is needed is time-consuming, error-prone, and mostly manual” (Neumann et al., 2006). Further, the feedback from the customer back to the system operator may be insufficient to assure the operator that adequate demand response has been achieved in real-time. Customer education may also be needed. Some energy consumers may lack the knowledge and sophistication necessary to take advantage of demand response opportunities. They may not understand the load associated with various equipment, the flexibility that they may have with respect to equipment operation, and electricity market economics and opportunities. Another challenge is political. Generation owners recognize the ability of demand response to reduce the value of generation assets, given the potential of demand response to constrain prices and provide a substitute for certain ancillary services and planning reserves. Generators often wield considerable power within the stakeholder processes used to design and operate markets. Consumers who could provide demand-side resources have primary interests that lie outside of power markets. Consequently, demand response initiatives may be difficult to establish when a stakeholder process is used to design a competitive market. “Consumer segments” may be less united and powerful than other market participant interests, and have relatively less understanding of the energy business than power producers. Demand response poses some interesting challenges for market monitors. In some situations, it may be difficult to distinguish “gaming” from demand response. For example, if a scheduling entity or market participant informs the ISO that its supply will exactly equal demand, but, after seeing a high price, curtails load under its control in order to create a net injection into the market and earn a profit from the unscheduled net sale to the market, is the market participant guilty of any improper behavior? The answer should be no. Yet there may be some suspicion that the (net) supply available from the entity was not as limited as the market was led to believe. It is important that market monitors have the information and tools necessary to distinguish between these situations. For ISOs, demand response can introduce some complications into the operation of power systems. In the absence of a priority pricing scheme (Oren et al., 1986), where the prices at which load will curtail are announced to the market, the ISO may have difficulty understanding the slope or elasticity of the market’s aggregate demand curve in a realtime energy market. ISOs sometimes complain that demand response affects the accuracy of their near-term forecasts of demand, thus complicating the task of balancing demand and supply in real-time. If more generation is scheduled than needed, additional costs may be imposed upon the market. The usual problems associated with setting customer baselines and estimating the amount of demand reduction achieved through a demand response action can become more contentious in a competitive market setting, where multiple market participants (rather than a single vertically integrated utility) have a stake in the method of calculating demand response and in designing the formulas used for compensation. In nodal or locational marginal cost (LMP) markets7 further difficulties may arise when the power consumed by an energy consumer is settled on a zonal basis while generation resources are settled on a nodal basis. Customers served by the load-serving entity will face average or muted zonal prices that will fail to reflect the true value of electricity consumed at a node or the value of a reduction in demand at a node. While the theory behind
EBL
7
See Chapter 4 by Singh (this volume).
Demand Participation in Restructured Markets
303
LMP markets clearly requires loads to be settled at nodal prices (Baughman et al., 1997; Schweppe et al., 1988), equity and technical concerns have resulted in compromises. It is difficult to charge some consumers more than other consumers for transmission congestion charges when they historically paid the same rates toward transmission investments to the same vertically integrated utility prior to restructuring. Externalities may be a problem – the actions of your neighbor on the transmission network could affect your transmission costs. There may also be practical difficulties in calculating and communicating nodespecific prices to consumers and in the settlement process. Finally, it should be noted that wholesale or retail rate caps may dampen price signals and response. Ironically, the concern over insufficient price elasticity that prompts policymakers to impose price caps reduces the incentives and interest by consumers in responding to prices. In addition, there are many regulatory barriers to be overcome by demand response programs. In a recent report, FERC (2006) identified nine “regulatory barriers” to demand response, as presented in Table 8.1. Many of these appear to be applicable to demand response initiatives outside of the United States as well.
Table 8.1. Regulatory barriers for demand response identified by FERC (2006) 1. Disconnect between retail pricing and wholesale markets. Retail rates for most customers are fixed, while wholesale prices fluctuate. 2. Utility disincentives associated with offering demand response. Reductions in customer demand reduce utility revenue. Without regulatory incentives such as rate decoupling or similar incentives, electric utilities lack an incentive to use or support demand response.
EBL
3. Cost recovery and incentives for enabling technologies. Utilities are reluctant to undertake investments in enabling technologies such as advanced metering unless the business case and regulatory support for deployment is sufficiently positive to justify the outlay. These investments may require an increase in rates. It is uncertain whether and how would regulators allow these costs to be recovered. 4. The need for additional research on cost-effectiveness and measurement of reductions. There are deficiencies in the measurement of demand response and assessment of its cost-effectiveness. Cost-effectiveness tests that have been used by regulators must be improved to reflect changes in the industry, especially in organized markets. 5. The existence of specific state-level barriers to greater demand response. Policies of retail rate regulators and state statutes in several states have created barriers to implementing greater levels of demand response, especially by exposing customers to time-based rates. 6. Specific retail and wholesale rules that limit demand response. Certain wholesale and retail market designs have rules and procedures that are not conducive to demand participation. 7. Barriers to providing demand response services by third parties. Shifting regulatory rules that allow third parties to provide demand response and potential sunset of various demand response programs are a disincentive to demand response providers. Because third parties often bear the risks of programs dependent on enabling technologies, they need long-term regulatory assurance or longterm contracts to raise the capital needed to invest in enabling technologies. 8. Insufficient market transparency and access to data. Lack of third-party access to data has been identified as a barrier to demand response. A related but more fundamental barrier related to data is timely access to meter data. 9. Better coordination of federal-state jurisdiction affecting demand response. While states have primary jurisdiction over retail demand response, demand response plays a role in wholesale markets under Commission (FERC) jurisdiction. Greater clarity and coordination between wholesale and state programs is needed.
Competitive Electricity Markets
304
While the challenges associated with promoting demand-side participation in a competitive market may be formidable, advances in technology are making some aspects of it more practical. Metering technology has advanced and the cost of metering loads in nearreal-time has declined. An increasing number of utilities are now adopting or considering advanced system-wide smart meter technologies. With an advanced metering infrastructure, consumption of smaller customers can be more easily matched with prices, and the amount of demand reduction obtained from small consumers can be measured directly from interval metering data rather than through statistical sampling techniques. The Internet, under-utilized paging networks, and other communications media also open up new avenues for communicating electricity prices to consumers. Finally, systems designed to control or optimize the operation of equipment at industrial facilities, commercial buildings, and homes, and other enabling technologies have improved, expanding the horizon for more effective demand responses in the near future.
8.3. Demand-Side Participation: From Traditional Utility Efforts to Restructured Markets In a traditional regulated utility setting, a very wide variety of programs and tariffs were established to improve customer exposure to price signals and provide demand reduction at the request of the utility. Such efforts include8 : •
•
•
•
•
•
Direct load control demand-side management programs, involving the control of customer appliances or equipment (e.g., air-conditioners, water heaters, or pool pumps) from a central location. The program participant receives an incentive payment or bill discount. Curtailment programs, providing a financial incentive to participants who agree to control their electricity-intensive equipment so as to reduce their electrical usage at the request of the utility. Interruptible tariffs, providing electricity at a discounted price to large industrial or commercial consumers who agree to interrupt their purchases at the request of the utility during a supply shortage or instantaneously in response to a system emergency. Time-of-use pricing, charging different retail prices for electricity purchased during different blocks of time. Typically, different periods within a day receive different prices. The pricing periods and price differentials are predetermined to correspond with average historical price patterns. Critical peak pricing, permitting retail prices to reflect their true market values or provide a strong price signal a few times a year. Otherwise, prices will often follow a time-of-use pattern. Real-time pricing, changing prices on an hourly basis to reflect the cost of providing electricity to the consumer each hour. Customer baselines and other features are often applied to ensure the utility’s revenue neutrality with respect to the consumer’s historical usage pattern (E Source, 1995).
EBL
These options are summarized in Table 8.2. 8
See also US DOE (2006).
Demand Participation in Restructured Markets
305
These various products and services may be differentiated by: •
Whether the customer is exposed to a price signal (economic or market-based demand response) or curtailment requests by a utility (reliability- or contingencybased programs). • Advance notice periods, which may range from instantaneous response (interruptible service involving under-frequency relays) to day-ahead response (e.g., participation in a day-ahead energy market). • Type of incentive provided to the participant, which may be a direct payment, a discounted electricity price, or time-based rates. DOE (2006) and FERC (2006) draw a distinction between “incentive-based demand response” and “time-based rates.” • The degree of commitment or cessation of control provided by the participant, which may range from third-party control over the operation of customer-owned equipment (e.g., direct load control) to voluntary actions (in the case of most price response programs). There are many similarities among the challenges and opportunities associated with promoting demand-side participation in markets with different structures. Yet, there are some differences as well. Regulated tariffs are available in regulated markets. Regulators often deviate from market economics to design pricing structures that meet long-term societal goals. There tends to be greater certainty associated with the costs and benefits of participating in regulated programs or accepting service under regulated tariffs. In restructured markets, the forces of supply and demand, retailer pricing strategies, and stakeholder processes tend to shape opportunities for demand-side participation. In a restructured competitive market, a load-serving entity might offer the same types of programs and pricing strategies as might be offered in a traditional regulated setting in order to shape its generation requirements. However, a variety of additional services might be offered, such as:
EBL
•
Direct access to a competitive wholesale market, providing the consumer with direct exposure to real-time or day-ahead market prices. • Demand bidding, allowing the consumer to submit a formal offer to curtail its electricity usage to a day-ahead or real-time market and receive a market price for the demand reduction. • Direct participation in ancillary services markets, providing an interruptible energy consumer with an opportunity to provide an operating reserve. • Participation in Installed Capacity or ICAP markets, paying an interruptible load an incentive in return for providing a call option that an ISO can exercise in order to curtail the load in the event of a system emergency. Whether these services or opportunities are offered by a traditional vertically integrated utility, a retailer, or the ISO or regional transmission organization (RTO) responsible for ensuring reliability may depend upon the market structure. Of particular note are the reliability-focused programs operated by ISOs in the northeastern United States and in California.9 The New England ISO (ISO-NE), the New York ISO (NYISO), and the PJM ISO (serving a large region including Pennsylvania, New Jersey, Maryland, and the upper Midwest) have all established successful programs focused on reliability. Reliabilityfocused programs tend to be reflected in reserve margin calculations and system planning 9
For a survey of programs operated by utilities, see FERC (2006).
306
Competitive Electricity Markets
Table 8.2. Demand response options Price-based options
Incentive-based programs
Time-of-use (TOU): a rate with different unit prices for usage during different blocks of time, usually defined for a 24-hour day. TOU rates reflect the average cost of generating and delivering power during those time periods.
Direct load control: a program by which the program operator remotely shuts down or cycles a customer’s electrical equipment (e.g., air-conditioner, water heater) on short notice. Direct load control programs are primarily offered to residential or small commercial customers. Interruptible/curtailable (I/C) service: curtailment options integrated into retail tariffs that provide a rate discount or bill credit for agreeing to reduce load during system contingencies. Penalties may be assessed for failure to curtail. Interruptible programs have traditionally been offered only to the largest industrial customers.
Real-time pricing (RTP): a rate in which the price for electricity typically fluctuates hourly, reflecting changes in the wholesale price of electricity. Customers are typically notified of RTP prices on a day-ahead or hour-ahead basis.
Demand bidding/buyback programs: customers offer bids to curtail based on wholesale electricity market prices or an equivalent. Mainly offered to large customers [e.g., one megawatt (MW) and over].
Critical peak pricing (CPP): CPP rates are a hybrid of the TOU and RTP design. The basic rate structure is TOU. However, provision is made for replacing the normal peak price with a much higher CPP event price under specified trigger conditions (e.g., when system reliability is compromised or supply prices are very high).
Emergency demand response programs: programs that provide incentive payments to customers for load reductions during periods when reserve shortfalls arise.
Capacity market programs: customers offer load curtailments as system capacity to replace conventional generation or delivery resources. Customers typically receive dayof notice of events. Incentives usually consist of upfront reservation payments, and face penalties for failure to curtail when called upon to do so.
EBL
Ancillary services market programs: customers bid load curtailments in ISO/RTO markets as operating reserves. If their bids are accepted, they are paid the market price for committing to be on standby. If their load curtailments are needed, they are called by the ISO/RTO, and may be paid the spot market energy price.
Source: US Department of Energy (2006). Benefits of demand response in electricity markets and recommendations for achieving them: A report to the U.S. Congress pursuant to Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005. February.
studies, while economic programs tend to be viewed as less reliable as a source of planning resources. Some prominent reliability-focused ISO-level demand response opportunities in US markets are summarized in Table 8.3. ISO-NE offers reliability programs with notice periods of 30 minutes or 2 hours, in addition to a real-time program. In 2006, 641 MW of load was available for interruption
Demand Participation in Restructured Markets
307
Table 8.3. Reliability-focused programs offered by selected ISOs in the United States ISO
NY ISO
Program
Number of participants
Potential demand Reduction (MW)
Emergency demand response program ICAP/special case resources
810
369
1460
861
ISO-NE
Emergency load response
1490
801
PJM
Emergency load response program
4427
1081
Cal-ISO
Various programs operated by utilities
NA
1800
Sources: Demand Response Department of ISO New England (2006).ISO New England/NEPOOL demand response working group meeting. Presentation, 6 December; NYISO (2006). November 2006 demand response registration. Presentation by Price Responsive Load Working Group, 8 December; PJM (2006). Load response activity report, January through September 2006. 30 September; and e-mail correspondence from Greg Fishman of the California ISO to Rebecca Farrell, 1 December 2006.
through the 30 minute program (in an ISO with a peak demand of 28 127 MW).10 An additional 117 MW is enrolled in the real-time program and 26 MW was available through the 2 hour program. Participants in the 30 minute program receive the higher of the realtime zonal price or $500/MWh for a minimum of 2 hours, while participants in the 2 hour notice program earn the higher of the real-time zonal price or $350/MWh for a minimum of 2 hours. Real-time resources receive the higher of the real-time zonal price or $100 per MWh. The majority of the 30 minute notice demand response is in Connecticut, where a supplemental program provides up to an additional $150/kW-year in this transmissionconstrained area. Participants in these ISO-NE programs qualify to participate in this ISO’s market for installed capacity (ICAP) planning reserves. The ICAP market is an important revenue stream for program participants. The value of ICAPs in the New England market was $3.05/kW-month in December 2006.11 In the NYISO, two major reliability-focused programs are available: the Emergency Demand Response Program (EDRP) and the ICAP/Special Case Resources (SCR) program. In the EDRP program, 161 MW was available in New York City and Long Island in 2006, while 208 MW was available in the rest of the state.12 Most of the EDRP resource is
EBL
10
Demand Response Department of ISO New England (2006). ISO New England/NEPOOL demand response working group meeting.Presentation, 6 December. 11 Figures in this paragraph are from: ISO-NE, FERC Electric Tariff No. 3, Section III, Market Rule 1 – Standard Market Design, p. 263, at: http://www.iso-ne.org/regulatory/tariff/sect_3/ section_iii_mr1_standard_mkt_design.pdf. 12 Figures in this paragraph are from: NYISO (2006).November 2006 demand response registration. Presentation by Price Responsive Load Working Group, 8 December, available at: http:// www.nyiso.com/public/webdocs/committees/bic_prlwg/meeting_materials/2006-12-08/ agenda_2_registration_update_nov.pdf.
308
Competitive Electricity Markets
provided through transmission owners. Nearly half of the SCR/ICAP resource is provided through demand-side aggregators. The New York market had a total peak demand of 33 939 MW in 2006. Participants in these two programs responded to five events in 2006 (Isser, 2006). SCR participants are provided at least 2 hours’ notice and receive the zonal real-time price for the duration of an event or 4 hours, whichever is greater. NYISO can activate the EDRP in response to a shortage of operating reserves or a major emergency, and will strive to provide at least 2 hours’ notice. When a curtailment is requested, EDRP participants receive compensation for a 4 hour period. For 2 hours or the duration of an event (whichever is greater) the participant receives the higher of the zonal real-time price or $500 per MWh. The zonal price is paid for the remainder of the 4 hour period. With a peak load of 144 796 MW, the PJM market is the largest of these three markets, and its reliability-focused programs are also much larger. PJM operates Emergency Load Response (ELR) and Active Load Management (ALM) programs.13 Within the ELR, participants can receive both an energy payment and an ALM credit, or simply receive an energy payment (in the “energy-only option,” which waives non-performance penalties, or “ALM deficiency charges”). Participants specify their notice time requirements. The minimum duration of a curtailment is 2 hours. Consumers without interval data recorders (IDRs) are permitted to participate in this program on a pilot basis. Each of these markets in the Northeast offers programs focused on economics as well. Each offers day-ahead and real-time markets, which permit demand-side participation.14 Offers generally require specification of the quantity, price, start-up cost payment, and minimum run-time information. In most of these markets, there is a $1000/MWh bid price cap.15 Offers to the real-time market must be submitted 1 hour in advance in NYISO and PJM, and 20 minutes in advance in ISO-NE. ICAP resources must submit bids into energy markets. Similar opportunities exist for loads to participate in energy markets in the Midwest ISO (MISO) market. In California, comprehensive sets of reliability-focused programs have been implemented at the utility level, but with extensive coordination with the ISO. About 1800 MW of demand reduction can be achieved through utility-administered reliability-focused programs.16 Commercial and industrial customers can voluntarily sign up for their utilities’ interruptible rate program and receive a reduced rate in exchange for reducing their energy demand to a firm service level under emergency conditions. In most cases, there are limits on how many times or how many hours they can be called on within a specified period of time. Currently, there are about 900 MW signed up statewide with the utilities. The second type of program is aimed at residential and smaller commercial customers that will allow their air-conditioner to be turned off for a specified number of minutes per hour under emergency conditions. They are typically compensated based on a flat payment. There are about 900 MW in those programs as well, aggregated statewide. The sheer coverage of some of the demand response initiatives launched by investorowned utilities in California is quite impressive. Table 8.4 provides a summary of the programs offered by Southern California Edison Company.
EBL
13
Figures in this paragraph are from: PJM (2006).Load response activity report, January through September 2006. 30 September, at: http://www.pjm.com/committees/working-groups/dsrwg/ downloads/20061026-item-06-dsr-activity-thru-sept-2006.pdf. Further information is posted at: http://www.pjm.com/committees/working-groups/dsrwg/dsrwg.html. 14 Demand-side participation in the ISO-NE market may not yet be fully implemented. 15 Some of this information is taken from Isser (2006). 16 E-mail correspondence from Greg Fishman of the California ISO to Rebecca Farrell, 1 December 2006.
Table 8.4. Demand response initiatives of Southern California Edison
’83
•
•
’01
•
’01 ’79 ’01
• •
’01
Ind. (>500 kW)
Comm. (>200 kW)
Comm. ( “technical potential” > “realistic potential” > “realizable potential.” Note that the technical potential is substantially larger than the realizable potential that takes into account current non-technological factors. 2 This cost barrier is partly due to the lack of a level playing field as long as externalities from fossil fuels and nuclear are far from being included in the consumer price. 3 See also Chapter 13 on distributed generation where the implications of absorbing large amounts of RES in the network are discussed.
Promoting Electricity from Renewable Energy Sources
421
example, issued a directive in 2001 with the target to increase the share of electricity from RES from 12% in 1997 to 21% by 2010 (EC, 2001). A decision made in 2007 sets an even more ambitious 20% RES target for total energy by 2020. Currently, a number of schemes are being implemented in different countries to increase the share of renewables in the energy mix. While the specifics vary, most schemes are attempting to • • • •
enhance social acceptance and increase public awareness of renewable energy; improve reliability, technical performance, and standardization; remove obstacles to grid connection; reduce administration and transaction costs while minimizing the financial subsidies; and • ensure sustainable growth of the renewable energy industry. The major promotional strategies include investment subsidies, feed-in tariffs (FIT), tax incentives, portfolio standards, quota-based tradable green certificates (TGC), and tendering systems. While each scheme has certain advantages, there is no consensus on what may deliver the best results at the lowest cost. This is a crucial issue, especially if we are going to rely on renewables for a growing percentage of energy mix in the future. This chapter examines the experience gained from various regulatory and support strategies for the promotion of electricity generation from renewables. A secondary objective is to provide evidence to improve future policies. The chapter’s primary focus is on countries with considerable experience including the EU, the United States, and Japan. The chapter is organized as follows. Section 12.2 covers historical development and the future potential of renewables. Section 12.3 classifies different types of promotional strategies and summarizes the experience up to 2005. Section 12.4 evaluates the most important promotional programs in different countries, and Section 12.5 discusses the relative merits of different strategies. The chapter’s main conclusions appear at the end.
EBL
12.2. Historical Overview For millennia until the advent of industrial evolution, humans relied on renewable energy for most of their needs, albeit at a mere fraction of what we typically use today. Over the past two centuries, humankind has increasingly relied on fossil fuels, which are blamed for global climate change. Figure 12.1 shows the recent pattern of electricity generation from renewables for EU-25, United States, and Japan for the period 1990–2004, where EU has managed a gradually increasing trend compared to the United States and Japan. The side bar in Fig. 12.1 shows the mix of renewables with the dominance of hydro power electric generation everywhere.4 An entirely new picture emerges if hydro power is excluded (Fig. 12.2). While in the early 1990s the United States had the highest non-hydro renewable generation, the EU has assumed this role since 2002, mostly due to a rapid growth of wind energy. The development in Japan can be characterized by modest growth in the waste-to-energy and geothermal power in 1990s and in PV and wind power in 2000s, with biomass resources such as black-liquor utilized in the pulp and paper industry playing an important role over the decades. 4
Annual fluctuations in meteorological conditions explain the year-to-year fluctuations.
Competitive Electricity Markets 500
100%
450
90%
Uunited States
80%
400
70%
350 EU-25
300
60%
250
50%
200
40% 30%
150
Japan
95 19 96 19 97 19 98 19 99 20 00 20 01 20 02 20 03 20 04
EU-25 United States
19
19
19
19
19
19
93
0%
94
10%
0 92
20%
50 91
100
90
Electricity generation (TWh/year)
422
Hydro power Biomass Geothermal
Japan Wind Waste Solar
Fig. 12.1. Recent pattern of electricity generation from RES in EU-25, the United States, and Japan (left) and breakdown of electricity generation from RES in 2004 (right). Sources: EUROSTAT (2007), IEA (2006b), METI (2007), Black and Veatch (2006, personal communication with Ryan Wiser).
100%
Electricity generation [TWh/year]
140
EBL
120 100
United States
80 60
80%
60%
40%
40 EU-25 Japan
20 0
97 19 98 19 99 20 00 20 01 20 02 20 03 20 04
EU-25
19
96
95
19
19
94
19
93
92
19
19
19
91
0%
90 19
20%
Wind Waste Solar
United Japan States Biomass Geothermal
Fig. 12.2. Historical pattern of electricity from non-hydro RES in EU-25, the United States, and Japan (left) and breakdown of the mix for 2004 (right). Sources: EUROSTAT (2007), IEA (2006b), METI (2007), Black and Veatch (2006, personal communication with Ryan Wiser).
Despite the recent gains in Europe, the recent pattern of growth of electricity generation from renewables is far from a success story. Between 1997 and 2004, for example, no country or region has been able to significantly increase the share of renewables as a percentage of total electricity consumed as illustrated in Fig. 12.3. In the EU, the gain is a modest 2% from 12 to 14%, Japan shows a slight decrease while there has been a significant drop in the United States, from about 14 to 9%.
RES-E share in gross electricity consumption
Promoting Electricity from Renewable Energy Sources
80%
80%
70%
70%
60%
60%
50%
50%
40%
40%
30%
30%
20%
20%
10%
10%
0%
423
0% AT BE DK FI FR DE GR IE IT LU NL PT ES SE UK CY CZ EE HU LA LT MT PL SK SI
1997
2004
EU target by 2010
EU-25
United Japan States
Fig. 12.3. Share of RES including large hydro power in gross electricity consumption in EU-25, the United States, and Japan. For the EU-25, 2010 targets are shown. Sources: Ragwitz et al. (2007), IEA (2006b).
Within the EU, only a few countries such as Denmark, Finland, Hungary, and Germany have managed to increase their renewable shares considerably during the period and may be considered to be on target to meet the indicative targets as set in Directive 2001/77/EC.5 For the EU as a whole, the 2006 actual is far from the target set for 2010. For the United States, no specific target currently exists on the national level.6 Elsewhere, renewables continue to grow in absolute terms, but the story is pretty much the same: as a percentage of total electricity generation, renewables have a hard time keeping their current penetration levels.
EBL
12.3. Promotional Strategies With the exception of hydro power, some biomass and wind energy plants at favorable locations, most renewable energy technologies currently are at a cost disadvantage relative to conventional technologies. As already mentioned, part of this cost disadvantage is due to the fact that most conventional technologies have traditionally received – and continue to do so – significant direct and indirect subsidies including those offered to nuclear energy and oil and gas exploration. Moreover, until recently, the full effect of the externalities, notably emissions of greenhouse gases, has not been reflected in prices. Renewable energy advocates argue that RES deserve similar subsidies to overcome their current cost disadvantage, pointing out that over time, these subsidies can be reduced or eliminated. Such arguments aside, the pace of development of electricity generation 5 In addition to these sector-specific targets, a 20% target on primary energy for all sectors except transport by 2020 was introduced in early 2007. Yet, no specific targets for electricity have been specified, which is a weakness of the new strategy. 6 However, in the United States, a number of states have set targets and currently there is a proposal for a 15% mandate by 2020.
Competitive Electricity Markets
424
from RES is closely linked to the level of financial incentives and/or regulatory mandates, both of which are dependent on political decisions. And these are the main variables that differentiate the development pace and penetration of RES in different countries. This section examines a number of schemes for supporting renewables and compares the results. Table 12.1 provides a classification of promotion strategies (Haas et al., 2004; Menanteau et al., 2003). Fundamentally, there are four basic ways to subsidize or promote RES: 1. Regulatory price-driven strategies. Under these schemes no quantity goals or targets are established. Instead, the focus is on providing generators with financial support in terms of a subsidy per kW of capacity installed or a payment per kWh of energy produced. There are a number of variations under this scheme such as •
investment-focused strategies where financial support is provided through investment subsidies, soft loans, or tax credits, usually per unit of generating capacity installed and • generation-based strategies where financial support is offered as a fixed payment or as a premium per unit of energy generated. Under a fixed payment scheme such as FITs, generators receive a fixed amount per kWh generated regardless of the costs of generation or price while under a premium scheme a fixed amount is added to the electricity price. In practice, this makes a difference for the renewable plant owner. In the latter case, the total price received per kWh (electricity price plus the premium) is less predictable than under the FIT because it depends on a volatile electricity price. In principle, a mechanism based on a fixed premium – one that reflects an environmental bonus for RES and penalizes conventional energy for their externality costs – could establish a level playing field allowing fair competition between RES and conventional power sources.
EBL
Table 12.1. Promotional strategies for supporting RES (Haas et al., 2004; Menanteau et al., 2003). Direct
Regulatory
Voluntary
Price driven
Quantity driven
Investment focused
Investment subsidies Tax credits Low interest/soft loans
Tendering system for investment grant
Generation based
(Fixed) Feed-in tariffs Fixed premium system
Tendering system for long-term contracts Tradable green certificate system
Investment focused
Shareholder programs Contribution programs Green tariffs
Generation based
Indirect
Environmental taxes Simplification of authorization procedures Connection charges, balancing costs
Voluntary agreements
Promoting Electricity from Renewable Energy Sources
425
Such schemes have the advantage of allowing renewables to penetrate the market quickly as their production costs drop below the electricity-price-plus-premium. Together with other incentives and considerations which tax conventional power sources in accordance with their environmental impact, well-designed fixed premium schemes are theoretically one of the most effective ways of promoting electricity from RES. 2. Regulatory quantity-driven strategies. Under these schemes, the policymakers set a desired quota or goal, usually with a target date, to encourage the market penetration of RES. Examples include the following: •
Tendering or bidding schemes which call for tenders to acquire specific amounts of capacity or generation from specified types of RES. Competition between bidders leads to the winners of contracts which will receive a guaranteed tariff for a specified period of time. • Tradable certificate schemes such as renewable portfolio standards (RPS), which are popular in the United States, or TGC in Europe. These schemes typically obligate one or more parties involved in the electricity supply chain such as the generators, wholesalers, distribution companies, or retailers to acquire a certain percentage of electricity from RES in their energy mix. Most schemes allow parties to trade certificates to demonstrate compliance. Certificates can be obtained in three ways: – from their own renewable electricity generation; – by purchasing renewable electricity and associated certificates from other generators; and – by purchasing certificates without purchasing the actual power from a generator or broker.
EBL
The price of the certificates is determined by a market for certificates, such as in Nord Pool. 3. Voluntary approaches. Voluntary schemes are based on the willingness of consumers to pay a premium for green energy. There are two main categories: 1. Investment based schemes driven where individuals voluntarily contribute to renewable energy by providing up-front capital and 2. Generation-based schemes where consumers pay a volumetric premium for renewable electricity deliveries. 4. Indirect strategies. Aside from the schemes already mentioned, there are other strategies which may have an indirect impact on the dissemination of renewables, including •
various forms of eco-taxes on electricity produced from non-renewable sources such as carbon taxes, sulfur taxes, or other7 ; • CO2 emission allowances which are the subject of much talk 8 ; and • removal of subsidies previously given to fossil and nuclear generation. Indirect schemes could also include regulatory and institutional assistance including preferential permitting and siting, easy connection to the grid, and the operational concessions that make it easy to feed RES-generated power into the system. This is particularly important because most RES generation tends to be intermittent and unpredictable. 7
Promotion of renewable electricity via energy or environmental taxes can be achieved either by exempting RES from energy taxes or by providing a partial or total refund of any taxes collected. 8 Refer to Chapter 14 on global climate change for further discussion.
426
Competitive Electricity Markets
Preferential permitting and siting can reduce potential oppositions to RES plants if they address issues of concern, such as noise and visual or environmental impacts. Regulations can be used to set aside specific locations for development and/or to omit areas of higher risk of environmental damage or injury to birds. Standardization of interconnecting RES-generated power to the grid can ease requirements that are often overly burdensome and inconsistent and can lead to high transaction costs for RES project developers.9 Safety requirements are essential, in particular in the case of the interconnection in weak parts of the grid. However, unusually burdensome criteria on interconnections can lead to higher prices for access to the grid – or in cases are used as an excuse to deny access. Clarity, transparency, and reasonableness of safety and interconnection requirements are critical. Moreover the rules must be clear and fair for distribution of additional costs imposed by RES on the network. Finally, there must be clear rules delineating responsibility for physical balancing associated to intermittent production from some RES-E technologies, in particular wind power.10 12.3.1. Historical milestones The birth of today’s modern renewable energy industries may be traced largely to the pioneering efforts of private Danish investors and developers in the early 1970s and to the passage in the United States of the Public Utilities Regulatory Policy Act of 1978 (PURPA), which arguably introduced the earliest form of a mandatory feed-in law in the power industry. The state of California, for long a proponent of alternative forms of generation, developed an attractive and generous subsidy scheme – called standard contract for qualifying facilities or QFs – which, when combined with available federal and state tax credits, stimulated the deployment of renewable energy projects. Both PURPA and the California scheme, however, had their drawbacks because, arguably, they did not provide an adequate incentive for the deployment of efficient technologies.11 Some critics have characterized the aggressive promotion of renewables in California as too much, too soon, and at too high a price.12 In contrast, the Danes implemented a testing and certification procedure for wind turbines as early as 1978 as a pre-condition for receiving subsidies resulting in high reliability and productivity (Meyer, 2004a, b). In the early 1990s, promotional programs based on regulated and obligatory tariffs for the purchase of electricity from specified renewable sources became common and were refined in various European countries. The most important schemes fixed FIT and fixed premium systems used in Denmark, Germany, and Spain to good effect. Under these schemes, utilities are legally obliged to pay the prescribed FIT as long as the RES plants meet certain technical standards. Not surprisingly, the 1990s saw a wind power boom in Europe – especially in Germany, Denmark, and Spain where generous FIT schemes were introduced. More than 80% of the European wind capacity installed at the end of the
EBL
9
Chapter 13 discusses regulatory aspects of encouraging distributed generation, RES, and combined heat and power (CHP). 10 These issues have become pronounced in countries like Germany and Denmark, with significant penetration of wind. 11 Although the federal government plays an important role in providing tax incentives for renewables, states have historically been the innovators in supporting the commercial application of RES technologies in the United States. 12 This colorful phrase is attributed to Michael Peevey, a senior vice president at Southern California Edison at the time and currently the Chairman of the California Public Utilities Commission.
Promoting Electricity from Renewable Energy Sources
427
1990s was located in these three countries. The competitive tendering system, favored in the United Kingdom and France, has had limited success. Meanwhile, in the United States, after an initial growth spurt in the 1980s, the 1990s saw relatively little new development as the standard offers established in California and other states were no longer aggressively promoted. With the ongoing liberalization of electricity markets across Europe and other countries, TGC, based on quota obligations for RES, have become more prominent. In Europe this scheme has been tried in Italy, the United Kingdom, and Sweden in different variations, so far without great success. The first application of such a quota-based system occurred in the United States, at the state level with or without TGC. Renewable energy quotas have recently become the most popular support scheme in the United States and an increasing number of states have implemented them. In general, whilst the main goal of early subsidies was to increase the supply security and fuel diversity, the focus of programs in recent years has shifted to reduce the emission of greenhouse gases. Table 12.2 summarizes the most important historical milestones for promotional strategies. Table 12.3 provides an overview of more recent promotion schemes to support electricity generation from RES in the countries investigated. In Europe, FITs serve as the main policy instrument, with the exception of Finland, which exclusively uses tax credits and investment incentives for the promotion of RES. Over time, many countries have gone through major changes and occasional reversals in their renewable support policies, either in response to what was or was not working, to make it more effective, or in response to political or public sentiment. Figure 12.4 shows the evolution of the main support instrument for selected countries over time. Countries where the FIT has been continuously in effect since 1997 are Austria13 , Germany, Greece, Luxembourg, Portugal, and Spain. Countries with major changes include:
EBL
•
• • • •
the United Kingdom and Ireland which replaced their problematic tender schemes by a quota regulation in combination with a TGC market in 2002 and 2005, respectively; a few others including Belgium and Italy who substituted their FIT systems for a quota regulation; Sweden which switched to a quota obligation complementing the already existing tax and investment incentives in some cases; the United States where tax credits have been complemented by the introduction of RPS obligations in a number of states starting in 2000; and Japan which introduced a quota system in 2003 on top of an existing voluntary net metering for PV that has been offered by utilities since 1992.
12.3.2. Institutional and political determinants of policy The wide variations in the choice of instruments, their timing, and intended goals may be largely explained by variations in political developments and intentions of different countries. Indeed, one can speculate a strong collation between the choice of instruments, the level of FIT or premium offered, and stability of the policies with the institutional and political environments in each country. Three main sets of parameters are at play in the institutional arena and further described in Box 12.1. 13
With a short interruption for small hydro power in 2001.
Table 12.2. Historical overview on promotion strategies for electricity generation from renewables (Haas et al., 2007). Year
Country
Type of strategy
Program name
1979–89 1978–89
DK US
Investment subsidies Feed-in tariffs/tax relief
PURPA
1989–96
DE
1991–93
DE
1990–99 1990–present 1992–94
UK DE AT
1992–97 1994–present 1991–96
IT US SE
1992–99 1992–99 1994–present
DK DE, CH, AT GR
Investment subsidies plus feed-in tariffs Investment subsidies plus feed-in tariffs Tendering system Feed-in tariffs Investment subsidies plus feed-in tariffs Feed-in tariffs Tax relief Investment subsidies/tax relief Feed-in tariff Feed-in tariffs Investment subsidies
1994–present
ES
1994–2005
JP
1992–present 1996–present
JP DE, CH, NL, AT, UK
Feed-in tariffs or fixed premium systems Investment subsidies Voluntary net metering Voluntary green tariffs
Technologies addressed
“100/250 MW Wind Programm"
Wind, biogas All technologies (except large hydro power) Wind
“1000-Dächer-Programm”
PV
NFFO/SRO/NI-NFFO “Einspeisetarif” 200 kW PV-Program
Selected technologies PV, wind, biomass, small hydro power PV
EBL
“CIP 6/92” Tax production credits
“Kostendeckende Vergütung” 1994–now: “Operational Program for Energy and Competitiveness” “Royal Decree 2366/1994” resp. “Royal Decree 436/2004” “Residential PV System Dissemination Program” “Surplus electricity purchase menu" Various brands
All technologies Varies over time; focus on wind Wind, solar, biomass Wind, biomass PV PV, wind, biomass, small hydro power, geothermal All technologies (except large hydro power) PV PV Selected technologies
1996–present 1997–present
CH FI
Voluntary stock exchange Tax incentives
“Solarstrombörse” Energy tax
1998–present
DE
Labeled “green electricity”
1999–present 1999–2000
DE NL
2000–present 1998–present
DE, FIT US
2001–04 2002–present 2002–present
IT ES IT, UK, BE
Soft loans (Voluntary) green certificates Regulated rates Quota obligation with TGC/renewable energy funds Rebates FIT/premium Quota obligation with TGC
TÜV, Grüner Stromlabel e.V., Öko-Institut “100,000 Dächer-Programm"
2003–present
JP
Quota obligation with TGC
“Tetti fotovoltaici” All technologies All technologies (wave, waste, and large hydro power depend on the country) “Renewables Portfolio Standard”
2003–present 2003–present 2003–present
AT SE NL
2005–present
IT
FIT Quota obligation with TGC Mixed strategy (FITs, tax incentives, TGC) PV feed in
“Ökostromgesetz” All technologies. No waste MEP (Environmental Quality of Power Generation) “Conto Energia”
“Renewable energy act” “Renewables Portfolio Standards”“Clean Energy Funds”
EBL
PV Wind, mini hydro power (