AGRARIAN CHANGE IN THE CEN SUDAN
L RAINLANDS:
A Socio-Economic Analysis
Edited by M.A. Mohamed Salih
Scandinavian I...
30 downloads
872 Views
3MB Size
Report
This content was uploaded by our users and we assume good faith they have the permission to share this book. If you own the copyright to this book and it is wrongfully on our website, we offer a simple DMCA procedure to remove your content from our site. Start by pressing the button below!
Report copyright / DMCA form
AGRARIAN CHANGE IN THE CEN SUDAN
L RAINLANDS:
A Socio-Economic Analysis
Edited by M.A. Mohamed Salih
Scandinavian Institute of African Studies, Uppsala 1987
ISBN 91-7106-270-X Nordiska afrikainstitutet, 1987 Printed in Sweden by Uppsala University, 1987
TABLE OF CONTENTS Map of t h e Sudan Acknowledgements Introduction M.A. Mohamed Salih Tapping t h e Agrarian S e c t o r f o r Economic Growth: T h e Sudan Experience Ibrahim A. Elbadawi Economic S t r a t e g y and Household Viability in a Dry Savannah Agricultural Society: Berti of Darfur Ladislav Holy Agricultural Intensification and Resource Maintenance: Some C a s e s f r o m Western Sudan Leif 0. Manger Poverty Versus Affluence: T h e Fiasco of Rainfed Mechanized Agriculture in Renk District: Southern Sudan Paul Wani Gore T h e T r a c t o r and t h e Plough: T h e Sociological Dimension M.A. Mohamed Salih National Ambivalence and External Hegemony: The Negligence of P a s t o r a l Nomads in t h e Sudan Abdel Ghaffar M. Ahmed Implications of 1983-1 985 F a m i n e on t h e Rural Sahel of t h e Sudan Abdullahi Osman El Tom From Rural t o Urban Labour Markets: T h e Derivation of t h e Shadow Wage R a t e and t h e Social R a t e of Discount f o r t h e Sudan Eltingani S. Moharned
36
E
C
O
N
G
G
O
Y
P
T
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS I a m m o s t g r a t e f u l t o m y colleagues a t t h e D e p a r t m e n t of Social Anthropology a n d Sociology, University of Khartoum, Sudan f o r accommodating my l e a v e of absence t o work on this book.
T h e editing of t h e a r t i c l e s and
t h e writing of my own a r t i c l e and t h e introduction w a s f a c i l i t a t e d by t h e generous research g r a n t which I received f r o m t h e Scandinavian Institute of African Studies, Uppsala, Sweden.
I t a k e this opportunity t o express my
g r a t i t u d e t o all t h e s t a f f of t h e Institute f o r their gracious help and cooperation which contributed considerably t o t h e completion of this work. My thanks also go t o all t h o s e who c o m m e n t e d on t h e f i r s t d r a f t s of t h e a r t i c l e s f o r their suggestions and revisions.
In t h e l a s t s t a g e s of pro-
duction I a m thankful t o Mrs. P.A. P a l m e r f o r typing t h e final d r a f t and t o Dr. Margaret Mohamed Salih f o r reading a n d correcting t h e proofs.
All
shortcomings a r e nonetheless m y sole responsibility. A special d e b t of g r a t i t u d e is d u e t o Margaret, my wife, and our daughter Hyat, f o r their p a t i e n c e and encouragement during my long periods of absence.
INTRODUCTION M.A. Mohamed Salih
T h e c e n t r a l rainlands of t h e Sudan e m b r a c e t h e a r e a b e t w e e n Lat. 9" a n d 15" N o r t h a n d Long. 22" a n d 36" E a s t within t h e boundaries of t h e Republic of t h e Sudan.
This t e r r i t o r y r e p r e s e n t s a b o u t o n e t h i r d of t h e 2.5
million s q u a r e k i l o m e t r e s t o t a l a r e a of t h e c o u n t r y , a n d o v e r half of t h e 85.46
million a c r e s t o t a l a r a b l e land.
F u r t h e r m o r e , under half of t h e 22
million t o t a l population of t h e Sudan l i v e in t h i s a r e a . per c e n t of t h e population
Between 80 and 85
is e n g a g e d in a g r i c u l t u r a l production w i t h only
10 t o 15 per c e n t pursuing a p u r e n o m a d i c life.
about
However, agro-
pastoralism is t h e m o s t p r e v a l e n t e c o n o m i c a c t i v i t y in t h e c e n t r a l rainlands. Agrarian c h a n g e in t h e c e n t r a l rainlands h a s been a c o n s e q u e n c e of t h e p e n e t r a t i o n of t h e m a r k e t e c o n o m y via t h e introduction of c a s h c r o p s especially c o t t o n , s e s a m e , groundnuts and hibiscus, a n d t h e expansion of large- scale
m e c h a n i z e d schemes.'
However,
traditional agriculture
has
r e m a i n e d t h e main e c o n o m i c a c t i v i t y and is p r a c t i s e d by t h e m a j o r i t y of the
rural
population.
One
of
the
striking
features
of
the
agrarian
s t r u c t u r e in t h e c e n t r a l rainlands is t h e obvious negligence of t h e smalls c a l e t r a d i t i o n a l p r o d u c e r s whose f a r m i n g t e c h n i q u e s a n d p r a c t i c e s have n o t b e e n improved d e s p i t e a n increasing p r e s s u r e on t h e m t o f e e d t h e mselves a n d t o produce a surplus f o r e x c h a n g e a n d f o r e x p o r t t o t h e i n t e r national m a r k e t .
C o n t r a r y t o this, t h e m o d e r n mechanized f a r m i n g s e c t o r
has been a c c o r d e d priority a n d provided with machinery, financial c r e d i t and b e t t e r m a r k e t i n g facilities.
Whereas t h e m e c h a n i z e d f a r m i n g s e c t o r
enjoys support in t e r m s of f a v o u r a b l e a g r i c u l t u r a l policies a n d provision of m o d e r n inputs, labour,
t h e traditional
f a r m i n g s e c t o r is still based on f a m i l y
small- scale production a n d l i m i t e d c a p i t a l input.
t h e r e h a s b e e n increasing c o m p e t i t i o n
Nevertheless,
b e t w e e n t h e t w o s e c t o r s of
the
a g r a r i a n s t r u c t u r e o v e r t h e land, labour, d e v e l o p m e n t a s s i s t a n c e a n d c a p i t a l i n v e s t m e n t in addition t o t h e i r unequal s t r u c t u r a l relationship in d e f o r m e d a n d f r a g m e n t e d local m a r k e t s . T h e ill-planned expansion of t h e m e c h a n i z e d f a r m i n g s e c t o r h a s had
disastrous i m p a c t s on t h e t r a d i t i o n a l producers mainly through t h e t r a n s f e r of much of t h e i r labour t o t h e m o d e r n s e c t o r in r e t u r n f o r very low paym e n t s which a r e n o t s u f f i c i e n t t o f i n a n c e t h e i r d e m a n d s f o r m a n u f a c t u r e d and o t h e r c o n s u m e r goods. large- scale
mechanized
I t is also obvious t h a t t h e labour migration t o
agr~cultural schemes
and
to
urban
c e n t r e s of
e m p l o y m e n t m e a n s t h a t t h e m i g r a n t s a r e increasingly unable t o c l e a r new plots f o r c u l t i v a t i o n in t h e i r h o m e a r e a s .
T h e c a r r y i n g c a p a c i t y of land
h a s t h e r e f o r e been e x c e e d e d by continuous cropping a t t h e e x p e n s e of t h e period t h a t i t should b e l e f t fallow. reduction
of
fallow
periods
has
Another c o n t r i b u t o r y f a c t o r t o r h e
been
t h e d i s p l a c e m e n t of
subsistence
c u l t i v a t o r s f r o m t h e i r f a r m s , especially in a r e a s w h e r e t h e old villages a r e surrounded by t h e s c h e m e s .
Shifting c u l t i v a t i o n which w a s traditionally
a d o p t e d in o r d e r t o r e g u l a t e land f e r t i l i t y by leaving t h e land fallow f o r a number of y e a r s in o r d e r t o r e g e n e r a t e is no longer possible.
The farmers
have had t o c h a n g e f r o m c u l t i v a t i n g s e v e r a l plots over long periods of t i m e t o fixed farming.
This in t u r n h a s t h e s a m e e f f e c t a s t h e reduction
of fallow periods a n d i t s a c c o m p a n y i n g n e g a t i v e i m p a c t on soil f e r t i l i t y 2
a n d h e n c e land productivity.
F u r t h e r m o r e , low productivity is coupled with a decline in t h e p r i c e s of a g r i c u l t u r a l p r o d u c t s r e l a t i v e t o m a n u f a c t u r e d goods.
I t is e s t i m a t e d
t h a t o v e r 40 per c e n t of f a m i l y labour in a g r i c u l t u r e is d i r e c t e d t o t h e production of c a s h c r o p s while 60 per c e n t of t h e c r o p s produced by t h e family,
including
food,
is
destined
t o b e exchanged
m a r k e t s , only t o b e e x p o r t e d a f t e r w a r d s .
on
t h e national
H e n c e t h e c l a s s i c c a s e of t h e
loss of household viability d u e t o t h e i n t e g r a t i o n of t r a d i t i o n a l producers i n t o t h e m a r k e t e c o n o m y prevails.3
When m e a s u r e d a g a i n s t a n annual
population g r o w t h of 2.8 per c e n t , t h i s is a c l e a r indication of a growing food
deficit.
The
1983-1985
f a m i n e r e v e a l e d t h a t o n e in e v e r y f i v e
i n h a b i t a n t s in t h e c e n t r a l rainlands of t h e Sudan w a s d e p e n d e n t on relief food.
A food d e f i c i t of o v e r 1.5 million t o n s in 1984 w a s only a m o d e s t
r e f l e c t i o n of t h e inability of
t h e s m a l l producers in this a r e a (which is
rich in n a t u r a l resources) t o f e e d t h e m s e l v e s a n d t h e f a i l u r e of t h e p r e s e n t agricultural
policies t o devise a p p r o p r i a t e
m e a s u r e s f o r addressing t h i s
growing crisis. Agrarian c h a n g e in t h e c e n t r a l rainlands h a s s o f a r been based on t h e h o r i z o n t a l expansion of m e c h a n i z e d f a r m i n g r a t h e r t h a n a v e r t i c a l improvem e n t in productivity. A d a p t i v e r e s e a r c h is lacking, high yielding c r o p
varieties have not been experimented with, soil management is poor, biotechnology has been directly or indirectly neglected, and t h e mechanization package has proved t o be inadequately conceived and hastily adopted a s t h e only means t o agricultural development.
Added t o t h e s e problems a r e
t h e classic restrictive f a c t o r s such a s excessive costs of mechanization in t e r m s of foreign exchange,
supply,
and under- utilization of machinery.
difficulties with maintenance, repair Moreover, t h e large- scale mechanized
agricultural schemes have particularly contributed t o t h e blight of t h e small producers both cultivators and pastoralists, especially those who w e r e displaced from t h e i r cultivable lands, Appropriate
planning could
water
points and animal
routes.
have eliminated such disasters which have
unnecessarily been inflicted upon t h e traditional producers of t h e c e n t r a l rainlands where t h e large- scale schemes a r e located.
The present agri-
cultural practices in t h e rainfed sector have led t o a n accelerating decline in soil fertility which makes t h e viability of t h e whole venture questionable.
Excessive cultivation, avoidance of rotation and soil erosion have
already resulted in low levels of productivity (see Mohamed Salih in this volume) which mean
t h a t t h e merchant f a r m e r s may soon s t a r t t o expand
their operations t o new a r e a s in order t o continue in business.
More
traditional f a r m e r s will eventually b e displaced and m o r e complex problems will e m e r g e following such a p a t t e r n of horizontal expansion.
What is a t
stake, therefore, is not only t h e degradation of t h e whole ecological zone, but also a f u t u r e strain in t h e ability of t h e population of t h e c e n t r a l lands t o f e e d itself. It has t o b e m a d e c l e a r a t this juncture t h a t I have not
argued t h a t
agricultural mechanization or technological change is incapable of achieving high productivity if i t has been properly planned and applied.
I have,
however, argued t h a t planned agrarian change in t h e rainlands has not taken into account t h e complexity of t h e ecosystem, t h e traditional agricultural and pastoral production systems and t h e likely i m p a c t s t h a t i t might have on society, economy and ecology.
As such, agrarian change in
the
an
central
rainlands
economic disaster Ecologically,
as the
their
can far
be as
regarded
of
natural
agricultural
malpractices.
ecological,
social
and
t h e traditional producers a r e concerned.
rainlands
degradation
as
have
resources Population
been due
a
drastic
t o traditional and
subjected
modern
concentration
to
adjacent
to
the
mechanized agricultural schemes has already led t o overcultivation and overgrazing, and both have contributed in t h e depletion of soil fertility and the
impoverishment of t h e vegetation cover, for example by t h e felling of
t r e e s t o provide firewood and charcoal.
Now t h a t t h e land has reached
and gone beyond i t s carrying capacity, t h e r e is increasing pressure t o fell m o r e large t r e e s in order t o f e e d small animals such a s calves, goats and sheep. This situation w a s aggravated by t h e t w o drought phases of 19711973 and 1983-1985 during which many human lives w e r e lost and herd holdings
were
reduced
by
death
and sale.
The
prices
of
livestock
decreased a s t h e m a r k e t mechanism worked against t h e steady supply and glutted markets. tragedy;
The ecological degradation has resulted in a human
i t is t h e pastoralists and t h e small cultivators of this climatically
unpredictable zone who have suffered most.
Much of t h e rural population
has l e f t their villages and their e m p t y animal camps t o move t o towns or adjacent t o t h e a r e a s w h e r e relief agencies operate. Socially, ecological degradation, drought and famine has m e a n t a n mostly from t h e c e n t r a l rainlands t o river-
accelerating r a t e of migration;
ain Sudan and t o t h e c a p i t a l towns in particular. 1986
indicated
Khartoum
that
the
population
of
the
The Economic Survey of Three
North and Omdurman) has increased
Towns
(Khartoum,
through migration from
500,000 in 1956 t o 1,802,000 in 1983 and over 2,000,000 in 1986, i.e., a f t e r t h e famine.
The population in t h e rainlands has nevertheless doubled
during t h e last 25 years, which indicates t h e e x t r a demands on land and predicates t h e migratory movement.
In i t s crudist but c o r r e c t sense,
migration means t h e loss of labour t o t h e urban c e n t r e s and t h e transformation of about 7 per c e n t of consumers.
t h e rural population every year t o food
Moreover, since most of t h e migrants a r e men, this increases
t h e work burden of
women in t h e sending villages.
More women a r e
engaged in wage labour working for t h e wealthy f a r m e r s and shopkeepers in t h e villages for very low r a t e s of payment relative t o men.
The
involvement of men and women in t h e production of cash crops and wage labour also means t h a t less t i m e is devoted t o home food production which in turn increases t h e
vulnerability
of traditional f a r m e r s t o ecological
change and fluctuations in t h e prices of manufactured goods which a r e t h e present
indicators
of
the
value
of
their
work
through
exchange.
Although i t is difficult t o s e p a r a t e t h e various impacts of agrarian
change,
economically, t h e population of
differentiated than e v e r before.
the central
rainlands is m o r e
The distinction between t h e traditional
f a r m e r who cultivates between 3 and 15 feddans with very rudimentary tools and
the
m e r c h a n t f a r m e r who acquires between 1,000
feddans and owns his own t r a c t o r or tractors, discs,
is a
distinction
t o 1,500
thresher, and combined
between absolute poverty and
ravishing wealth.
Furthermore, t h e integration of t h e whole region i n t o national and international
economic
structures
has been
accomplished
not
only
by
the
penetration of c o m m e r c i a l capital, but also by t h e creation of marketing boards mandated t o e x t r a c t surpluses from t h e small producers.
These
include t h e Oil Seeds Marketing Corporation, Livestock and Meat Marketing Corporation and t h e Gum Arabic Marketing Corporation. It is ironic t h a t despite t h e huge t r a n s f e r s of financial capital, technological machinery and know how, t h e food situation has not improved and t h e traditional economy.
sector
has lost i t s dynamism t o t h e dominant
Poverty has increased and f e w e r people c a n
now
market produce
sufficient grain t o f e e d themselves or s e c u r e a surplus t o sell in t h e m a r k e t t o m e e t a small fraction of t h e increasing demand f o r consumer goods. poor
The agrarian change has so f a r seemed unrewarding t o t h e rural who
should
ideally
be
the
beneficiaries
of
development.
4
The t h e m e s outlined above a r e well represented in most of t h e papers in this book.
However, Elbadawi holds t h e view t h a t t h e Sudanese agrarian
s e c t o r suffers from malformed incentive s t r u c t u r e s and policies which a r e t h e main reason behind t h e c u r r e n t decline in productivity. extracted
from
agriculture
is
not
The surplus
re- invested in improving
t h e infra-
s t r u c t u r e , innovative technology, and redressing t h e segmented m a r k e t in t h e traditional sub- sector. anization,
Elbadawi
technology,
C o n t r a r y t o my critique of agricultural mech-
maintains
research
and
t h a t a d e q u a t e investment in agricultural
associated shifters of
supply such a s human
resources and infrastructure a r e t h e crucial f a c t o r s needed t o m e e t t h e increasing demand for food and secure resource transfers f r o m agriculture t o o t h e r s e c t o r s of t h e economy. investment in considerable
surplus
mobilization
and
agriculture
This author also notes t h e lack of
t h e traditional sector which has customarily
is
of
export
transfer
neither
of
desirable
commodities, surplus
from
nor
feasible
but a
produced a
comments
that
technologically as a
long
term
'the
stagnant policy'.
Holy's paper gives weight t o t h e general findings of a l l t h e papers included in this book concerning t h e e m e r g e n c e of wage labour, t h e involve m e n t of traditional producers in t h e m a r k e t economy, and t h e mechanisms through which rich and poor households m a k e ends meet.
The s t r a t e g y
adopted by t h e Berti agro- pastoralists shows a g r e a t d e g r e e of sophistication
in
t h e allocation
resources - which economic
of
labour
and
capital
-
mainly
livestock
a r e conceived a s t h e c r i t i c a l f a c t o r s in household
performance
and
hence
viability.
The
association
between
poverty and t h e a c c e p t a n c e of work a s hired labourers in agriculture and pastoral production is a c l e a r indication of t h e growing commercialization of t h e s e i m p o r t a n t spheres of subsistence activities.
It is c l e a r t h a t t h e
Berti agricultural s y s t e m works within a s t a g n a n t technology without any modern inputs.
It is i n t e r e s t i n g t h a t this s y s t e m remains viable unless i t s
balance is s h a t t e r e d by ecological disasters o r excessive consumption of manufactured goods.
T h e internal dynamics of consumption and production
p a t t e r n s a r e convincingly d e m o n s t r a t e d by t h e manner in which t h e limited resources of t h e Berti a r e a c t i v a t e d t o o f f s e t t h e deficit in urgent requirements. Manger discusses t h e ability of traditional farming s y s t e m s t o respond t o e x t e r n a l pressures.
The c a s e s of Liri a n d Kheiran reveal t h a t small
producers a r e a w a r e of t h e i m p o r t a n c e of
resource m a i n t e n a n c e if t h e
intensive utilization of land i s t o b e practised.
Manuring and t e r r a c i n g a r e
among t h e measures a d o p t e d t o m e e t t h e c r i t e r i a of a c a r e f u l utilization of resources.
T h e development of irrigated agriculture in t h e Kheiran
oases r e f l e c t s t h e c a p a c i t y of rural communities t o t r a n s f e r technology and induce agrarian change.
Both t h e shadouf
and saqia technologies work
well and a r e relatively c h e a p and efficient. sequence of t h e penetration of
An all t o o familiar con-
t h e m a r k e t economy is t h a t t h e s e t w o
techniques have been rendered futile while t h e wealthy f a r m e r s have opted f o r t h e m o r e expensive and land exhausting pump schemes.
It is unfort-
u n a t e t h a t f o r socio- economic reasons t h e t w o societies a r e moving away from t h e intensive t o t h e e x t e n s i v e s y s t e m s of production a t a t i m e when resource
maintenance
i s a n issue of
a major concern in t h e
sahel
.
In c o n t r a s t t o t h e c a s e s of agricultural intensification and resource m a i n t e n a n c e in t h e traditional s e c t o r , G o r e analyses t h e a b s e n c e of this notion
in
the
financially
prosperous
and
technologically
developed
mechanized f a r m i n g sub- sector.
He explains how t h e expansion of large-
s c a l e mechanization in Dinkaland h a s c r e a t e d a r e s e r v e of agricultural labourers, many of whom having lost t h e i r land t o t h e p r i v a t e sector. While t h e mechanized s c h e m e s have c r e a t e d a f f l u e n c e on t h e o n e hand, t h e y h a v e c r e a t e d poverty on t h e other.
T h e contribution of this f o r m of
a g r a r i a n change t o t h e development of social services in t h e a r e a s where t h e s c h e m e s a r e l o c a t e d is negligible.
R a t h e r , i t has c r e a t e d a dependency
of t h e poor on t h e r i c h in t h e f i r s t i n s t a n c e and a dominance of t h e rich over t h e poor.
T h e o u t c o m e of agricultural mechanization is t h e relegation
of t h e subsistence c u l t i v a t o r s a n d pastoralists t o e x t r e m e poverty a n d t h e reduction of t h e i r ability t o f e e d themselves while t h e i r labour is sold t o s e c u r e t h e production of millions of t o n s of grain. T h e breaking down of household v i a b i l i ~ y , t h e drive towards extensive s y s t e m s of agricultural production in t h e ecologically degraded sahel
,
and
t h e concentration of c a p i t a l intensive modern technologies in t h e hands of wealthy m e r c h a n t f a r m e r s h a v e culminated in t h e f a m i n e c r i s e s of 19831985.
El Tom highlights t h e unpredictability of t h e c l i m a t e of t h e sahelian
zone, and paints t h e t r a g i c p i c t u r e of f a m i n e and t h e way i t structurally p e n e t r a t e s e v e r y a s p e c t of t h e lives of t h e subsistence c u l t i v a t o r s and pastoralists.
Livestock e i t h e r died or w a s sold f o r very low prices, wells
dried up, and no harvest w a s collected f o r t h r e e consecutive years.
How-
e v e r , t h e population used t h e i r local knowledge about t h e i r ecology s o e f f e c t i v e l y , processing wild plants and s e e d s arduously into edible food. This in itself indicates t h e frequency of c r o p failures.
Nevertheless, t h e
question remained a s t o why drought e n d e d in such a n a c u t e f a m i n e crisis this time.
And o n e answer proposed i s t h a t t h e c u r r e n t agricultural
policies and t h e articulation of t h e peasants in t h e m a r k e t economy have led t o t h e i r marginalization. surplus i s e x t r a c t e d
A f t e r their produce is m a r k e t e d and t h e
by t h e p a r a s t a t a l s a n d t h e merchants,
t h e small
producers a r e l e f t with nothing but t h e i r poverty. Following t h e s a m e t h e m e but a t t h e national and international levels, Ahmed provides a thorough explanation of t h e dynamics of pastoral s y s t e m s of production a n d t h e i m p a c t of governmental intervention on t h e small producers, both c u l t i v a t o r s and agro- pastoralists.
It clearly e m e r g e s t h a t
national ambivalence coupled with t h e s t r u c t u r a l dependence of t h e s t a t e on externally m o t i v a t e d p r o j e c t s represent s o m e of t h e f a c t o r s behind t h e
d e m i s e of pastoralism in t h e Sudan.
Although f a m i n e c a n b e a t t r i b u t e d t o
ecological f a c t o r s , t h e ill-planned a g r i c u l t u r a l s c h e m e s which h a v e c o n t r i b u t e d t o ecological d e g r a d a t i o n a r e only o n e f o r m of i n t e r v e n t i o n f r o m t h e s t a t e a n d t h e i n t e r n a t i o n a l a g e n c i e s i n t o t h e lives of local c o m m u n i t i e s w i t h o u t o f f e r i n g any s u i t a b l e ' d e v e l o p m e n t ' a l t e r n a t i v e .
While A h m e d is
n o t c r i t i c a l of i n t e r v e n t i o n per s e , h e d o e s f o c u s on t h e disastrousness of neglecting
particular
groups in s o c i e t y
when
development
projects
are
planned, when t h e i r c o n t r i b u t i o n t o t h e national r e v e n u e is a s s u r e d w i t h o u t any i m p r o v e m e n t s in t h e i r social life. The
choice
of
technology
sociological dimension of elaborated
by Salih
who advocates
agricultural t h e use of
development rather
than
animal
and
the
another
traction
is
a s an
r e a c h i n g t h e m a j o r i t y of t h e f a r m e r s in t h e t r a d -
a p p r o p r i a t e m e a n s of itional s e c t o r .
for
using o n e technology
Given t h e p r e s e n t e v i d e n c e f r o m o t h e r A f r i c a n c o u n t r i e s
a n d t h e l i m i t e d e x p e r i e n c e with a n i m a l t r a c t i o n in Sudan, t h e a u t h o r c a n not
credit
the
failure
to
appreciate
the
relevance
of
this
type
of
technology f o r t h e Sudanese e c o n o m y a n d s o c i e t y o n t h e p a r t of n a t i o n a l governments.
Nevertheless,
nology
be
should
t h i s labour saving a n d l e s s expensive t e c h -
preceded
by
favourable
prices
for
crops,
effective
training, t h e c r e a t i o n of r e p a i r f a c i l i t i e s , a n d t h e provision of a n a d e q u a t e infrastructure.
If
a
gradual
approach
is
commanded,
animal
draft
technology will c e r t a i n l y h a v e a positive e f f e c t on raising t h e s t a n d a r d s of living of
the
majority
of
mechanization programme
the
rural
poor
in
relation
to
the
present
which f a v o u r s t h e w e a l t h y m e r c h a n t f a r m e r s .
T h e m e s s a g e f r o m Salih's p a p e r is t h a t t h e r e is a need f o r assessing t h e e c o n o m i e s of f a r m s i z e a n d productivity in t h e Sudan w i t h r e g a r d t o t h e various
technological
perception
of
options
the tractor
as
available t h e only
r a t h e r than alternative
holding
to a
t o hoe
faulty
cultivation.
T h e issue of r u r a l / u r b a n migration h a s b e e n t o u c h e d upon by a l m o s t a l l t h e authors.
Mohamed d e a l s w i t h t h e e c o n o m i e s of t h e m o v e m e n t of
workers f r o m t h e r u r a l t o t h e urban labour m a r k e t s , a n d i t is obvious f r o m his analysis t h a t r u r a l / u r b a n m i g r a t i o n is a r e s u l t of e c o n o m i c deprivation in t h e r u r a l a r e a s .
What is m o r e i n t e r e s t i n g is t h e a u t h o r ' s i n s i s t e n c e on
c a l c u l a t i n g t h e shadow w a g e r a t e a s a disguised social b e n e f i t t h a t t h e m i g r a n t r e c e i v e s f r o m working in t h e r e l a t i v e l y privileged u r b a n c e n t r e s . Mohamed
also a t t r i b u t e s t h e a c c e l e r a t i n g
r a t e of
migration
from
the
agricultural t o t h e underdeveloped industrial sector t o t h e c u r r e n t disintegration of t h a t s e c t o r d u e t o lack of maintenance, and shortage of a d e q u a t e inputs.
The e f f e c t of this a t t h e macro level is t h e staggering
fall in public s e c t o r income relative t o t h e r a t e of change in t h e social valuation of public s e c t o r consumption.
This implies t h a t t h e public sector
would lose m o r e by depending on a decaying urban industrial s e c t o r and a disintegrating agrarian s e c t o r t h a t sends o u t thousands of labourers every year t o t h e f o r m e r sector.
If labour follows capital, t h e r o o t s of rural/
urban migration a r e t h e r e f o r e found in t h e uneven development between t h e sending regions and t h e receiving large- scale mechanized schemes and t h e semi- industrialized urban centres. Some conclusions c a n be drawn from t h e r e c e n t experience of agrarian change in t h e c e n t r a l rainlands.
The scholars have demonstrated t h a t t h e
rainfed s e c t o r is still largely disorganized. poor,
The s t r u c t u r e of incentives is
t h e local m a r k e t s a r e fragmented, e f f e c t i v e pricing policies a r e
lacking, t h e infrastructure is inappropriate, and t h e mechanization policies a r e f a r from adequate.
These negative f a c t o r s have contributed t o t h e
present agricultural depression which in t u r n has resulted in a general economic
recession.
Re- organizing
such
agrarian
doldrums
s t r u c t u r a l change and not simple sectoral improvements.
requires a
T h e recognition
of t h e s e problems and any a t t e m p t towards solving t h e m is unfortunately structurally related t o t h e international development institutions which a r e partially responsible f o r t h e present agrarian crisis. Most of t h e c u r r e n t agrarian problems in t h e c e n t r a l rainlands s t e m from t h e f a c t t h a t t h e traditional farming systems a r e largely neglected. They a r e still characterised by t h e lack of c a p i t a l and l i t t l e use of modern inputs o r bio-technology.
The answer t o t h e declining soil fertility and low
yield r a t e s per feddan lies with t h e modification of t h e traditional agricultural practices and techniques.
Since extension service has not been
accorded any significant value in t h e rainfed s e c t o r in general and t h e traditional farming s y s t e m in particular, i t is high t i m e t o develop human resources through t h e introduction of a viable extension service.
However,
such a n e f f o r t requires more research in t h e s e s a m e traditional systems of production if extension is t o disseminate t h e knowledge acquired by t h e research institutions t o t h e traditional farmers.
I t is unfortunate t h a t
most of t h e research t h a t has been carried o u t in t h e rainfed s e c t o r
is mainly directed t o t h e mechanized sector.
Very l i t t l e is known about
t h e social and economic structures, agronomical practices, farmers' motivation,
responses t o income opportunities, prices and incentives in t h e
traditional sector. equipment
Research on i n t e r m e d i a t e technology and animal drawn
is particularly
needed t o o f f e r some hope t o t h e t e n s of
thousands of traditional f a r m e r s who still use t h e hoe t o c o m p e t e with t r a c t o r s over t h e s a m e f r a g m e n t e d rural markets. Despite their contribution t o national development through t h e surplus e x t r a c t e d by t h e parastatals working in t h e marketing of their products, pastoralists a r e particularly neglected.
No plan has so f a r been devised
for improving their standards of living or providing t h e m with necessary services.
They a r e instead, subjected t o economic pressures through their
incorporation into t h e m a r k e t economy, and ecological misfit through t h e expansion of large- scale mechanized schemes.
Developments in this a r e a
a r e s c a r c e and d o not r e f l e c t t h e reality of pastoral systems of production today.
T h e question of how t o develop pastoralism in t h e Sudan c a n n o t be
answered within t h e limits of t h e available knowledge and existing research. More research is t h e r e f o r e required not only t o update our knowledge about pastoralists
but also t o explain such issues a s their response t o
famine and drought, t h e emerging socio- economic s t r u c t u r e s within which ecological adaptation is taking place, t h e contemporary shifts in migratory patterns, herd management and responses t o prices and marketing facilities and t h e possibility of introducing small- scale dairy industries.
All t h e
studies in this book point, t o t h e f a c t t h a t t h e 1983-1985 famine was a result of t h e negligence of pastoralists and traditional cultivators.
Food
security in i t s t r u e sense lies with improving t h e methods and techniques of
production
in
these
two
sectors
of
the
rural
Land t e n u r e problems a r e certainly gathering momentum, with t h e large- scale expansion of
mechanized farming.
economy. especially
The prevalent
agrarian transition has already led t o t h e relegation of thousands of small producers t o t h e c a t e g o r y of wage earners.
Thousands m o r e have been
displaced from their land which is now allocated t o t h e m e r c h a n t farmers. Prompt action is required before t h e system of land t e n u r e develops t o a n e x t e n t w h e r e governmental intervention becomes impossible owing t o t h e resistance of those who have a vested i n t e r e s t in t h e prevailing s y s t e m of land allocation.
The
areas
where
the
large- scale mechanized
located a r e largely underdeveloped.
schemes
have
been
The agrarian transition has passed
over t h e rural poor t o t h e benefit of those who a r e already wealthy.
This
malformed agricultural development has also contributed t o migration outside t h e farming communities t o towns and o t h e r c e n t r e s of employment. I t is obvious t h a t t h e problems of social and economic
policy making a r e
closely r e l a t e d t o t h e p a t t e r n of agricultural surplus allocation.
In t h e
c a s e of t h e c e n t r a l rainlands which produce over 75 per c e n t of t h e grain consumed in t h e country or exported during t h e good harvests,
schools,
health clinics, w a t e r supplies, roads and o t h e r social services a r e e x t r e m e l y lacking.
This in itself questions t h e very wisdom behind this p a t t e r n of
sectoral agrarian change and i t s relevance t o rural development, if
by
development w e mean t h e improvement of . t h e quality of t h e life of t h e rural population. more
attention
In developing t h e agrarian s e c t o r in t h e c e n t r a l rainlands should
be
given
to
the
relationship
between
surplus
extraction, regional inequalities and prospects of reaching t h e rural poor. The s e c t o r a l approach which has been adopted has, s o far, proved t o b e incapable of diffusing t h e benefits of development t o t h e majority of t h e rural population who still depend on a s t a g n a n t technology.
If agricultural
development r e f e r s t o increasing crop production by overcoming production constraints, t h e planned agrarian change in t h e c e n t r a l rainlands has barely succeeded in increasing production in t h e mechanized farming s e c t o r a t t h e expense of t h e masses of t h e traditional producers.
Nonetheless, t h e
technological package which has been deployed for t h e purpose of overcoming production constraints has c r e a t e d another s e t of constraints which a r e d e t r i m e n t a l t o t h e production capacity of t h e traditional f a r m e r s and pastoralists.
If technological change is conceived a s one of t h e means for
overcoming production constraints, i t follows t h a t a n i n t e r m e d i a t e technology, animal traction, bio-technology, seed improvement programme and t h e introduction of high yielding varieties m a y c o n s t i t u t e a b e t t e r avenue of
technological change.
However, this objective is difficult t o a t t a i n
unless t h e present agricultural policies a r e re- structured and t h e a g e n t s of change, both national and international, a r e willing t o m e e t t h e challenge of changing their a t t i t u d e s towards small producers.
(I)
For m o r e m a t e r i a l on t h e traditional s y s t e m s of production a n d their main c h a r a c t e r i s t i c s r e f e r t o t h e Introduction in G. Haaland (ed) Problems of Savannah Development: The Sudan Case, Bergen Occasional P a p e r s in Social Anthropology, No. 19, 1982. Also r e f e r t o Tothill (ed) Agriculture in t h e Sudan, Oxford, 1948, F. Barth, 'Economic Spheres in Darfur' in R. F i r t h (ed) Themes in Economic Anthropology, Tavistock, 1967. For t h e i m p a c t of mechanized farming on traditional c u l t i v a t o r s and pastoralists r e f e r t o M.H. Saeed, Economic E f f e c t s of Agricultural Mechanization in Rural Sudan, in G. Haaland (ed) Problems of Savannah Development, Bergen, 1982, a n d F.H. Adam e t a1 : Mechanized Agriculture in t h e C e n t r a l Rainlands in P. Oesterdiekhoff e t a1 (eds) T h e Developm e n t P e r s p e c t i v e of t h e Republic of t h e Sudan, Munich, 1983.
(2)
The overall d e c r e a s e in land productivity for t h e traditional s e c t o r is e s t i m a t e d a s follows (kgtfeddan):
Sorghum Cotton Sesame Groundnuts E s t i m a t e s compiled f r o m various r e p o r t s by t h e Ministry of Agriculture, Food and Natural Resources f r o m 1960 t o 1985. (3)
T h e l i t e r a t u r e on t h e political economy of agriculture in A f r i c a has c o n c e n t r a t e d on providing t h e o r e t i c a l frameworks r a t h e r t h a n policy oriented contributions. Most scholars have highlighted t h e problem of t h e impoverishment of t h e peasantry through their incorporation i n t o t h e capitalist mode of production, o t h e r s m o r e emphasized t h e i r s t r u c t u r a l dependence on t h e m a r k e t economy, or t h e unequal exchange processes t h a t h a v e been taking place between t h e producers of primary e x p o r t s on t h e one hand and t h e producers of t h e c a p i t a l goods on t h e other. This book transcends such conceptualizations t o analysing t h e a c t u a l p a t t e r n of relations between t h e agrarian s e c t o r and t h e internal a s well a s t h e e x t e r n a l f a c t o r s of change. For m o r e m a t e r i a l on t h e political economy of African a g r i c u l t u r e r e f e r t o R.H. Bates, Essays on t h e Political Economy of R u r a l Africa, Cambridge University Press, 1983, G. Arrighi and Saul, Essays on t h e Political Economy of Africa, E a s t A f r i c a Publishing House, 1973. C.Y. Thomas, Dependence and Transformation, New York, 1977. S. Amin, 'Accumulation on a World Scale,' Monthly Review, New York, 1974. C. Leys, C a p i t a l Accumulation, Class Formation and Dependency, Socialist Register, 1978.
(4)
For f u r t h e r explanations of t h e r e c e n t f a m i n e crisis which a f f e c t e d t h e Sudan a m o n g o t h e r African countries r e f e r to, Review of African Political Economy, special issue on World Recession and
t h e Food Crisis in Africa, edited by Peter Lawrence, 1986. Famine: A Man Made Disaster: A report by t h e Commission on Humanitarian Issues, London, 1985. Seeds of Famine by R.W. Franke and B. Chasin, Montdesir, 1980. C. Stevens, Food, Aid and t h e Developing World, London, 1979. J. Carlsson (ed) Recession in Africa, Scandinavian Institute of African Studies, 1983. A. Sen, Poverty and Famine, Oxford, Clarendon Press, 1983.
TAPPING THE AGRARIAN SECTOR FOR ECONOMIC GROWTH: The Sudan Experience Ibrahirn A. Elbadawi T h e Sudan is endowed w i t h huge e c o n o m i c p o t e n t i a l in t e r m s of c u l t u r a l resources.
agri-
A r a t h e r impressive a r r a y of s t a t i s t i c s c a n b e c i t e d in
support of this claim.
Being t h e l a r g e s t c o u n t r y in Africa, t h e Sudan has
a t o t a l a r a b l e land of 85.46 million feddans.
Only 20 per c e n t of t h i s
potential
resources a r e
is
currently
utilized.
The
water
also
quite
s u b s t a n t i a l and vastly under- exploited with only 50 per c e n t of w a t e r p o t e n t i a l being utilized. Sudan's a g r i c u l t u r a l p o t e n t i a l a l s o lies in i t s s e c t o r a l diversity. broad a g r i c u l t u r a l s e c t o r c o m p r i s e s t h r e e sub- sectors: m e c h a n i z e d rainfed a n d t h e irrigated.
The
t h e traditional, t h e
E a c h of t h e s e sub- sectors produces
food a n d c a s h c r o p s both f o r l o c a l consumption and export.
The irrigated
sub- sector includes s c h e m e s such a s t h e G e z i r a , t h e Rahad, Khashm El Girba, El Suki, and t h e Toker a n d Gash Deltas.
T h e s e a r e s p e c i a l i z e d in
t h e production of c o t t o n , groundnuts, a n d o t h e r food c r o p s s u c h a s w h e a t in G e z i r a and Khashm El Girba.
Sugar c a n e i s produced under t h e i r r i g a t e d
sub- sector of Kennana, Guneid, Assalya a n d Khashm El Girba.
While t h i s
s e c t o r c o v e r s 4 million a c r e s , t h e m e c h a n i z e d rainfed sub- sector c o v e r s 6 million a c r e s of
t h e c e n t r a l c l a y plains.
T h e t r a d i t i o n a l sub- sector on
which t h e m a j o r i t y of t h e population subsists c o v e r s over 9 million a c r e s a n d is considered t h e l a r g e s t sub- sector.
Besides being t h e m a i n s o u r c e of
t h e n a t i o n ' s livestock, t h i s sub- sector produces sorghum, millet, groundnuts, s e s a m e , gum a r a b i c a n d o t h e r minor crops. This a g g r e g a t i v e p o t e n t i a l has b e e n used t o r a t i o n a l i z e a m o d e of a g r i c u l t u r a l d e v e l o p m e n t based on e x t e n s i v e r e s o u r c e utilization.
Hence,
t h e o f f i c i a l view on a g r i c u l t u r a l d e v e l o p m e n t has s t a t e d t h a t , "with v a s t untapped
land
resources
in
the
country,
the
horizontal
expansion
of
a g r i c u l t u r a l production holds promise f o r a quick and e c o n o m i c a l i n c r e a s e in production" (Ministry of unqualified
National Planning, 1977).
This p l e a f o r a n
horizontal expansion has been e x e c u t e d with minimal infra-
s t r u c t u r a l services, a n i n a d e q u a t e i n c e n t i v e s t r u c t u r e , virtually no a d a p t i v e a g r i c u l t u r a l r e s e a r c h a n d a d e f o r m e d technological package.
This paper draws on l i t e r a t u r e a b o u t Sudan's agricultural development e f f o r t s in order t o e x a m i n e t h e potential r61e of technology and incentives in t h e process of agrarian transformation, and finally t o assess critically the
significance
of
pricing
policies
in
Sudan's Agricultural Development Efforts: Like
other
less
developed
promoting agricultural
growth.
An Overview
sub- saharan countries,
agriculture
i m p o r t a n t r61e in economic development in t h e Sudan.
plays a n
It contributes 40
per c e n t of t h e t o t a l GDP, 75 per c e n t of t h e GDP in t h e productive sectors, over 50 per c e n t of t h e t o t a l employment and 9 0 per c e n t of t h e country's foreign exchange earnings. productive c a p a c i t y
depends on
Also, most of t h e non- agricultural
agriculture
in s o m e
way
or
another.
Besides, of course, agriculture is t h e main source of food supply.
Never-
theless, this paper a r g u e s t h a t t h e agricultural s e c t o r remains backward and
deprived
of
the
necessary
essential f o r i t s development.
i n f r a s t r u c t u r e and
technological
inputs
Even when such investment has been made,
i t has usually been c h a r a c t e r i z e d by inadequate incentive structures, o f t e n d i c t a t e d by policies favourable t o t h e urban c e n t r e s and susceptible t o non- agrarian pressure groups and o t h e r financial constraints advocated by t h e international funding institutions. It is interesting t o mention a t this juncture, t h a t a review of t h e c u r r e n t l i t e r a t u r e on agricultural development would show t h a t t h e Sudan's agricultural s e c t o r exemplifies s o m e of t h e dominant t r e n d s in o t h e r LDC's. Consider f o r e x a m p l e t h e f a c t t h a t during t h e 1950's and t h e 1960's economic development w a s e q u a t e d with growth in per c a p i t a income. Also t h e s t r u c t u r a l t r a n s f o r m a t i o n of t h e economy w a s perceived a s a n achievement through a continuous squeeze on agriculture.
Thus t h e r6le of
economic development w a s seen t o f a c i l i t a t e t h e process of transformation by a f f e c t i n g a continuous decline in t h e agricultural s h a r e in t h e national product and t h e labour force.
In t h e words of L i t t l e (1982), " agriculture
w a s o f t e n t r e a t e d a s a black box f r o m which people and food and perhaps c a p i t a l c a n be released". Lewis's Development
(1954) influential with
and
widely c i t e d contribution,
Unlimited Supplies of
Labour',
'Economic
focuses on how
the
t r a n s f e r of labour f r o m t h e subsistence s e c t o r (when t h e marginal productivity i s assumed t o b e z e r o in t h e limit) t o t h e industrial s e c t o r f a c i l i t a t e d
c a p i t a l i s t e x p a n s i o n t h r o u g h t h e r e - i n v e s t m e n t of p r o f i t s .
Since t h e labour
supply c u r v e f a c i n g t h e c a p i t a l i s t s e c t o r i s a s s u m e d t o b e i n f i n i t e l y e l a s t i c at t h e r u l i n g w a g e , L e w i s ' s m o d e l p r e d i c t s t h a t e x p a n s i o n in t h e c a p i t a l i s t
s e c t o r will c o n t i n u e u n t i l e a r n i n g s in t h e t w o s e c t o r s a r e e q u a l ; point a dual sector model
is
no longer relevant.
o n e s e c t o r ( S t a a t z a n d E i c h e r , 1984).
a t which
G r o w t h p r o c e e d s a s in
T h e r e l e v a n c e of t h i s s t a t e m e n t
to
this paper, lies in t h e proposition inherent in Lewis's assumption which f i r s t l y n e g l e c t s t h e a g r i c u l t u r a l s e c t o r a n d s e c o n d l y m a k e s a provision of e x t r a c t i n g s u r p l u s f r o m a g r i c u l t u r e w i t h o u t i n v e s t i n g i n it.
T h i s h a s in
t u r n led t o m o r e c o n c e n t r a t i o n o n t h e p r o m o t i o n of t h e i n d u s t r i a l s e c t o r a s a m e a n s of d e c l i n i n g t h e s h a r e of a g r i c u l t u r e in t h e d o m e s t i c e c o n o m y . J o r g e n s o n (1961) m a d e a p o i n t (which is a l s o r e l e v a n t t o t h e 1983-1985 f a m i n e ) t h a t t h e g r o w t h of t h e non- farm s e c t o r w i t h o u t a r e a s o n a b l e r a t e of g r o w t h in t h e f a r m s e c t o r m a y l e a d t o f o o d s h o r t a g e a n d d e c a y of t h e e x i s t i n g i n f r a s t r u c t u r e w h i c h c o u l d c h o k e o f f t h e g r o w t h of t h e n o n - f a r m s e c t o r by m a k i n g i t s l a b o u r supply l e s s t h a n i n f i n i t e l y e l a s t i c .
Therefore
s o m e i n v e s t m e n t in a g r i c u l t u r e t o a c c e l e r a t e t h e g r o w t h of i t s s u r p l u s is d e e m e d t o b e i m p o r t a n t in t h e e a r l y s t a g e s of e c o n o m i c g r o w t h .
Further-
m o r e , J o h n s t o n a n d Mellor (1961) a n d Nicholls (1964) w e r e m o r e a w a r e of s u c h d i f f i c u l t i e s a n d a r g u e d i n c o n t r a s t t o L e w i s t h a t a g r i c u l t u r e is t h e motive f o r c e in economic growth. I t h a s b e e n a r g u e d t h a t t h e d i s a p p o i n t i n g r e c o r d s of r u r a l d e v e l o p m e n t d u r i n g t h e 1950's a n d 1 9 6 0 ' s c o u l d b e a t t r i b u t e d t o t h e w r o n g a s s u m p t i o n t h a t f a r m e r s c o u l d s u b s t a n t i a l l y i n c r e a s e t h e i r a g r i c u l t u r a l p r o d u c t i v i t y by a l l o c a t i n g e x i s t i n g r e s o u r c e s m o r e e f f i c i e n t l y a n d by a d o p t i n g a g r i c u l t u r a l practices and technologies from t h e industrial countries.
The huge invest-
m e n t i n a g r o - i n d u s t r i e s in t h e S u d a n d u r i n g t h e 1960's a n d t h e e a r l y 1970's i s o n l y a n e x a m p l e of t h e p r o m i n a n c e of s u c h i d e a s d u r i n g t h a t period. N o t only in t h e S u d a n b u t i n o t h e r L D C 1 s i t is e v i d e n t t h a t t h e d i f f u s i o n a p p r o a c h h a s f a i l e d m i s e r a b l y i n solving t h e p r o b l e m s of f o o d s h o r t a g e a n d has slowed agricultural growth. T h e diffusion m o d e l of a g r i c u l t u r a l g r o w t h h a s t r i g g e r e d off t w o m a j o r departures
in
the
literature
1970's a n d t h e 1980's.
on
agricultural
transformation
during
the
S c h u l t z a n d h i s a s s o c i a t e s w e r e i n t e r e s t e d in t h e
i d e a t h a t d e s p i t e low l e v e l s of p e r c a p i t a o u t p u t , t r a d i t i o n a l a g r i c u l t u r e is c h a r a c t e r i z e d by a l l o c a t i v e e f f i c i e n c y .
S c h u l t z (1964) g o e s o n t o a r g u e
t h a t , " m a j o r i n c r e a s e s in p e r c a p i t a a g r i c u l t u r a l o u t p u t in t h e T h i r d World
could c o m e about only if f a r m e r s a r e provided with new m o r e productive f a c t o r s of production".
F u r t h e r m o r e Schultz called f o r a major shift from
agricultural extension t o investment in agricultural research and human capital. Another a r e a of development in t h e l i t e r a t u r e is r e l a t e d t o t h e rapid growth of
radical political economy and dependency models of
development (Frank, 1966, Amin, 1973, 1974, 1976).
under-
This approach likewise
managed t o shed s o m e valuable light on t h e process of
linkages and
exchange arrangements t h a t t i e d t h e peasants t o t h e prevailing economic structures.
The basic assumption however remained t h e s a m e with s o m e
alterations, and one c a n t h e r e f o r e maintain with confidence t h a t t h e main lessons from t h e 1960's t o t h e early 1970's y e r e t h a t technological change must b e included a s a crucial component in both t h e theory and practice of rural development. change of heart. of development launched
by
The official policies however did n o t show any
The 1970's thus witnessed t h e flourishing of t h e concept with equity which was a d i r e c t result of t h e critique
radical and
humanitarian
approaches.
These
ideas
were
f u r t h e r advanced t o pave t h e way for s o m e important theoretical and policy d e b a t e s considering t h e interaction distribution,
between growth and income
employment output trade- off, rural employment and income
generating activities together with an implicit consideration of food and nutritional aspects in development planning. This new thrust in t h e d e b a t e has implied a g r e a t e r r81e f o r agric u l t u r e in economic development through t h e following important channels. Firstly, since incomes in both rural and urban a r e a s a r e determined by food prices, i t has been recognised t h a t low productivity in agriculture is t h e main cause of poverty and a s such agricultural productivity is deemed a top development priority.
Secondly, t h e failure of industries in LDC's
t o provide a d e q u a t e employment opportunities t o migrants has led t o more concern about expanding t h e rural employment base through developing t h e agricultural
sector.
Thirdly,
the
development of
bio- technologies has
provided higher agricultural productivity and hence a strong c a s e for a positive
r6le for agriculture in t h e process of economic development.
Such considerations have l e f t a considerable i m p a c t on t h e r e c e n t critique of Sudan's agricultural development planning during t h e 1970's and the
1980's.
Take, for example,
Ali (1984) who observes t h a t , "it is -1 7-
perhaps in recognition of t h e dominant r61e of agriculture in t h e economy growth - especially e x p o r t oriented
a n d i t s potential a s a n engine of growth
-
t h a t successive plans have given i t t o p priority in public s e c t o r
investment allocation".
This i s clearly shown in Table 1 which gives t h e
p e r c e n t a g e distribution of planned public investment over t h e period from 1970 t o 1983 on a s e c t o r a l basis.
This period also covers t h e Five Year
Plan 1970-1975 which w a s e x t e n d e d t o include 197611977 and t h e Six Year Plan 1977-1 98211 983 t o g e t h e r
with
t h e World
Bank Rolling Investment
Programmes. A c o m m e n t on agricultural i n v e s t m e n t policy is d e e m e d necessary since i t reveals t h e general t r e n d s in policy priorities which have a d i r e c t bearing on t h e growth of t h e agricultural sector.
It c a n b e observed t h a t
investment in t h e agricultural s e c t o r has been very lop-sided.
All invest-
m e n t has been a l l o c a t e d t o t h e modern sub- sector which encompasses t h e mechanized rainfed and t h e irrigated sub- sectors. threshers, combine h a r v e s t e r s t h e process of production.
Inputs such a s t r a c t o r s ,
a n d f e r t i l i z e r s a r e imported and included in Moreover, i n v e s t m e n t in services and infra-
s t r u c t u r e has been c o n c e n t r a t e d mainly in t h e modern s e c t o r while t h e traditional sub- sector has been l e f t out. nology,
animal
traction,
credit
Improvements in biological tech-
facilities,
promotion
of
marketing
and
institutional abilities and o t h e r viable inputs f o r small traditional f a r m e r s have n o t been positively thought of.
The result is obvious.
T h e trad-
itional s e c t o r which supports t h e majority of t h e Sudanese population has been neglected.
I t a p p e a r s t h a t Sudanese development plans manifest a n
application of t h e modernization approaches of t h e 1950's and t h e 1960's which I have reviewed earlier.
The modern s e c t o r enjoys a much b e t t e r -
although n o t a d e q u a t e - s y s t e m of infrastructure, marketing and services a s well a s s o m e a c c e s s t o t h e f r u i t s of a d a p t i v e research and technology. However, t h e rigidity of t h e s t r u c t u r e s within which t h e s y s t e m o p e r a t e s have
placated
t h e irrigated
sector
while weakening t h e incentives t o
farmers. The Structure of Incentives
F a c t o r s related t o inadequacies in transportation, c r e d i t and s t o r a g e have caused f a r m e r s t h e loss of t h e i r c o m m a n d over a substantial proportion of their produce.
As illustrated by Table 2, transportation, marketing and
TABLE I Agricultural Secror Policy Rating: Public Sector lnvesrmenr 1970- 1983
Original Five Year Plan
Amended Five Year Plan
Six Year
Plan
Rolling Programme 1979180-1981/82
Agriculture
38
23
27
28
32
Industry
17
25
16
Infrastructure
20
18
23
Services
20
15
9
6
13
20
Sector
Miscellaneous
I ,
T o t a l planned i n v e s t m e n t (Ls M ) of c u r r e n t prices
Y Source:
A.A. Ali (1984), Adapted f r o m World Bank (1983), Vol. 2.
Rolling Programme 1983184-1985186
TABLE 2 Transportation C o s t s f o r Agricultural Commodities a s a P e r c e n t a g e of Net Value of O u t p u t (Both a t Broader Prices) a
Source:
World Bank (1983), Vol. 3:
b
59)
a = Transportation c o s t f r o m fields t o P o r t Sudan a s a p e r c e n t a g e of FOB cost. b = Figures in b r a c k e t s give t o t a l marketing, distribution and transportation cost.
*
The ratios f o r both t h e traditional and modern sub- sector look comparable, basically because t h e y a r e based on n e t returns. Due t o t h e high c o s t of input in t h e modern sub- sector, r a t i o s based on gross r e t u r n s will be much higher for t h e traditional sub- sector compared t o t h e modern sub- sector.
distribution costs a r e q u i t e substantial.
Another significant point is t h a t
agricultural m a r k e t s a r e drastically segmented especially in t h e rural a r e a s where t h e lower levels of t h e m a r k e t s t r u c t u r e a r e dominated by p e t t y t r a d e r s and t h e absence of marketing boards.
As such t h e s e p e t t y t r a d e r s
and middlemen appropriate vital profits through their monopoly of t h e m a r k e t and their ability t o pay lower prices than t h e floor f a r m g a t e prices declared by t h e government.
The majority of smallholders in t h e
traditional sub- sector a r e entrapped by t h e f a r m e r s g e t less in t i m e s of
shail
system, by which small
need and pay more in t i m e s of plenty.
The modern s e c t o r is slightly b e t t e r d u e t o t h e relatively improved marketing and c r e d i t systems.
Nonetheless, even if w e assume t h a t all
f a r m e r s c a n benefit from a n improved incentive structure, t h e r e is still t h e possibility t h a t t h e s e prices may not align with t h e broader price equivalent,
t h e r e f o r e suggesting a negative
protection for
most crops
e x c e p t wheat and sorghum (Table 3). The World Bank (1983) reported t h a t , " the evidence clearly suggests t h e key r61e of price incentives is encouraging higher yields and output. Therefore, t h e combination of malformed incentives, s t r u c t u r e s and policies must
have
significantly
agricultural sector.
contributed
t o the
present
depression
in
the
The issue of incentives is broader than just considering
prices and t h e r a t e of protection for a given c r o p or crops.
In f a c t i t
r e l a t e s t o t h e macro- economic level of t h e management of t h e economy such a s foreign
t r a d e , exchange r a t e ,
and
monetary policies a s well.
These f a c t o r s have a serious i m p a c t on t h e incentive s t r u c t u r e in respect t o t h e development of t h e agricultural sector.
In order t o bring o u t this
point m o r e clearly, a t t e n t i o n c a n b e drawn t o Sudan's ambitious plan, during t h e 19701s, which c o n c e n t r a t e d on import substitution in agriculture and agro- based commodities such a s sugar,
wheat,
textiles, etc.
The
policies deployed t o achieve t h e s e goals have inflicted considerable damage on t h e economy. order
t o cover
The plan w a s dependent on 5 3 per c e n t foreign loans in the
period f r o m
197711978
component, expected t o be financed mounted
t o 38 per c e n t of
to
198211983.
The local
by c r e d i t from t h e c e n t r a l bank,
t h e t o t a l domestic finance of
t h e plan.
Excessive spending, heavy reliance on foreign borrowing and money printing as a
main source of
finance, a s well a s t h e decay of
t h e existing
TABLE 3 F a r m G a t e , Export (FOB) P r i c e s and Net Production R a t i o s f o r Some Selected Croos (in Ls M) f o r t h e Period from 1975-1 984
cotton Farm Gate Export (FOB) Protection Ratio
388.2 454.0 85.5
714.3 544.0 713.8 821.0 842.0 633.9 1080 1137.9 84.83 85.82 66.1 71.36
900.0 1200 1179.4 1346.5 76.31 89.12
Wheat Farm Gate Export (FOB) Protection Ratio
Farm Gate Export(F0B) Protection Ratio
65 71.6 90.78
65 75 75 85 118 68.5 61.9 49.3 65.9 117.7 94.89 121.16 152.13 128.89 105.64
160 132.7 120.57
71.0 54.0 138.0
51.3 45.8 112.1
48.5 41.5 116.6
80.4 51.3 156.6
84.3 74.3 113.4
180 101.9 176.8
175.3 134.1 130.6
223.19 361.12 209.01 356.55 106.8 101.3
59 159.5 30.1
63 144.2 43.7
60 160.7 37.3
70 206.6 33.9
131.0 300.3 43.6
78 341.4 22.8
263 565.2 46.5
208.03 529.20 39.31
202.03 199.81 254.99 279.91 356.16 422.94 613.16 895.40 1157.5 509.91 527.34 663.17 914.44 924.75 1519.9 1957.9 2735.8 3404.3 39.62 37.89 38.45 30.61 38.51 27.83 31.32 32.73 34.0
Romchts Farm Gate Export (FOB) Protection Ratio
G m Arabic Farm Gate Export (FOB) Protection Ratio
[Net protection ratios a r e c o m p u t e d by taking t h e p e r c e n t a g e of f a r m g a t e prices t o (FOB) export prices a f t e r converting t h e l a t t e r t o nationai c u r r e n c y using t h e official exchange rate].
Sources:
World Bank (1983) Sudan Pricing Policies and S t r u c t u r a l Balances, Vol. 3, Dept. of Agricultural Economics, Ministry of Agriculture: Agricultural P r i c e s in t h e Sudan: An Historical Review and Analysis, 1970-1 984.
i n f r a s t r u c t u r e in t h e modern irrigated s e c t o r led t h e country i n t o a crisis situation.
All t h e s e f a c t o r s h a v e had a negative i m p a c t on t h e country's
economic performance, especially in a situation of a soaring d e b t and high T h e high inflation r a t e t o g e t h e r with t h e over- valuation of
inflation rate.
t h e c u r r e n c y has caused t h e slim incentive s t r u c t u r e t o b e biased against t h e e x p o r t oriented s e c t o r (mainly agriculture) and in favour of t h e nonproductive t e r t i a r y services in t h e urban centres. A s a result of t h e ensuing economic difficulties, t h e government has been f o r c e d t o a c c e p t t h e a c t i v e involvement of multi- national institutions especially t h e IMF and t h e IBRD, in managing t h e economy in r e t u r n for concessionary
loans
and
debt
re- scheduling
arrangements
mediated
or
While t h e *Sudan has missed t h e 1970's
g r a n t e d by t h e s e institutions.
m a r k e t incentives by over - valuing i t s currency, t h e IMF package which c a m e during t h e l a t e 1970's a n d early 1980's has done just t h a t , but under t h e wrong banner.
It is worthwhile t o recall t h a t t h e IMF had t a k e n a
leading r61e by proposing a package f o r economic stabilization, based on c u r r e n c y devaluation.
What concerned t h e agricultural s e c t o r w a s t h a t i t s
very s t r u c t u r e would n o t have given t h e IMF policies a c h a n c e t o succeed (Ali, 1984):
first, improving t h e s t r u c t u r e of incentives t o f a r m e r s w a s a
precondition t o generating growth.
Hence, when t h e pound w a s devalued,
this w a s r e f l e c t e d in t h e floor prices which m e a n t t h a t a sizeable number of
t h e producers could n o t r e a p i t s fruits.
segmentation
of
This i s mainly d u e t o t h e
t h e m a r k e t in t h e traditional sub- sector.
Second, an
a d e q u a t e response on t h e supply side required both initial heavy investment in innovative
technology
and
infrastructure,
and s o m e t i m e b e f o r e an
a d e q u a t e response t o t h e incentives could b e felt.
In short, t h e economic
policies adopted by t h e government at t h a t t i m e have illustrated t h e twin shortcomings of a g g r e g a t e macro- economic measures:
firstly, t o cushion
basic needs, and secondly, t o p r o m o t e a n a d e q u a t e supply response o u t of technologically s t a g n a n t agriculture. Agricultural Technology Prices and Structural Transformation In t h e c a s e of Sudan, w h e r e agriculture is t h e dominant economic activity, t h e process of agricultural t r a n s f o r m a t i o n has t o be financed through t h e t r a n s f e r of agricultural surplus.
The point of contention, however, is w h a t
mechanisms have t o b e a d o p t e d in order t o a f f e c t such a t r a n s f e r and a t
w h a t s t a g e of e c o n o m i c d e v e l o p m e n t t h a t t r a n s f e r is m o s t useful.
Two
c l a s s i c views on t h i s issue c a n b e highlighted here: It is m o s t e s s e n t i a l t o t r a n s f e r c a p i t a l t o a g r i c u l t u r e t o m e e t
1.
a n increasing d e m a n d f o r food a s a r e s u l t of industrialization a n d t h e a c c e l e r a t i n g p r o c e s s of rural/urban migration ( r e f e r t o Eltigani S. Moharned in t h i s volume).
Moreover, i t is a r g u e d
t h a t d u e t o t h e r a t h e r high c a p i t a l o u t p u t r a t i o in a g r i c u l t u r e c a u s e d by t h e diminishing r e t u r n s perceived t o c h a r a c t e r i z e agricultural
production,
these
transfers
may
have
to
be
substantial.
A c o n t r a s t i n g a r g u m e n t c a l l s f o r a s q u e e z e on a g r i c u l t u r e and
2.
net
outflow
of
resources
agricultural sectors, same
diminishing
from
agriculture
to
non-
other
p a r t i c u l a r l y t h e industrial s e c t o r .
marginal
return
hypothesis
is
The
used
to
m a i n t a i n t h a t i n v e s t m e n t will b e relatively higher in t h e nona g r i c u l t u r a l s e c t o r s , which is m o r e favourable, e x i s t e n c e of (1984)
has
interesting
external pointed
due t o t h e Mellor
e c o n o m i e s in t h e s e s e c t o r s .
out
t h a t , "a
c a s e a r i s e s when
much
m o r e c o m p l e x and
technological
change
in
agri-
c u l t u r e sharply i n c r e a s e s r e t u r n s t o i n v e s t m e n t in a g r i c u l t u r e a n d sharply r e d u c e s c a p i t a l o u t p u t ratios". This second a r g u m e n t is based on t h r e e assumptions:
t h e hypothesis
of diminishing marginal productivity in a g r i c u l t u r e , t h e linkage principle, and t h e s e c u l a r decline h yp othesis.
Hirshrnan (1977) d e f i n e s t h e linkage
e f f e c t s of a given p r o d u c t l i n e a s t h e i n v e s t m e n t g e n e r a t i n g f o r c e s t h a t are
set
in
motion
through
input/output
relations.
This
is
so
when
p r o d u c t i v e f a c i l i t i e s t h a t supply i n p u t s t o t h a t line o r u t i l i z e i t s o u t p u t a r e i n a d e q u a t e or non- existent. inpu-t using facilities.
Poor linkages lead t o new i n v e s t m e n t in
Hirshman goes on t o a r g u e t h a t g o v e r n m e n t invest-
m e n t should b e c o n c e n t r a t e d in a c t i v i t i e s w h e r e t h e linkage e f f e c t s a r e greatest, industries.
since
this
would
maximize
indigenous
investment
in
related
I t is t h e n a r g u e d t h a t " agriculture c e r t a i n l y s t a n d s c o n v i c t e d on
t h e a c c o u n t of
i t s l a c k of
d i r e c t s t i m u l u s t o t h e s e t t i n g up of
new
a c t i v i t i e s through linkage e f f e c t s , t h e s u p e r i o r i t y of m a n u f a c t u r i n g in t h i s r e s p e c t is crushing"(Hirshman, 1958).
T h e t h i r d assumption holds t h e view
t h a t i t is t h e s e c u l a r t e n d e n c y f o r t e r m s of t r a d e t o run a g a i n s t c o u n t r i e s
t h a t e x p o r t primary products and import manufactured goods.
From this
i t is maintained t h a t growth through agricultural and o t h e r primary exports is very limited.
Thus t h e emphasis should be placed on t h e import
substitution manufactures. Both diminishing marginal productivity and linkage arguments failed t o t a k e account of t h e i m p a c t of modern technology on f a r m economies.
It
is now well known t h a t agricultural technology has provided g r e a t potential for substantial increases in f a r m productivity through t h e diminishing of capital- output substantial
ratios.
linkages
Also, within
high
and
yielding
outside
the
variety
crops
agricultural
can
create
sector.
For
example, a n enhanced demand for fertilizers and t h e provision of abundant c o s t e f f e c t i v e grains may trigger off investments in chemical and grainintensive livestock industries.
As for t h e secular decline hypothesis, i t is
mainly criticized on t h e grounds t h a t i t is extremely aggregative in nature. It is by no means c l e a r t h a t t h e real price of every tropical commodity has fallen and much of t h e empirical material backing up t h e thesis of t h e secular fall in t h e t e r m s of t r a d e is period specific. L e t us consider t h e c a s e of Sudan a s a n example. agricultural
t e r m s of
period of t i m e in r e c e n t history. 1985,
The a g g r e g a t e
t r a d e h a v e held their ground for a considerable Through t h e period from 1970 t o 19841
Sudan's t e r m s of t r a d e fluctuated around t h e 90 index with t h e
exception of
197511976 when i t fell t o 71 (Brown, 1986;
Bond, 1983).
During t h e period in question, price hikes in key export crops such a s oil seeds and gum a r a b i c mitigated t h e decline in c o t t o n lint prices.
It
follows t h a t a t early s t a g e s of economic growth, a d e q u a t e investment in agricultural technology, research and associated shifters of supply such a s irrigation, human capital and infrastructure, c a n permit resource transfers from agriculture without precipitating negative consequences on t h e sector.
The Record of Surplus Transfers from Sudanese Agriculture A massive extraction of surplus from Sudanese agriculture prevailed since t h e early period of t h e Anglo-Egyptian colonial rule (1898 continued through t h e post- Independence period However,
prior
to
1970,
the
private
until
export
the
capital
-
1956).
This
present dominated
day. the
mechanism of such transfers through i t s control on t h e exports of Sudan's major agricultural crops including t h e s t a t e owned c o t t o n crop.
By 1969,
m e r c h a n t c a p i t a l handled 99.8 per c e n t of Sudan's t o t a l e x p o r t s leaving t h e public s e c t o r with a m e a g r e 0.2
per c e n t of
t h e m a r k e t share.
The
control of t h e private s e c t o r was c o m p l e t e over t h e e n t i r e range of operations in t h e e x p o r t m a r k e t f r o m t h e f a r m g a t e t o t h e export delivery. The Government control w a s limited t o a variety of d i r e c t and indirect t a x e s on domestic and export t r a d e (Sultan, 1986). By 1970, t h e s t a t e sought t o e x e r c i s e m o r e control over t h e export market.
T h e mechanism f o r achieving such control w a s through
establishment boards.
of
an elaborate system
of
agricultural c r o p s
the
marketing
These included t h e Public Corporation for C o t t o n Production and
Marketing (PCPMC), t h e Oil Seeds Marketing Corporation (OMC) and t h e Arabic Company (GAC).
Gum
succeeded
in enhancing
Whether o r not t h e s e p a r a s t a t a l s have
governmental control over t h e e x p o r t of
cultural crops is debatable.
agri-
However, t h e y h a v e certainly succeeded in
providing a much m o r e e f f e c t i v e d e v i c e f o r e x t r a c t i n g agricultural surplus by s e t t i n g floor prices t h a t t u r n t o b e maximum prices for t h e producers. The process of resource t r a n s f e r f r o m agriculture a f f e c t e d through t h e s e p a r a s t a t a l s and
i t s consequences on
t h e economy
can
be analysed a s
follows: 1.
T h e declared objectives of
t h e p a r a s t a t a l s included, among
o t h e r things, a c o m m i t m e n t t o increase e x p o r t surplus through t h e provision of a t t r a c t i v e prices for farmers. practice
of
these
parastatals,
however,
has
The a c t u a l been
o n e of
revenue maximization r a t h e r t h a n of export promotion.
To
test
be
this
claim,
presented
in
the
order
following
empirical
e x a m p l e will
t o model t h e objective function of
a
typical p a r a s t a t a l by noting t h a t n e t revenues from export a r e given by: NR = Q (Pw - P f ) w h e r e NR stands f o r n e t revenues, Q for t h e quantity of exports, P f o r t h e d o m e s t i c o r f a r m g a t e prices, and !$ for
f
t h e e x p o r t (FOB) price.
A revenue maximizing p a r a s t a t a l
would choose P s o a s t o maximize i t s n e t revenue. f M NR = Q (pw solve t h e following problem: By simple
calculus w e g e t t h e first
maximization: -26-
Then t o -
pf]
order conditions for
Multiplying both sides by 'f yields:
Q
Simplifying and denoting t h e revenue maximizing solution by P r , w e get:
w h e r e e is t h e long run e l a s t i ~ i t yof supply with r e s p e c t t o t h e f a r m g a t e price. For a given p
W
and e, t h e p a r a s t a t a l c a n s e t p s o a s t o
maximize revenues since p is on a n increasing function of e ; r a s e g e t s smaller, t h e p a r a s t a t a l c a n reduce p further. f 0.6 f o r gum Assuming a reasonable long t e r m elasticity of arabic, s e s a m e and groundnuts, w e c a n t e s t t h e revenue maximization hypothesis f o r t h e (GAC) a n d (OMC) by comparing t h e hypothetical revenue maximizing prices p t o t h e a c t u a l price r' a t t h e f a r m g a t e - pf for e a c h of t h e above c r o p s (Table 4). Thus i t i s c l e a r t h a t t h e a c t u a l behaviour is closely approxi m a t e d by revenue maximizing behaviour, especially in t h e c a s e s of gum a r a b i c and groundnuts.
Even t h e a c t u a l revenue
t o t h e government from t h e p a r a s t a t a l a t t e s t t o t h e above assumption. 2.
F u r t h e r evidence t o t h e e x t e n t of agricultural surplus t r a n s f e r through t h e p a r a s t a t a l s c a n be judged from Table 3 which provides a profile of t h e d e g r e e of protection f o r s o m e key e x p o r t crops.
These indexes of protection c a n b e used t o
assess t h e e x t e n t and volume of t r a n s f e r s t o and from agriculture.
(a)
T h r e e modes of t r a n s f e r can, t h e r e f o r e , be identified
t h e r e is a massive t r a n s f e r of surplus outside agriculture in t h e c a s e of crops usually produced in t h e traditional sub- sector.
These transfers, in t h e c a s e of gum a r a b i c
TABLE 4 A Profile of Export (FOB) F a r m G a t e and Revenue Maximizing P r i c e s f o r Some P a r a s t a t a l Controlled C r o ~ s .1980- 1984"
Gum Arabic Export (FOB) price P
924.75
1519.9
1957.90
2735.8
3404.3
Actual F a r m G a t e price pf
356.16
422.94
61 3.26
895.40
1157.5
Revenue Maximizing prices p
314.42
51 6.77
665.69
930.17
1 157.46
34 1.4
565.2
-
-
975.0
78.0
263.0
-
-
331.5
1 16.08
192.17
- -
389.37
513.1
689.1
-
1040.0
526
737.14
W
Groundnuts Export (FOB) price p W
Actual F a r m G a t e price pf Revenue Maximizing prices p
Sesame Export (FOB) price p
750
W
Actual F a r m G a t e price p f Revenue Maximizing p r i c e p
260
300
174.45
234.29
*Pr is a derived price given by p run supply elasticity of own price. e
-
0.6
=
421.29 255.0
.
353.6
Pw e w h e r e e i s t h e long l + e T h e calculations a r e based on
and groundnuts,
amount t o about 60 per c e n t of t h e
value of t h e s e t w o crops since their n e t protection ratios a r e less t h a n 40 per c e n t (on average).
According t o
r e c e n t m a t e r i a l collected by t h e author (Elbadawi, 1986), o t h e r crops raised in t h e traditional sub- sector such a s hibiscus,
water
experienced
melon
seeds
and
sesame
would
have
a surplus t r a n s f e r of about 40 per cent.
Although t h e traditional cultivators could
have gained
from sorghum, this gain is likely t o b e very minimal due t o t h e f a c t t h a t most traditional f a r m e r s
in a frag-
m e n t e d m a r k e t d o not benefit from t h e f a r m g a t e prices s e t by t h e parastatal.
It is t h e r e f o r e obvious t h a t t h e
figures of n e t protection probably underscore t h e e x t e n t of
t r a n s f e r s from
this sub- sector.
This is normally
coupled with t h e f a c t t h a t t h e r e a r e very small capital inflows coming t o this sub- sector in t e r m s of investment agricultural inputs. (b)
The high n e t protection r a t i o s for sorghum have induced t h e mechanized rainfed sub- sector t o experience inflows in t h e order of 28 per c e n t of t h e value of sorghum production during t h e period from 1975 t o 1983.
It can
hence b e a s s e r t e d t h a t t h e mechanized rainfed sub- sector is t h e main beneficiary f r o m t h e hikes in sorghum prices since t h e producers in this sub- sector have a c c e s s t o e x p o r t facilities and loans f r o m t h e Agricultural Bank of t h e Sudan (ABS) and o t h e r banks which g u a r a n t e e t h e floor price a s a minimum price. (c)
The irrigated sub- sector dominates t h e production of long staple cotton, sugar cane, w h e a t and o t h e r crops.
This
sub- sector experienced inflows t h a t exceeded 15 per c e n t of t h e t o t a l value of wheat produced during t h e period from 1975 t o 1981.
It also witnessed a substantial out-
flow in t h e groundnut economy which mounted t o 60 per c e n t of i t s value during t h e period from 1975 t o 1981. It is also observed t h a t about 20 per c e n t of t h e value
of
c o t t o n h a s been t r a n s f e r r e d o u t of
during t h e s a m e period.
t h e sub- s e c t o r
T r a n s f e r s o u t of
this sector
w e r e a l s o a f f e c t e d by expensive rehabilitation p r o g r a m m e s provided o r m e d i a t e d by t h e s t a t e . T w o main findings c a n b e gained f r o m t h e a b o v e discussion:
first,
d u e t o t h e s u b s t a n t i a l s h a r e of t h e t r a d i t i o n a l s e c t o r in a g g r e g a t e agric u l t u r a l production (Table 5), n e t t r a n s f e r s o u t of a g r i c u l t u r e w e r e q u i t e s u b s t a n t i a l a n d probably e x c e e d e d 30 per c e n t of t h e t o t a l a g r i c u l t u r a l production in t h e country. of
high
prices
input
Second, c a p i t a l t r a n s f e r s t o a g r i c u l t u r e in t e r m s subsidies
may
not
necessarily
produce
new
T h e r a i n f e d m e c h a n i z e d sub- sector e x e m p l i f i e s t h i s idea.
technologies.
3.
and
T h e f i g u r e s shown in T a b l e 3 d o n o t disclose t h a t t h e surplus e x t r a c t i o n f r o m t h e technologically s t a g n a n t t r a d i t i o n a l subs e c t o r h a s a limit.
T h e l a c k of i n c e n t i v e a n d m o d e r n inputs
p r e c i p i t a t e d e x t r a c t i o n o u t of a g r i c u l t u r e a n d h a s r e s u l t e d in a
continuous d e c l i n e in a g r i c u l t u r a l o u t p u t
period f r o m 1970 t o 1984. t o inadequacies of
throughout t h e
During t h e s a m e period a n d d u e
e x p o r t surplus, earnings o u t of
exports
h a v e declined s u b s t a n t i a l l y d e s p i t e virtually constant e x p o r t prices.
T h e c o n s e q u e n c e s f o r t h e e c o n o m y h a v e been q u i t e
grave.
Besides
the
difficult
macro- economic
problems
e x p e r i e n c e d by t h e c o u n t r y , d e c l i n e s in a g r i c u l t u r a l surplus g r e a t l y diminished t h e r e v e n u e t a p p e d by t h e g o v e r n m e n t and in f a c t f o r c e d t h e s t a t e t o incur c o s t s in subsidising t h e production
of
s t r a t e g i c food
crops
by
the
technologically
i n e f f i c i e n t rainfed m e c h a n i z e d sub- sector. T h e crisis of surplus e x t r a c t i o n e x p e r i e n c e d by t h e s t a t e h a s a l s o been explained by t h e f a i l u r e of t h e s t a t e t o m a i n t a i n c o n t r o l o v e r t h e agric u l t u r a l surplus.
This is mainly d u e t o t h e f a c t of manipulation of t h e
e x p o r t m a r k e t by p r i v a t e e x p o r t c a p i t a l a n d i t s ability t o r e a l i s e a sizea b l e proportion of t h e surplus (Sultan, 1986).
I t is c l e a r t h a t e v e n if t h e
s t a t e w a s a b l e t o r e a l i s e s u c h c o n t r o l o v e r t h e a g r i c u l t u r a l surplus, s o m e s o r t of a crisis could e n s u e unless t h e s t a t e used t h a t surplus t o i n v e s t in a g r i c u l t u r a l supply.
T h e c r u x of t h e discussion i s t h a t t h e mobilization and
t r a n s f e r of surplus f r o m a technologically s t a g n a n t a g r i c u l t u r e is n e i t h e r desirable nor f e a s i b l e a s a long- term policy.
TABLE 5 P e r c e n t a g e of Peasant Production in T o t a l Production of Export Crops, 1977-1 981
Crop -
Crop AV.
NA
Cotton Sorghum
35.81
Millet
100.0
Groundnuts
70.92
Sesame
61.66
Gum Arabic
100.0
Melson Seeds
100.0
Hibiscus
100.0
Average
81.2
Source:
Sultan (1986) compiled f r o m M.O.M. Table 2, p.43 and Table 4, p.45.
Suleiman (19841,
The Relative R6le of Technology and Prices in Agricultural Growth In r e a c t i o n t o t h e low p r i c e s in t h e LDC's, m a n y scholars t r a p p e d in s o m e s o r t of p r i c e ' f u n d a m e n t a l i s m ' .
tend
t h a t i t t a k e s only high p r i c e s in o r d e r t o a c h i e v e high
rates
(Krishna,
for
1984).
To
assure
commensurate
to
T h e impression prices
be
is of
given growth
farmers,
one
indispensible p r i c e s t r a t e g y a l o n e c a n n o t o f f e r a n o p t i m a l solution t o t h e problems of system
of
low a g r i c u l t u r a l growth. agricultural
production
in
For e x a m p l e , under t h e c u r r e n t the
Sudan,
a
long
term
supply
e l a s t i c i t y with r e s p e c t t o a g r i c u l t u r a l t e r m s of t r a d e , is shown as no m o r e t h a n 0.6.
This e s t i m a t e holds f o r highly d e m a n d e d e x p o r t c r o p s s u c h a s
oil seeds.
As such, a m o d e s t t a r g e t r a t e of g r o w t h in a g r i c u l t u r a l pro-
duction of 5 per c e n t would r e q u i r e a n annual i n c r e a s e in a g r i c u l t u r a l t e r m s of
t r a d e throughout t h e period f r o m 1970 t o 1985.
p r e c i p i t a t e serious m a c r o - e c o n o m i c difficulties.
This would
Extending t h i s a r g u m e n t
f u r t h e r , i t c a n b e n o t e d t h a t w i t h t h e c u r r e n t r a t e of population g r o w t h of a b o u t 2.8 per c e n t , a 3 per c e n t a n n u a l i n c r e a s e in food production barely m a i n t a i n s per c a p i t a consumption.
However t h e p r e r e q u i s i t e f o r s u c h a
r a t e t o b e a c h i e v e d under a p u r e p r i c e s e t g r o w t h s t r a t e g y is e i t h e r t h e production of a highly priced food which r e q u i r e s subsidy o r t h e supply of a n impossible food p r i c e f o r t h e urban poor a n d t h e landless a g r i c u l t u r a l labourers in t h e m o d e r n a g r i c u l t u r a l sub- sector.
However, t h e World Bank
(1983) p r o j e c t e d t h a t overall a g r i c u l t u r a l production should grow a t a n annual r a t e of around 5 per c e n t during t h e period f r o m 198211983 t o 198911990. is
very
In t h e light of t h e a b o v e discussion i t b e c o m e s c l e a r t h a t i t difficult
to
achieve
this
target
by
price
policy
alone.
T h e e m p i r i c a l e v i d e n c e of a g r i c u l t u r a l production s u g g e s t s t h a t supply e l a s t i c i t i e s with r e s p e c t t o s h i f t e r s of supply s u c h a s technology, irrigation, c h e m i c a l s , etc.,
t e n d t o b e m u c h higher t h a n p r i c e e l a s t i c i t y .
c a s e s t h e supply e l a s t i c i t y could elasticity
(Krishna, 1984).
In s o m e
be more than three times t h e price
Technological c h a n g e by definition i n c r e a s e s
t o t a l f a c t o r productivity of o t h e r c o n v e n t i o n a l inputs such a s land, labour, and c a p i t a l .
Even a t unchanged o u t p u t and input p r i c e s ( t e r m s of t r a d e ) ,
i t m u s t t h e r e f o r e i n c r e a s e t h e r e t u r n s per u n i t of cost. technological
innovation
(being absolute)
can
add
I t follows t h a t
significantly
to,
and
supplement, a n i n c r e a s e in t e r m s of t r a d e a n d t h u s b e c o m e a s t i m u l u s f o r e c o n o m i c g r o w t h a n d f a c i l i t a t e s t h e t r a n s f e r of a g r i c u l t u r a l surplus a t t h e
s a m e time.
In t h e Sudan t h e d e b a t e has currently focused on t h e r81e of
incentives in achieving agricultural growth.
I t is high t i m e now t h a t
investment in innovative technology and infrastructure equal
importance a s a
m e a n s of
achieving
be accorded a n
rapid agricultural
growth.
The main conclusion t o b e drawn from this paper is t h a t agricultural resources a r e y e t t o b e appropriately tapped in order t o play a leading r81e in promoting economic growth, a s well a s providing a surplus t h a t c a n be utilized t o finance t h e process of agrarian transformation.
Such a
move would eventually f a c i l i t a t e t h e building of a viable agro- industrial economy.
P r i c e incentives coupled
technological generate
innovation
and
other
with
a
associated
t h e agricultural growth necessary
substantial shifters
investment of
supply
in can
f o r a n economic recovery.
References Amin, S.
Transitional Phases in Sub- Saharan Africa, Monthly Review, Vol. 25, No. 5: 52-7, 1973. Accumulation in a World Scale: A Critique of t h e Theory of Development, New York, Monthly Review Press, 1974. Unequal Development: An Essay on t h e Social Formations of Peripheral Capitalism, New York, Monthly Review, 1976.
Ali, A.A.G.
Some Aspects of Sudan Economy, P G Teaching Material, No. 2, DSRC, University of Khartoum, 1984.
Bond, M.E.
Agricultural Responses t o P r i c e s in Sub- Saharan African Countries, IMF Staff Papers, Vol. 30, 1986.
Brown, R.
On t h e Rationale and E f f e c t s of t h e IMF Stabilization Programs, Development Association Conference, Developm e n t Studies, University of E a s t Anglia, Sept. 15th - 19th, 1986.
Eicher a t el (eds)
Agricultural Development in t h e Third World, John Hopkins University Press, 1984.
Elbadawi, I.A.
A n o t e on Pricing a n d Taxation Policies f o r S o m e of Sudan's Key Export C r o p s (in Arabic) A Memo. 1986. Ministry of Planning, Sudan.
Frank, A.G.
T h e Development of Underdevelopment, Monthly Review, 1966.
Hirshman, A.O.
T h e S t r a t e g y of Economic Development, New Havens Yale University Press, 1958. A Generalized Linkage Approach t o Development with Special R e f e r e n c e t o Staples, Economic Development and C u l t u r a l C h a n g e 2 5 (Supp.), 1977: 67-98.
Johnston, B.F. & Mellor, J.W.
The R81e of Agriculture in Economic Development, American Economic Review, Vol. 51, No. 4, 1961.
Jorgensen, D.W.
The Development of Dual Economy, Economic Journal, Vol. 71 (June), 1961 : 309-34.
Krishna, R.
P r i c e and Technology, in C a r l E. Eicher and J. S t a a t z (eds), Agricultural Development in t h e Third World, John Hopkins University Press, 1984.
Lewis, W.A.
Economic Development with Unlimited Supplies of Labour, Manchester P a p e r s in Economic and Social Studies, Vol. 22, NO. 2: 139-91, 1954.
Mellor, J.W
Agricultural Development of Resources, in C a r l K. Agricultural Development Hopkins University Press,
and t h e Intersectoral Transfer Eicher and John M. S t a a t z (eds) in t h e Third World: John 1984.
Ministry of Planning
T h e Six Year Plan, 1977-1983.
Nicholls, W.H.
T h e P l a c e of Agriculture in Economic Development, in Agriculture in Economic Development Car1 K. Eicher (eds), New York, McCraw Hill, 1964.
Schultz, T.W.
Transforming Traditional Agriculture, New Haven, Yale University Press, 1964.
Sultan. P.H.
T h e S t a t e Agrarian Policies a n d P e a s a n t Production, 1970-198418s MA Thesis, University of East Anglia, UK, 1986.
World Bank
Pricing Policies a n d S t r u c t u r a l Balances Vol. 1-3, R e p o r t No. 4528 a-Su. 1983.
ECONOMIC STRATEGY AND HOUSEHOLD VIABILITY I N A D RY SAVANNAH AGRICULTURAL SOCIETY: Berti of Darfur Ladislav Holy According t o their own tradition, t h e original homeland of t h e Berti is t h e Tagabo Hills region in t h e Northern Darfur Province of t h e Republic of the
Sudan.
About 30,000 Berti inhabit this original tribal area.
their neighbours, they a r e Muslims;
Like all
originally they spoke their own lang-
uage which belonged t o t h e Middle Sahara language group and was closest t o t h e Zaghawa, but for several generations now they have spoken only their own dialect of Arabic. The country in which t h e Berti live is a n upland plateau lying at 700 t o 1,000m above s e a level with isolated sandstone and basalt hills rising above i t and culminating in t h e sandstone and volcanic mountains of t h e vast Tagabo Hills range, which reaches a n altitude of 1,500 m. Apart from t h e hills, t h e Berti a r e a consists mainly of s t a b l e old sand dunes with t h e natural vegetation of Acacia rnellifera, Species of
Aristida
thornbush and dry savannah:
A, raddiana, and
A. senegal
and
t h e main t r e e s a r e Boscia
senegalensis.
Eragrostis predominate among t h e grasses.
The
average rainfall during t h e t h r e e month rainy season, which s t a r t s a t t h e beginning of July and lasts until t h e end of September is 200 t o 300 mm. The Berti a r e fully sedentary in small villages, o f t e n consisting of less
than a hundred people.
The village is organised a s a cluster or,
more rarely, a n irregular c i r c l e of individual homesteads. e a c h village is formed by men
The c o r e of
who a r e members of t h e s a m e patrilineal
lineage and a r e usually genealogically close.
Most married couples reside
virilocally, but t h e incidence of uxorilocal residence is high (21.8 per c e n t ) and if husband and w i f e a r e of different lineages, a n uxorilocal marriage is t h e starting point of t h e growth of a new lineage within t h e village which eventually leads t o t h e fission of t h e village along lineage lines. The composition of t h e homestead is a f f e c t e d by t h e f a c t t h a t t h e couple d o not establish their own homestead immediately a f t e r they have been married and s t a r t e d t o cohabit a s husband and wife but only a f t e r t h e husband has completed t h e transfer of parents have agreed t o their daughter
bridewealth and t h e wife's
establishing her own independent
household.
The bridewealth generally t a k e s several years t o pay and t h e
a v e r a g e t i m e between t h e wedding and t h e establishing of t h e couple's own homestead is four years.
During this time, both t h e husband and wife
continue t o live with their n a t a l families and t h e husband visits his wife regularly in her home.
O n e or m o r e children a r e born t o most couples
before t h e y establish their own homestead and a typical Berti household a t t h e t i m e of i t s inception comprises a married couple and their children. As t h e children grow older and s t a r t t o marry, t h e household grows t o comprise
t h e e l e m e n t a r y families of
daughter or daughters.
the
parents
and
those of
their
In t h e final s t a g e of i t s development, a f t e r t h e
married children leave t h e household of. their parents and s e t up their own households,
the
household
is
inhabited
by
a n elderly
married
couple.
The composition of a household which is determined by t h e s t a g e of development i t has reached, is always f u r t h e r modified by natural and social f a c t o r s of procreation o r non- procreation of descendants, by death and by divorce. a f f e c t e d by hold;
It is unusual t h a t relatives whose own household has been
decease or divorce become a t t a c h e d t o an established house-
i t is quite common for a household t o continue in existence a s an
independent unit even when reduced t o a single member and, f o r example, a household in t h e final s t a g e of i t s development typically consists of a widow living on her own.
It happens only rarely t h a t t h e elderly widowed
f a t h e r of e i t h e r t h e husband or wife lives with t h e m in their homestead and even r a r e r a r e t h e c a s e s of s o m e o t h e r of their kinsmen residing 1 permanently with them. Some men, a s t h e y grow older, marry addtional wives.
But t h e r a t e
of polygyny is not high and 80 per c e n t of men have only one wife.
17.6
per c e n t of men have t w o wives, 2.0 per c e n t have t h r e e and only 0.4 per c e n t have four.2 marriages and
A wife is usually opposed t o her husband's subsequent
t h e basically
continuation of this opposition.
hostile relationship between
CO -wives
is a
Open expressions of hostility between co-
wives a r e circumscribed when t h e
CO -wives
live in different villages.
is t h e common p a t t e r n particularly f o r younger men.
This
Only older m e n who
a r e no longer a b l e t o travel regularly between distant villages move t h e household of t h e second wife t o t h e village of t h e first.
Even when
established in t h e s a m e village, a compound family never inhabits a single homestead, e a c h wife having her own. -37-
The husband does not have his own
homestead, but dwells alternatively in those of his wives and i s t h u s a member of several households.
Regular s t a y s and equal participation in
t h e a c t i v i t i e s of e a c h household a r e o t h e r f a c t o r s which prevent t h e outbreak of open conflict between stay
in
his
respective
between them.
CO -wives.
homesteads
T h e duration of a husband's
depends
primarily
on
t h e distance
If t h e y a r e l o c a t e d in villages f a r a p a r t , h e m a y spend up
t o a week o r m o r e in e a c h a t a time.
If t h e y a r e in neighbouring villages
his s t a y in e a c h usually l a s t s t h r e e days;
if t h e y a r e in t h e s a m e village
h e m a y spend only o n e night in each. Each homestead, irrespective of i t s composition, c o n s t i t u t e s a household and a basic unit of production.
The Berti h a v e a mixed economy,
t h e main e l e m e n t of which is hoe cultivation practised on rainfed fields during t h e rainy season. also grown;
The s t a p l e c r o p is millet and a l i t t l e sorghum is
o t h e r cultivated
crops a r e sesame,
water
roselle, cucumbers, pumpkins and occasionally tomatoes.
melons,
okra,
Among utility
plants t h e y grow gourds and, t o a very limited e x t e n t , cotton.
In view of
t h e f a c t t h a t imported c o t t o n and s y n t h e t i c fabrics a r e available in all local m a r k e t s and a r e m o r e p r a c t i c a l and c h e a p t h a n home- woven c o t t o n cloth, c o t t o n cultivation is steadily declining.
Mostly i t is only spun into
t h r e a d used f o r sewing and repairing l e a t h e r bags. T h e second component of Berti economy is animal husbandry. keep c a t t l e , g o a t s a n d sheep;
a r e used f o r riding a n d carrying loads. dogs and poultry.
They
donkeys, c a m e l s and, less frequently, horses O t h e r d o m e s t i c animals include
T h e ' t h i r d i m p o r t a n t sphere of
production has been
traditionally -the collecting of wild growing gum a r a b i c which w a s t h e only r e a l c a s h crop.
Most of t h e g u m yielding t r e e s (Acacia senegal ) died in
t h e s e v e r e drought of t h e e a r l y 1970's;
this, t o g e t h e r with t h e drop in
t h e p r i c e of gum a r a b i c a t international m a r k e t s which led t o i t s low local price, has drasticaliy reduced i t s production which is no longer seen a s profitable by most people. T h e Berti a r e not self- sufficient in t h e i r production;
t h e y depend
heavily on t h e local m a r k e t s and c a s h plays a n i m p o r t a n t r61e in their economy.
It is needed f o r p a y m e n t s of brideweaith, d a m a g e s a n d govern-
m e n t t a x e s a s well a s t o s e c u r e t h e i m m e d i a t e m a t e r i a l existence.
The
Berti h a v e t o buy m a n y products which f o r m t h e basis of daily food and which t h e y d o not grow themselves: -38-
onions, r e d peppers, dried t o m a t o e s ,
salt, sugar and t e a which is consumed in l a r g e quantities, not t o mention dispensable luxury i t e m s like wheat flour, dates, biscuits and sweets, t h e consumption of
which is very low.
Besides footstuffs,
t h e y also buy
commodities produced outside t h e Berti a r e a like cloth, mats, saddles, glass beads,
matches,
and possibly kerosene
for lamps, soap, tobacco,
perfume and recently many m e t a l cooking pots and e n a m e l dishes. Berti also have t o buy local products of individual craftsmen:
Most
pottery,
iron tools and some wooden i t e m s which not everybody produces f o r himself, like stamp- mills, w a t e r troughs f o r livestock, etc. Cash thus plays a n i m p o r t a n t r61e. crops cultivated exclusively f o r cash.
Y e t t h e Berti h a v e no special
In consequence, all cultivated crops
function a s cash crops t o a g r e a t e r or lesser e x t e n t and all domestic animals a r e a source of cash income. T h e Berti pursue their agriculture in a n a r e a which lies well beyond t h e northern border of sufficient humidity for millet cultivation which on the
sandy
soil
is
considered
(Mensching and Ibrahim 1977:
t o correspond
31).
t o t h e 500
mm
isohyet
But t h e sandy soil on which they grow
their crops has t h e capability t o s t o r e almost a l l precipitation t o b e taken up by t h e plants and i t is not so much t h e annual amount of rainfall a s r a t h e r i t s distribution over t i m e which determines a good yield.
Very
heavy rainfalls a s well a s t o o l i t t l e rain c a n adversely a f f e c t t h e millet cultivation.
The annual rainfall c a n b e well above a v e r a g e and t h e crop
fail completely if t h e rainfall is badly distributed over time.
If t h e rains
arrive early in May or J u n e and a r e followed by a prolonged period of dry weather, t h e seeds die or t h e young sprouts wither away.
If t o o l i t t l e
rain falls in t h e period of growth in July and August, t h e millet ripens prematurely giving a small yield. about
Millet needs a cultivation period of
100 days and heavy rains following a t about t w o week intervals
during t h e cultivation period which i r r i g a t e t h e soil t o t h e depth of a t l e a s t 50 c m a r e ideal; of
not
much
light showers which merely irrigate t h e s u r f a c e a r e
use a s t h e soil quickly dries o u t without t h e moisture
penetrating t o t h e plant roots. The Berti a r e a is very sparsely populated.
No figures on population
density a r e available, but according t o t h e author's
rough e s t i m a t e i t
probably does not e x c e e d five or six persons per square kilometre.
In
consequence, t h e Berti do not suffer from any shortage of land.
The
tribal a r e a is divided into lineage territories (haw6kir sg. haklira)and rights over land a r e in t h e hands of sTd (pl. asy6d ) al-hakura
( t h e m a s t e r of t h e
lineage territory) whose office is hereditary and who is a d i r e c t descendant of t h e founder of t h e lineage or lineage s e g m e n t which f i r s t s e t t l e d t h e area.
The lineage t e r r i t o r y is divided into smaller a r e a s called fawiisa
(axes) in which t h e rights over land a r e vested in t h e owner of t h e axe;
sid al-flis
(the
t h e a x e is used for clearing undergrowth f o r new
fields), again a d i r e c t descendant of t h e man who f i r s t s e t t l e d t h e area. Although specific a r e a s a r e seen a s belonging t o specific lineages, lineages a r e not localised and most people live elsewhere than in their lineage territory;
a c c e s s t o land in t h e lineage t e r r i t o r y is open t o a l l irrespective
of their lineage membership a s long a s they give t h e s?d al-fcis
one t e n t h
of t h e harvest a s t i t h e (for a m o r e detailed discussion of rights over land cf. Holy 1974:
37-39, 94-1 05, 179-181).
Since t h e r e is only sparse growth of bushes and t r e e s in t h e savannah, founding a new field is not difficult and a married man by himself c a n c l e a r in a f e w days a large enough piece of land for his f u t u r e household. An established household which has m o r e labour available for t h e task, c a n even m o r e easily found a new field a n y t i m e i t needs it.
A field is
usually cultivated continuously for f i f t e e n t o twenty years but t h e highest yield from i t is e x p e c t e d f o r a f e w years following t h e third or fourth year of i t s establishment. fields of different age.
Heavy o r light rainfall has a different e f f e c t on If t h e rains a r e heavy, a newly established field
gives a b e t t e r yield t h a n a n old one; old field which gives a b e t t e r yield.
if t h e rains a r e only light, i t is an For this reason, new fields a r e
established long before t h e old ones a r e l e f t fallow and e a c h household sows
m o r e land t h a n i t c a n possibly weed and c o n c e n t r a t e s on weeding
t h a t field which, according t o t h e p a t t e r n of t h e rains in t h e given year, c a n b e expected t o give t h e best yield.
It is preferable t o have t h e fields
a s widely separated a s possible, r a t h e r than t o have all land in one block, because t h e rainfall is localised with t h e result t h a t while one field may s t a y dry, another one may g e t sufficiently irrigated.
Even so, a s t h e
rainfall p a t t e r n is only rarely ideal for successful cultivation, t h e r e is t o t a l c r o p failure in s o m e years and bad harvests in several successive years a r e not unusual. Like founding a new field, sowing and harvesting a r e easy tasks. -40-
All
t h e household's fields c a n b e sown by one person in about t w o weeks and in a f e w days if m o r e people d o t h e job;
harvesting is done by women
and again one woman alone is a b l e t o g a t h e r t h e whole harvest since t h e millet ripens gradually over about t w o months. hand, is very strenuous; work:
Weeding, on t h e other
i t is also t h e most important of all agricultural
provided t h a t t h e rains a r e favourable, t h e s i z e of t h e harvest does
not depend on t h e a r e a sown but on how much land has been successfully weeded. weeks.
Weeding begins about a month a f t e r sowing and l a s t s about six It is done by most m e n and women;
children above t h e a g e of
seven or eight also participate, with t h e exception of o n e child of t h a t a g e who s t a y s a t home, guards t h e house and, if a girl, s e e s t o t h e domestic tasks, especially t h e brewing of beer.
Those who weed d e p a r t
for t h e fields between eight and t e n o'clock in t h e morning;
in t h e a f t e r -
noon t h e y r e s t for t w o t o four hours, and t h e y r e t u r n f r o m t h e fields before sunset a t about six o'clock.
It is not possible t o influence t h e size
of t h e harvest by extending t h e weeding period a s any weeding carried o u t l a t e r t h a n about t w o and half months a f t e r sowing is useless.
By t h a t
t i m e t h e grass is so high and t h e millet competing with i t so stunted t h a t i t could not ripen even if t h e grass w e r e removed. The Berti e s t i m a t e t h a t a n adult person is a b l e t o weed about 4 h e c t a r e s (ha) of
land during t h e season.
T o weed t h a t much is also
essential for securing t h e long t e r m subsistence needs of t h e household, for t h e Berti e s t i m a t e t h a t a couple with t h r e e or four small children must weed about 7.6 h a e a c h year t o avoid buying grain f r o m t h e m a r k e t in years of poor harvest or t o t a l c r o p failure;
this e s t i m a t e corresponds
exactly t o my own calculation based on recording household consumption and production over f i v e years.3 180 hours;
To weed 4 ha t a k e s on a v e r a g e about
this means t h a t i t c a n be achieved by weeding approximately
five hours e a c h working day during t h e weeding season, on t h e f a c e of i t not a n impossible task t o achieve considering t h a t people spend on a v e r a g e about eight hours in t h e field on a n ordinary working day and about t h r e e hours
on
Mondays.
But
most
people
Not all Berti weed equally intensively.
weed
less
than
that.
How much weeding a person
does during a cultivation season depends not only on his or her age, ability and e f f o r t but also on how many days h e or s h e will lose through searching for s t r a y and stolen animals, through observation of mourning following t h e
d e a t h of a close kinsman or through attending indispensible rituals. intensity of weeding also varies between good and bad rainy
The
reason^.^
If
t h e rainy season has been progressing well, more weeding is done in anticipation of a good harvest.
If t h e rains a r e poor and a good harvest
not expected t h e n people a r e inclined t o consider weeding a futile effort. How any given rainy season is perceived, of course, differs f r o m person t o person and this results in s o m e considerable variation in t h e e f f o r t with which different households a t t e n d t o t h e weeding of their fields.
Taking
into consideration all t h e s e f a c t o r s which in o n e way or another a f f e c t t h e decision on how much land is weeded, t h e figures concerning t h e average amount of land weeded by o n e producer have t o b e t r e a t e d a s nothing more t h a n approximations which level o u t all existing individual variability. Even so, they nevertheless indicate t h e different emphasis put on agric u l t u r e by wealthy and poor households. Over
the
five
years (1975-1979)
for
which
t h e author
collected
necessary quantitative d a t a 5 , t h e a v e r a g e a m o u n t of land weeded by one producer w a s 2.07
ha, i.e.,
reasonably b e weeded.
about half of what t h e Berti e s t i m a t e c a n
An individual producer from a
Imabsct) weeded on a v e r a g e 1.36 h a
6
,
rich household
a producer from a comfortable house-
hold ( shabaho) 2.32 ha and a producer from a poor household (rniskin) 2.17ha. More detailed d a t a about t h e a v e r a g e amount of land weeded by one producer a r e given in Table 1.
TABLE 1 The Average Amount of t h e Householdls Own Land Weeded by O n e Producer (Measured in Hectares) Average
1975
1976
1977
1978
1979
1.77
1.26
0.91
1.51
1.46
1.36
2.82
1.97
1.82
2.52
2.42
2.32
Poor households
2.52
1.92
1.61
2.12
2.12
2.07
All households
2.52
1 .X2
1.56
2.22
2.17
2.07
Rich households Shabaha households
*
shabaha
means comfortably off households -42-
Considering t h a t m o s t Berti weed much less than what is perceived a s t h e minimum a m o u n t of land t o be weeded t o achieve t h e household's viability and w h a t is considered t o b e t h e amount of land which can reasonably b e weeded by a n able- bodied producer, i t is not surprising t h a t about half of all households fail t o produce grain sufficient for t h e i r own subsistence.
Only half of t h e households produce enough grain in t h e
years of good harvests t o t i d e t h e m over t h e years of poor or disastrous harvests and, over t h e f i v e y e a r s during which production and consumption had been recorded, produced enough grain for their own subsistence.
The
29 households in t h e a u t h o r ' s sample a r e arranged in Table 2 according t o
overall
agricultural
performance
over
the
five
years.
This
varied
enormously from household t o household and while a t o n e end of t h e scale t h e r e is a household which in t h e five years taken together produced less than half t h e amount of grain which i t consumed, a t t h e o t h e r end of t h e s c a l e t h e r e is a household which over t h e s a m e period had a surplus of grain of 53 per c e n t over i t s consumption requirements. Productive efficiency c o r r e l a t e s with t h e ratio of household consumers t o producers (C/W ratio; of workers:
t h e number of consumers divided by t h e number 7 Chayanov 1966) although t h e c h a n c e t h a t a household with a
C/W r a t i o between 1 and 2 will underproduce o r m e e t i t s consumption requirements is approximately equal.
A high C/W r a t i o r e f l e c t s a high
relative proportion of consumers, typically many children, and i t is chara c t e r i s t i c of most households during t h e f i r s t s t a g e in their developmental cycle.
Of t h e 14 households which w e r e self sufficient in grain in t h e
long run or produced a surplus, four had a C/W r a t i o of 1 , nine had a n average C/W r a t i o between 1 and 2 during t h e five years, and only one had a n a v e r a g e r a t i o of 2.
Of t h e 15 households which regularly under-
produced, only one (No. 15) had a C/W r a t i o of 1;
this household was
a b l e t o produce almost a s much a s i t consumed over t h e f i v e years.
Six
households had a n a v e r a g e r a t i o higher than 2 during t h e f i v e years (some in f a c t a s high a s 4.3) and t h e remaining 8 all had a n a v e r a g e C/W ratio between 1 and 2. The Berti a r e well a w a r e of t h e hazards of rainfall and a prudent household aims a t having a supply of grain a d e q u a t e for a t l e a s t t w o years;
s o m e households have a supply of grain t o last t h e m up t o four
years o r even longer.
The grain is stored in underground pits in which i t
Sample Households
No.
status1)
~nirnal') Wealth
~~ricultural~) Production
c/w4'
I
P
2.64
-53%
2.7
2
P
1.21
-40%
2.6
28
S
6.34
+33%
1.0
29
S
3.43
+53%
2.0
I) 2) 3) 4) 5) 6)
weedlngS'
erd din^^)
Ratio
+
P - poor, S -shataha, R = r ~ c h The flgure ~ndlcatesthe average slze of the household's anfmal holdings durlng the census p e r ~ o d expressed In l~vestockunits. The rate by which the household has fallen short of or exceeded its millet consumption needs over the census per~od. The household's average C/W rat10 durlng the census per~od. + employs labour for weeding; - = weeds for cash. + - employs herdsmen; - = prov~desherdsmen for other households.
c a n b e k e p t f o r a s long a s f i v e years without any loss t o insects and without d e t r i m e n t t o i t s quality.
T h e s t r a t e g y of most households is t o
consume t h e old grain and t o s t o r e t h e new, whenever possible, keeping t h e grain pits perpetually full.
The regular turnover of grain i s also
achieved by lending i t in small quantities t o neighbours own and who r e t u r n fresh grain a f t e r t h e harvest.
who lack their
No i n t e r e s t i s charged
on such loans a s t h e freshness of t h e returned grain i s considered a s sufficient payment.
It is, however, only a minority of households which
m a n a g e t o maintain a n a d e q u a t e supply of grain in their s t o r a g e pits over t h e years.
These a r e households which succeed in producing a reasonable
a m o u n t of grain in good y e a r s t o t i d e t h e m over t h e bad ones.
Of t h e
29 census households, only nine (Nos. 21-29) f a l l i n t o this category.
All
of t h e m h a v e a low C/W r a t i o averaging 1.k f o r t h e c a t e g o r y a s a whole and varying between 1 and 2 among individual households.
Two of t h e s e
nine households a r e poor in t e r m s of livestock, t h e remaining seven a r e considered e i t h e r shabaha (comfortable) o r rich, although typically none of t h e richest households falls i n t o this category:
of t h e six households in
t h e s a m p l e classified a s rich, i t is only t h e t w o least rich o n e s which over t h e f i v e years h a v e produced a surplus over t h e i r subsistence needs. significant t h a t a l l t h e seven
shabaha
It is
o r rich households employ wage
labour t o produce t h e i r agricultural surplus.
They pursue w h a t t h e Berti
generally consider t o b e t h e best economic strategy:
this is t o build up a
reasonable supply of grain, investing available cash i n t o hiring labour f o r weeding and with a n a d e q u a t e supply of grain t o l a s t f o r s e v e r a l y e a r s t o invest t h e surplus c a s h into livestock.
T h e t w o poor households in this
c a t e g o r y d o n o t have enough s p a r e c a s h t o employ hired labour but they a r e also not in such a d e s p e r a t e need f o r c a s h a s t o b e f o r c e d t o weed themselves f o r p a y m e n t a s m o s t poor households a r e (four o u t of seven poor households in t h e sample).
T h e r e l a t i v e prosperity of t h e households
in this c a t e g o r y is indicated by t h e f a c t t h a t of t h e seven m a l e household heads (households No. 22 and 28 a r e headed by women), f i v e a r e polygynists (Nos. 21, 23, 24, 26 and 29). Most households in this c a t e g o r y regularly m a r k e t their livestock and usually sell grain in small quantities t o c o v e r their c u r r e n t household expenses.
Although s o m e of
t h e m a r e forced
t o buy grain a f t e r a
succession of bad y e a r s when t h e i r own supply has run low, they d o not depend on regular purchases of grain f r o m t h e market. -45-
This enables t h e m
t o m a r k e t t h e i r animals advisedly a t a r a t e which does not jeopardise t h e growth of t h e i r animal wealth, or, depending on their m o m e n t a r y supply of grain, e v e n t o sell a g r e a t e r quantity of i t a f t e r a successful harvest t o reduce t h e i r o f f t a k e of livestock in a n e f f o r t t o increase t h e growth r a t e of t h e i r herds.8
T h e differences in t h e volume of a c t u a l o f f t a k e between 9 rich and poor a r e , of course, considerable. In t e r m s of livestock units ,
t h e a v e r a g e annual o f f t a k e f r o m t h e t w o rich households r e p r e s e n t s 15.2 per c e n t .
In r e a l t e r m s i t m e a n s a n a v e r a g e s a l e of 2.75 head
of c a t t l e
(worth LS 550 a t t h e a v e r a g e 1980 prices10) per household f r o m a h e r d of 13.5 c a t t l e ( o f f t a k e of 20.4 per cent), of 1.5 g o a t s (worth LS 18.75) per household f r o m a herd of 17.5 g o a t s ( o f f t a k e of 8.6 per c e n t ) and of 0.75 sheep (worth LS 37.50) per household f r o m a herd of l I s h e e p ( o f f t a k e of T h e a v e r a g e annual o f f t a k e f r o m t h e herds of t h e five
6.8 per cent).
s h a b a h a households r e p r e s e n t s 14.7 in t e r m s of livestock units. t e r m s i t means a n a v e r a g e s a l e of 1.1 head
In real
of c a t t l e (worth LS 220) per
household from a herd of 5.8 c a t t l e ( o f f t a k e of 19 per cent), of 3.4 g o a t s (worth LS 42.50) per household f r o m a herd of 20 g o a t s ( o f f t a k e of 17 per c e n t ) a n d of 1.1
sheep (worth LS 55) per house from a herd of 13.6 sheep
( o f f t a k e of 8.1 per cent).
In t e r m s of livestock units, t h e a v e r a g e annual
o f f t a k e f r o m t h e t w o poor households i s only 2.1 per cent.
In r e a l t e r m s
i t r e p r e s e n t s a s a l e of o n e g o a t (worth LS 12.50) f r o m 2 per household ( o f f t a k e of 50 per cent). T h e agricultural production of households Nos. 14-20 is m o r e o r less a d e q u a t e f o r their subsistence needs.
This c a t e g o r y includes households
which h a v e achieved a surplus n o t exceeding 10 per c e n t a b o v e their subsistence requirements over t h e five years, a s well a s households whose overall agricultural production does n o t fall below 90 per c e n t of their subsistence needs.
T h e l a t t e r households f a l l short of t h e i r ideal sub-
sistence requirements s o slightly t h a t a possible s h o r t a g e of millet c a n be easily compensated f o r by slightly reduced consumption o r c a r e f u l household m a n a g e m e n t without a f f e c t i n g t h e i r consumption profile in any conside r a b l e way.
Virtually all t h e s e households depend on regular purchase of
grain in years of c r o p failure; s o m e grain in
years of
covering
necessary expenditure.
their
good
on t h e o t h e r hand, t h e y a r e a b l e t o m a r k e t harvest
t o realise t h e c a s h needed for In
consequence,
their d o m e s t i c
economy varies considerably f r o m y e a r s of good harvests t o years of c r o p failure.
The less successful agricultural performance of t h e households in this c a t e g o r y c o r r e l a t e s postively with their higher C/W r a t i o which averages 1.5 f o r t h e category a s a whole and varies between individual households. rich, t h r e e a r e shabaha
1 and 1.9 among
Two of t h e seven households in this c a t e g o r y a r e and t w o a r e poor.
Both rich households employ
wage labour for weeding their fields in addition t o their own labour, one of t h e poor households (No. 15) uses i t s labour t o weed others' fields for cash. The differences in t h e o f f t a k e from t h e herds of rich and poor households a r e again considerable.
In t e r m s of livestock units, t h e average
annual o f f t a k e from t h e t w o rich households is 11.6 per cent. t e r m s i t represents a n a v e r a g e s a l e of 2.75 head
In real
of c a t t l e (worth LS 550)
per household from a herd of 20 c a t t l e ( o f f t a k e of 13.75 per c e n t ) and of 11.5 g o a t s (worth LS 143.75) per household from a herd of 96 goats (offt a k e of 12 per cent). three
shabaha
units.
The a v e r a g e annual o f f t a k e from t h e herds of t h e
households represents 18.1 per c e n t in t e r m s of livestock
In real t e r m s i t means a n average s a l e of 1.3 head
of c a t t l e
(worth LS 260) per household f r o m a herd of 6.5 (offtake of 20.5 per cent) of 3.2 g o a t s (worth LS 40) f r o m a herd of 15.3 goats (offtake of 20.6 per c e n t ) and of 0.7 sheep (worth LS 33) from 1 per household (offtake of 70 per cent).
In t e r m s of livestock units, t h e average annual o f f t a k e from
t h e t w o poor households is 14 per cent.
In real t e r m s i t represents an
average s a l e of 0.25 cows (worth LS 50) from 1.75 per household (offtake of 14.3 per c e n t ) and of 1.5 g o a t s (worth LS 18.75) per household from a herd of 9 (offtake of 16.7 per cent). Households 1-13 consistently fail t o produce enough millet for their subsistence needs.
Not only d o they not have any millet t o m a r k e t , but
they have t o buy millet regularly, o f t e n in considerable quantities, in years of
poor harvests.
Their domestic economy hardly changes from
years of good harvests t o those of bad ones:
they do not sell grain in
bulk in either of t h e s e years and a t most sell grain in small quantities in good y e a r s t o realise c a s h for t h e purchase of o t h e r commodities from t h e m a r k e t (typically food which t h e Berti do not produce themselves).
Their
poor agricultural performance again positively c o r r e l a t e s with their shorta g e of labour for weeding: a whole is 2.15;
t h e average C / W r a t i o for t h e category a s
i t varies f r o m 1.2 t o 4.3 among individual households.
Moreover, six of t h e 13 households in this c a t e g o r y use t h e i r labour t o weed f o r cash (fourof t h e six households weeding f o r cash a r e poor ones, only t w o households employ hired labour for weeding
t w o a r e shabaha ); (one
of
them
is
a
rich
one,
the
other
one
is shabaha).
In t e r m s of livestock units, t h e a v e r a g e annual o f f t a k e f r o m t h e herds of t h e t w o rich households in this c a t e g o r y i s 9.9 per cent. i t r e p r e s e n t s a n a v e r a g e sale of 3.5 head
In real t e r m s
of c a t t l e (worth LS 700) per
household f r o m a herd of 42 heads of c a t t l e ( o f f t a k e of 8.3 per cent), of 17.5 g o a t s (worth LS 219) per household f r o m a herd of 49 g o a t s ( o f f t a k e of 35.7 per c e n t ) and of 4.5 sheep (worth LS 225) per household f r o m a herd of 5 5 ( o f f t a k e of 8.2 per cent). herds of t h e eight stock units.
shabaha
T h e a v e r a g e annual o f f t a k e f r o m t h e
households is 22.3 per c e n t in t e r m s of live-
In r e a l t e r m s i t r e p r e s e n t s on a v e r a g e a s a l e of 1 head of
c a t t l e (worth LS 200) f r o m 5.4 per household ( o f f t a k e of 19.5 per c e n t ) , of g o a t s (worth LS 125) per household f r o m a herd of 33.3 ( o f f t a k e of 30.6 per c e n t ) and of 0.2 sheep (worth LS 10) f r o m 3.7 sheep per household ( o f f t a k e of 4.9 per cent).
In t e r m s of livestock units t h e annual o f f t a k e
f r o m t h e herds of t h e t h r e e poor households represents 20.6 per c e n t . r e a l t e r m s i t means on a v e r a g e a s a l e of 0.3
head
In
of c a t t l e (worth
LS 66) f r o m 1.2 head. of c a t t l e per household ( o i f t a k e of 28.4 per c e n t ) and of 3.8 g o a t s (worth LS 47.50) per household from a herd of 14.3 g o a t s ( o f f t a k e of 26.7 per cent). T h e information a b o u t a n i m a l o f f t a k e of t h e d i f f e r e n t c a t e g o r i e s of households and their a v e r a z e income f r o m t h e s a l e of livestock is summarised in Table 3. O f f t a k e r a t e s of
t h e poor and
shabaha
households consistently
c o r r e l a t e negatively with t h e d e g r e e of a household's success in agricultural production:
t h e less grain a household produces, t h e higher is i t s
expenditure over a n d a b o v e t h a t on o t h e r necessary commodities.
I t also
has t o purchase grain f r o m t h e m a r k e t and t h e necessary c a s h has t o be realised through t h e s a l e of livestock.
As f a r a s t h e o f f t a k e r a t e s a r e
concerned t h e rich households s e e m t o d e v i a t e from t h e p a t t e r n displayed by poor and and
shabaha
shabaha
households.
Although t h e o f f t a k e r a t e of t h e poor
households is higher t h a n t h a t of t h e rich ones, a s h a b a h a
household m a r k e t s only about a third of animals brought t o m a r k e t by a rich household and only a f e w animals a r e actually m a r k e t e d by poor
households b e c a u s e of t h e s m a l l s i z e of t h e i r herds.
T h e bigger t h e herd,
t h e s m a l l e r n e e d s t o b e t h e o f f t a k e t o r e a l i s e a s p e c i f i c s u m of money. For
this
reason,
e f f e c t of
the actual
income from
livestock s a l e s i n d i c a t e s t h e
t h e d e g r e e of a g r i c u l t u r a l s u c c e s s on a n i m a l w e a l t h probably
better than t h e offtake rate.
T h e c a s h i n c o m e of t h e t h r e e c a t e g o r i e s of
households consistently c o r r e l a t e s negatively w i t h t h e d e g r e e of t h e household's s u c c e s s in a g r i c u l t u r a l production.
I t is, n e v e r t h e l e s s , t h e o f f t a k e r a t e which a f f e c t s t h e g r o w t h of t h e Given t h a t t h e r e is a l w a y s a n a t u r a l w a s t e of a n i m a l s through
herd.
disease, loss o r t h e f t , a herd of c a t t l e is likely t o grow if t h e annual offt a k e d o e s n o t e x c e e d a p p r o x i m a t e l y 20-25 p e r c e n t a n d a h e r d of g o a t s and s h e e p if t h e o f f t a k e d o e s n o t e x c e e d a p p r o x i m a t e l y 30-35 per c e n t . D u e t o t h e l a r g e s i z e of t h e i r herds, t h e a n i m a l o f f t a k e of rich households i s well below t h e s e c r i t i c a l levels:
of
t h e six rich households in t h e
sample, only o n e had a c r i t i c a l l y high o f f t a k e f r o m i t s herd of c a t t l e and a n o t h e r o n e f r o m i t s h e r d of goats.
Of t h e 16 shabaha
households, nine
had a n o f f t a k e a b o v e t h e c r i t i c a l l e v e l (in f o u r households t h e o f f t a k e of c a t t l e e x c e e d e d t h e c r i t i c a l level, in t h r e e households t h e o f f t a k e of g o a t s a n d in t w o households both t h e o f f t a k e of c a t t l e and goats).
Of t h e seven
poor households, f i v e m a r k e t e d a n i m a l s and t h e o f f t a k e f r o m g o a t s a s well a s c o w s of all t h e s e f i v e households w a s a b o v e t h e c r i t i c a l level.
The
r e s u l t of t h e c o m p a r a t i v e l y s m a l l o f f t a k e f r o m t h e h e r d s of rich households is t h a t t h e i r a n i m a l w e a l t h c o n t r a s t , t h e a n i m a l w e a l t h of remained t h e same;
h a s been perpetually increasing.
shabaha
In
households t a k e n t o g e t h e r has
hidden behind t h i s s t a b i l i t y of t h e c a t e g o r y a s a
whole is, however, a n upward a n d downward m o v e m e n t of individual households.
In s p i t e of
t h e l a r g e a n i m a l o f f t a k e of
poor households, t h e i r
o v e r a l l a n i m a l w e a l t h h a s been slightly increasing;
t h i s is mainly d u e t o
t h e redistribution of a n i m a l s f r o m rich t o poor households (cf. p 60 While
it
is
the
level
of
the
household's
success
in
).
agricultural
production which d e t e r m i n e s w h e t h e r i t s a n i m a l w e a l t h will grow, r e m a i n c o n s t a n t o r d e c r e a s e , i t is, on t h e o t h e r hand, t h i s a n i m a l w e a l t h itself t h a t c r i t i c a l l y d e t e r m i n e s t h e household's o v e r a l l e c o n o m i c p e r f o r m a n c e . T h e a v e r a g e annual i n c o m e of a rich household f r o m t h e s a l e of livestock is LS 814;
such i n c o m e is s u f f i c i e n t f o r c o v e r i n g a l l expenses, including
t h e h i r e of w a g e labour f o r weeding. -50-
It is a l s o high enough t o e n a b l e t h e
rich household t o purchase a n y grain i t needs from t h e market.
Because
t h e rich households h a v e enough animals t o b e a b l e t o realise a l l t h e necessary cash through t h e s a l e of
livestock without d e t r i m e n t t o t h e
growth of their herds, t h e level of their agricultural performance is basically irrelevant t o their viability. The average annual income from livestock sales of shabaha households is only about 40 per c e n t of t h a t of rich households (LS 332) and t h e income of poor households is on a v e r a g e only LS 72. and most
For poor households
shabaha households, t h e s a l e of livestock does n o t realise all t h e
cash t h e y need t o cover their expenses and t h e y depend o n o t h e r sources of cash income t o sustain their viability. The most widespread method of earning cash is t h e s a l e of grass for animal fodder.
The grass is c u t in t h e dry season when t h e r e is no work
t o be done in t h e fields and i t is transported on c a m e l s t o l a r g e m a r k e t c e n t r e s around which t h e r e is no grazing.
I t is sold in bulk t o middlemen
who re-sell i t with profit in small quantities. holds, 22 were participating in t h e grass trade.
Of t h e 29 census houseC u t t i n g t h e grass does
not t a k e long but i t is t h e journey t o t h e m a r k e t which is t i m e consuming: i t c a n t a k e four days or even longer t o c o m p l e t e t h e return journey t o t h e market.
In consequence, i t is not worthwhile travelling with just one
c a m e l load and those who intend t o sell grass hire additional c a m e l s for t h e journey.
They c u t t h e grass themselves and they divide between them-
selves and t h e owner of t h e c a m e l t h e money for which t h e grass had been sold.
As a rule, i t is men and women from poor and
shabaha
households who travel with grass t o t h e market, hiring additional c a m e l s from rich or shabaha households.
Poor householders who d o n o t have their
own c a m e l s use only hired ones.
As t h e price of grass has risen sharply
in r e c e n t years, i t s s a l e has been seen a s a m o r e lucrative source of cash income
than any o t h e r and several household heads who did not own
c a m e l s before, bought t h e m during t h e past t w o years mainly t o be a b l e t o use t h e m t o transport grass
11
.
The purchase of c a m e l s is one of t h e
reasons for t h e high o f f t a k e from t h e herds of cows mentioned before: most men who lately bought c a m e l s sold t w o heads of c a t t l e t o raise t h e necessary money. Of t h e seven poor households only t w o d o not sell grass (neither of the s e t w o households has a camel).
All t h e remaining five d o ( t w o use only -51-
hired
camels
and
three
hired
camels
in
addition
to
Of t h e 16 shabaha households s e v e n d o n o t sell grass;
their
own).
t h r e e of t h e s e
seven, however, p a r t i c i p a t e in t h e g r a s s t r a d e by lending t h e i r c a m e l s t o others.
Three
shabaha
households sell grass using only t h e i r own c a m e l s
for transporting i t t o t h e m a r k e t , six use both t h e i r own c a m e l s a s well a s hired ones. Of
t h e six rich households, o n e sells g r a s s (No. 17 - c f . N o t e 6) Four o t h e r rich households lend t h e i r
besides lending i t s c a m e l s t o others.
c a m e l s t o o t h e r s and only o n e d o e s not p a r t i c i p a t e in t h e g r a s s t r a d e a t all. T h e highest annual income f r o m t h e s a l e of t h e g r a s s achieved by a household using i t s own and hired c a m e l s w a s LS 429.75 (i.e., t h e p r i c e of t w o cows);
more than
t h e highest income a household had f r o m lending
i t s c a m e l w a s LS 196 (approximately e q u a t i n g t h e p r i c e of a cow). a v e r a g e income figures a r e , of annual income of
a
course, lower t h a n t h a t :
the average
rich household participating in t h e g r a s s t r a d e is
shabaha household
LS 68.45, of a
The
LS 115.85 and of a poor household
LS 105.05. Another c a s h e a r n i n g a c t i v i t y similar t o t h e s a l e of g r a s s is t h e s a l e of rock s a l t e x c a v a t e d in t h e d e s e r t .
The m e n d e p a r t f o r t h e rock s a l t
deposits in winter o r i m m e d i a t e l y a f t e r t h e rainy season when t h e c a m e l s are fittest
f o r t h e journey which t a k e s a b o u t a month t o c o m p l e t e .
again m e n f r o m poor o r
I t is
shabaha households who e n g a g e in t h i s e n t e r p r i s e .
Each m a n t r a v e l s usually with 10 c a m e l s , of which o n e is his own, if he has one, and t h e remaining nine hired.
I t is t h e responsibility of t h e
owner of t h e c a m e l t o supply t h e l e a t h e r bags in which t h e rock s a l t will b e brought and t o fill t h e m with g r a s s with which t h e c a m e l will b e fed on t h e journey.
A c a m e l , depending on i t s a g e , c a r r i e s f r o m 180 t o 230kg
of rock s a l t w o r t h f r o m LS 30 t o LS 100 depending on t h e t i m e and place of i t s marketing. pays f r o m LS 4.50
T h e rock s a l t belongs t o t h e owner of t h e c a m e l who t o LS 6.00 (depending on t h e s i z e of t h e load t h e
c a m e l c a r r i e s ) t o t h e m a n who brought t h e s a l t .
This m e a n s t h a t a man
without his own c a m e l e a r n s b e t w e e n LS 45 and LS 60 f r o m a t r l p t o t h e rock s a l t deposits;
a m a n travelling with his own c a m e l e a r n s f r o m LS 70
t o LS 130, depending on t h e . a g e of t h e o t h e r nine c a m e l s h e is leading and on t h e t i m e and p l a c e of m a r k e t i n g his salt. -52-
This is approximately
equal t o what c a n b e earned from selling grass. t o t h e m a r k e t usually with t w o camels.
The grass seller travels
If both a r e hired, h e earns from
LS 35 t o LS 90 in a month, depending on t h e t i m e of t h e year;
a man
travelling with his own and o n e hired c a m e l e a r n s between LS 50 and LS 135.
Selling grass is, however, f a r less arduous t h a n a winter t r i p into
t h e d e s e r t which is t h e reason why many m o r e people prefer selling grass t o selling rock salt. A f e w men e a r n cash by hunting gazelle and selling i t s dried m e a t , by drawing w a t e r for local schools or working a s school caretakers.
An
occasional source of c a s h income is short - term wage employment in large m a r k e t c e n t r e s or short- term labour migration t o Eastern Darfur, usually t o harvest peanuts.
A f e w m e n who have a t t e n d e d Koranic schools and
reputedly have learnt t h e Koran by heart, a r e recognised a s fugara (sg. holyman) (households Nos. 1 1 and 12 in t h e sample).
faki, income
from
writing
amulets,
performing
divination
They obtain and
healing.
The money earned from t h e sale of livestock, surplus millet, o r other cash eaning activities mentioned, is used by t h e household head t o buy clothing for a l l members of his family and t o buy sugar and tea.
The
cash a t his disposal is f u r t h e r used t o pay hired labourers, if t h e r e a r e any, t o buy grain in bulk if t h e household has a shortage, possibly t o buy additional animals, and t o pay government taxes, damages, his sons' bridewealth a s well a s bridewealth
for his own additional marriages.
Apart
from buying sugar and t e a , a household head has nothing t o d o with t h e day-to-day management of t h e household which is t h e responsibility of his wife.
She herself has t o provide t h e cash which she needs f o r t h e day- to-
day running of t h e household, in particular f o r t h e purchase of foodstuffs which t h e Berti e i t h e r d o not produce themselves or which t h e household may not have produced in sufficient quantity (like dried m e a t , butter, oil or okra).
To make t h e necessary purchases in t h e market, t h e woman who
is in c h a r g e of t h e domestic management of t h e household, usually sells a small amount of millet in t h e form of grain, flour or millet beer, okra, sesame, melons, pumpkins, eggs or any other produce of which she has a surplus in t h e marker. In Table 4, a household's a v e r a g e income from t h e s a l e of livestock is compared
with i t s
income
from
all o t h e r
-53-
sources
mentioned.
A
household's income f r o m t h e woman's s a l e of surplus produce has not been considered a s i t w a s technically impossible t o record all women's p e t t y transactions which go on csntinuously.
In poor households with little
income f r o m t h e s a l e of livestock o r o t h e r sources, i t is basically t h e woman's income on which t h e household economy depends in i t s day- to- day management.
While
the
woman's
income
may
be a d e q u a t e
for
the
purchase of food f r o m t h e m a r k e t , i t is, however, never sufficient f o r t h e purchase of
clothing,
sugar,
tea,
grain, tools and implements a n d for
payment of t a x e s and bridewealth, which in t h e i r t o t a l r e p r e s e n t t h e major expenditure of e v e r y household.
In this respect, leaving o u t t h e house-
hold's income f r o m t h e woman's p e t t y m a r k e t transactions d i s t o r t s only slightly
t h e p i c t u r e of
the
household's
overall economic
performance.
The t a b l e indicates t h a t t h e majority of income of most Berti households c o m e s f r o m t h e s a l e of livestock and t h a t in s p i t e of considerable involvement in various o t h e r c a s h earning activities, i t is t h e s a l e of livestock
on
which
most
households
rely
to
realise
the
necessary
cash.
Although households which h a v e surplus grain sell s o m e of i t , t h e surplus of grain i s never such a s t o realise a l l t h e c a s h t h e household needs and, in consequence,
t h e s a l e of livestock remains t h e main s o u r c e of cash
income irrespective of whether t h e household fails t o produce enough grain f o r i t s subsistence, produces just about a s m u c h grain a s i t consumes or h a s a surplus in years of good harvest t o t i d e i t over t h e years of c r o p failure.
As c a n b e e x p e c t e d , t h e s i z e of t h e household's income from
o t h e r sources t h a n t h e qale of livestock c o r r e l a t e s negatively w i t h i t s animal wealth.
While a l m o s t 90 per c e n t of a rich household's t o t a l
income derives f r o m t h e s a l e of livestock, t h e s a l e of livestock of a shabaha
household r e p r e s e n t s only a b o u t t w o thirds of i t s t o t a l income.
A significant exception t o this overall picture a r e poor households with small herds who a r e f o r c e d t o realise t h e necessary c a s h through o t h e r m e a n s t h a n m a r k e t i n g t h e i r animals.
They t o o have only a limited
supply of grain, if any, and n o t being a b l e t o sell enough animals, t h e y rely m o r e t h a n t h e
shabaha o r rich households on t h e a l t e r n a t i v e sources
of cash income mentioned above. cash,
Even with a l l o t h e r m e a n s of earning
t h e i r income i s o f t e n n o t sufficient t o cover all t h e necessary
expenses:
while t h e a v e r a g e annual income of a rich household is LS 910
and of a
shabaha household LS 484, t h e a v e r a g e annual income of a poor
household is only LS 188.
To realise additional cash, some households with
low t o t a l cash income resort t o weeding t h e fields of m o r e prosperous households for payment. From
t h e point of
view of
t h e employment of
household labour,
weeding for cash presents problems which d o not arise from any other method of earning cash.
Unlike weeding, all o t h e r cash earning activities
t a k e place in t h e dry season of t h e year when t h e r e is not a heavy if they w e r e not pursued, t h e t i m e spent on t h e m
demand on labour;
would b e more likely spent in leisure.
Even t h e women's s a l e of surplus
produce in small quantities in t h e local m a r k e t is not a n exception t o this; women a t t e n d t h e m a r k e t only when their labour is not required for agricultural tasks;
typically, they s t o p attending t h e m a r k e t a t t h e height
of t h e rainy season when t h e y d e v o t e all their t i m e t o weeding their fields. The importance a t t r i b u t e d by m o s t Berti t o t h e employment of all available labour in weeding ( t o which only t h e rich household heads a r e a n exception) is signified not only by t h e f a c t t h a t t h e m a r k e t s a r e deserted during
the
weeding
season
and
the
t r a d e is
reduced t o t h e
barest
minimum, but also by t h e f a c t t h a t t h e weeding season is t h e t i m e when social interaction of a n y kind is a t i t s lowest ebb. As weeding for payment d e f l e c t s labour from weeding t h e household's own fields, i t has obviously quite different repercussions for t h e houseold's
overall
economic
performance
t h a n any o t h e r
cash earning
activity. It has been mentioned before t h a t most Berti weed considerably less land than t h a t which is considered t o b e t h e minimum a m o u n t which can reasonably b e weeded by a n able- bodied producer.
When considering t h e
average amount of land weeded by one producer, only t h e weeding of t h e household's own land w a s taken into account in Table 1.
The Berti weed
in f a c t m o r e than t h a t if weeding f o r cash is taken into consideration. The a v e r a g e t o t a l amount of land weeded by one producer (including his or her household's own land a s well a s t h e land of o t h e r households weeded for cash) is shown in Table 5.
A comparison of Tables 1 and 5 indicates
t h e amount of labour involved in weeding for cash.
TABLE 5
T h e Average Amount of All Land Weeded by O n e Producer
As already indicated, those who weed fbr cash obviously d o i t a t t h e expense of weeding their own fields.
A producer from a
shabaha house-
hold which weeds only i t s own fields, weeds on average 2.5 h a a year; t h e o t h e r hand a producer f r o m a
shabaha
on
household which employs i t s
labour for weeding f o r cash, weeds on average only 1.8 ha of his household's land.
Similarly, a producer from a poor household which does not
weed f o r others, weeds on a v e r a g e 2.25 h a a year; producer
on t h e o t h e r hand, a
from a poor household which weeds for o t h e r s f o r payment,
weeds on a v e r a g e only 1.9 ha of his or her household's land a year (figures for t h e f i v e year survey period a r e given in Table 6 ) . TABLE 6
The Average Amount of t h e Household's Own Land Weeded by O n e Producer from Households Weeding and Households Not Weeding for Cash
*The figure in t h e f i r s t column for e a c h year is t h e average amount of household land (in hectares) weeded by one producer from households which do not weed for cash. The figure in t h e second column is t h e a v e r a g e amount of household land weeded by one producer from households which weed for cash. Rich households a r e not included a s their m e m b e r s do not weed for cash.
If t h e y employed all available labour for weeding their own fields only, t h e agricultural production of households which weed for cash would improve by 13-48 per c e n t , depending on t h e amount of wage weeding they do.
The household weeding for cash suffers not only t h e s e productive
losses but also losses in i t s potential income:
t h e money which i t earns
from weeding compares unfavourably with t h e cash value of grain which i t could produce if i t used all i t s labour for weeding i t s own fields instead, in spite of t h e f a c t t h a t due t o perpetual shortage, t h e c o s t of wage labour has risen more sharply over t h e years than t h e price of millet or animals.
As Table 7 shows, weeding for c a s h is profitable in t e r m s of
investment returns only in years of almost t o t a l c r o p failure (for example 1977). - - -- - -
.
Investment Returns on Wage Weeding
Given t h e obvious economic disadvantages of hiring one's labour t o weed f o r cash, i t is only those with a d e s p e r a t e need of i m m e d i a t e cash who do so and of t h e 29 census households only seven resort t o this strategy.
Four of t h e s e a r e poor households (in f a c t t h e t h r e e poorest
households in t h e sample all weeded for cash) and t h r e e a r e
shabaha
.
Obviously most pressed for cash a r e households which fail t o produce enough millet for their subsistence and t h e r e f o r e do not have any grain t o m a r k e t and which d o not own enough livestock t o realise t h e cash they need for i t s sale.
All poor households which weed for payment a r e in -58-
this position.
A s i t is partly their high C/W r a t i o which prevents t h e m
f r o m producing enough grain f o r their subsistence needs, t h e deflection of t h e i r labour f r o m t h e i r own agricultural production only a g g r a v a t e s their predicament and t h e y a r e t r a p p e d in a vicious circle:
t h e y do n o t weed
enough land for their subsistence requirements and h a v e t o buy grain from t h e market;
t o b e a b l e t o realise t h e necessary cash, t h e y h a v e t o weed
f o r payment;
in consequence, they c a n n o t employ all t h e i r labour for
weeding their own fields and consistently f a i l t o m e e t t h e i r subsistence needs,
T h e t w o households with t h e lowest overall agricultural production
(Nos. 1 and 2) f a l l i n t o this category. The
households which weed f o r c a s h do i t f o r d i f f e r e n t
shabaha
reasons.
They a r e households whose animal wealth has been constantly
decreasing:
t o avoid depleting their herds y e t further through a n excessive
s a l e of livestock, t h e y weed f o r cash instead.
Like t h e poor households,
however, t h e y a r e a l s o trapped in a vicious circle;
weeding f o r cash
prevents t h e m f r o m producing enough grain f o r their subsistence and they h a v e t o buy grain f r o m t h e m a r k e t ; necessary cash,
they
a s weeding alone does n o t realise t h e
h a v e t o resort
t o selling livestock
thus further
decreasing t h e i r herds. T h e Berti a r e a w a r e of t h e consequences of weeding f o r cash a n d this s t r a t e g y is generally considered t o be t h e worst possible one.
I t is t h e
general feeling t h a t people who resort t o i t a r e doomed t o remain poor forever. On t h e contrary, t h e best s t r a t e g y is t o hire labour f o r weeding even a t t h e c o s t of selling a n a n i m a l t o raise t h e necessary c a s h because t h e s a l e of grain produced by hired labour enables one not only t o replace t h e animal sold but leaves a profit a s well. resort t o this strategy.
Of t h e 29 census households, 1 1
They a r e households of t w o types:
firstly, shabaha
households which produce a surplus of grain over their subsistence needs in good years and which have enough animals t o m a r k e t (Nos. 22, 24, 25, 25, 291,
and,
market
secondly, and
depend
rich
households which
primarily
on
its
have sufficient sale
for
its
livestock cash
to
income.
Because all rich households a r e a b l e t o realise necessary c a s h from t h e s a l e of livestock, t h e a m o u n t of grain which t h e y m a n a g e t o produce is basically irrelevant t o t h e i r overall economic viability.
The economic
s t r a t e g y of t h e
shabaha households hinges on a successful c o m b i n a t i o n of
a g r i c u l t u r e a n d a n i m a l husbandry.
T h e successful
joint pursuit of
both
t h e s e s p h e r e s of production l e a v e s t h e m with enough surplus c a s h t o hire labour;
but hiring labour is a t t h e s a m e t i m e e s s e n t i a l f o r a n y successful
combination of a g r i c u l t u r e a n d a n i m a l husbandry.
T h e h e r d s of s h e e p a r e
a t p a s t u r e outside t h e village t h e whole y e a r a n d t h e y h a v e t o b e herded c o n c u r r e n t l y w i t h t h e weeding of t h e fields.
Although t h e h e r d s of c a t t l e
and g o a t s a r e k e p t in t h e village in t h e rainy season a n d , unlike in t h e dry season, d o n o t h a v e t o b e w a t e r e d , t h e y h a v e t o b e occasionally h e r d e d t o p r e v e n t t h e m f r o m e n t e r i n g f i e l d s a n d causing d a m a g e t o crops.
This p u t s
a heavy d e m a n d on labour a n d o f t e n r e q u i r e s m o r e hands t h a n t h e household c a n provide. In s p i t e of shabaha
n o t relying t o t h e s a m e e x t e n t on a g r i c u l t u r e a s t h e
households do, rich households, too, typically f a c e t h e problem of
labour s h o r t a g e d u e primarily t o t h e i r own s m a l l labour o u t p u t .
Weeding
is considered by t h e B e r t i t h e m o s t s t r e n u o u s work of all a n d a l l prosperous household h e a d s e m u l a t e t h e behaviour of m e r c h a n t s a n d e i t h e r d o n o t w e e d a t a l l (Nos. 7, 14 a n d 23) o r d o only a l i t t l e weeding t h e m s e l v e s (Nos. 12 a n d 26). A p a r t f r o m hiring labour f o r weeding, s o m e of t h e rich a n d shabaha households which pursue w h a t t h e B e r t i consider t o b e t h e i d e a l e c o n o m i c s t r a t e g y , e m p l o y labour a l s o f o r herding t h e i r animals. young u n m a r r i e d m e n f r o m p o o r e r households.
The herdsmen a r e
T h e young m e n f r o m four
poor households (of t h e t o t a l of seven) a n d f r o m four shabaha households (of t h e t o t a l of prosperous Berti.
16 in t h e census) herd s h e e p a n d c a t t l e of t h e m o r e T h e h e r d e r s a r e paid in kind:
a m a n herding c o w s
r e c e i v e s a calf e v e r y y e a r a n d a m a n herding s h e e p r e c e i v e s six s h e e p e v e r y y e a r f r o m e v e r y hundred h e looks a f t e r . effective
re- distribution of
h e r d s of
t h e poor
I t is mainly through t h i s
a n i m a l s f r o m t h e h e r d s of
t h a t t h e a n i m a l s of
t h e rich t o t h e
t h e poor households h a v e been
increasing in s p i t e of a c o m p a r a t i v e l y high o f f t a k e . T h e households whose m e m b e r s w e e d f o r c a s h a n d l o r work a s herdsmen, pursue, in f a c t , a s t r a t e g y which is virtually t h e r e v e r s e of t h a t which depends on hired labour.
Of t h e 29 c e n s u s households, 1 1 r e s o r t t o
i t (Nos. 1 , 2, 4, 5 , 6, 8 , 9, 13, 15, 18, 211.'
All f i v e shabaha households
pursuing t h i s s t r a t e g y f a i l t o produce enough grain f o r t h e i r subsistence; -60-
of t h e six poor households, t h r e e fail in t h e i r agricultural production, two m a n a g e t o produce a b o u t enough grain for t h e i r subsistence in y e a r s of good harvests and only one h a s a
m o d e r a t e surplus of grain over i t s
subsistence needs. The remaining seven households (Nos. 3 , 10, 1 1 , 16, 19, 20 and 27) neither hire labour, nor d o t h e i r m e m b e r s work a s herdsmen o r weed for c a s h (household No. 3 i s included h e r e although i t employs hired labour for weeding;
a young m a n from t h i s household is away a s a herdsman a n d t h e
hired labour basically c o m p e n s a t e s for his loss). and o n e is poor.
Six of t h e m a r e shabaha
Their economic viability depends, in differing degrees, on
a combination of all t h r e e sources of c a s h income:
t h e s a l e of livestock,
t h e s a l e of any surplus of grain and t h e pursuit of various c a s h earning a c t i v i t i e s in t h e dry season of t h e year.
All t h e six shabaha households
in this c a t e g o r y e i t h e r do n o t produce enough grain f o r their own subsistence o r have only a m o d e r a t e surplus in years of good harvests and depend mainly on t h e s a l e of livestock and o t h e r c a s h earning activities. T h e poor household produces enough grain f o r i t s own subsistence s o t h a t i t c a n a f f o r d t o m a r k e t only a couple of g o a t s e a c h year, depending on o t h e r c a s h earning a c t i v i t i e s f o r i t s income. As no Berti household is self- sufficient in i t s production, depending on a regular purchase of many commodities f r o m t h e market, i t i s basically t h e success of i t s agricultural production which d e t e r m i n e s t h e growth or d e c r e a s e of i t s animal wealth.
The m o r e grain t h e household is a b l e t o
m a r k e t t o realise t h e necessary cash, t h e smaller needs t o be t h e o f f t a k e from i t s herds and t h e b e t t e r their growth r a t e .
T h e d e g r e e of success in
agricultural production c o r r e l a t e s positively with t h e C / W ratio;
house-
holds which fail t o produce enough grain t o m e e t their subsistence needs have on t h e whole higher C / W r a t i o s than those which e i t h e r m a n a g e t o produce a surplus of grain over t h e years o r whose agricultural production is about a d e q u a t e f o r their needs.
The e f f e c t of t h e C/W r a t i o on t h e
d e g r e e of success of t h e household's agricultural production is, however, t o a g r e a t e x t e n t modified by t h e s t r a t e g y employed;
households which weed
f o r cash regularly underproduce in s p i t e of t h e f a c t t h a t many of them have a
m o r e favourable C / W
r a t i o t h a n households which m a n a g e t o
produce enough grain for t h e i r subsistence labour in weeding only t h e i r own fields. -61-
through employing all their
In spite. of t h e e f f e c t which t h e household's agricultural production has on i t s overall economic performance, in t h e ecological conditions in which t h e Berti live no household would be viable if i t depended solely on agriculture a s t h e yield is o f t e n well below t h e household's subsistence needs a n d years of
t o t a l or a l m o s t t o t a l c r o p failure a r e not unusual.
While t h e r e a r e y e a r s when most households c a n m a r k e t a t l e a s t s o m e millet, t h e y a r e years when virtually all households, e x c e p t a f e w who have managed t o build up a supply of grain over t h e years, h a v e t o purchase millet f r o m t h e m a r k e t , o f t e n in g r e a t a m o u n t s t o survive.
It is
thus t h e m a r k e t which g u a r a n t e e s t h e household's subsistence security. Under t h e s e conditions, i t is t h e household's animal wealth which critically d e t e r m i n e s i t s overall economic performance. T h e rich households depend a l m o s t exclusively on t h e s a l e on livestock for t h e i r c a s h income;
t h e y have only a limited income f r o m o t h e r cash
earning a c t i v i t i e s without employing t h e i r own labour in pursuit of them. And because of their overall animal wealth, their d e g r e e of success in agricultural production is t o a g r e a t e x t e n t irrelevant t o t h e i r overall economic performance.
T h e economy of rich households clearly indicates
t h a t pastoralism would b e a viable a l t e r n a t i v e f o r t h e Berti.
But t h e
herds of m o s t households a r e t o o small t o m a k e t h e household viable. Hence all households depend on combining, in various degrees, agriculture with animal husbandry and on earning additional cash through t h e s a l e of grass, rock s a l t and through p e r m a n e n t o r occasional wage employment or short - term labour migration.
T h e household's viability ultimately depends
on t h e d e g r e e of i t s success jn t h e joint pursuit of a g r i c u l t u r e and animal husbandry.
But combining t h e s e t w o e c o n o m i c pursuits puts a heavy
demand on labour and, in consequence, i t i s t h e management of t h e household's labour which lies a t t h e root of t h e differences in t h e economic s t r a t e g i e s employed. Only a minority of households m a n a g e t h e i r economy by employing all t h e i r available labour s t r i c t l y within t h e household's economic sphere and without recruiting any additional labour f r o m t h e outside.
The two
e x t r e m e economic s t r a t e g i e s which t h e Berti consider t o b e t h e best and t h e worst respectively, and which a r e resorted t o by most Berti households, depend, on t h e o t h e r hand, on t h e rnovement of labour between households.
Within t h e economy a s a whole, t h e s e t w o s t r a t e g i e s a r e
complementary and interdependent:
t h e rich households c a n pursue agri-
c u l t u r e and animal husbandry because of t h e recruitment of labour from poor households;
t h e poor households a r e a b l e t o e a r n badly needed cash
and/or increase their animal holdings by providing labour f o r t h e rich.
Notes
(I)
In my sample of 201 households, t h e a v e r a g e number of inhabitants per household w a s 4.25. The a c t u a l number of household inhabita n t s varies considerably and ranges f r o m one t o twelve. For a more detailed discussion of t h e household composition and developm e n t a l cycle cf. Holy 1974: 1-15.
(2)
These figures r e f l e c t t h e present number of wives among married men. The occurrence is higher if past marriages of living men a r e taken into account: 71 per c e n t of men never had m o r e t h a n one wife during their lives, 24.7 per c e n t had t w o wives during at l e a s t one s t a g e of their lives and 0.4 per c e n t had four. The proportion of polygynous unions is g r e a t e r among older t h a n among younger men; 41.5 per c e n t of men with married sons and daughters of t h e i r own a r e polygynists and 59.7 per c e n t of this category had m o r e t h a n o n e wife a t l e a s t during one s t a g e of their life. For a m o r e detailed discussion of polygyny cf. Holy 1974: 12-17.
(3)
Various anthropologists have used slightly different formulae for assessing household consumption requirements (cf. Bailey 1957: 277; Salisbury 1962: 79; Epstein 1967; 160; Sahlins 1972: 103; Donham 1981: 523). I worked with t h e coefficients presented by Epstein. I recorded t h e consumption of millet in t h r e e s e l e c t e d households during four different months of t h e year t o account for t h e seasonal variation in food. When t h e coefficients w e r e used against this recorded consumption, t h e y needed t o be slightly modified t o f i t and in t h e end, taking t h e adult male a s standard (1.0), t h e m a l e and f e m a l e consumers of different a g e s w e r e computed a s follows:
!!.E
Male
70c 14-69 10-13 6-9 2-5
0.8 1 .O 0.8 0.5 0.3
Female 0.65 0.8 0.65 0.4 0.3
As a result, my e s t i m a t e is t h a t a m a l e over 14 years of a g e consumes on a v e r a g e 325kg of millet per year, a boy of 10-13 years, a woman over 14 years and a n old man over about 70 years
of a g e on a v e r a g e about 174kg, a girl of 10-13 years and a n old woman over about 70 years of a g e on average 140kg, a boy of 6-9 years of a g e lO8kg and a girl of t h e s a m e a g e about 87kg, and a child between t h e a g e of 2 and 5 on average about 65kg. These e s t i m a t e s correspond t o t h e recorded consumption a s well a s t o t h e informants' own reports of consumption in their households. (4)
C o m p a r e t h e figures in Table l for 1976, 1977 and 1979 which had below a v e r a g e rains with ensuing bad harvests with those for 1975 and 1978 which w e r e t h e years of good rainy seasons and a v e r a g e yields of 215kg/ha and 240kg/ha respectively.
(5)
I was in t h e field in August and September 1977, from July 1978 t o January 1979 and f r o m J u n e t o October 1980. During my absence t h e quantitative d a t a w e r e collected for m e by Adam Abakar and his son Abdulahi Adam t o whom I wish t o express my sincere gratitude. My visit t o t h e Sudan in 1977 w a s financed by t h e Queen's University of Belfast and my subsequent research was sponsored by t h e Social Science Research Council. I a m g r a t e f u l t o t h e s e bodies for t h e i r generous assistance.
(6)
This figure would be much lower if i t w e r e yielded from a bigger sample. T h e r e w e r e only six rich households in t h e village in which t h e census was t a k e n and t h e m e m b e r s of one of t h e s e (No. 17) weeded a considerable amount of land in s p i t e of their animal wealth: on a v e r a g e 2.6 h a per producer over t h e five years. They w e r e hard workers who did not leave any economic opportunity unexploited; t h e y were, f o r example, actively involved in in selling grass during t h e dry season which is something not generally done by wealthy households. There was a similarly enterprising household (No. 29) among those classified a s shabaha : t h e members weeded on a v e r a g e 4.1 ha per producer over t h e five years. As t h e r e a r e altogether 16 shabaha households in t h e sample, this exceptional performance does not a f f e c t t h e figure of t h e average amount of land weeded by shabaha households t o t h e s a m e e x t e n t t o which t h e exceptional performance of household No. 17 a f f e c t s t h e figure for rich households.
(7)
In calculating t h e C/W ratio, m e n and women over t h e a g e of 14 w e r e computed a s 1.0 worker units and t h e children who weeded but w e r e younger than 14 years a s 0.5 worker units. This r e f l e c t s reasonably a c c u r a t e l y t h e relative work output of children and adults. Each member of t h e household was computed a s 1.0 consumer unit. As a c t u a l consumption varies with a g e and sex (cf. Note 3), this crude method of computing consumer units does not r e f l e c t t h e household's a c t u a l level of consumption. But a s t h e C/W r a t i o is used h e r e merely t o indicate t h e relative amount of labour which t h e household has a t i t s disposal in relation t o t h e amount of labour available t o o t h e r households, and not t h e absolute amount of labour in t h e household and t h e absolute level of t h e household's consumption, t h e adopted method of calculating C / W r a t i o s e e m s a d e q u a t e for this purpose, although i t would not b e for o t h e r s (cf. Donham 1981).
(8)
Given t h a t t h e Berti measure t h e household's wealth in t e r m s of t h e s i z e of i t s herd, a n obvious way of determining whether t h e household's wealth is increasing or decreasing would b e t o consider whether i t s herd grows or is decreasing in size. However, a considerable number of livestock succumbs every year t o disease and from t i m e t o t i m e t o epidemics. Diseases and epidemics do not s t r i k e all herds equally; s o m e herds survive a n epidemic virtually unscathed, o t h e r s a r e drastically decimated. The d e g r e e t o which a herd suffers from outbreaks of disease is beyond human control and only t o a small d e g r e e depends on husbanding skills. Should t h e e s t i m a t e of t h e growth or decline of t h e household's wealth b e measured in t e r m s of t h e increase or d e c r e a s e in size of i t s herd, t h e e l e m e n t s of c h a n c e and luck beyond human control would b e analytically fused with economic performance which is fully controlled. To s e p a r a t e good or bad luck which can equally s t r i k e a good a s well a s a bad husbandman, I c o n c e n t r a t e in t h e following analysis on t h e s i z e of t h e o f f t a k e f r o m existing herds rather t h a n on their a c t u a l growth or decrease. The average annual o f f t a k e from t h e Berti herds is about 14.6 per c e n t and a t this r a t e of o f f t a k e t h e i r herds grow by about 5.9 per c e n t a year.
(9)
Livestock units (LSU) a r e used t o indicate t h e s i z e of t h e household's overall livestock holding consisting of different animals and a r e computed a s follows: c a m e l 1.0; head of c a t t l e : 0.72; sheep 0.1; g o a t 0.06.
(10)
LS 1.00 (one Sudanese pound) was worth 5 5 new pence in 1980.
(1 1)
I took animal censuses in l978 and 1980. All six rich households had a c a m e l a t both times. Of t h e 16 shabaha households, 12 had a c a m e l in 1978 and 1 3 in 1980. Of t h e seven poor households, only one had a c a m e l in 1978 but t h r e e in 1980.
(12)
Apart f r o m t h e seven households which hire o u t their labour f o r weeding, four o t h e r households which provide herders f o r t h e more prosperous households a r e included h e r e (Nos. 4, 16, 18, 21).
AGRICULTURAL INTENSIFICATION AND RESOURCE MAINTENANCE: 1 Some Cases from Western Sudan
Leif 0. Manger
Although t h e l i t e r a t u r e on agricultural intensification is q u i t e substantial (Geertz,
Boserup, 1965;
1963;
Barlett, 1980;
Burnham, 1980;
Netting, 1968, 1974;
Brookfield, 1972;
Burton and White, 1984;
and Dow, 1985)
t h e r e is no common definition of w h a t intensification means.
However,
intensification has been used t o d e n o t e t h e production s y s t e m s using plough or irrigation techniques.
It has also been r e f e r r e d t o a s t h e s y s t e m s in
which methods like terracing, green manuring, animal manuring, transplanting and t h e use of a n i m a l t r a c t i o n h a v e been utilized.
Boserup ( op. cit. )
uses t h e c o n c e p t t o d e n o t e t h e shortening of fallow periods by any method, (
op. cit. ) used i t t o m e a n any process t h a t
increases yield per h e c t a r e .
I shall n o t dwell on any of t h e s e definitions
while Burton and White
since t h e y a l l have something t o o f f e r with regard t o t h e development of intensive production s y s t e m s and a s such t h e y a r e all of s o m e relevance t o this study.
In c o m m o n with Burton and White, therefore, if w e hold land
a s a c o n s t a n t variable, agricultural intensification is a result of labour intensification, c a p i t a l intensification o r technological change. Another i m p o r t a n t a s p e c t of agricultural intensification is t h e use of animals in such s y s t e m s (Allan, 1965;
e t a1
1979;
Ruthenberg, 1980;
Morgan and Pough, 1969;
Vincze, 1980;
Jahnke, 1982).
MacCown We know
t h a t in traditional savannah a d a p t a t i o n s t h e r e is a low d e g r e e of integration
between
crop
f a r m i n g and
animal
raising.
Furthermore,
the
relationship between t h e t w o i s a c c i d e n t a l r a t h e r t h a n socially planned. Thus pastoral nomads m i g r a t e in a r e a s with cultivation but only in f e w c a s e s is t h e r e any conscious a t t e m p t t o r e g u l a t e their m o v e m e n t s t o maximize f a r m fertility.
Similarly, animals a r e k e p t by c u l t i v a t o r s but
rarely used t o improve c r o p production.
In m o r e intensive s y s t e m s this
link h a s developed f u r t h e r and animals a r e used for traction, m a n u r e may systematically be applied and fodder m a y b e grown.
In such systems,
animals a r e used in a purposeful way t o c r e a t e a m o r e complex s y s t e m of a n i m a l l f a r m relationship
than
w h a t is commonly found in t h e African -66-
savannah. herd. for
T h e r e is t h u s a c o m p l e m e n t a r y relationship b e t w e e n field and
However, t h e relationship m a y also b e o n e of competition. example t h e case
when
traditional
Take
pasture is t a k e n over
by t h e
expansion of cultivation, or when t h e keeping of animals and agricultural work
put
strains
on
the
labour
force
within
the
household.
O n e point of special i m p o r t a n c e in t h e l i t e r a t u r e on agricultural H e r e I shall c o n c e n t r a t e
intensification i s how such s y s t e m s c o m e about.
on t h e African experience w h e r e s e v e r a l c a s e s of such a d a p t a t i o n s a r e found.
Consider
Cameroon
for
Highlands
example
(Allan,
the
Ukara
1965;
Island
Burnham,
1968),
(Ludwig,
198O), t h e
Jos
(Netting, 1968) and t h e Kano Closed S e t t l e d Zone (Hill, 1977).
the
Plateau
In addition
t o t h e s e t h e r e a r e t h e Sudanese c a s e s of Kheiran (Manger, 1981), t h e Nuba Mountains (Nadel, 1942;
Roden, 1972) a n d 'Jebel Mara (Allan
op. cit. ).
A c e n t r a l position in this d e b a t e is t h a t of Boserup (1965) who argues that
people in extensive
s y s t e m s of
production
will
intensive methods without s o m e kind of pressure. related t o t h e use of labour.
not
adapt
more
Their r e l u c t a n c e is
The extensive system is c h a r a c t e r i z e d by a
high r e t u r n of labour and low r e t u r n of land.
Any intensification process
t h a t increases productivity f r o m land is paid f o r by decreasing marginal returns of labour.
However, people will n o t e n t e r i n t o such a situation
without being exposed t o s o m e kind of pressure. t h e demographic pressure t h a t growth
and
the
absence
of
Boserup a r g u e s t h a t i t is
brings such change about. possibilities
for
Population
out- migration
develop
a
situation in which people have t o give priority t o increasing land productivity and t a k e less n o t i c e of labour productivity. Although
this a r g u m e n t
empirical situation in Africa.
is valid, i t c a n n o t by itself
explain
the
T h e r e t h e general situation is c h a r a c t e r i z e d
by a r a t h e r low population density and people, t o a large e x t e n t , have a c c e s s t o new f a r m lands. higher
population
densities
T h e f a c t t h a t c e r t a i n a r e a s h a v e developed cannot
be explained
by
natural
growth, but has t o be seen in a politico- historical context.
population
The a r e a s of
agricultural intensification which I have mentioned s o f a r w e r e all, e x c e p t t h e Kano Closed S e t t l e d Zone, r e f u g e a r e a s f o r a population t h r e a t e n e d by slave raids a f t e r living in general insecurity d u e t o stronger predators and neighbours.
I t is t h u s specific historical developments t h a t have brought
about t h e s e adaptations, involving relationships between groups of unequal -67-
military strength a s well a s t h e position of t h e various groups within t h e pre-colonial savannah states.
O n e example t h a t indicates t h e significance
of t h e above f a c t o r s is t h a t of t h e Kofyar and t h e Tiv in Nigeria's c e n t r a l belt.
The t w o groups a r e neighbours and w e r e exposed t o similar external
influences and pressures.
Whereas t h e Kofyar r e a c t e d t o pressure on t h e
resources by adopting a system of agricultural intensification, t h e Tiv, due t o their segmentary organization and military strength, solved t h e problem by expanding their t e r r i t o r y and thus continued their traditional extensive system of agricultural production (Burnham, 1980). To elucidate t h e general points raised above I shall present t w o cases of agricultural intensification from Western Sudan.
They a r e both found in
Kordofan Region, which is divided into North and South Kordofan Provinces. The
first
case
is f r o m
t h e Kheiran
oases in
irrigated orchard cultivation has developed. consisted f i r s t of t h e saqia
North Kordofan,
where
The irrigation methods here
and t h e shadouf both common along t h e Nile,
and mechanical pump schemes which b e c a m e more dominant in r e c e n t years.
The second c a s e is f r o m South Kordofan.
This is Liri, which is
found in t h e southern p a r t s of t h e Nuba Mountains.
The Nuba groups
inhabiting t h a t a r e a have developed intensive forms of hill cultivation, building terraces, applying manure t o c e r t a i n plots and collecting fodder for
their animals in order t o b e able t o maintain themselves in t h e
mountain habitat. The purpose of
this presentation is t o explain how s o m e African
communities have developkd systems of adaptation t h a t a r e ecologically more viable t h a n t h e extensive systems common in t h e African savannah and which a r e in a s e v e r e crisis a t present. lies in t w o positive achievements;
The value of such systems
first, increasing production and land
productivity, and second, preserving t h e soil by avoiding ecological degradation.
Ploughing and manuring in Kheiran and terracing t o control soil
erosion in Liri, represent examples of how intensive cropping has been operated.
Moreover, t h e study of how such intensive systems of production
emerged and how they have been maintained provide a n insight into some major problems facing students of rural development and planners alike in their dealing with
t h e contemporary African crisis.
This is t h e problem
of how t o develop ecologically viable intensive mixed farming systems in Africa. -68-
The Setting T h e p r e s e n t a t i o n t o follow is s t r u c t u r e d around c e r t a i n basic t h e m e s .
The
h i s t o r i c a l c o n t e x t within which t h e Kheiran a n d Liri i n t e n s i v e s y s t e m s of c r o p production e m e r g e d a n d t h e key f a c t o r s in t h e i r m a i n t e n a n c e and c h a n g e will b e explained.
F u r t h e r m o r e , both Kheiran a n d Liri a r e under-
going significant c h a n g e s in t h e m o d e r n c o n t e x t of e c o n o m i c a n d political development. the
way
I t is, t h e r e f o r e , i m p o r t a n t t o i s o l a t e t h e f a c t o r s t h a t d e f i n e
in which
t e m p o r a r y situation.
people d e v e l o p s y s t e m s of
adaptation
in
t h e con-
Since b o t h c a s e s a r e s i t u a t e d within t h e s a m e region
a n d w e r e s u b j e c t e d t o c e r t a i n i n t e r - r e l a t e d historical processes I shall s t a r t by introducing t h e Kordofan region in s p a c e a n d time. Kordofan is a v a s t open plain, l o c a t e d w e s t of t h e White Nile. major ecological z o n e s d o m i n a t e t h i s country:
Three
semi- desert in t h e north, a
c e n t r a l goz (or s t a b i l i z e d sand dunes) a n d t h e Nuba Mountains in t h e south west.
T h e Nuba Mountains z o n e is c h a r a c t e r i z e d by s e r i e s of hills with
s t r e t c h e s of c l a y plains b e t w e e n t h e hills.
T h e m e a n annual rainfall v a r i e s
f r o m lOOmm in t h e f a r n o r t h t o s o m e 600-800mm per annum in t h e south. S y s t e m s of a d a p t a t i o n vary f r o m c a m e l a n d s h e e p nomadism in t h e f a r north, mixed hoe c u l t i v a t i o n a n d pastoralism in t h e c e n t r a l z o n e t o mixed f a r m i n g a n d c a t t l e pastoralism in t h e south.
A c o m m o n f e a t u r e of t h e s e
t h r e e s y s t e m s of a d a p t a t i o n is t h a t t h e y a l l r e p r e s e n t p a r t of t h e e x t e n s i v e savannah
system
of
production.
p r a c t i s e d with long fallow
In
this system,
cultivation has
been
periods a n d a n i m a l s a n d human beings h a v e
a d o p t e d a t r a n s h u m a n t w a y of life, moving f r o m south t o n o r t h c o v e r i n g t h e t h r e e ecological z o n e s in response t o v a r i a t i o n s in p a s t u r e and rainfall. A m o r e intensive s y s t e m of a g r i c u l t u r a l production is found in Kheiran a n d
B a r a in t h e n o r t h w h e r e i r r i g a t e d o r c h a r d s a r e c u l t i v a t e d , and in t h e south in t h e Nuba Mountains w h e r e i n t e n s i v e mixed t e r r a c e d f a r m i n g s y s t e m s a r e practised. T h e history of Kordofan i s t i e d t o t h e Funj and D a r f u r Kingdoms (O'Fahey, 1980;
Spaulding, 1985).
Kordofan w a s never a n independent
s t a t e , but f o r m e d p a r t of t h e t w o kingdoms a t various times.
Common t o
both kingdoms w a s t h a t t h e y did n o t i n t e r v e n e d i r e c t l y with t h e Kordofani people, but w e r e mainly i n t e r e s t e d in t r a d e .
Major c a r a v a n r o u t e s w e n t
through t h e c e n t r a l goz belt t o t h e t r a d i n g t o w n s of B a r a a n d El Obeid. T h e i m p o r t a n t t r a d e i t e m s w e r e slaves, gold a n d g u m arabic. -69-
The slaves
were captured from
t h e south (the
Nuba
Mountains),
t o be exported,
employed a s soldiers, or put i n t o c u l t i v a t i o n o r p a s t o r a l a c t i v i t i e s by t h e i r owners.
Gum a r a b i c w a s c o l l e c t e d in t h e goz belt a n d w a s considered a
major s o u r c e of i n c o m e f o r t h e s t a t e a s well a s t h e local i n h a b i t a n t s of t h e region.
T h e e x p l o i t a t i o n of Kordofan a n d o t h e r p a r t s of t h e Sudan
w a s intensified during t h e Turco- Egyptian r u l e (1821-1881) (e.g., Spaulding, 1982).
More slaves w e r e c a p t u r e d a n d t h e t a x burden increased.
growing d i s c o n t e n t with t h i s r u l e c u l m i n a t e d
The
in t h e Mahdist revolution
(1881-1898) which t u r n e d Kordofan i n t o a b a t t l e f i e l d with n e g a t i v e cons e q u e n c e s f o r a g r i c u l t u r a l production.
I t a l s o brought serious implications
f o r t h e c a s e s under consideration. T h e 20th c e n t u r y , on t h e o t h e r hand, h a s s e e n a n increasing d e g r e e of c o m m e r c i a l i z a t i o n of t r a d i t i o n a l production.
C a s h c r o p s such a s c o t t o n and
groundnuts w e r e introduced, labour migration t o o t h e r p a r t s of t h e Sudan a c c e l e r a t e d , and new e c o n o m i c a c t i v i t i e s in t h e urban c e n t r e s m a d e people m o r e d e p e n d e n t on t h e m a r k e t economy.
G o v e r n m e n t i n t e r v e n t i o n through
t h e e s t a b l i s h m e n t of a g r i c u l t u r a l m o d e r n i z a t i o n and large- scale m e c h a n i z e d agricultural
schemes
have changed
t h e traditional context.
Population
g r o w t h a n d t h e expansion of t h e c u l t i v a t e d a r e a , a s well a s t h e i n c r e a s e in livestock numbers, h a v e led t o t h e d e t e r i o r a t i o n of soil quality.
This
h a s been followed by a serious p r o c e s s of d e s e r t i f i c a t i o n which is p a r t icularly e v i d e n t in t h e sand g r a z i n g and
deforestation
belt.
F u r t h e r m o r e , o v e r - c u l t i v a t i o n , over-
h a v e brought a b o u t a n ecological crisis,
the
e f f e c t of which w a s m a d e d r a m a t i c a l l y c l e a r during t h e r e c e n t drought. Such ecological d e g r a d a t i o n i s m o r e visible around population s e t t l e m e n t s and within t h e a r e a s w h e r e m e c h a n i z e d a g r i c u l t u r e w a s introduced w h e r e t h e soil w a s r e g a r d e d a s less vulnerable. T h e t w o c a s e s of Kheiran, which lies in t h e n o r t h e r n in
the
Nuba
cultivation The
in
Mountains areas
characteristics
in
that of
both
the are
south, facing
ecological
represent severe
of
intensive
environmental
problems.
zones emerged
d i f f e r e n t historical d e v e l o p m e n t s in Western Sudan. cases
themselves
to
see
how
they -70-
islands
stand
in
goz, a n d Liri
as a
result
of
Now I t u r n t o t h e this
general
picture.
2
Kheiran
The Kheiran a r e a consists of a series of oases located within large sand dunes and situated
just west of Bara town in northern Kordofan.
The
oases a r e depressions with c l a y soils and have a shallow w a t e r table, mostly within 10 m e t r e s from t h e surface.
This makes i t possible for t h e
inhabitants t o c u l t i v a t e vegetables and f r u i t t r e e s in irrigated orchards. There
a r e t w o methods of irrigation: a hand operated lever ( t h e 3 4 shadouf ) and mechanical pumps. The ox drawn waterwheels ( s a q i a )
w e r e previously used but disappeared r a t h e r quickly a f t e r t h e introduction of
mechanical
occur:
pumps during t h e early 1960's.
Two cropping systems
first, t h e irrigated cultivation which t a k e s place during winter and
summer, and second, t h e rainfed cultivation valleys ( wadis) during t h e rainy season.
which t a k e s place in t h e
Vegetables and f r u i t a r e t h e main
crops cultivated in t h e irrigated plots, while sorghum, millet, sesame, and w a t e r melon a r e mostly cultivated in t h e rainfed cropping system. inhabitants also keep a number of animals. minor
d e g r e e camels, c a t t l e and sheep.
important
watering
centre
for
the
The
They raise goats and t o a Furthermore,
pastoralists
Kheiran is a n
in
the
region.
T h e Kheiran oases may b e divided into southern and northern parts. This distinction is valid on several points.
The south e m b r a c e s t h e biggest
oases, with villages on t h e s t r e t c h of land between t h e orchards and t h e sand dunes. village
The northern oases a r e smaller and people f r o m t h e s a m e
m a y c u l t i v a t e in
different
areas.
The sand dunes a r e more
stabilized in t h e north which enabled people t o build their houses on them and live in dispersed s e t t l e m e n t s r a t h e r t h a n distinct villages a s in t h e south. The m a r k e t links a r e also different. south depends on El Obeid market. markets. south: green
According t o i t s location, t h e
The north relies on smaller, local
This has led t o a higher d e g r e e of commercialization in t h e a wide variety of vegetables - tomatoes, egg plants, red peppers,
peppers,
onions,
lettuces,
turnips,
radishes
-
and
others,
are
cultivated and transported by lorries t o El Obeid every day during t h e harvesting season.
Onion cultivation is m o r e important in t h e north since
t h e vegetable can travel for long distances or b e preserved f o r a long t i m e without being spoiled.
There a r e f e w e r mechanical pumps, fewer wage
labourers and a less developed transport system (camels a r e still being used. -71-
saqia
Finally, most of t h e migrant groups who brought in t h e
shadouf
methods of irrigation a r e found in t h e south.
northerners from Dongola. over their farms.
and
They a r e nlainly
Their long stay in Kheiran gave them rights
T h e north on t h e other hand is dominated by groups
from Dar Hamid federation, t h e largest group of t h e m is t h e Ferahna. These a r e pastoralists and agro- pastoralists by tradition. of
However, some
t h e m took up t h e new agricultural innovations and b e c a m e orchard
cultivators. The system of
land use which I have described s o f a r , m a d e i t
possible for people t o live in o n e locality and c u l t i v a t e a l m o s t bounded orchards
for
generations.
The
main
techniques
of
land
preservation
adopted by t h e s e people a r e t h e application of a rotation system, which involves one year of cultivation and one or t w o years fallow for e a c h plot.
Land fertility is kept by t h e application of fertilizers o r t h e use of
ploughing and hoeing.
The a r e a under cultivation is usually fenced with
branches of thorn t r e e s while t h e fallow land is l e f t for grazing.
It is
observed t h a t t h e use of fertilizers is increasing and t h e f a r m e r s who use intensive cultivation c a n purchase t h e m at a n expensive r a t e .
With t h e
opening up of new f a r m land o r with t h e shift from one c r o p t o another on c e r t a i n plots, t h e soil is turned and prepared.
Land productivity has
t h e r e f o r e been maintained
by applying such soil preservation practices.
The
productivity
maintenance
of
land
in
Kheiran
comparing t h e values produced per feddan (i.e., 1976 (Manger, 1980:
123-4).
can
be
judged
by
1.04 acres) in 1928 and
The t w o values a r e not different in absolute
terms. The s t a t e of a f f a i r s is dramatically different from t h a t within t h e s a m e savannah zone around Kheiran.
The savannah extensive s y s t e m of
5 years cultivation and s o m e 15-20 years fallow has been changed t o one of 5 years fallow in t h e a r e a s around Kheiran and this has triggered off serious
ecological
degradation.
d e c r e a s e in land productivity.
This
development
has
resulted
in
a
It is interesting, therefore, t o look into t h e
Kheiran c a s e in order t o e x a m i n e how i t succeeded in maintaining i t s intensive
cultivation
system
without -72-
degrading
the
environment.
The Emergence of Irrigated Cultivation T h e i n t e n s i v e a g r i c u l t u r a l production s y s t e m in Kheiran is r e l a t e d t o t h e migration of t h e Danagla a n d t h e Jaliyyin groups i n t o t h e region during t h e 18th and 19th c e n t u r i e s ( B j ~ r k e l o ,1983). t r a d e r s and religious m e n ( f a q i s ) .
T h e s e m i g r a n t s w e r e mainly
They s e t t l e d in t h e f r o n t i e r regions of
Muslim a r e a s t o e n g a g e in t r a d i n g in slaves, gold a n d gum a r a b i c . historical
context
s o m e of
t h e riverain
groups s e t t l e d
In this
in or c l o s e t o
Kheiran a n d t h e y w e r e a b l e t o i n t r o d u c e t h e t w o irrigation t e c h n i q u e s which t h e y brought f r o m home.
A n e x a m p l e t o i l l u s t r a t e t h i s p r o c e s s is
q u o t e d in John P e t h e r i c k , who w a s a t r a v e l l e r a n d t r a d e r in Kordofan in t h e 1840's.
H e noted in o n e of his journeys t h a t h e w a s i n v i t e d t o spend
t h e night in t h e compound of: "a n a t i v e f r o m Dongola, n a m e d Mackaui (Makkawi), a shrewd welli n f o r m e d m a n of f i f t y y e a r s of a g e , who when a boy with his f a t h e r a n d f a m i l y had m i g r a t e d t o t h e province of Kordofan a n d w a s p r e s e n t a t t h e c o n q u e s t of t h e province by t h e D e f t e r d a r . Mackaui possessed a f e w s l a v e s a n d l i k e m o s t of t h e o c c u p i e r s of t h e rich o a s e s ( n e a r Bara), supported himself by t h e produce of his garden, which w a s w a t e r e d f r o m a well of t w e l v e f e e t in d e p t h by his s l a v e s by m e a n s of a l e v e r ( s h a d o u f ) i r r i g a t e d during t h e w i n t e r a n d s u m m e r months. In t h e rainy season, t h e g a r d e n which w a s n o t m o r e t h a n a n a c r e in e x t e n t , w a s abandoned a n d with his s l a v e s and e v e r y m e m b e r of his f a m i l y c a p a b l e of labour, h e c u l t i v a t e d on t h e sandy slopes in t h e neighbourhood of his village s u f f i c i e n t dukhn, o r millet f o r t h e i r consumption." ( P e t h e r i c k , 186 1: 259, q u o t e d in Bj$kelo, 1983: 282). T h e n o r t h e r n m i g r a n t s a p p r o p r i a t e d land mainly by establishing links with t h e p a s t o r a l i s t s who d o m i n a t e d t h e a r e a a n d used t h e Kheiran o a s e s for watering
t h e i r animals.
They w e r e t h e r e f o r e n o t a f f e c t e d by t h e
cultivators.
T h e m i g r a n t s a l s o a c q u i r e d permission t o use t h e land by
paying a nominal r e n t of four hods of onion a n d a bag of chillies ( s h a t l a ) , (MacMichael, 1919:
236).
This s m a l l p a y m e n t i n d i c a t e s t h a t i t w a s n o t a
r e a l r e n t but a t o k e n of friendship, a symbol of good will t o t h e p a s t o r a l l e a d e r s f o r allowing t h e m t o live a m o n g s t t h e m .
T h e d o m i n a n t f o r m of
labour w a s s l a v e labour which w a s used t o o p e r a t e t h e shadouf
.
production,
saqia
and t h e
In f a c t , s l a v e s w e r e of p a r a m o u n t i m p o r t a n c e t o all t y p e s of not
only
in
Kheiran,
but
also
outside
among
Dar
p a s t o r a l i s t s who used t h e m a s h e r d e r s or in rainfed cultivation.
Hamid The
m i g r a n t n o r t h e r n e r s produced w h e a t which w a s sold in t h e m a r k e t s in t h e area;
especially B a r a and El Obeid which w e r e t h e main m a r k e t p l a c e s a s
well a s being a d m i n i s t r a t i v e
and
m i l i t a r y c e n t r e s f r e q u e n t l y visited by -73-
5
t r a d e caravans. This s y s t e m developed d i f f e r e n t l y a m o n g t h e various groups in Kheiran. T h e pioneer leading groups a m o n g t h e m i g r a n t s w e r e used by t h e Turks a s t a x c o l l e c t o r s a n d t h e y a l s o s u c c e e d e d in a u g m e n t i n g t h e i r i n c o m e f r o m t h e commissions t h e y r e c e i v e d f r o m t h e t a x e s . engaged
in t r a d i n g a c t i v i t i e s
besides o p e r a t i n g
Such groups w e r e also t h e i r l a r g e o r c h a r d s in
Kheiran. T h e s e leading groups w e r e a t t a c k e d
by t h e Mahdist f o r c e s in t h e
1880's a n d had t o f l e e t h e a r e a a n d r e t u r n e d only a f t e r t h e e s t a b l i s h m e n t of
the
Anglo-Egyptian
Condominium
r u l e (1 898-1 956).
Many
of
them
a c t u a l l y r e t u r n e d t o t h e i r s e t t l e m e n t s in t h e n o r t h e r n p a r t of Kheiran o n c e peace and order were restored.
T h e reason f o r this w a s t h a t f o r ordinary
m i g r a n t s like Mackaui, Kheiran w a s a p l a c e w i t h o p p o r t u n i t i e s f o r deploying t h e irrigation t e c h n i q u e s t h a t t h e y brought with t h e m f r o m home.
I t is a l s o probable t h a t D a r Hamid groups took up t h e s a m e t y p e of c u l t i v a t i o n p r a c t i s e d by t h e migrants.
Thus t h e l e a d e r s of t h e p a s t o r a l i s t s
w e r e a b l e t o u t i l i z e s o m e of t h e i r s l a v e s in i n t e n s i v e i r r i g a t e d cultivation. I t is a l s o e v i d e n t t h a t s o m e of t h e p a s t o r a l i s t s who w e r e impoverished by t h e loss of t h e i r h e r d s joined in a n d c u l t i v a t e d land in Kheiran in o r d e r t o gain t h e i r s u s t e n a n c e a n d re-build t h e i r herds.
Changes in the 20th Century Kheiran
has witnessed s e v e r a l c h a n g e s during t h i s century:
f i r s t , land
ownership w a s s e t t l e d by t h e British a f t e r t h e Danagla r e t u r n e d f r o m t h e i r r e f u g e f r o m t h e Mahdist troops.
The Ferahna cultivators also obtained
t i t l e t o t h e i r individual plots.
Thus t h e land s e t t l e m e n t c r e a t e d a rough
division
a
of
the
Kheiran
into
d o m i n a t e d by o n e of t h e groups.
southern
and
a
northern
part,
each
F u r t h e r m o r e , t w o t y p e s of land e m e r g e d :
t h a t which w a s considered p r i v a t e l y owned a n d could b e i n h e r i t e d by t h e Danagla and F e r a h n a descendants.
T h e o t h e r w a s t h e land o u t s i d e t h e
oases, w h e r e c o m m u n a l ownership prevailed.
T h e c o n t r o l of t h e pastoralist
l e a d e r s o v e r t h e f e r t i l e lands of t h e Kheiran o a s e s w a s t h e r e f o r e broken. T h e British also prohibited s l a v e r y a n d t h e big f a r m e r s had t o depend on f a m i l y labour o r hired labour.
T h e r e s u l t w a s t h a t w a g e labour gained
m o r e i m p o r t a n c e a s a s u b s t i t u t e f o r s l a v e labour.
T h e main products have a l s o changed f r o m w h e a t t o onions since t h e price of
t h e imported w h e a t w a s c h e a p e r t h a n t h a t produced locally.
Recently, t h e cultivation of o t h e r types of vegetable crops b e c a m e m o r e i m p o r t a n t in t h e south due t o t h e expansion of El Obeid urban market. Although t h e saqia
and shadouf
w e r e t h e main technologies, mech-
anical pumps w e r e introduced during t h e 1960's and t h e y replaced t h e
saqia r a t h e r quickly.
Thus in El Bashiri, t h e biggest village and oasis in
t h e south, t h e r e w e r e t w o
saqia
in 191 1 , six in 1940 and only t h r e e by
1960 when t h e f i r s t pump w a s installed. 1976 t h e r e w e r e no
saqia
During my s t a y in t h e village in
l e f t while t h e number of pumps had risen t o
five with t w o m o r e being installed in t h e s a m e year.
F o r t h e whole of
Kheiran t h e r e w e r e 25 pumps in t h e south, and 7 pumps in t h e north in 1976.
l e f t in 1976. than
saqia in 1957 but none of t h e s e w e r e The decline in shadouf numbers which w e r e m o r e numerous
Born (1965) registered 1 3
saqia
w a s gradual and those who g a v e up using i t usually took up While t h e r e w e r e 14 shadouf
o t h e r activities, especially w a g e labour.
El Bashiri in 191 1 , t h e r e w a s n o shadouf by t h e year 1976. c u l t i v a t o r s of leaving t h e shadouf
in
This t r e n d of
s e c t o r t o t h e pumps is m o r e visible in
t h e south t h a n in t h e north w h e r e m o r e f a r m e r s tended t o c a r r y on with t h e shadouf.
In t h e following seciion I e x a m i n e t h e general t r e n d of such
developments and t h e i r i m p a c t on Kheiran.
Development Trends in Kheiran It is obvious s o f a r t h a t rich f a r m e r s w e r e a b l e t o change over f r o m t h e
saqia
and t h e
shadouf
t o invest in mechanical pumps.
T a x collectors
f r o m Azhaf in t h e south s e t t l e d in El Bashiri a f t e r t h e collapse of t h e Mahdist s t a t e and invested in t h e new technology.
They also owned
animals and o p e r a t e d a s t r a d e r s in t h e a r e a which enabled t h e m t o invest their surplus in mechanical pumps.
T h e tribal leaders of t h e F e r a h n a w e r e
also able t o invest in pumps by selling s o m e of their animals and using t h e cash for
t h e purchase of
t h e machinery needed f o r irrigation.
This
explains why four o u t of seven pumps in t h e north belong t o t h e leading Farahna family.
An i m p o r t a n t a d v a n t a g e of t h e new pump technology is
t h a t i t i s m o r e e f f i c i e n t than t h e saqia of t h e wooden wheels of t h e saqia among i t s disadvantages.
.
Constraints such a s t h e friction
and t h e loss of w a t e r in irrigation a r e
More important, however, is t h e use of oxen a s
t r a c t i o n animals and their need t o be f e d on fodder which should b e grown Tothill (1948) reported t h a t a s much a s 50 per c e n t of t h e
on t h e plots.
saqia
c u l t i v a t e d land under t h e
t h e oxen drawing t h e wheel.
might b e used for producing fodder for Compared with t h e g r e a t e r c a p a c i t y of
mechanical pumping a n d i t s closed pipes which eliminate w a t e r loss, t h e modern
system
can
be
regarded
as
more
efficient.
Even
if
fuel
consumption is substantial and has t o b e purchased, t h e 1976 figures reveal t h a t only about an equivalent of 30 per c e n t of t h e c r o p value w a s spent on
fuel.
The mechanical
development f o r
Kheiran
pumps h a v e t h u s represented a n i m p o r t a n t
innovative
rich f a r m e r s who could a f f o r d t o
obtain this t y p e of technology. More land and labour w e r e needed in o r d e r t o m a k e t h e full use of t h e pump c a p a c i t y t h a n w a s t h e c a s e with t h e saqia
.
MacMichael's l a ~ d
distribution ordinance e a r l y in this c e n t u r y w a s based on t h e t h e n existing technology, and small polots of about t h r e e feddans w e r e allocated
saqia
e a c h saqia.
T h a t f a r m s i z e w a s sufficient and i t was possible t o c u l t i v a t e
o n e feddan and thus t o keep t h e rotation s y s t e m operational.
The diesel
pump c a n i r r i g a t e m o r e land (about 3-5 feddans) and such a f a r m c a n b e viable only if t h e f a r m e r has a b o u t a t l e a s t t e n feddans t o be a b l e t o observe t h e rotation system.
T h e major problem for pump owners today
is, therefore, how t o a c q u i r e m o r e land. T h e answer t o t h e land question i s found in t h e s t r u c t u r e of t h e
shadouf
economy which has been in decline, a s I described earlier.
use of t h e
shadouf
The
f o r 'irrigation i s seasonal because t h e f a r m e r s under
this s y s t e m usually r e t r e a t t o rainfed cultivation during t h e rainy season. In addition t h e y k e e p s o m e animals and m a y work a s wage labourers for t h e m e r c h a n t farmers.
In a n analysis of this s e c t o r (Manger, 1980, 1981)
I a r g u e t h a t t h e decline of t h e
shadouf
s y s t e m c a n be r e l a t e d t o t h e
increasing demand f o r labour in o r d e r t o b e able t o s e c u r e t h e annual income needed by t h e family t o m a k e ends meet.
This is r e l a t e d t o t h e
d e c r e a s e in t h e income f r o m rainfed cultivation due t o desertification.
As
their income declines, family m e m b e r s have t o compensate this by putting m o r e e f f o r t s into t h e shadouf cultivation.
Carrying on this t y p e of work
f o r a long t i m e m a y lead t o f r u s t r a t i o n and discontent and t h e f a r m e r s m a y t r y t o seek a n a l t e r n a t i v e source of income, especially w a g e labour. The
shadouf
land i s t h u s abandoned by t h e smallholders who t h e n r e n t
t h e i r f a r m lands t o t h e pump owners. Again, t h e r e a r e d i f f e r e n c e s between northern and southern Kheiran. In t h e north m o r e people maintained shadouf cultivation while in t h e south t h e f a r m e r s began t o r e n t t h e i r several factors
such
as
the
land. This c a n b e r e l a t e d t o
shadouf
commercialization
in
t h e south
involving
numerous c r o p v a r i e t i e s which need intensive agricultural operations, such a s watering, transplanting, a n d making new vegetable beds.
O t h e r socio-
cultural f a c t o r s such a s women's m o r e a c t i v e participation in agricultural production in t h e north helped t o r e d u c e pressure on t h e m e n t o increase t h e i r e f f o r t s in t h e shadouf. Furthermore,
t h e population in t h e north still
keep a
significant
number of animals, e i t h e r by themselves o r , w i t h pastoral relatives.
They
c a n t h e r e f o r e g e n e r a t e m o r e income f r o m t h e herds t h a n in t h e south. Finally, t h e population of t h e south belong t o t h e group of m i g r a n t s who settled
throughout
Kordofan
and
c o n t a c t s with t h e urban population. a l t e r n a t i v e jobs in towns.
have
long- standing
relationships
and
They c a n , therefore, m o r e easily find
All t h e s e f a c t o r s indicate t h a t t h e f a r m e r s in
t h e north c a n o p e r a t e a t a lower level of
labour intensity with t h e
shadouf t h a n t h e f a r m e r s in t h e south.
This
process
does
not
bring c o n s t r a i n t s on
s c h e m e owners in t h e north a s in t h e south.
t h e mechanical
pump
T h e tribal leaders have
a c c u m u l a t e d m o r e land t h a n in any o t h e r place.
They c o n t r o l several
oases which c a n be put under cultivation and s e c u r e high production levels. T h e pumps in t h e north a r e constrained m o r e by t h e n a t u r e of t h e fragm e n t e d m a r k e t s within which t h e y a r e found and t h e long d i s t a n c e s from o n e m a r k e t place t o a n o t h e r and f r o m t h e urban markets.
Onions a r e
still produced and a r e regarded t h e m o s t i m p o r t a n t cash c r o p because they c a n t r a v e l for long d i s t a n c e without being damaged.
I t is a l s o t r u e t h a t
t h e r e is n o t any rapid expansion of commercialization in t h e north.
The
northern p a r t of Kheiran a p p e a r s t o be m o r e traditional d e s p i t e t h e f a c t t h a t diesel pumps w e r e introduced about 25 y e a r s ago. Wage labourers a r e recruited from migrant or displaced people from outside Kheiran t o work in t h e pump schemes.
They usually d r i f t from
drought stricken a r e a s o r a f t e r t h e y have confronted environmental crises. These workers mostly belong t o t h e Dar Hamid group of agro- pastoralists who
normally have s o m e a n i m a l s a n d c u l t i v a t e m i l l e t , sorghum a n d o t h e r minor crops
during
the
rainy
season.
The summer and
winter
agricultural
a c t i v i t i e s f i t v e r y well w i t h t h e i r s e a s o n a l a g r i c u l t u r a l c y c l e a n d i n s t e a d of m i g r a t i n g t o t h e d i s t a n t i r r i g a t e d m e c h a n i z e d s c h e m e s in t h e Nile valley or t h e m e c h a n i z e d r a i n f e d s c h e m e s in t h e c e n t r a l c l a y plain, t h e y c a n work c l o s e t o sector
home. In t h i s r e s p e c t Kheiran a p p e a r s a s a s m a l l modern
in a n a r e a of
t r a d i t i o n a l p a s t o r a l and agro- pastoral adaptations.
6 Liri Liri is a m o u n t a i n a r e a in t h e very s o u t h of t h e Nuba Mountains, a l m o s t on t h e border of Southern Sudan. massif
T h e a r e a is d o m i n a t e d by a l a r g e hill
which h a s given t h e a r e a i t s name.
T h e land surrounding t h e
mountain i s sandy, w h e r e a s f u r t h e r a w a y a r e t h e c l a y plains s o c h a r a c t e r i s t i c of s o u t h e r n Kordofan. t h e f o o t of t h e mountain. t h e mountain itself.
Most of t h e i n h a b i t a n t s live in villages around However, t w o villages a r e still found on t o p of
T h e i n h a b i t a n t s of Liri a r e H a w a z m a a n d Kawahla
A r a b s a n d a l s o Liri, L a f o f a a n d T a l a s a Nuba.
In addition t h e r e a r e s o m e
J e l l a b a t r a d i n g f a m i l i e s in t h e m a i n m a r k e t s , West A f r i c a n F e l l a t a and Southerners, mainly Dinka, Nuer a n d Shilluk. T h e a d a p t i v e s y s t e m in t h e a r e a is based on agriculture.
P e o p l e living
both on t h e mountain a n d in t h e plain c u l t i v a t e d i f f e r e n t t y p e s of field calle d house fields, a d j a c e n t fields a n d d i s t a n t fields.' T h e f i r s t t w o t y p e s a r e in o r around t h e villages on t h e sandy soil.
Quick m a t u r i n g v a r i e t i e s of
sorghum, m a i z e a n d bean5 a r e planted h e r e t o g e t h e r with peanuts.
For
t h e m a j o r i t y of people, however, t h e d i s t a n t fields a r e t h e m o s t i m p o r t a n t o n e s economically. plains.
T h e y a r e found a w a y f r o m t h e mountain on t h e c l a y
They a r e p l a n t e d with slow m a t u r i n g sorghum in J u n e a n d h a r v e s t -
e d in J a n u a r y and February.
A p a r t frorn rainfed c u l t i v a t i o n people k e e p
s o m e animals, especially c a t t l e and g o a t s .
In addition, t h e i n h a b i t a n t s
exploit possibilities t o e a r n m o n e y in t h e a g r i c u l t u r a l s c h e m e s in t h e region both
t h e cotton schemes and
sorghum.8
t h e bigger,
m e c h a n i z e d s c h e m e s growing
Many people also l e a v e t h e a r e a f o r w a g e labour, especially in
K h a r t o u m a n d o t h e r big c i t i e s in t h e S u d a ~ . T h e L a f o f a Nuba a l s o follow t h i s g e n e r a l p a t t e r n of a d a p t a t i o n , but s o m e d e c a d e s a g o t h e y w e r e m u c h m o r e confined t o o n e of t h e villages on the
mountain,
also called
Lafofa.
My
main
f o c u s shall
be on
this
mountain village and t h e development of
mixed farming there.
Today
t h e r e a r e s o m e 400 inhabitants in t h e village, living on a plateau s o m e 200m a b o v e t h e plain.
Most of t h e L a f o f a have, however, moved down
f r o m t h e mountain and a r e t o d a y found in t h e villages a t t h e f o o t of t h e mountain or in s o m e regional town c e n t r e s . situation w a s different.
But s o m e d e c a d e s a g o t h e
Many m o r e people lived on t h e mountain, depend-
ing on a system of intensive cultivation.
This system w a s based on t h e
building of t e r r a c e s t o control w a t e r flow a n d erosion, t h e manuring of house fields and t o s o m e e x t e n t t h e near fields, and t h e collection of fodder f o r t h e i r animals. aspects
of
this
The following section will describe t h e i m p o r t a n t
system,
both
its
emergence
and
maintenance.
The Lafofa in Liri T h e L a f o f a a r e not original inhabitants of t h e Liri a r e a . live in a n a r e a e a s t of t h e Liri mountain, in Tikeim.
They used t o
In t h e 19th c e n t u r y
this was p a r t of t h e Tegale kingdom, a pre- colonial s t a t e in t h e e a s t e r n Nuba Mountains (Ewald, 1983).
This southern p a r t w a s under t h e admin-
istration of t h e mek of Gedir who collected t r i b u t e from his people and who maintained links with t h e king in Tegale.
The system a t t h a t t i m e
w a s dominated by general insecurisy d u e t o f r e q u e n t slave raids, both by t h e rulers themselves, by t r a d e r s and by pastoralist groups.
Thus s o m e
pastoralists had fixed a g r e e m e n t s with t h e rulers t o raid c e r t a i n mountains paying f o r this by leaving p a r t of t h e booty f o r t h e rulers.
During t h e
Turkish period t h e situation w a s particularly bad because of t h e increasing demand f o r slaves a t t h a t time.
Also, during t h e Mahdia
t h e region
experienced g r e a t unrest, particularly in t h e t i m e of Khalifa Abdull'ahi who s e n t one of his amirs , Abu Anja, on a punitive expedition t o Tegale because t h e rulers t h e r e refused t o support t h e Mahdist regime.
This
punitive expedition w a s very brutal and people fled f r o m their homes areas.9
This t h e n w a s t h e background t o t h e Lafofa m o v e m e n t i n t o Liri
a r e a , and their s e t t l e m e n t in t h e mountains. o t h e r s e t t l e m e n t s in Liri a s well.
A t the time there were
The Liri a n d Talasa Nuba w e r e t h e r e a s
w e r e t h e s e t t l e m e n t s of t h e H a w a z m a and Kawahla groups.
Some of t h e s e
groups also consisted of fugitive slaves, and on their arrival in Liri t h e y took on t h e tribal identities of their f o r m e r masters.
The Nuba lived on
t h e hills where they c u l t i v a t e d t h e i r f a r m s on t h e t e r r a c e s in order t o
As f o r t h e plains t h e r e w e r e no
p r o t e c t themselves from slave raiding. villages a s is t h e situation today.
People clustered together according t o
social links, but mostly for d e f e n c e purposes.
Slave t r a d e w a s going on
and t h e r e was a small c e n t r e a t t h e e a s t e r n side of t h e mountains from where this type of t r a d e was conducted. This s t a t e of a f f a i r s continued into t h e 20th century.
The f i r s t task
f o r t h e British colonialists was t o control t h e source a r e a s of slaves and t o c r e a t e t h e means for a peaceful
CO - existence
of t h e various groups.
The f i r s t 20 years of t h e Anglo-Egyptian rule (1898-1956) w e r e c h a r a c t e r ized by frequent punitive controls and a t t e m p t s t o build a n administrative s t r u c t u r e t h a t could c r e a t e such a peaceful
CO - existence.
The last British
expedition was a s l a t e a s 1920 when they a t t a c k e d Lafofa village on t o p of t h e mountain. t o pay taxes.
The official reason w a s t h a t t h e inhabitants had refused
Consequently, t h e Lafofa w e r e forced t o m i g r a t e down from
t h e tops of t h e hills and t o s e t t l e a t t h e f o o t of t h e hill slopes where they could easily be controlled.
However, t h e regulations banning living on
t h e tops of hills w e r e abolished s o m e years later.
Some of those who
lived on t h e plains have undergone a process of change a s a consequence of their c o n t a c t s with o t h e r e t h n i c groups in Liri a r e a , and from having a c c e s s t o education, dispensaries, and markets.
At t h e s a m e t i m e Islam
and t h e Arabic language began t o p e n e t r a t e and t h e matrilineal Lafofa society
was profoundly a f f e c t e d by
t h e s e changes.
From
the
1930's
onwards, t h e r e was t h u s a gradual process of integrating t h e Lafofa into larger political and econqmic structures.
This in turn had a significant
i m p a c t on their socio- cultural life and their system of ecological a d a p t a t i o n
Mixing Farming among t h e Lafof a From
their
t i m e in
the
mountain
village,
t h e Lafofa
had
developed
intensive production techniques in order t o maintain a dense population within a marginal mountain environment.
O n e method was t h e building of
t e r r a c e s t o reduce w a t e r run-off and thus t o limit soil erosion.
These
t e r r a c e s a r e no longer being maintained in t h e village, only remnants can be seen on t h e mountain slopes.
R e m n a n t s of old s e t t l e m e n t s in more
r e m o t e places, away from t h e plain w h e r e people a r e today living, indicate a past period with m o r e people and more pressure on land.
A second
technique is t h e more close integration between livestock and field.
The
Lafofa kept their animals in kraals during t h e night, and t h e dung was collected and spread on t h e house fields and those of t h e adjacent fields t h a t w e r e close enough.
This technique is t o a c e r t a i n e x t e n t c a r r i e d on,
and people still put s o m e e f f o r t into it.
But t h e animal numbers a r e
smaller although interestingly, t h e mountain Lafofa keep animals belonging t o their relatives in t h e plains villages during t h e cultivation season.
This
is t o avoid c a t t l e entering t h e fields and t h u s spoiling t h e grain.
The
e f f e c t of this is t h a t numbers of animals on t h e mountain increase at c e r t a i n periods and t h e fields g e t m o r e manure.
This link between field
and manure is common also elsewhere in t h e savannah, and people a r e a w a r e of i t s implications.
O n e example of this is from Darfur where
informants in t h e Gidad a r e a s t a t e t h a t a herd of 30 cows produce enough manure t o keep one makhammas(about 314 of a feddan) of goz permanently f e r t i l e if they a r e k e p t for 18 nights on t h e fields (Haaland, 1980:
84).
The Lafofa a r e unable t o give such precise information but t h e y a r e fully a w a r e of t h e benefits. among t h e Lafofa.
There is also s o m e fodder collection going on
A f t e r t h e introduction of peanuts a s a cash crop, t h e
f a r m e r s began t o utilise t h e leaves of t h e plant;
they a r e collected, made
into bundles and put into big t r e e s o u t of reach of animals until summer when
pasture
will
be
scarce,
or
given
to
a
sick
animal.
Apart from t h e problems of developing a viable cultivation technique t o keep a dense population on a limited a r e a of land, t h e t r a n s f e r and redivisions of land becomes a n important bottleneck in maintaining such systems.
The plots become smaller and smaller and have t o b e cultivated
more intensively.
Another problem is t h a t of securing land f o r those who
actually need it.
Land among t h e Lafofa is transferred through t h e m a t r i -
lineal line of descent.
The members of t h e s a m e matrilineage live near
e a c h o t h e r within a specific boundary known by land marks, a w a t e r course, a hill or some stones.
House fields a r e inherited by matrikin, usually a
sister's son who has been brought up in t h a t house.
Such a system based
on land transfers within unilineal groups could develop imbalances between t h e land controlled by t h e group, and population growth (and other demographic developments) within t h e s a m e group.
This problem is also pointed
out by Goodenough (1955) in a n a r t i c l e on Malayo-Polynesian social organization.
The solution t h e r e is t h a t people can t a k e land from a wider range
of relatives and not only t h e members of t h e s a m e descent group.
The
Lafofa have in common with t h e Malayo-Polynesians, a similar t y p e of
land t r a n s f e r e n c e of
t h e a d j a c e n t fields.
Such fields c a n be acquired
through both t h e matrilineal and t h e patrilineal lines of descent during t h e owner's
life time.
T h e flexibility of t h e system allows for p r a g m a t i c
solutions t o t h e land problem a s has also been reported by Nadel (1947) among t h e Mesakin and Korongo m a t r i l ~ n e a lgroups of t h e southern p a r t of t h e Nuba mountains. Today, with less pressure on t h e mountains and t e r r a c e d cultivation, such e l e m e n t s of social organization a r e of less i m p o r t a n c e than in t h e past, a n d people h a v e a wider choice of fields.
The m o s t important
a l t e r n a t i v e now is t h e opening up of d i s t a n t f a r m s on t h e plain clays. H e r e land is not s c a r c e and a person m a y c l e a r a plot without asking t h e permission of anyone.
A son m a y t h e r e f o r e c l e a r his own plot a w a y from
t h a t of his f a t h e r s o t h e question of land t r a n s f e r becomes less problematic.
In t h e c e n t r a l Nuba Mountains, however, where population density is
higher, all land has been confined t o c e r t a i n owners and t h e t r a n s f e r of land
including
t h e distant
farms
is of
g r e a t importance.
There,
in
c o m m o n with Liri, t h e t r a n s f e r of distant f a r m s is from f a t h e r t o son following a patrilineal principle of descent which is also d i f f e r e n t from t h a t of t h e mountain's residents. Another problem r e l a t e d t o intensive s y s t e m s of production is t h e mobilization operations.
of
sufficient
labour
power
t o s e c u r e all labour intensive
A p a r t f r o m household labour a very prominent f e a t u r e among
t h e L a f o f a is t h e extensive use of communal labour.
The common t y p e of
communal work groups o r beer parties, known in Sudan a s c o m m o n all over Africa.
nafir
,
However, t h e r e a r e also t w o m o r e e l a b o r a t e
f o r m s of communal labour, namely, hakurna (government) and rnaliki malik o r king).
(from
These t w o f o r m s of labour mobilization institutions
m o r e formal, with fixed membership, work e a c h
are
are
t h e y h a v e rules about how much
participant should c a r r y o u t a n d how much beer and food
should b e provided t o g e t h e r with a s y s t e m of sanctions t h a t k e e p t h e m e m b e r s of t h e group abiding by i t s rules. system
of
ranks
administration,
with
etc..
titles I
have
borrowed provided
e l a b o r a t e analysis of such work groups.
T h e groups have a n e l a b o r a t e from
the
elsewhere
army, (Manger,
the
police,
1987)
an
H e r e I shall only point o u t a f e w
f e a t u r e s of such s y s t e m s of labour mobilization. Without reducing a l l t h e i n t r i c a t e labour organizations found among
t h e L a f o f a into a m e r e functional f i t within a n intensive production s y s t e m , o n e significant implication
i s surely t h a t t h e making a n d repairing of
t e r r a c e s , weeding, and harvesting t o g e t h e r with house building and o t h e r tasks a r e m a d e easier by mobilizing such groups.
The development of
t h e s e work groups and t h e i r deterioration in t h e contemporary c o n t e x t a r e m i t i g a t e d by t h e increase in t h e cost involved in their mobilization. price of
The
grain a s well a s of o t h e r consumption goods provided t o t h e
participants
a r e getting
m o r e expensive
and
less
people a r e a b l e t o
mobilize t h e work groups of which t h e y a r e members.
Those who c a n
mobilize t h e communal groups a t t h e present a r e t h e migrants and t h e shopkeepers who h a v e sufficient cash.
The migrants who h a v e sufficient
land in t h e mountains use work groups which a r e m o r e e f f e c t i v e t h a n wage labour.
T h e s h o r t a g e of cultivable lands on t h e hill slopes is t h e major
c o n s t r a i n t t o mobilizing attractive
for
such groups while t h e d i s t a n t f a r m s a r e not
work group participants.
In c a s e t h a t a
migrant
has
acquired sufficient land in a distant f a r m , h e has t o work by himself or h i r e agricultural labourers. t h e r e f o r e marks t h e
T h e movement f r o m t h e hills t o t h e plains
disintegration of t h e old traditional s y s t e m of mobil-
ization of labour. Another i m p o r t a n t reason f o r this disintegration is t h e general decline in t h e use of beer a m o n g t h e young Lafofa, especially t h e migrants.
This
is r e l a t e d t o t h e increasing involvement into t h e wider society t h a t t h e s e migrants experience.
In this wider c o n t e x t t h e y stand, a s Nuba, in an
inferior position t o many o t h e r groups d u e t o t h e s t i g m a of having been slaves, using beer in such a n extensive way, not dressing properly, etc.. T o b e c o m e able t o p a r t i c i p a t e in a wider s y s t e m t h e young L a f o f a a r e today going through
processes of assimilation, in which t h e y renounce
i m p o r t a n t a s p e c t s of t h e i r traditional cultural background and t a k e on a 'Sudanese' identity.
O n e a s p e c t of this c h a n g e is t h e stopping of using
beer a n d this f u r t h e r a c c e l e r a t e s t h e disintegrating process of communal work groups. Conclusions: The
main
Agricultural Intensification and Resource Maintenance focus of
this paper
has been on t w o s y s t e m s of
cultivation in Western Sudan;
Kheiran and Liri.
vary
both qualify a s examples of
in
many
respects they
intensive
Although t h e t w o cases
intensification a s i t w a s defined in t h e introduction.
agricultural
T o end this paper i t
is n e c e s s a r y t o d r a w s o m e of
t h e main e m p i r i c a l conclusions f r o m t h e
e x a m p l e s a n d a l s o t o d r a w s o m e lessons which a r e of r e l e v a n c e t o t h e applied
problems
mentioned
in
the
introduction,
i.e.,
how
to
develop
intensive mixed f a r m i n g s y s t e m s in A f r i c a t h a t allow people t o m a k e a living f r o m t h e i r land w i t h o u t d e s t r o y i n g t h e r e s o u r c e base o n which t h e y depend. F i r s t of
all, t h e c a s e s show t h a t t h e a d a p t a t i o n s developed had a
p o t e n t i a l f o r sound c u l t i v a t i o n p r a c t i c e s t h a t helped m a i n t a i n t h e productivity of land a s well a s avoiding e n v i r o n m e n t a l degradation. r o t a t i o n s y s t e m , ploughing a n d t h e a p p l i c a t i o n of f e r t i l i z e r s w e r e t h e t e c h n i q u e s used in Kheiran; t h e o n e s in Liri.
A flexible
manure and chemical t e r r a c i n g and manuring
T h e s e t e c h n i q u e s f o r preserving t h e soil a r e still p r e s e n t
in t h e a r e a s , but a s w e h a v e s e e n , t h e y a r e n o t used by a l l people any longer.
This is r e l a t e d t o t h e changing c o n t e x t t h a t people within t h e s e
s y s t e m s find t h e m s e l v e s in.
T o understand t h e human response t o t h i s
c h a n g e w e h a v e t o g o back t o t h e conditions under which t h e s e agric u l t u r a l s y s t e m s developed. T h e e n v i r o n m e n t a l c o n t e x t of t h e K h e i r a n m a k e s i t a s p e c i a l c a s e . T h e availability of w a t e r c l o s e t o t h e s u r f a c e is uncommon in t h e region. T h e introduction of n e w technologies i s p a r t of a long historical developm e n t in which migration f r o m t h e Nile w a s a m a j o r c h a r a c t e r i s t i c . m i g r a n t s brought t h e i r knowledge a b o u t saqia
The
and shadouf technology, but
t h e rapid expansion of i t in t h e K h e i r a n w a s d e p e n d e n t on t h e availability As peopl'e b e g a n t o depend on t h e i r own labour t h e whole
of s l a v e labour.
v e n t u r e b e c a m e less c o n d u c i v e a n d t h e y l e f t t h e i r g a r d e n s u n a t t e n d e d t o work a s hired l a b o u r e r s in t h e p u m p s c h e m e s a n d elsewhere.
Only in
a r e a s w h e r e t h e socio- cultural c o n t e x t w a s of a kind t h a t r e d u c e d dependence
on
the
continued.
gardens The
in
only
the
total
beneficiaries
economy, from
the
has
orchard
existing
cultivation
opportunities
in
Kheiran a r e t h e rich f a r m e r s w h o c a n a f f o r d t o purchase t h e f u e l pumps. F o r t h e l e s s f o r t u n a t e f a r m e r s i r r i g a t e d c u l t i v a t i o n is of l e s s i m p o r t a n c e t h a n in t h e past. T h e L a f o f a c a s e r e v e a l s t h a t t h e willingness t o develop m o r e i n t e n s i v e mixing
farming
was
a
function
of
hostility,
slave
raiding
c o n s e q u e n t isolation of t h e Nuba groups in a mountain h a b i t a t . -84-
and
the
With t h e
intervention of t h e modern s t a t e , p e a c e w a s guaranteed and a c c e s s t o t h e productive
resources
was
regulated.
However,
the
incentives for t h e intensive system have disappeared.
most
important
The move now is
towards t h e distant fields w h e r e t h e extensive system of
production is
practised and wage labour is in demand. What is important h e r e is t h a t t h e developments in t h e t w o places a r e not identical for a l l units involved.
In Kheiran, t h e commercialized
units continue t o expand whereas those based on household labour tend t o
shadouf
leave t h e
sector.
This is clearly related t o t h e increased
drudgery of t h e work and t h e difficulty in gaining a livelihood from t h e traditional adaptation. labour.
The a l t e r n a t i v e is t o base their incomes on wage
In Liri t h e situation is different.
who control suitable
land
in
It is t r u e t h a t s o m e migrants
t h e mountains a r e still maintaining hill
cultivation, using traditional work groups, but they do not maintain t h e old t e r r a c e s any more and
t h e general trend is for people t o leave t h e
mountain altogether t o s e t t l e on t h e plain and t a k e p a r t in cultivation there.
This trend cannot b e explained by people's subjective evaluation of
t h e drudgery of
work a s was t h e c a s e in Kheiran.
Rather, t h e new
adaptation implies a higher level of work input than t h e traditional one in t h e mountain where t h e work groups helped keep t h e individual's labour input down. m o r e on Labour
To understand why this change is occurring w e have t o focus
t h e general integration of migration,
education
and
t h e Lafofa into society a t large.
other
factors
have
brought
about a
process of assimilation through which s o m e Lafofa adopt a 'Sudanese' way of life.
Down- migration from t h e mountain is a s t r a t e g y t h a t makes i t
easier f o r them t o t a k e p a r t in a new way of life t h a t t h e y now prefer. What t h e c a s e s show is t h a t people, in their a t t e m p t s t o m a k e a living, follow a variety of s t r a t e g i e s t h a t imply different allocations of t i m e , resources and o t h e r assets.
When changes occur, t h e new f a c t o r s
t h a t a f f e c t an adaptation also a f f e c t t h e s e allocations and may produce new social realities.
To r e t u r n t o our t w o examples again i t now becomes
c l e a r t h a t t h e adaptive techniques t h a t w e r e intensive in n a t u r e w e r e not developed because they w e r e ecologically sound, but because they w e r e responses t o a specific c o n t e x t a s it existed a t t h e t i m e of their development.
The overall a i m of t h e people was rather t o make a living for
themselves and their dependents within such a context.. -85-
Today, people
respond t o a new t y p e of c o n t e x t in which many of favoured
t h e intensive adaptation a r e
removed.
the factors that
Relations with other
groups h a v e changed, a c c e s s t o land a n d c a p i t a l has changed a s well a s t h e relationships t o t h e ruling groups and power holders and t h e position in the market.
T h e r e s u l t is a n e w t y p e of a d a p t a t i o n which f r o m t h e point
of view of n a t u r e is m o r e h a r m f u l b u t which a p p e a r s a s a r a t i o n a l w a y of making a living. T h e implications of
t h i s paper a r e r e l e v a n t f o r ongoing e f f o r t s in
A f r i c a t o i n t r o d u c e n e w technologies and t o develop m o r e i n t e n s i v e mixed f a r m i n g systems.
A t t e m p t s t o i n t r o d u c e G r e e n Revoiution m e a s u r e s have
o f t e n f a i l e d b e c a u s e of t h e under- estimation of local responses t o w a r d s t h e i n c r e a s e d labour d e m a n d built i n t o such s y s t e m s c o m p a r e d with t h e existing ones.
s e c t o r a l a p p r o a c h e s h a v e c r e a t e d o b s t a c l e s s i n c e only
Similarly,
w h a t has been labelled a s a n e c o n o m i c a c t i v i t y has been valued, e.g., c u l t i v a t i o n p r a c t i c e s , i s o l a t e d f r o m t h e o t h e r r e s o u r c e s m a n a g e d by t h e farmers
within
a
project
area
-
socio- cultural
factors and
influence e c o n o m i c l i f e a r e r a r e l y t a k e n i n t o consideration.
how
they
Both t h e
Kheiran and Liri c a s e s show t h a t such f a c t o r s a r e of i m p o r t a n c e a n d t h a t t h e y play a decisive rBle in p e o p l e ' s a d a p t i v e choices.
T h e bringing in of
new technologies or n e w production m e t h o d s c a n t h e r e f o r e only s u c c e e d if such new s y s t e m s a r e based o n a n understanding t h a t t a k e s such c o m p l e x relationships i n t o consideration.
NOTES (1)
An e a r l i e r version of t h i s p a p e r w a s p r e s e n t e d a t a workshop in Oxford o n ' S o c i e t y a n d Ecological C h a n g e in North E a s t Africa: C a s e Studies a n d H i s t o r i c a l Perspective.' (1 1- 1 2 Juiy, 1986).
(2)
T h e m a t e r i a l used in t h i s s e c t i o n w a s c o l l e c t e d during 1976. T h e s t u d y w a s f i n a n c e d by t h e Norwegian Agency f o r I n t e r n a t i o n a l Development (NORAD) a s p a r t of t h e Savannah P r o j e c t , a n i n t e r diciplinary r e s e a r c h p r o j e c t based a t t h e D e p a r t m e n t of Social Anthropology, University of Bergen. A m o r e d e t a i l e d analysis of t h e s i t u a t i o n in Kheiran is f u r t h e r e l a b o r a t e d in Manger, 1978, 1980, 1981.
(3)
Shadouf is a hand o p e r a t e d l e v e r which is c o m m o n alongside t h e Nile in N o r t h e r n Sudan.
(4)
Saqia is a wooden w a t e r wheel, usually o p e r a t e d by oxen, also c o m m o n along t h e Nile.
(5)
Hod is a v e g e t a b l e bed and chillies h e r e r e f e r t o shatta or r e d peppers.
(6)
hily fieldwork in Liri w a s undertaken in various periods f r o m 1979 t o 1982. This r e s e a r c h w a s also financed by NORAD a s p a r t of t h e Savannah P r o j e c t . For m o r e d e t a i l s s e e Manger 1984 and 1987.
(7)
Adjacent fields and d i s t a n t fields a r e r e f e r r e d t o in Nadel (1947) a s n e a r fields a n d f a r fields, respectively.
(8)
T h e Mechanized F a r m i n g Corporation of t h e Sudan (MFC) began t o open up large- scale m e c h a n i z e d a g r i c u l t u r a l s c h e m e s f o r p r i v a t e owners in t h e Nuba Mountains s i n c e 1968. Towards t h e l a t e 1970's t h e y introduced such s c h e m e s in t h e s o u t h e a s t e r n mountains in Talodi and El Beida. Thousands of t h e local i n h a b i t a n t s of t h e Nuba Mountains b e c a m e regular seasonal w a g e e a r n e r s working f o r t h e owners of such schemes.
(9)
Vicars-Miles, a British a d m i n i s t r a t o r n o t e s t h a t , 'during t h e Mahdia, t h e people of Gedir w e r e r e p e a t e d l y a t t a c k e d and overcome. Many of t h e i r Nuba s u p p o r t e r s w e r e c a p t u r e d o r killed and most of t h e r e m a i n d e r flyd t o Talodi o r Liri.' (1930)
REFERENCES Allan, W.
T h e African Husbandman.
Edinburgh, 1965.
B a r l e t t , P.
Adaptive S t r a t e g i e s in P e a s a n t Agricultural Production in Annual Review of Anthropology, Vol. 9, 1980.
Bjorkelo, A.
F r o m King t o Kashif. Shendi in t h e 19th Century. D o c t o r a l Thesis, Bergen, 1983.
Born, M.
Bauern und Nomaden i m C e n t r a l Kordofan. 1965.
Boserup, E.
T h e Conditions of Agricultural Growth.
Brookfield, H.
Intensification and Disintensification in P a c i f i c Agriculture. A T h e o r e t i c a l Approach in P a c i f i c Viewpoint, Vol. 13, 1972.
Burnham, P.
Changing Agricultural and P a s t o r a l Ecologies in t h e West African Savannah Region in Harris (ed) Human Ecology in Savannah Environments, London, 1980.
Burton, M., and White, D.
Sexual Division of Labour in Agriculture in American Anthropologist, Vol. 86, No. 3, 1984.
Dow, M.
Agricultural Intensification a n d C r a f t Specialization: A Nonrecursive Model in Ethnology, Vol. xxiv, No. 2, 1985.
Elles, R.
T h e Kingdom of Tegale in Sudan Notes and Records, Vol. xviii, 1935.
Ewald, J.
Leadership a n d Social Change on a n Islamic Frontier: The Kingdom of Tegale, 1780-1 900. PhD Thesis, Wisconsin-Madison, 1983.
G e e r t z , C.
Agricultural Involution. T h e Process of Ecological C h a n g e in Indonesia. Berkely. 1963.
Goodenough, W.
A Problem in Malayo- Polynesian Social Organization in American Anthropologist, 57, 1955.
Hill, P.
Population, Prosperity and Poverty. 1970. Cambridge, 1977.
Haaland, G. (ed) Problems of Savannah Development. Bergen, 1980.
Marburg.
Chicago, 1965.
Rural Kano 1900 and The Sudan Case,
Jahnke, H.
Livestock Production Systems and Livestock Development in Tropical Africa. Kiel, 1982.
Ludwig, H-D.
P e r m a n e n t Farming on Ukara. The Impact of Land Shortage on Husbandry P r a c t i c e s in Ruthenberg (ed) Smallholder Farming and Smallholder Development in Tanzania. Munich, 1968.
MacMichael, H.
The Kheiran in Sudan Notes and Records, Vol. 3, 1919.
McCown e t al
T h e I n t e r a c t i o n between Cultivation and Livestock Production in Semi- Arid Africa in Hall, Canell, Lawton (eds) Agriculture in Semi- Arid Africa. Ecological Studies, Vol. 34, Berlin, 1979.
Manger, L.
Some R e m a r k s on t h e Use of Labour in Kheiran, Sudan in Eriksen e t a1 Aspects of Agro- Pastoral Adaptations in E a s t Africa. Bergen, 1978.
Manger, L.
Cultivation S y s t e m s and t h e Struggle f o r Household Viability under Ccnditions of D e s e r t Encroachment in Haaland (ed) Problems of Savannah Development. 1980
Manger, L.
The Sand Swallows our Land. Overexploitation of Productive R e s o u r c e s and t h e Problem of Household Viability in t h e Kheiran- a Sudanese Oasis, Bergen, 1981.
Manger, L.
T r a d e and T r a d e r s in t h e Nuba Mountains: Jellaba Family F i r m s in t h e Liri A r e a in Manger (ed) T r a d e and T r a d e r s in t h e Sudan. Bergen, 1984.
Manger, L.
Communal Labour a m o n g t h e Lafofa. Vehicle of Economic and Social C h a n g e in Manger (ed) Communal Labour in t h e Sudan (in press), Bergen, 1987.
forthcoming
Mountaineers a n d Plainsmen. Down- migration, C o m m ercialization a n d Socio- Cultural Change a m o n g t h e L a f o f a in t h e Southern Nuba Mountains of t h e Sudan.
Morgan, W., and Pough, J.
West Africa.
Nadel, S.
T h e Nuba. An Anthropological Study of t h e Hill Tribes of Kordofan. London, 1947.
Netting, R.
Hill F a r m e r s of Nigeria. C u l t u r a l Ecology of t h e Kofyar of t h e J o s Plateau. S e a t t l e , 1968.
Netting, R.
Agrarian Ecology in Annual Review of Anthropology, Vol. 3 , 1974.
O I F a h e y , R.
S t a t e and Society in Darfur, London, 1980.
.
London, 1969.
O'Fahey, R., and Kingdoms of t h e Sudan, London, 1974. Spaulding, 3. Roden, D.
Down- Migration in t h e Moro Hills of Southern Kordofan in Sudan Notes and Records, LIII, 1972.
Ruthenberg, H.
Farming Systems in t h e Tropics.
Spaulding, J.
Slavery, Land Tenure and Social Classes in Northern Turkish Sudan in International Journal of African Historical Studies, Vol. 15, No. 1 , 1982.
Oxford, 1976.
Spaulding, J.
T h e Heroic A g e in Sinnar, Ethiopian Series Monograph No. 15. African Studies C e n t r e , Michigan S t a t e Univsity. 1985.
Thomas, F.C.
T h e R61e of A r a b Tribal Authorities in Local Administration between t h e Nile and L a k e Chad. PhD Thesis, University of London, 1956.
Tothill, J. (ed)
Agriculture in t h e Sudan.
Vicars-Miles.
T h e Kawahla of Kalogi. Rural Council. 1930.
Vincze, L.
P e a s a n t Animal Husbandry: A Dialectical Model of Techno- Environmental Integration in Agro- Pastoral Societies. Ethnology, ixix, 4, 1980.
London, 1948. Government Report in Talodi
POVERTY VERSUS AFFLUENCE: The Fiasco of Rainfed Mechanized Agriculture, The Case of Renk District, Southern Sudan Paul Wani Gore One of t h e most striking f e a t u r e s of t h e Sudanese economy in t h e l a s t 25 years o r so, has been t h e growth of mechanized rainfed farming, propelled largely by m e r c h a n t f a r m e r s a n d t o s o m e e x t e n t by t h e government. r81e
of
the
government
in
mechanized
farming
has
The
diminished
very
considerably during t h e l a s t f e w years a s m o s t government f a r m s have been sold t o m e r c h a n t f a r m e r s o r t o t h e oil- rich countries in t h e Gulf. The range of operation of
t h e s e m e r c h a n t f a r m e r s has increased from
production t o t h e marketing of crops grown in t h e mechanized rainfed schemes. ability
Their control of marketing information i s enormous and their to
operate
in
all
parts
of
However, another striking f e a t u r e of
the
country
is
great.
t h e Sudanese economy is t h e
e v e r widening g a p b e t w e e n t h e rich and t h e poor a r e a s of t h e country, and between t h e rich urban c e n t r e s and t h e poor rural areas.
While i t i s t r u e
t h a t t h e g a p between t h e rich and t h e poor countries of t h e world is widening, i t i s also t r u e t h a t t h e g a p b e t w e e n t h e rich a n d t h e poor in developing countries is widening a t a f a s t e r rate.
In f a c t , a s o t h e r
scholars have observed, t h e level of income of t h e majority of t h e poorest people in t h e developing countries, especially t h e poorest ones, has declined absolutely (Griffin, K. 1978). Ibrahim Kursany has rightly reported t h a t o n e of t h e most "serious effects
of
the
-
-
by
the
in t h e rainfed a r e a s is t h e appropriation of
the
private,
merchant farmers)
capitalist
production
(monopolized
economic surplus and i t s t r a n s f e r e n c e o u t of t h e a r e a s of i t s original generation.
Since m o s t of t h e s c h e m e s a r e owned by m e r c h a n t s who w e r e
a t t r a c t e d t o rainfed f a r m i n g through i t s quick and high r a t e of r e t u r n on investment, t h e y used t o utilize most of t h e surplus g e n e r a t e d h e r e outside these (I.
areas
and
Kursany, 1981).
more
significantly
in
non- productive
expenditure."
H e goes on t o s t a t e t h a t a n investigation of
the
destination of surplus (by geographic a r e a and field of economic activity), 'Levealed urban bias coupled w i t h accumulation of m e r c a n t i l e c a p i t a l (by m e r c h a n t s who c o n s t i t u t e t h e largest groups of f a r m owners)".
Thus, he
concludes, "The efficiency of mechanized f a r m i n g in raising funds f o r rural
development
programmes
In a similar
is
very
doubtful."
(I.
Kursany,
1982).
vein Griffin s t a t e s t h a t in o n e way t h e s e m e r c h a n t
f a r m e r s c a n be regarded a s instruments f o r improving t h e distribution of resources in t h e country.
But on t h e whole t h e y a r e o f t e n t h e means by
which exploitation is e x t e n d e d t o t h e rural population, t h u s perpetuating t h e subordination of t h e poor by t h e rich.
If one c a n c o m p a r e t h e s e
f a r m e r s t o t h e multi- nationals, " they c a n be regarded a s a n invisible black box which merely combines labour and m a t e r i a l inputs and t r a n s f o r m s t h e m into i n t e r m e d i a t e and final products.
In t h e process of doing so, value
added i s g e n e r a t e d and t h e result i s higher income f o r t h o s e who pay labour and t h e m e a n s of production and for governments which t a x t h e s e (Griffin, K. 1978).
incomes." There
a r e t w o disturbing a s p e c t s of
mechanized rainfed farming.
First, t h e land under t h e mechanized rainfed farming sub- sector is usually expropriated f r o m t h e rural population who usually used i t f o r t h e i r subsistence
economy
either
tiirough
cultivation or a s grazing land.
the
traditional
system
of
shifting
And since private mechanized rainfed
farming has been found t o c o n t r i b u t e t o t h e destruction of t h e natural resources of t h e s e rural a r e a s , making t h e land practically unusable f o r t h e rural population, vast eroded and exhausted wastelands a r e l e f t , which a r e useless even t o t h e m o r e
s u s t a i n a b l e traditional f o r m s of agriculture.
The
have
traditional
cultivators
been
displaced
by
the
extension
of
mechanized farming, and t h e y a r e pushed t o marginal unproductive lands. (Caroline d e Jong, B. 1984). T h e second a s p e c t is t h a t t h e government in t h e s e a r e a s a c t s like t h e merchants.
T h e t a x e s collected from t h e m e r c h a n t f a r m e r s a r e used else-
w h e r e instead of improving t h e rural poor f r o m whom this wealth had been e x t r a c t e d , whether directly or indirectly. It i s interesting t o t a k e a c c o u n t of Griffin's s t a t e m e n t t h a t "International integration h a s led t o National disintegration and dependence on t h e Third World countries."
By extension o n e could say t h a t national
integration in t h e Sudan has led t o local disintegration and dependence of t h e poor on t h e rich.
This is clearly r e f l e c t e d in t h e growing regional
inequality and t h e widening social differentiation amongst population.
he country's
I t is q u i t e a p p a r e n t t h a t while t h e r e is a growing harmony of
i n t e r e s t among t h e e l i t e s in t h e country, t h e r e is a process of conflict
emerging between t h e e l i t e s a n d t h e masses who a r e largely poor.
This
conflict has o f t e n e r u p t e d i n t o violent civil strife. While this paper will t r y t o t r a c e t h e process of impoverishment in Renk District, i t should b e k e p t in mind t h a t t h e a r e a is only used a s a c a s e study.
Renk has f o r a long t i m e been regarded a s t h e bread basket
of Southern Sudan.
However, like most p a r t s of Southern Sudan, Renk has
not benefited from t h e presence of mechanized agricultural schemes.
This
paper will a t t e m p t t o t r e a t t h e problem of poverty in Renk within t h e wider c o n t e x t of rural poverty in t h e Sudan in general. T h e m a t e r i a l used in t h i s paper was collected in Renk during t w o field research trips in 1983 and 1984. igated
in
Renk
(a)
during
the
T h e following a s p e c t s w e r e invest-
research,
in
addition
T h e traditional
subsistence economy
introduction
a
of
scheme
and
the
to
other
issues:
before
and a f t e r
the
labour
supply
the
to
scheme. (b)
T h e p a t t e r n s of population s e t t l e m e n t in t h e D i s t r i c t and t h e influence of t h e s c h e m e on this pattern. T h e development of mechanized f a r m i n g in Renk, t h e partici-
(c)
pation of t h e local population, and t h e utilization and t r a n s f e r of income g e n e r a t e d f r o m farming. T h e development of services in t h e District.
(d)
It has t o be noted t h a t s e v e r a l i m p o r t a n t changes have t a k e n place in Renk since t h e author last visited t h e a r e a .
T h e civil w a r now being
fought in Southern Sudan has a f f e c t e d Renk in one i m p o r t a n t respect, namely food.
Grain no longer reaches m o s t p a r t s of Southern Sudan.
Also, because of t h e s e c u r i t y situation, t h e control of rinderpest, birds and locusts has b e c o m e difficult and a f f e c t s sorghum production.
Rural Development and the Dimensions of Rural Poverty Throughout human history " poverty" and i t s elimination has been of major concern.
However, poverty a s a social problem has t a k e n on a
dimension f r o m t h e old standard.
new
Although t h e r e have been increased
development e f f o r t s in agriculture and industry, i t has been observed t h a t t h e s e e f f o r t s a r e proving
inefficient
in
m e e t i n g t h e demands of
the
millions of rural poor in t h e Third World. launched
a
development
poverty by 1985.
programme
which
In 1965, t h e United Nations was
intended
t o eradicate
This p r o g r a m m e was reviewed by t h e ILO in 1975, and
i t would found t h a t in most of t h e Third World countries, t h e r e had been T h e r e w a s also no sign of a n a l t e r -
no c o n c e r t e d a t t a c k on rural poverty.
native s t r a t e g y which would o v e r c o m e t h e deeply entrenched s t r u c t u r e of power
and inequality
of
income,
which a r e inherently inimical t o t h e
p a t t e r n of development in which growth and equity become complementary. T h e main objective of any rural development programme, a s i t is often
stated,
is t o
reduce
poverty,
and
they
are,
therefore,
usually
designed t o i n c r e a s e production and r a i s e t h e productivity of labour f o r c e s in t h e rural areas. supply
and
As is s t a t e d in a World Bank Report, "improved food
nutrition,
together
with
basic services such a s health and
education c a n n o t only directly improve t h e physical well-being and quality of t h e rural poor, but c a n a l s o indirectly e n h a n c e their productivity and their ability t o c o n t r i b u t e t o t h e national economy."
(World Bank, 1975).
However, M c N a m a r a has put i t rightly in his foreword t o t h e World Bank Development R e p o r t in 1978 when h e s t a t e d : "The past q u a r t e r c e n t u r y has been a period of unprecedented change and progress in t h e developing world.
And y e t despite t h i s impressive
record, s o m e 800 million individuals continue t o be trapped in which I have t e r m e d absolute poverty:
a condition of life s o c h a r a c t e r i z e d by mal-
nutrition, illiteracy, disease, squalid surroundings, high infant mortality, and low l i f e e x p e c t a n c y s o a s t o belie any reasonable definition of
human
decency." C h a m b e r s concluded similarly t h a t , " the e x t r e m e s of r u r a l poverty in
...
t h e Third World a r e a n o u t r a g e
T h e o u t r a g e is not just t h a t avoidable
deprivation, suffering and d e a t h a r e intolerable; coexist with affluence." It
is implied in
i t is also t h a t t h e s e
(Chambers, R. 1983). these statements
t h a t a s t h e p a c e of
economic
development is a c c e l e r a t e d and productivity increased, poverty c e a s e s t o be an i m p o r t a n t issue.
I t is a l s o implied t h a t poverty is t h e result of social
injustice which could a n d should be eliminated because i t c a n b e c o m e a problem which endangers t h e social s y s t e m by producing national upheavals and divisions, o f t e n ending in revolutions.
T h e word "poverty" itself has been used t o m e a n s e v e r a l things.
It
is, however, i m p o r t a n t t o g i v e broad definitions of w h a t p o v e r t y m e a n s According t o Wedderburn, " Poverty c a n b e d e f i n e d objectively
generally. and
applied
consistently
deprivation ...
only
in
terms
of
the
concepts
of
relative
Individual f a m i l i e s a n d groups in t h e population c a n b e said
t o b e in p o v e r t y when t h e y lack t h e r e s o u r c e s t o o b t a i n t h e t y p e s of diets,
p a r t i c i p a t e in
t h e activities and
h a v e t h e living conditions and
a m e n i t i e s which a r e c u s t o m a r i l y , o r a r e a t l e a s t widely e n c o u r a g e d o r approved,
in
societies
t o which
they
belong.
Their r e s o u r c e s a r e s o
seriously below t h o s e c o m m a n d e d by t h e a v e r a g e individual o r f a m i l y t h a t t h e y a r e , in e f f e c t , excluded f r o m ordinary living p a t t e r n s , c u s t o m s and activities."
(Wedderburn, 1974).
T h e a b o v e definition would include a l l t y p e s of poverty. (1978)
others
appropriate
have
for
provided
today's
a
definition
underdeveloped
which,
countries.
O s t e r and
in
my
In
t h e i r definition,
opinion,
is
p o v e r t y is s e e n t o r e f e r g e n e r a l l y to a c o m p l e x s e t of e c o n o m i c , social and
psychological conditions.
Accordingly, " poverty is f r e q u e n t l y c h a r -
...
acterized a s an inadequate command over resources relative t o needs The
lack
of
resources
is
highly
correlated
with
other,
less
easily
quantified, c o n c o m i t a n t s of poverty, t h u s r e s o u r c e inadequacy is viewed a s a reasonable proxy f o r t h e full s e t of p o v e r t y attributes" .
I t is i m p o r t a n t
t o include w e a l t h a n d a s s e t s t o g e t h e r w i t h i n c o m e in t h e c a t e g o r y of c o m m a n d o v e r resources; subsistence, i.e.,
while n e e d s should
b e d e f i n e d in t e r m s of
t h e minimum r e s o u r c e s r e q u i r e d f o r food, clothing, and
shelter. In c o n f o r m i t y w i t h t h i s s t a t e m e n t , G r i f f i n (1978) h a s observed t h a t t h e p o o r e s t people in m o s t underdeveloped c o u n t r i e s a r e a l m o s t t o t a l l y lacking in both e c o n o m i c a n d political power. less w e a l t h .
H e continues:
They possess f e w skills and
" Politically, t h e y a r e t o o h e t e r o g e n e o u s in
e v e r y t h i n g e x c e p t t h e i r poverty, a n d f o r t h e m o s t t o o i s o l a t e d and subm e r g e d a t t h e b o t t o m of t h e r u r a l power s t r u c t u r e s , t o b e a b l e t o unite o t h e r t h a n locally and e p h e m e r a l l y t o i m p r o v e t h e i r lot... poor
because
economy.
of
the
way
they a r e integrated
into
their
T h e poor a r e society
and
They will n o t c e a s e t o b e poor until t h e e c o n o m y a n d t h e
polity a r e re- organized a n d t h e rules by which t h e f r u i t s of t h e e a r t h a r e d i s t r i b u t e d a r e altered" .
Rural development policies h a v e n o t only been unsuccessful, but i t has also been observed t h a t government administrators who control rural a r e a s and development s c h e m e s o f t e n collaborate with local notables who turn state
resources t o t h e i r
excluded
from
access
p r i v a t e advantage.
to
local
resources
The poorer and
farmers are
government
decisions.
Government policies rarely improve r u r a l incomes or agricultural output, o f t e n such policies t e n d t o worsen inequalities. Renk District:
Its People and Economy
Renk District is t h e northernmost p a r t of Upper Nile Region bordering t h e Blue and t h e White Nile Provinces.
It lies between 9'3'N
occupying a n a r e a of about 32,000 sq.km.
and 1Z015'E,
It is p a r t of t h e c e n t r a l clay
plain of t h e Sudan, with a n a v e r a g e annual rainfall of between 400 and 600 m m , falling mainly b e t w e e n t h e months of July and October.
The
plain is criss- crossed by sandy ridges which a r e used a s a r e a s f o r perma n e n t s e t t l e m e n t by t h e local population.
Although t h e c l a y plain is
generally fertile, t h e sandy ridges, w h e r e t h e population is c o n c e n t r a t e d , h a v e soils of poorer f e r t i l i t y which a r e less i m p o r t a n t subsistence crops. with
bushy
thickets
of
acacia
used f o r t h e production of t h e
T h e vegetation is mainly open grassland trees,
t h e density
of
which
increases
southwards. T h e present population of Renk District is e s t i m a t e d a t about 130,000 people.
It grew f r o m a population of about 59,000 in 1956.
The e t h n i c
composition of t h e District reveais t h a t t h e C e n t r a l Southerners c o n s t i t u t e t h e largest group.
T h e Dinka f o r m m o r e t h a n 70 per c e n t of t h e t o t a l
population of t h e District.
T h e r e s t being m a d e up of Shilluk, Burum, and
t h e Ta'aisha group of Khalifa Abdullahi.
In r e c e n t years i t has been
observed t h a t o t h e r nomadic t r i b e s f r o m t h e southern p a r t of t h e Blue N ~ l e Province h a v e been s e t t l i n g in Renk District in large numbers; been
pushed a w a y f r o m
t h e y have
t h e i r original a r e a s by t h e expansion of
the
mechanized s c h e m e s in D a m a z i n e area. Travellers, during t h e e a r l y p a r t of t h e 19th century, have reported t h a t t h e Dinka inhabited t h e land a s f a r a s Gebelein.
During t h e slave
t r a d e and a s t h e A r a b t r i b e s expanded southwards, t h e Dinka w e r e reduced in numbers and w e r e pushed southwards t o be c o n c e n t r a t e d largely in t h e a r e a s presently occupied by them.
Renk District is predominantly rural, w i t h f e w s e t t l e m e n t s which c a n hardly be c h a r a c t e r i z e d a s urban centres, such a s Renk, Geiger and Melut. However, t h e most i m p o r t a n t f e a t u r e of Renk District is t h a t t h e population tends t o b e c o n c e n t r a t e d into l a r g e villages on t h e sandy ridges which a r e usually dry during t h e rainy season in c o n t r a s t t o t h e w a t e r It is not c l e a r whether this is a r e c e n t f e a t u r e , a
logged clay plain.
result of t h e expansion of t h e mechanized f a r m i n g schemes, o r whether i t has been t h e traditional p a t t e r n of t h e Dinka settlements.
If o n e looks a t
t h e villages f u r t h e r a w a y f r o m t h e schemes, t h e y a r e much smaller and s c a t t e r e d t h a n those near t h e s c h e m e s and s o i t is possible t h a t t h e s c h e m e s h a v e influenced t h e p a t t e r n of population c o n c e n t r a t i o n in t h e District. T h e population in Renk District, a s in o t h e r p a r t s of Region, depend upon a n i m a l rearing, agriculture,
Upper Nile
fishing a n d hunting.
The
Dinka of this a r e a (Abialang, a s t h e y a r e known) have been r e p u t e d t o possess f e w e r c a t t l e t h a n o t h e r Dinka t r i b e s in t h e o t h e r p a r t s of t h e country.
However, like t h e o t h e r Dinka, t h o s e in Renk who k e e p c a t t l e
practise
a transhumant p a t t e r n of movement d i c t a t e d by t h e rainy season.
During t h e rainy p a r t of t h e year t h e animals a r e moved t o t h e sandy ridges w h e r e t h e p e r m a n e n t s e t t l e m e n t s a r e found.
During t h e dry season,
t h e animals t o g e t h e r with m o s t of t h e village population m o v e t o t h e banks of t h e River Nile f o r grazing and water. Subsistence f a r m i n g is t h e most i m p o r t a n t economic a c t i v i t y of t h e population in t h e D i s t r i c t during t h e rainy season.
A local v a r i e t y of
sorghum and millet a r e grown on t h e c l a y plain mainly f o r household consumption.
In t h e past, e a c h household had t h e right of usufruct t o a plot
of t h e communal land in t h e village.
Although t h e m e m b e r s of t h e house-
hold
labour,
provided
the
main s o u r c e of
communal
labour could
be
utilized by organising beer parties. Besides growing t h e local variety of sorghum and millet f o r d o m e s t i c consumption, t h e local population also grow groundnuts in small quantities t o be sold for cash.
T r a d e r s from Renk used t o t r a v e l t o t h e villages
during t h e dry season buying t h e groundnuts f r o m t h e individual households who g r e w them. Ls 5.00,
In t h e l a t e 1970's a s a c k of groundnuts w a s worth
but by 1982 t h e c o s t of a sack had risen t o L s 20.00.
The
t r a d e r s had stopped going t o t h e villages t o collect t h e groundnuts, and
consequently t h e villages had stopped growing t h e m . discouraged
the
traders
from
buying
groundnuts
O n e f a c t o r which
was t h e
heavy
taxes
imposed by t h e Southern Sudan Regional G o v e r n m e n t in t h e l a s t y e a r s of t h e 1970's.
For
every sack
collected from t h e trader.
of
groundnuts, a levy of
L s 10.00
was
Although t h e g o v e r n m e n t had b e n e f i t e d f r o m
t h e t a x , u l t i m a t e l y both t h e people a n d t h e g o v e r n m e n t w e r e t h e losers. T h e intensity of production in R e n k w a s limited by t h e t r a d i t i o n a l methods
of
cultivation
using
manual
labour
and
i m p l e m e n t s , t h e m o s t i m p o r t a n t being t h e hoe.
a
limited
range
of
Although s o m e p a r t s of
Southern Sudan had e x p e r i e n c e d s o m e c h a n g e s in t h e use of n e w agric u l t u r a l i m p l e m e n t s which w e r e i n t r o d u c e d a f t e r 1972, Renk population had n o t b e n e f i t e d f r o m this.
T h e number of f e d d a n s c u l t i v a t e d by t h e house-
t o b e 3 feddans.
hold w a s e s t i m a t e d
In t h e past, plots of
land f o r
c u l t i v a t i o n w e r e s h i f t e d f r e q u e n t l y f r o m o n e a r e a t o a n o t h e r within t h e c o m m u n a l land owned by t h e village. because In
of recent
the
expansion
years
i m p o r t a n t f e a t u r e of
the
of
Today t h i s is no longer possible
the
mechanized
R e n k District.
s c h e m e s along t h e White Nile.
rainfed
mechanized
schemes have
schemes.
become t h e
most
C o t t o n w a s o n c e grown in public
A f e w of t h e s e pump s c h e m e s a r e still
found mainly
in t h e n o r t h e r n m o s t p a r t of t h e D i s t r i c t a n d on t h e e a s t e r n
part
Nile.
of The
the
The
Sudanese
rest
government
h a v e been became
allowed
interested
t o fall in
i n t o disuse.
developing
grain
c u l t i v a t i o n in Renk during t h e 1950's when a d i s t r i c t a g r i c u l t u r a l o f f i c e w a s established a n d w a s assigned t h e t a s k of supervising t h e l o c a l f a r m e r s in t h e i r s u b s i s t e n c e cultivation. vast agricultural
potential
of
T h e g o v e r n m e n t w a s soon t o r e a l i z e t h e t h e District,
and i t
desired
t o increase
production n o t only t o m e e t l o c a l d e m a n d f o r grain, but a l s o t h e d e m a n d s of o t h e r a r e a s including t h o s e in o t h e r p a r t s of Southern Sudan.
The
D e p a r t m e n t of A g r i c u l t u r e t o o k t h e responsibility of supervising t h e local production in land p r e p a r a t i o n f o r c u l t i v a t i o n a n d advising f a r m e r s on t h e a m o u n t of land t o b e l e f t fallow and f o r how long. B e c a u s e of t h e high d e m a n d f o r sorghum and t h e growing need f o r suitable
land
for cultivation,
t h e local administrative
authorities
were
asked t o t a k e t h e i n i t i a t i v e of distributing land t o households, a n d stopping t h e annual burning of g r a s s a s i t w a s traditionally done.
Instead, land
ear- marked for cultivation in a particular year w a s l e f t unburnt until t h e year for cultivation when i t w a s eventually burnt.
The six major a r e a s of
Urn Dilwis, Kolong, Shamadic, Oboyot, Joug, and Melut w e r e a f f e c t e d by this control. By t h e l a t e 1950's t h e agricultural authorities s t a r t e d a series of experiments on their own land t o investigate t h e possibility of producing sorghum on a large scale.
Five schemes of
1,000 feddans e a c h w e r e
cultivated by 1959, and they proved very successful.
This success laid t h e
basis for t h e f u t u r e expansion of mechanized rainfed cultivation in Renk District
at
t h e expense of
the
local
farmers.
Although
a massive
expansion did not t a k e place immediately a f t e r 1959, i t w a s obvious t h a t t h e expansion would t a k e place at t h e expense of t h e local population. From t h e early period of t h e development of mechanized farming in Renk,
it
was c l e a r
that
t h e tendency
w a s towards t h e allocation of
schemes t o individuals who w e r e mainly m e r c h a n t s living in t h e a r e a or in Kosti.
In 1964, 60 s c h e m e s occupying a n a r e a of about 120,000 feddans
w e r e distributed for cultivation in Renk, mainly in Goz Roum and Akon areas.
Ninety per c e n t of t h e s e schemes w e r e given t o individuals, seven
per c e n t w e r e given t o village co- operatives and t w o per c e n t designated public schemes, controlled by t h e government. In 1968, t h e Mechanized Farming Corporation was c r e a t e d t o supervise t h e expansion of
rainfed
mechanized farming in t h e Sudan, and Renk
b e c a m e p a r t of i t s empire. under mechanization,
It continued t o survey and expand t h e land
and by t h e 1969170 season, 209,000 feddans w e r e
allocated, 60.2 per c e n t of which went t o individuals, 14.1 per c e n t w e r e given t o village co- operatives and 9.3 per c e n t remained a s public schemes i.e.,
under t h e Mechanized Farming Corporation.
schemes was boosted Southern
Region.
The expansion in these
by t h e now defunct Regional Government of t h e
In 1983 t h e Regional Ministry of Agriculture in Juba
had distributed 448 schemes of project s t a r t e d in 1976.
1,500 feddans e a c h t o individuals, in a
90.8 per c e n t of t h e s e schemes w e r e given t o
individuals most of whom already had schemes in a r e a s controlled by t h e Mechanized Farming Corporation. Who was eligible
t o receive t h e schemes in t h e initial s t a g e s of
expansion of mechanization in Renk? c e n t of
According t o s t a t e d policy, 60 per
t h e schemes w e r e t o be given t o individuals who w e r e legal -99-
However, t h e r e w e r e o t h e r c r i t e r i a for eligibility
residents of t h e District.
f o r g e t t i n g t h e schemes, namely financial ability, e x p e r i e n c e in agricultural work
and
ownership
of
at
least
During t h e e a r l y period of
a
tractor
and
Dinka
villages
disk
harrow.
t h e distribution of t h e s c h e m e s i t was
found t h a t t h e policy w a s upheld, up t o a c e r t a i n point. a l l recorded
a
and
those
I t w a s found t h a t
belonging t o o t h e r groups w e r e
organized i n t o co- operatives, a n d e a c h co- operative received a scheme. w a s assumed t h a t e a c h village w a s occupied by r e l a t e d families.
It
In order
t o be a m e m b e r of t h e village co- operative, e a c h family head had t o pay Ls 10.00, s o t h a t a village of a b o u t 100 households could pay f o r a s c h e m e of 1,000 feddans.
Individuals f r o m t h e a r e a who applied f o r t h e s c h e m e s
w e r e usually not p r e f e r r e d ; t w o o r t h r e e per s c h e m e .
i n s t e a d t h e y w e r e given s c h e m e s in groups of J o i n t ownership w a s p r e f e r r e d by t h e a u t h o r i t i e s
because i t was thought t h a t t w o or m o r e individuals could a f f o r d t o pay t h e c o s t of obtaining o n e s c h e m e . How could t h e l o c a l Dinka population pay f o r t h e s c h e m e s ?
I t must
b e m a d e c l e a r t h a t t h e Dinka did n o t have a n y m e a n s t o e a r n cash money o t h e r t h a n through t h e s a l e of c a t t l e . t h e m t o pay t h e land fees.
Those who had c a t t l e sold s o m e of
I t w a s a l s o c l e a r t h a t in order t o r e t a i n t h e
ownership of t h e s c h e m e , one had t o be a b l e t o pay t h e annual land f e e s , which by 1976 stood a t Ls 0.25 per feddan. raised t o Ls 0.58 per feddan, i.e.,
In 1977 t h e s e land f e e s w e r e
Ls 870 pounds per s c h e m e of
1,500
feddans. In f a c t , i t could be said t h a t t h e process of impoverishment among t h e majority of t h e Dinka of Renk s t a r t e d with t h e establishment of t h e mechanized s c h e m e s in t h e District.
While t h e Dinka did not possess
t r a c t o r s and disk harrows, t h e y did not have a n y m e a n s of obtaining them. T h e e x i s t e n c e of t h e Agricultural Bank of Sudan s i n c e 1959 did n o t m a k e any
difference
functions
for
to
the
Dinka
t h e establishment
f a r m e r s t o cover t h e c o s t of
population. of
Although one of
main
t h e Bank was t o e x t e n d c r e d i t t o
a g r i c u l t u r a l production, t h e conditions of
eligibility for t h i s c r e d i t w e r e a g a i n s t t h e non- merchant f a r m e r . gives t w o t y p e s of loans;
the
The Bank
long- term loans, repayable over t h r e e t o four
years, and seasonal loans repayable within 18 months.
In order t o be
eligible for a long- term loan (which is usually m o r e substantial t h a n a seasonal loan) o n e m u s t , of course, own a scheme.
T h e f a r m e r must also
house t o b e mortgaged or produce a document
own a s s e t s such a s a
guaranteeing repayment of t h e loan a t t h e prescribed time. at
least
85
per
cent
of
the
scheme
should
have
In addition, been
cleared.
These conditions eliminated t h e traditional f a r m e r s and t h e village co- operatives from competing for credits.
The traditional f a r m e r s who
w e r e given schemes w e r e considered ineligible for t h e loans because they w e r e regarded a s mobile people who moved from o n e a r e a t o another. The co- operatives w e r e considered unstable,
They did not have any assets.
very poorly organized and were, therefore, unviable recipients of t h e loans. The village co- operatives and t h e Dinka individuals who w e r e allocated schemes by t h e MFC (The Mechanized Farming Corporation) e n t e r e d into arrangements with t h e m e r c h a n t f a r m e r s in t h e clearing and cultivation of A m e r c h a n t f a r m e r would l e a s e a cleared
t h e land allotted t o them.
s c h e m e f r o m t h e co- operative o r t h e Dinka a t a n annual c o s t of between Ls 300 - LS 400 when t h e s c h e m e b e c a m e operational.
This arrangement
still l e f t t h e co- operative or t h e Dinka with t h e job of finding additional money t o pay for t h e annual land fees. unsuccessful,
and
by
the
early
1970's
This arrangement o f t e n proved many co- operatives and
Dinka
individuals s t a r t e d t o sell their schemes t o t h e merchant farmers, although t h e s a l e of schemes w a s considered illegal by t h e MFC.
While in 1975176
t h e Dinka in Renk owned 22.8 per c e n t of t h e schemes there, by 1983 this figure fell t o 0.5 per c e n t s i n c e many had sold their schemes t o merchant farmers.
There was o n e basic reason why t h e y sold their schemes, and
t h a t w a s t h a t many of them had sold their c a t t l e t o pay t h e land f e e s during
the
period
when
they
were
still
keeping
the
schemes.
Some indication of how t h e schemes a f f e c t e d t h e Dinka of Renk with r e f e r e n c e t o c a t t l e ownership was shown when 115 households w e r e asked in 1984 a s t o how many head
of c a t t l e they had.
Seventy seven per c e n t
of t h e s e households had no c a t t l e , 84 per c e n t had no sheep and 66 per c e n t had no goats.
For those who owned s o m e animals 90 per c e n t had
less than 20 head.
When this number is compared t o t h e number of
animals usually owned by Dinka living in o t h e r districts, Renk District Dinka appear t o be r a t h e r poor. The introduction of serious effects.
mechanized farming into Renk had o t h e r more
O n e of t h e s e e f f e c t s was t h e development of a small
Dinka e l i t e based in t h e c e n t r e s like Renk, Melut and Geiger. e f f e c t w a s t h e restriction of
T h e second
m o v e m e n t on t h e local population in t h e
District in a r e a s now occupied by t h e permanent villages;
t h e y w e r e no
longer a b l e t o move i n t o a r e a s of t h e s c h e m e s which used t o b e traditional cultivation land. T h e small group of Dinka who have grown t o b e relatively wealthy in Renk a r e those who had s o m e influence in t h e local administration because of being a chief o r sub- chief, o r o n e of t h e i r sons.
These people usually
have political power a t t h e village level, a n d t h e y a r e responsible f o r t h e collection of
government
t a x e s (poll tax).
They have acquired s o m e
r e s p e c t from t h e local m e r c h a n t f a r m e r s who a r e willing t o provide t h e m with c r e d i t f o r agriculture.
This group still own s c h e m e s acquired from
t h e MFC, a p a r t from those given by t h e f o r m e r Regional Government of Southern Sudan and f r o m t h e Regional Government of Upper Nile Region. While t h e SSU (The Sudan Socialist Union) w a s still in existence, t h e y w e r e a l s o t h e most i m p o r t a n t r e p r e s e n t a t i v e s of government.
t h e local population t o t h e
Although t h e s e people s o m e t i m e s identify themselves with
their own local population, t h e y o f t e n a c t against t h e i n t e r e s t s of t h e local population.
And this is o f t e n clearly shown in disputes connected
with land. T h e expansion of large- scale mechanized farming w a s typically into a r e a s traditionally used by t h e Dinka f o r cultivation.
According t o MFC
policy, t h e s c h e m e s w e r e planned t o be a t least 5 km a w a y f r o m t h e n e a r e s t village;
a z o n e a r e a known a s
haram el Hila.
T h e surrounding
land within t h e 5 km radius could b e used f o r cultivation by t h e local village population.
In reality, i t w a s observed t h a t most of t h e villages
w e r e barely o n e k i l o m e t r e f r o m t h e schemes.
It w a s c l e a r t h a t t h e only
available land w a s on t h e sandy ridges on which t h e villages w e r e situated, and which w e r e generally of poor soil quality and not suitable f o r sorghum cultivation.
The villagers
h a v e t o c u l t i v a t e this land, usually with poor
results in t e r m s of production levels. O n e reason why t h e s e s c h e m e s w e r e closed t o t h e villages was t h a t t h e s c h e m e owners w e r e o f t e n illegally expanding t h e f a r m land i n t o a r e a s considered a s village land.
S o m e t i m e s i t w a s t h e local Dinka e l i t e s who
c o m e from t h e s e villages who would c u l t i v a t e this land, arguing t h a t if t h e y did not c u l t i v a t e
this land
m e r c h a n t s would appropriate
it.
In
practice, local populations have been squeezed on both sides by t h e s c h e m e owners and t h e village e l i t e s who usually h a v e t h e i r bases in t h e urban areas. O n e i m p o r t a n t a s p e c t of t h e Renk traditional s y s t e m of cultivation was t h e communal ownership of land which provided t h e basis for shifting cultivation.
Since t h e s c h e m e s e x t e n d a c r o s s and o v e r traditional Dinka
agricultural land, t h e p r a c t i c e of shifting cultivation has been curtailed. In relative t e r m s this s y s t e m was b e t t e r f o r t h e fertility of t h e soil than t h e s t r i p mechanized farming.
The older s c h e m e s in R e n k which have
now been abandoned in p r e f e r e n c e t o t h e new more f e r t i l e ones, can b e described simply a s useless land, unsuitable for agricultural production. What a r e t h e options l e f t t o t h e Dinka in t h e rural a r e a of Renk a s they a r e unable t o utilize t h e land t h a t traditionally belonged t o them? O n e would a r g u e t h a t t h e process of mechanized farming expansion has tended t o c r e a t e labour reserves for t h e schemes.
In t h e traditional
subsistence economy, t w o types of labour f o r c e w e r e distinguished, i.e., t h e regular labour f o r c e engaged in agriculture and livestock herding, composed of young men and women, and grown up children;
t h e second
is t h e i n t e r m i t t e n t labour force, composed of old men, women and young children, who c o m e t o assist t h e regular labour f o r c e during t h e critical period of
harvesting, or b e c o m e a s u b s t i t u t e during illness.
Because
land and c a t t l e w e r e becoming s c a r c e , t h e larger p a r t of t h e regular labour f o r c e b e c a m e under- utilized during most of t h e year.
These people
had t h r e e options f r o m which t o choose: (a)
Migrate t o R e n k town which is a growing c e n t r e of t r a d e and t h e headquarters of t h e District;
(b)
Migrate t o o t h e r p a r t s of t h e country, mainly t o Kosti or Khartoum;
(C)
R e m a i n in t h e village a s a subsistence cultivator or b e c o m e a seasonal wage- labourer in t h e schemes.
Although i t is not possible t o measure t h e r a t e of migration of people from R e n k t o o t h e r p a r t s of t h e Sudan, what is clearly visible is t h e growing number of Dinka s e t t l e m e n t s in R e n k town.
This was already
a p p a r e n t even before t h e present civil war had reached R e n k District early
in 1985.
Renk town does not have much t o o f f e r in t e r m s of employment,
but being near t h e River Nile, those living t h e r e have become engaged in fishing, while their
womenfolk
have become engaged in beer brewing.
Those Dinka who remain in t h e villages have become seasonal wage labourers, and although they a r e less preferred a s seasonal labourers (for being antagonistic)
t o t h e Shilluk or t h e Nuer, i t is not
in c o n t r a s t
uncommon t o find Dinka men and women working in t h e schemes during weeding,
harvesting and t h e cleaning of sorghum.
The money earned
through wage labour is used t o buy grain f r o m t h e m e r c h a n t s who have established supply points in most of t h e large villages.
The Dinka have
become dependent not only on t h e schemes, but also on t h e merchant f a r m e r s who c u l t i v a t e their land. Renk District and the Southern Sudan Administration
In spite of i t s composite c h a r a c t e r , being a n a r e a bordering a mixture of both southern
and
northern
politically and geographically.
groups,
Renk
is a
southern
district
both
It is p a r t of t h e Southern Sudan in t h e
development planning and administrative processes.
Since 1972, Renk was
regarded a s a s t r a t e g i c district by t h e Southern Sudan Regional Government, even a f t e r i t b e c a m e p a r t of Upper Nile Region. f o r several reasons,
t h e m o s t important
It was s t r a t e g i c
being t h a t i t w a s t h e
important single supplier of sorghum t o Southern Sudan.
most
Moreover, t h e
revenue collected from t a x e s in Renk was extremely large, and i t was a very important source of money for t h e regional government.
When t h e
regional government decided t o i n i t i a t e i t s own development schemes in Renk in 1976 i t had t w o main objectives; uction
for
the
growing
population
f i r s t t o boost sorghum prod-
in Southern Sudan,
and second,
to
increase regional government revenue. The
regional government imposed
produce of Renk.
i t s own t a x e s on land and t h e
Whereas t h e MFC levied a n annual land t a x of Ls 225
per s c h e m e t o be collected by t h e MFC, t h e regional government imposed a
t a x of
Ls
l 0 per sack of sorghum and Ls 14 per sack of sesame
produced in Renk, besides a levy of Ls 500 for any s c h e m e in Renk. E s t i m a t e s given by t h e commercial bank in Renk showed t h a t t h e money r e m i t t a n c e s t o Juba, for t h e Ministry of Finance and Planning (Regional), averaged Ls 500,000 monthly,
between t h e months of October and July
e a c h year since 1972. of
salaries
and
P a r t of this money c a m e back t o Renk in t h e form
wages
for
government
employees
in
the
District.
Besides t h e money from t h e schemes, t h e regional government also collected a poll t a x f r o m e a c h household with a n adult male, t h e value of which stood a t Ls 8.25 in 1984.
This money was collected by t h e local
government in Renk through t h e local chiefs. Who benefited f r o m this money?
When you ask a m a n f r o m t h e
village, "When did you s e e t h e district officer this year?"
The reply would
b e "Last year in March, when h e c a m e t o t a k e our taxes."
And if you
ask him another question, "When did you l a s t s e e a health worker this year?"
H e would reply, "We heard t h a t one would be coming soon, and w e T h e r e is one visible thing in t h e rural
have been hearing this since 1972."
a r e a s of Renk District, and t h a t is t h e absence of any schools or health centres
in all
villages occupied
by
the
Dinka.
Another conspicuous
c h a r a c t e r i s t i c of t h e District is t h e absence of Abialang Dinka in any political or
administrative
post;
t h e f i r s t Dinka administrators w e r e
recruited in 1982. Since 1972 t h e SouthernSudan Regional Government had several s t a t e d objectives regarding rural development in t h e Southern Region, t h e most important being t o improve t h e agricultural systems in t h e rural a r e a s in order t o increase production.
Self- sufficiency in food crops was a major
a i m in t h e development policies.
Several e f f o r t s w e r e m a d e t o improve
food production in t h e Southern Sudan through t h e traditional f a r m e r with t h e provision of improved seeds, f r e e or a t a reduced c o s t ,
t h e supply of
improved agricultural implements, and t h e provision of small c r e d i t s t o enterprising
individuals engaged in agriculture.
Assistance from Inter-
national Organizations, both governmental and non- governmental, was given t o t h e regional government a f t e r t h e end of t h e civil war in 1972, for reconstruction
and
development
purposes.
In
addition,
the
Sudanese
government g a v e special assistance through t h e regional development fund. Although this assistance did not boost food production in all regions of Southern Sudan,
most
a r e a s had
their educational and
restored t o t h e pre-civil war situation, and expanded. t h e s a m e thing about Renk. centres
of
population
health services
O n e could not say
While Renk town and t h e o t h e r f e w large
concentration
had
some
educational and
health
facilities, t h e rural population of Renk w a s barely touched by any e f f o r t ,
both
f r o m t h e regional o r
agencies.
national
government, and t h e
international
Development w a s n o t simply reaching t h e s e people.
T h e lives
of t h e people w e r e n o t only s t a g n a t i n g in human t e r m s but declining in t h e s a m e t e r m s (McNamara, R.S.,
1975).
As Sinha has s t a t e d , " recent experience in several countries suggests t h a t t h e s e l e c t i v e approach t o agricultural development, in which s c a r c e resources a r e c o n c e n t r a t e d on t h e people, f a r m s and regions best a b l e t o t a k e a d v a n t a g e of modern technology, rarely works t o t h e a d v a n t a g e of t h e
...
poor
Policies whose e f f e c t is t o favour t h e rich a t t h e expense of t h e
poor a r e not only manifestly unjust, but in t h e end a r e economically selfdefeating. economic
They push advance
f r u s t r a t i o n t o t h e point of
into
a
costly
collapse
of
violence,
and turn
social
stability."
Conclusion I t is usually s t a t e d t h a t globally, t h e p a t t e r n of world poverty r e f l e c t s a gradient f r o m e x t r e m e s of w e a l t h t o e x t r e m e s of poverty. there
CO -exist
rich,
urban,
A t o n e end
industralized, high s t a t u s cores, and on t h e
other, poor, rural, agricultural, and low s t a t u s peripheries.
Thus, poverty
is t o be understood primarily in t e r m s of economic forces, social relations, property rights, and power.
It c a n also b e viewed n o t only a s r e l a t i v e
deprivation, but also deprivation f o r t h e many and a f f l u e n c e f o r t h e few. Poverty should b e regarded a s " the socio- economic phenomena whereby t h e resources available t o a s o c i e t y a r e used t o satisfy t h e w a n t s of t h e f e w while t h e many do n o t h a v e e v e n t h e i r basic needs met."
(Chambers,
1983).
T h e poor in Renk a r e t h e victims of a n economic and social system over whichthey have l i t t l e o r n o control.
As their conditions d e t e r i o r a t e
in t e r m s of a n absolute fall in t h e i r income, t h e rural and urban rich continue t o c o n c e n t r a t e t h e existing resources in their own hands.
This
unequal development m e a n s t h a t t h e rural poor a r e becoming m o r e and m o r e dependent on t h e rich f o r a c c e s s t o t h e resources necessary for their survival, f o r example, employment a s wage labourers.
T h e dependency/
dominance relationship not only f a c i l i t a t e s t h e exploitation of t h e poor by t h e rich but undermines t h e development of t h e productive c a p a c i t i e s of t h e poor.
References Allen, C., and Williams, G.
Sociology of Developing Societies. MacMillan Press, 1982.
Boer, L., Buijs, D. and Galjort, B. (eds)
Poverty and Internationals: Cases from Developing Countries. Leiden Development Studies, No. 6, 1985.
d e Jong, Caroline Boon
Modernising Agriculture in t h e Third World: Some Ecological Consequences and Alternatives, DSRC Seminar Series, 1984, University of Khartoum.
Cole, John
The Poor of t h e Earth.
Chambers, Robert
Rural Development: Longrnan, 1983.
Griffin, K.
International Inequality and National Poverty. MacMillan Press, 1978.
Ibrahim Kursany
The Dynamics and Limits of Capitalist Development in Sudanese Agriculture, P a r t 2: Mechanized Rainfed Farming: Dura Production and t h e Limits t o Private Capitalism, DSRC Seminar, 1982. University of Khartoum.
Myrdal, Gunnar
The Challenge of World Poverty. Press, 1970.
Oster, Sharron,
The Definition and Measurement of Poverty Vol. 1: A Review. 'Westview Press, 1978.
Sinha, R.
Food and Poverty: The Political Economy of Confrontation. Croom Helm, 1976.
Wedderburn, D. (ed)
Poverty, Inequality and Class Structure. Cambridge University Press, 1974.
World Bank
Annual Report.
The MacMillan Press, 1976.
Putting t h e Last First,
New York, 1975.
Kingsport
THE TRACTOR AND THE PLOUGH: The Sociological Dimension M.A. Moharned-Salih A common denominator in agricultural policies of post- Independence Sudan
is t h e quest f o r agricultural tractors
with
threshers
and
their
related
combined
discs
modernization through t h e introduction of technologies in
such
rainfed
the
as
combine
sector.
harvesters,
However,
the
transition f r o m traditional t o modern technology has been very limited and has reached only a very small proportion of farming communities.
It is
e s t i m a t e d t h a t t h e r e w e r e a b o u t 3,000 operational t r a c t o r s in t h e rainfed s e c t o r in 1985, most in good working condition.
T h e t o t a l number of
t r a c t o r owners is not known because in most c a s e s t h e wealthy m e r c h a n t f a r m e r s own m o r e t h a n o n e t r a c t o r .
This in itself shows t h e e x t e n t t o
which large- scale agricultural mechanization in t h e rainfed s e c t o r is limited t o a small number of people while t h e majority of t h e population live off t h e traditional technologically s t a g n a n t sector. T h e question a r i s e s a s t o whether t h e various c e n t r a l governments could have adopted a policy which would h a v e spilled over technological innovation t o a larger portion of t h e population in t h e traditional s e c t o r in order t o bridge t h e g a p between t h e t w o sub- sectors.
What c o m e s t o mind
is whether t h e t r a c t o r w a s t h e most a p p r o p r i a t e option for agrarian change in t h e Sudan, considering f o r e x a m p l e t h e possibility of developing animal drawn equipment.
In judging t h e deployment of animal t r a c t i o n in East
Africa, Johnston (1984:
39) w r i t e s t h a t , " the evidence now available s e e m s
t o b e reasonably consistent in indicating t h a t with t h e prevailing c a p i t a l price relationships, reliance on animal d r a f t power generally r e p r e s e n t s t h e most economical approach t o overcoming constraints and labour bottlenecks which a r e t h e major f a c t o r s underlying t h e low level of c r o p yield and labour productivity t h a t c h a r a c t e r i z e farming in semi- arid E a s t Africa". Collinson (1965) a s s e r t s t h a t , "in Sukumuland, Western Tanzania, t h e r e is no c a s e f o r t h e introduction of t r a c t o r s in a r e a s w h e r e ox ploughing is established. cheaply".
These c a n
perform
t h e s a m e function
as tractors
more
The c a s e f o r t h e introduction of animal t r a c t i o n in order t o
improve t h e agricultural p r a c t i c e s a m o n g t h e majority of t h e rural poor in t h e rainfed s e c t o r is supported by t w o f u r t h e r facts: - 1 08-
first, t h e availability
of animals in t h e s a m e semi-arid zone (for example, over t w o million camels, 15 million head of c a t t l e and m o r e t h a n half a million donkeys); second, t h e availability of skilled blacksmiths who c a n easily b e trained t o undertake t h e process of equipment production from t h e abundant scrap m e t a l found in t h e industrial a r e a s located in all p a r t s of
t h e Sudan.
Riverain Sudan is familiar with animal drawn equipment such a s t h e
sagia (water wheel), and t h e plough. and Dafala (1 975).
These a r e described by Tothill (1948)
However, t h e integration of animals in agricultural
production in t h e savannah belt of t h e Sudan is limited and is found only in t h e c a s e s of Northern Kordofan where northern migrants have settled. These have brought i n t o t h e semi- arid zone s o m e of t h e animal drawn equipment which they used in their home areas.
Manger (in t h i s book and
1980) has m a d e r e f e r e n c e t o t h e use of ploughs a s p a r t of t h e process of resource
maintenance
in
the
intensive
cultivation
of
the
oases
It is, therefore, obvious t h a t t h e savannah belt of t h e Sudan has not been extensively reported a s a n a r e a of a n i m a l drawn f a r m equipment, especially with regard t o land preparation, hoeing and weeding.
Even when
t h e C e z i r a s c h e m e w a s due t o b e modernized, t h e transition was made from t h e hoe t o t h e t r a c t o r without moving through t h e i n t e r m e d i a t e s t a g e of
t h e use of
animal power.
The justification for t h e negligence of
animal powered f a r m technology has always been a t t r i b u t e d t o t h e plough not being suitable for t h e heavy clay of t h e C e z i r a or t h e c e n t r a l clay plains of t h e savannah belt in general.
The gap in t h e technical knowledge
about t h e use of animal powered equipment is clearly demonstrated by t h e lack of any r e f e r e n c e t o t h e importance of relatively
inexpensive
economic development. The
technology in
this easily maintained and
t h e Sudan's
plans
for
social
and
1
l i t e r a t u r e on agricultural mechanization in t h e Sudan usually
criticises t h e political economy of t h e allocation of t h e means of production r a t h e r than questioning t h e limits of t h e technologies used in t h e agrarian s e c t o r in bridging t h e income gap between t h e rich and t h e poor farmers.
The tools t h a t c a n bring about agricultural transformation a r e
described e i t h e r in isolation f r o m t h e technology used in t h e agricultural sector national
(Mahmoud, economy
1984 and
from
financing institutions
Kursany) or
in
t e r m s of
'de-linking'
the
i t s s t r u c t u r a l dependence on t h e international
such
as
the
IMF (Oesterdiekhoff
- 1 09-
and
Wohlmuth,
1983, 1985).
Adam
et a1 (1983) concluded their study of t h e mechanized
farming system in t h e rainlands of t h e Sudan by advocating t h e improvem e n t of machinery employment and productivity through t h e introduction of co- operatives t o b e t h e best solution t o t h e problems of t h e rainfed sector.
Saeed (1982) m a d e t h e remark t h a t , " the modernized schemes a r e
expected t o b e suitable for agricultural transformation in rural Sudan". These scholars o f f e r a f r a g m e n t e d diagnosis and critique of t h e agricultural practices in t h e rainfed s e c t o r which have s o m e e l e m e n t of t r u t h in them. The questions of how t o bring about t h e 'de-linking' of t h e economy from t h e exploitative international financing institutions, and industrialization
is
capable
of
achieving
the
goal
of
w h a t form equity
and
of its
accompanying technologies, have not been thoroughly investigated both by rural development practitioners and a c a d e m i c s in t h e Sudan. This paper describes and analyses t h e sociological implications of large- scale mechanization,
smallholder modernization schemes,
introduction of animal traction in Western Sudan.
and
the
The argument presented
h e r e supports t h e critique of t h e political economy of agrarian change in t h e Sudan.
It goes f u r t h e r , by criticising this approach for i t s failure t o
a p p r e c i a t e t h e f a c t t h a t agricultural mechanization through tractorization is not t h e best solution e i t h e r for reaching t h e mass of t h e rural poor or for uncoupling t h e national economy from t h e hegemony of t h e external international
financing
insitutions.
The
long
forgotten
animal
drawn
contraptions, given t h e appropriate institutional and organizational framework a r e conceivably t h e best method of agrarian transformation in t h e semi- arid zone of t h e Sudan. Mechanized Farming via the Tractor A good deal of
information
has been accumulated with regard t o t h e
economies of mechanized farming in t h e rainfed sector.
F.H. Adam e t a1
(1984) have reviewed t h e m a t e r i a l on t h e history of t h e development of such schemes in t h r e e phases.
The f i r s t was t h e 1945-1953 phase which
was based on t h e r e c r u i t m e n t of f a r m e r s in Gadaref, Eastern Sudan, t o work on government managed schemes.
Adam et a1 (ibid) observe that,
" allotments t o t h e s h a r e croppers have not survived because of permanent s e t t l e m e n t difficulties manifested by t h e seasonality of production and t h e inadequacy of t h e requisite infrastructure" .
The second phase continued
from 1953 t o 1968 and, due t o a s h o r t a g e of public c a p i t a l finance, t h e private
sector
was
s y s t e m of leasehold.
involved
in
large- scale
mechanization
through
the
This s y s t e m w a s described a s being open t o abuse
since concessions w e r e passed t o people who w e r e n o t real f a r m e r s .
As a
consequence, an unreasonably high proportion of land w a s a l l o t t e d t o local and outside notables a n d merchants.
Most of t h e s e people have acquired
mechanized f a r m s not because of a genuine i n t e r e s t in f a r m i n g but because of t h e desire t o maximize t h e r a t e of r e t u r n on new i n v e s t m e n t in t h e s h o r t e s t possible time. until today.
The t h i r d phase s t a r t e d in 1968 and h a s continued
This h a s been m a r k e d by t h e establishment of t h e Mechanized
Farming Corporation.
Some of
p r e p a r e land f o r large- scale
i t s main objectives a r e t o survey and
mechanized f a r m s f o r
p r i v a t e owners,
to
f a c i l i t a t e c r e d i t services f o r financially able a n d i n t e r e s t e d f a r m e r s , and t o advise t h e f a r m e r s on modern agricultural techniques. T h e government has been leasing land t o t h e private s e c t o r since 1968 in t h e provinces of Blue Nile, Kassala, Southern Kordofan a n d Upper Nile. Each f a r m e r is a l l o t t e d 1,500 feddans a s a leasehold f o r 25 years.
The
c o n t r a c t between t h e government, represented by t h e Mechanized Farming Corporation, is renewable only when t h e ' f a r m e r ' m e e t s t h e obligation of paying 5 p i a s t r e s (Ls 0.05) annual r e n t and t h e initial expense of L s 750 payable at t h e beginning of
t h e f i r s t agricultural season.
The a r e a
d e m a r c a t e d f o r large- scale mechanized a g r i c u l t u r e e x t e n d s right i n t o t h e central
clay
plains
between
Lat.
9
and
15
North
(see
map).
L a r g e a r e a s w e r e appropriated f r o m traditional cultivators and pastoralists with t h e promise of
providing t h e m with co- operatives a s com-
pensation for t h e i r lost cultivable lands and pasture.
Gum a r a b i c r e v e n u e s ,
an i m p o r t a n t source of income t o t h e population, declined a s t h e gum producing t r e e s w e r e c l e a r e d f r o m millions of hectares.
In only a very
short span of t i m e t h e local population began t o f e e l t h e intrusion of mechanized
farming into their
lands and
t h e y gradually
began
t o be
involved in t h e process through wage labour, by working f o r t h e very people who appropriated their main source of livelihood.
T h e p a t t e r n of
agrarian transformation t h a t h a s e m e r g e d in t h e a r e a is o n e of destitution and poverty for t h e majority of t h e subsistence f a r m e r s and pastoralists. T h e specific negative i m p a c t s of t h e a c t i v i t i e s of t h e Mechanized Farming Corporation and t h e c o m m e r c i a l f a r m s t h e Corporation distributed
t o m e r c h a n t farmers, r e t i r e d a r m y officers, politicians, lawyers and o t h e r wealthy
educated
elites
have
167-184) in his widely quoted
been
described
by
M.H.
Saeed
(1982:
a r t i c l e on " Economic E f f e c t s of Agricultural
Mechanization in Rural Sudan:
T h e C a s e of Habila, Southern Kordofan".
In concluding his discussion, M.H. Saeed (1982:
182-1 83) maintains t h a t ,
" the production efficiency of agricultural mechanization is questionable in comparison second,
with
the
inequalities
the
pattern among
commercialization
traditional of
income
different of
agriculture distribution
groups
agriculture,
practised
the
has worsened
h a v e widened and third,
in
region,
and
income
a s a result of
the
t h e conventional i d e a of
replacing labour by machine is irrelevant in t h e savannah situation since i t suits
only
some
production .
operations,
i.e.,
labour
remains
the
main
factor
of
T h e introduction of machinery in such conditions c a n allow
i1
t h e horizontal expansion of f a r m s t h u s c r e a t i n g g r e a t e r demand f o r labour. T h e demand f o r labour in mechanized a g r i c u l t u r e c a n b e judged by t h e 100,000 casual labourers who l e a v e t h e i r villages e v e r y year t o p a r t i c i p a t e in weeding and harvesting in t h e large- scale mechanized schemes.
They
live in appalling conditions with n o organization t o defend t h e i r rights viz t h e m e r c h a n t f a r m e r s who pay t h e m v e r y low wages (on a v e r a g e a b o u t t w o pounds (Sudanese) daily.) unattended
or
totally
Most of t h e labourers l e a v e t h e i r own f a r m s
dependent on t h e i r wives who in this situation
c u l t i v a t e t h e land in additiion t o t h e i r traditional d o m e s t i c responsibilities. Many labourers who work on a seasonal basis rush t o t h e i r villages with t h e e a r l y showers of rain, a t i m e when i t is impossible f o r t h e m t o c l e a r a new piece of land o r properly p r e p a r e t h e i r f a r m s f o r t h e agricultural season. The situation is e v e n w o r s e f o r those who lost their lands t o t h e owners of large- scale mechanized s c h e m e s by governmental order if their villages w e r e within a r e a s surveyed f o r t h e establishment of schemes. Such groups of landless agricultural labourers began t o e m e r g e , especially in t h e Eastern D i s t r i c t of Southern Kordofan Province (see map). have largely been t r a n s f o r m e d i n t o groups of
These
rural poor who work for
m e r c h a n t f a r m e r s on t h e s a m e land t h a t t h e y previously owned.
The s a m e
awkward situation applies t o t h e nomads who lost their traditional grazing lands, w a t e r points a n d animal r o u t e s t o t h e schemes.
It is e s t i m a t e d t h a t
80 per c e n t of t h e 350,000 pastoralists and agro- pastoralists of Southern Kordofan province a r e seriously a f f e c t e d by t h e expansion of large- scale - 1 12-
mechanized schemes. do not
This is rnainly because t h e owners of t h e schemes
abide by t h e agricultural p r a c t i c e s devised by t h e Mechanized
Farming Corporation.
They have in
many c a s e s cultivated
even
animal t r a c k s (width t w o kilometres) specified by t h e Corporation. c o n t ~ n u o u s conflict
between
t h e owners of
the The
t h e large- scale mechanized
schemes and pastoralists is described by Ahmed (1982:
47) who reports
t h a t in t h e rainfed sector, " cultivators a r e forced t o sell their labour cheaply, pastoral nomads a r e driven o u t of t h e best a r e a s of their traditional pasture and
t o places which a r e not favourable t o their herd grov;th,
agro- pastoralists
are
being
subjected
to
various
socio- economic
pressures and forced t o abandon one of t h e t w o a c t i v i t i e s and changed over
t o agricultural labourers with low wages and lower standards of
living". The n a t u r e of t h e c o m m e r c i a l agricultural schemes gives no priority t o social services and t h e provision of educational and health services t o t h e a r e a s where surplus has been e x t r a c t e d .
T h e Mechanized Farming
Corporation s e t s itself t h e t a s k of administering t h e demarcation of t h e schemes but has no resources or manpower t o e d u c a t e f a r m e r s against t h e f o r m s of exploitative a n d exhaustive land m a n a g e m e n t which t h e y practise. With no rotation system, wind barriers or vegetation cover around t h e schemes, t h e soil has begun t o lose i t s fertility and very low productivity has been observed, f o r e x a m p l e by Gala-el-din (19741, OIBrien (1977), and Ibrahim (1978, 1984).
The opting of t h e owners of t h e l a r g e mechanized
agricultural schemes for quick and high profit, t h e lack of infrastructure such a s roads, health c a r e and educational facilities, and t h e f a c t t h a t t h e owners of
t h e schemes
were
not originally f a r m e r s or belong t o t h e
regions from which t h e y o p e r a t e , m i t i g a t e against a conscientious policy of resource maintenance and soil conservation. C o m m e n t s about t h e use of t r a c t o r s have not always been negative. The Mechanized Farming Corporation has i t s own rationale which underlies t h e logic behind using them.
The main objectives included t h e expansion
of food production t o fulfil t h e t a r g e t of becoming t h e bread basket of Africa and t h e Middle East, and second, t o produce cash crops and thus contribute t o t h e nation's foreign exchange earnings. agricultural
mechanization,
therefore,
has
economic benefits which c a n a c c r u e t o it. -1 13-
been
The social c o s t of weighed
against
the
T h e result of t h i s policy was,
however,
witnessed worldwide during t h e 1983-1 985 f a m i n e crisis which
c l a i m e d t h e lives of thousands in t h e rainfed s e c t o r .
T h e socio-economic
repercussions of t h a t f a m i n e a r e y e t t o b e evaluated.
However, t h e r e a r e
a l r e a d y hints of t h e d a m a g e which h a s cumulatively
been inflicted upon
t h e n a t u r a l and t h e human r e s o u r c e s alike.
Tractors for Modernizing the Smallholders I t is ironic t h a t e v e n when
t h e a g r i c u l t u r a l plans w e r e f o r m u l a t e d t o
develop smallholders during t h e 19701s, t r a c t o r s w e r e envisaged a s t h e only In this s e c t i o n I d e a l with t h e modern-
a l t e r n a t i v e t o t h e t r a d i t i o n a l hoe. i z a t i o n (or
t a h d i t h ) s c h e m e s of t h e Nc~ba Mountains ( s e e m a p ), t o
i l l u s t r a t e t h e e x t e n t of
t h e i r contribution t o agricultural d e v e l o p m e n t in
t h e semi- arid conditions of t h e region. T h e Nuba Mountains C o t t o n Industry w a s established during t h e AngloEgyptian
Condominiun
colonial
rule
c o m p a n i e s with s h o r t s t a p l e c o t t o n .
in
1923
t o supply
British
textile
C o t t o n production w a s dependent on
individual f a m i l i e s while t h e Nuba Mountains Industry provided c o t t o n seeds, marketing facilities and
administration.
In
1970,
t h e Nuba
Mountains
Corporation was established with t h e a i m of f i r s t , modernizing traditional a g r i c u l t u r e by m e a n s of introducing t r a c t o r s e r v i c e s t o groups of f a r m e r s ; second, achieving a p p r o p r i a t e utilization of resources by t h e application of modern and s c i e n t i f i c a g r i c u l t u r a l p r a c t i c e s and third, c r e a t i n g a sound t e c h n i c a l , e c o n o m i c a n d social policy in o r d e r t o develop t h e agricultural s e c t o r in t h e Nuba Mountains. The modernization p r o g r a m m e w a s inaugurated in 1971 and based on t h e provision of t r a c t o r s e r v i c e s t o groups of f a r m e r s in consolidated units in t h e l a r g e schemes.
T h e villages chosen f o r t h e i m p l e m e n t a t i o n of t h e
p r o g r a m m e w e r e s c a t t e r e d throughout t h e Nuba Mountains.
The D i s t r i c t
H.Q.'s and o t h e r l a r g e towns w e r e s e l e c t e d a s a d m i n i s t r a t i v e c e n t r e s f r o m which t h e r e p r e s e n t a t i v e s of t h e Nuba Mountains Agricultural Corporation could o p e r a t e .
T h e C o r p o r a t i o n also provided f r e e c o t t o n seeds, pest
c o n t r o l services, c r e d i t f o r m e c h a n i z e d a g r i c u l t u r e and a f i r e break around e a c h scheme.
The a r e a of e a c h s c h e m e w a s e x p e c t e d t o e x c e e d 1,000
f e d d a n s b e f o r e t r a c t o r s e r v i c e s could b e provided. The
whole
p r o g r a m m e revolved around - 1 14-
t h e idea of
o f f e r i n g cost-
e f f e c t i v e t r a c t o r services t o a large number of smallholders (farming from t w o t o 20 feddans).
An increase in c o t t o n production was envisaged and
eight ginneries were established for c o t t o n processing.
The towns where
t h e ginneries w e r e located w e r e used a s production units and a t t h e s a m e time, a s agropolitan c e n t r e s aiming a t securing a spill-over of agricultural and social services.
These production units a c t e d a s growth pole centres,
absorbing t h e surplus produced by t h e countryside while offering amenities such
a s schools,
health services,
recreation
activities and employment
opportunities in t h e c o m m e r c i a l or civil service sectors. Despite i t s ambitious programme t o modernise traditional agriculture, t h e Nuba Mountains Agricultural Corporation has suffered s e v e r a l setbacks. These problems a r e of a similar n a t u r e t o those mentioned by U m a Lele (1975:
34) in t h e c a s e of smallholders:
equipment;
second,
the
high
first, a high capital cost of t h e
overheads
servicing t h e under- utilized tractors;
involved
in
maintaining
and
third, t h e administrative problems of
sharing a limited number of machines by a l a r g e number of diverse users, and fourth, t h e technical difficulties of deploying t r a c t o r s under c e r t a i n topographical and soil conditions.
Following this appraisal, U m a Lele made
t h e point t h a t none of t h e s e problems a r e insurmountable and t h a t t h e use of t r a c t o r s is justified only if t h e high c a p i t a l cost is accompanied by a substantial increase in productivity. The Nuba Mountains Corporation has so f a r failed t o solve t h e above surmountable
problems
agricultural
production
discussion of
involving among
the
use
of
smallholders.
t h e economies of
the tractor
tractors Without vis
for
developing
entering
into
a
5 vis traditional hoe
cultivation, t h e evidence from c r o p yields in t h e Nuba Mountains region is conclusive (Table 1).
The a v e r a g e yield kglfeddan in t h e traditional s e c t o r
is 125 kglfeddan, while only 97 kglfeddan in t h e c a t e g o r y of traditional f a r m e r s who a r e also p a r t of t h e modernization programme.
The figures
for t h e absolute a r e a cultivated under t h e traditional and t h e modern system
condemn
(Table 2).
rather
than
support
the
modernization
programme
The t a b l e shows t h a t t h e t o t a l a r e a cultivated in c o t t o n and
sorghum actually decreased f r o m 589,117 feddans in 197011 971 when t h e 2 modernization programme was introduced t o 342,980 feddans in 198011981.
TABLE 1 Indicative Crop Yields in Southern Kordofan Province
Crop Sorghum:
poor years average years good years
Millet:
average years good years
Sesame:
average years good years
Groundnuts:
average years
Cotton:
Highest (1957158) Lowest (1962163)
Average traditional growers Average traditional and modernised schemes
* Sources:
Compiled by South Kordofan Agricultural Development Project from HTS (1981), Western Sudan Agricultural Research Project (1984) and Nuba Mountains Agricultural Corporation (1985186). TABLE 2 Areas Cultivated in Cotton and Sorghum under t h e Modern and t h e Traditional Sectors: 197011971 t o 1980/1981 (in Feddans)
Year
Modern Cotton Sorghum
Traditional Cotton Sorghum
1970171
14,115
19,063
159,095
1973174
6,893
11,013
1975176
20.022
00,344
Total
396,095
589,117
109,921
326,602
452,429
107,053
341,690
469,109
1977178
54,538
00,292
47,751
279,401
381,982
1980181
36,666
30,746
4,250
271,318
342,980
*
Source:
Nuba Mountains Agricultural Corporation, 1986.
After two years of research into t h e Nuba Mountains modernization project in Abyei District of south-western Sudan, Huntington, Ackroyd and Deng (1981:
51-2) concluded that, 'the major difficulty with most proposed
improvements is t h a t they a r e often presented by their proponents a s relatively simple solutions t o t h e problems of rainfed agriculture.
The
tractors seem t o make little technical contribution t o agriculture,
for
instance, t h e deeply cracking clay soils a e r a t e themselves, c r o p residues a r e effectively incorporated into t h e soil by termites, and weed growth cannot be controlled by t r a c t o r s because of t h e timing of t h e rains and weed growth'. The inspectorate system upon which t h e distribution of t r a c t o r services w a s based, is rigid, o u t of touch with t h e farmers, and gives t h e impression of a superior elitism t o t h e participants.
The system makes
decisions about t h e deployment of agricultural inputs from t h e main towns which in most cases d o not t a k e into account local knowledge o r f i t in with t h e a c t u a l beginning of t h e rainy season.
These decisions have c r e a t -
e d an identity crisis among t h e f a r m e r s who think of t h e modernization schemes a s government schemes.
In o t h e r words, t h e lack of local part-
icipation in decision making has been one of t h e main f a c t o r s behind t h e f a r m e r s ' a t t e m p t s t o pay m o r e a t t e n t i o n t o t h e i r traditional f a r m s in order t o minimize t h e risk
of
depending on t h e uncertain t r a c t o r services.
It is clear t h a t t h e inadequate t r a c t o r services provided by t h e Nuba Mountains Corporation have distorted t h e traditional p a t t e r n of c r o p production without offering a n appropriate alternative.
Many farmers, d u e t o
t h e uncertainty of t r a c t o r s , mechanical breakdowns, shortage of fuel and l a t e arrival of t r a c t o r s t o t h e s ~ t e , have split their labour between t h e traditional f a r m s and t h e plots inside t h e scheme.
Although t h e modern-
ization programme represents a good intention in itself, and has l i t t l e or no social c o s t relative t o private large- scale mechanized schemes, i t s ina d e q u a t e technological mix has essentially led t o i t s failure.
T h e capabil-
ity of t r a c t o r services t o c r e a t e a n overall agrarian transformation among t h e smallholders is m a d e questionable by t h e f a c t t h a t t h e Nuba Mountains Croporation has s o f a r reached only about 15,000 t o 19,000 households in 16 years which is less than 2 per c e n t of t h e t o t a l population of Southern
Kordofan Province.
Considering t h e overheads involved in maintenance, t h e
purchase of s p a r e parts, fuel and servicing, i t becomes obvious t h a t t h e use of t r a c t o r s in t h e Nuba Mountains' conditions is not conducive t o increasing production nor diffusing t h e benefits of t h e technological package t o t h e whole rural economy. The next step, therefore, is t o examine t h e limited experience with animal t r a c t i o n in t h e rainfed s e c t o r in order t o e v a l u a t e i t s likely advant a g e s over both traditional hoe cultivation and t r a c t o r services within t h e prevailing c o n t e x t of t h e present level of
t h e country's underdeveloped
economic structure. Animal Traction in Western Sudan
In c o n t r a s t t o t h e activities of t h e Mechanized Farming Corporation (MFC), and t h e Nuba Mountains Agricultural Corporation (NMAC), t h e J e b e l Mara 3
Rural Development Project (JMRDP)
and t h e Nuba Mountains Rural Dev-
elopment Project (NMRDP) a r e geared towards t h e use of animal traction r a t h e r than tractors.
T h e t w o projects a r e q u i t e recent.
T h e J e b e l Mara
Rural Development P r o j e c t w a s re- oriented f r o m t r a c t o r t o animal traction in 1980;
during t h e s a m e year preparations f o r t h e Nuba Mountains Rural
Development P r o j e c t w e r e s t a r t e d . almost identical.
The objectives of t h e t w o projects a r e
Major t o t h e m a r e t h e following:
first, t h e improve-
m e n t of productivity, standard of living, and incomes of t h e mass of t h e rural population;
second, t o maintain a sustained system of livestock and
c r o p production;
third, t o develop a system of popular participation so
t h a t t h e development activity will b e m e t with local support and approval by t h e local population, and fourth, t o increase local government revenue, e i t h e r directly or indirectly and where possible t o contribute t o foreign exchange earning and savings. The range of e a c h rural development project included extension, veterinary services, demonstration farms, community development, and mechanical engineering, accounting and administration departments.
Their s t r a t -
egy is primarily concerned with t h e development of t h e agricultural s e c t o r and t h e provsion of r e l a t e d agricultural services.
Extension officers and
local extension assistants w e r e recruited and trained.
About 360 villages
and 49,950 households w e r e covered by t h e JMRDP programme which sells ploughs, sorghum seeds, seed dressing and insecticides on credit.
The ext-
ension staff trained t h e f a r m e r s on t h e use of c a m e l ploughs, explained t h e purpose and value of inputs and showed t h e m how t o apply superphosphates and seed dressings and how t o use t h e plough weeder toolbar and improved seeds. The Nuba Mountains Rural Development Project, on t h e other hand, has covered t h r e e villages in four years with over 3,000 participant households.
Ox ploughing is encouraged instead of camels since t h e population
of t h e Nuba Mountains a r e c a t t l e breeders.
The s a m e agricultural inputs
a r e also provided t o participants on credit a f t e r t h e completion o i t h e harvesting
season.
Despite
repayment
rate
the
for
of
Jebel
the Mara
drought and
years of
the
Nuba
1983-1985, Mountains
the
Rural
Development Projects was between 50 - 60 per c e n t during 1982184, and between 70 - 80 per c e n t a f t e r t h e end of t h e drought phase in 1985186. The Jebel Mara Rural Development Project, which is more established than t h e Nuba Mountains one, has been able t o drill 1 1 wells, construct 61 rural health units and 25 kilometres of roads built by self-help with a minimum
of
development
mechanical
support
from
the
Project.
The
community
unit was also successful in organizing women's health and
nutrition programmes, child c a r e , and t h e sale of medicines on a revolving fund basis. The average increase in a r e a cultivated in t h e two projects relative t o t h a t of t h e traditional f a r m e r s is between 18 t o 9 feddans or about 80 per c e n t in absolute figures for Kordofan Agricultural Development using animal traction
both small and big farmers.
South
Project calculated t h e advantage of
for traditional farming with respect t o labour in
t e r m s of a r e a cultivated by hour t o be on average 283.27 hours for t h e participant farmers relative t o t h e non- participants per average holding of 14.9 feddans (Table 3).
TABLE 3 Average Area Cultivated Per Houk and Advantage of t h e Use of Animal Traction t o Traditional Farming in t h e Nuba Mountains, 1984185
Operation Hoeing Seeding
Feddan Per Hour Hoe Plough 0.09 0.22 0.30
Hours Per Holding Hoe Plough 166.67 68.18
0.10
50.00
150.00
100.00
150.00
84.78
NA
283.27
Weeding
0.23
0.10
65.22
Advantage
NA
NA
NA
* Source:
Advantage plough/~oe 98.49
South Kordofan Agricultural Development Project, 1986, compiled from Nuba Mountains R u r a l Development Project R e p o r t s 1984185.
An interesting point about t h e J e b e l Mara Rural Development Project is i t s ability t o c r e a t e a local industry for plough making which contributes t o local employment.
In c o n t r a s t t h e Nuba Mountains Rural Development
P r o j e c t is still dependent on imported equipment f o r demonstration and for inducing f a r m e r s t o participate in t h e programme. Four f e a t u r e s of farmers.
t h e use of animal t r a c t i o n a r e appealing t o t h e
First, most of t h e f a r m e r s continue cultivating their own f a r m s
instead of land in a consolidated scheme. favour of
This solves t h e land question in
t h e traditional producers, whereas t h e mechanized f a r m s put The large- scale mechanized schemes a r e privately
their land in jeopardy. owned by t h e class of
m e r c h a n t f a r m e r s and t h e smallholder schemes
re- group f a r m e r s every year according t o t h e rotation system, thus t h e r e is no security of t e n u r e for t h e participants. Second, in addition t o t h e plough, t h e animal traction package consists of a ridger, a seeder and a c a r t . a r e offered on a c r e d i t basis.
T h e four i t e m s c o s t over L s 800 and
The f a r m e r s a r e particularly encouraged by
t h e inclusion of c a r t s in t h e package.
These a r e used f o r transporting
their crops t o t h e houses or t o market, for bringing w a t e r and firewood, and for inter- village transport of
manufactured goods.
The c a r t s have
alleviated t h e pressure on women who traditionally transport t h e crops and bring w a t e r from long distances. Third, t h e plough saves labour and increases productivity relative t o t h e traditional system of production.
It is e s t i m a t e d t h a t productivity per
feddan is 140 kg in t h e J e b e l Mara Rural Development P r o j e c t and just under
130
Project. the
same
kg of
sorghum in t h e
Nuba
Mountains Rural Development
These figures a r e significantly higher than t h e 90 kglfeddan for crop
in
the
smallholders
mechanized
farming
sub- sector.
Fourth, t h e animal t r a c t i o n package represents a simple technology which involves a
minimum o r
expensive foreign expertise.
no importation of s p a r e parts, fuel or
Most of t h e f a r m s repair and service their
own equipment and t h e y sometimes seek assistance from local mechanics and blacksmiths t o fix c e r t a i n p a r t s which t h e y cannot handle themselves. With r e s p e c t t o this,
Johnston (1984:
42) argues that, " animal drawn
ploughs, cultivators, ridgers and similar equipment c a n b e manufactured with
reasonable
but
increasing
efficiency
by
small
and
medium- scale
workshops.
Such f i r m s employ relatively labour intensive technologies, and
t h e y a l s o have a strong incentive t o minimize t h e import c o n t e n t of their products".
This,
in m y view, m e e t s t h e c r i t e r i a of developing human
resources in a m o r e positive way, towards a b e t t e r application of interm e d i a t e technology a s a
pre- requisite t o a m o r e advanced agricultural
industrialization in t h e future.
Conclusions T h e m a t e r i a l presented in this paper c o n s t i t u t e a modest contribution t o t h e under- researched a r e a of
t h e appropriateness of t r a c t o r and animal
t r a c t i o n technologies t o t h e semi- arid zone of t h e Sudan. discussion is t h a t of
T h e issue under
t h e wider sociological implications of t h e use of
t r a c t o r s o r animal t r a c t i o n technologies a s exemplified by t h e Sudanese experience.
T h e r e l e v a n c e of t r a c t o r s a n d t h e i r associated technologies t o
agricultural
transformation
significance
of
such
has
not
technologies
been to
negated; underdeveloped
nonetheless,
the
infrastructures
(organizational, institutional a n d economic) and their c a p a c i t y t o e l i m i n a t e poverty has been questioned.
With t h e a b o v e points in mind, t h e following
conclusions c a n b e e x t r a c t e d f r o m t h e study: As regards t h e benefits achieved by t h e use of t r a c t o r s both by p r i v a t e owners and groups of smallholders, t h e beneficiaries a r e limited t o
a small proportion of t h e population.
In t h e c a s e of t h e p r i v a t e large-
s c a l e holders, t h e beneficiaries a r e t h e wealthy m e r c h a n t f a r m e r s o r t h e educated
and
political
elites
who
accumulated
sufficient
consciously decided t o invest in c o m m e r c i a l agriculture.
capital
and
They, in f a c t ,
own a major proportion of all t r a c t o r s and h a v e a t o t a l monopoly over t h e importation of modern agricultural technology.
This s y s t e m of agricultural
production c r e a t e s a mechanism which f a c i l i t a t e s t h e e m e r g e n c e of a class of wage labourers who a r e eventually t r a n s f o r m e d into landless agricultural workers (Kerblay:
through
the
1971, Long:
Goodman and Redclif t:
appropriation
of
land
by
1972, Arrighi and Saul: 1 98 1 , Harriss:
large- scale
producers
1973, Bernestein:
1979,
1 982).
T r a c t o r s c a n be useful in dispersing t h e benefits of sustained high productivity only if t h e surplus g e n e r a t e d f r o m agriculture i s re- invested in agriculture o r o t h e r productive non- farm linkages.
This, however, h a s not
been t h e c a s e with t h e c o m m e r c i a l farming s y s t e m is t h e Sudan w h e r e t h e investment of agricultural surplus has been directed t o t r a d e or transferred t o t h e urban centres, and utilized in t h e construction of lavish houses and t h e importation of expensive luxury items. foreign
exchange
agricultural
which
is
to
keep
inputs
in
short the
Consequently, t h e process of
This adds t o t h e problems of
supply
for
agricultural
the
importation
machinery
of
operational.
social polarization is a c c e l e r a t e d and t h e
income g a p between t h e poor and t h e rich increased. While t r a c t o r s a r e dependent on t h e availability of both national and international
linkages
with
the
dependent on imported inputs.
external
economy,
ploughs
are
less
In m o s t conditions, animal t r a c t i o n m a y be
preferable t o t r a c t o r s because of i t s relatively g r e a t e r flexibility, lower cost, and g r e a t e r linkages with o t h e r s e c t o r s of t h e rural economy (Uma Lele, 1976: 38).
T o a d v o c a t e animal t r a c t i o n a s p a r t and parcel of agri-
cultural development planning implies a positive approach towards regional equity in t h e allocation of development funds and t o maintain system- wide balances
in
the
macro- economic
major
parameters.
This approach is
particularly important in t h e c a s e of Sudan w h e r e t h e surplus produced by t h e large- scale mechanized f a r m s is totally transferred t o investment in t h e metropolitan centres.
As a m a t t e r of f a c t , neither t h e government
nor t h e private s e c t o r has undertaken any measures t o improve t h e social services or t h e infrastructure in t h e a r e a s w h e r e t h e a b s e n t e e commercial capitalist
t y p e of
agriculture
is
The inter- regional equity
practised.
dimension in t h e use of t h e relatively simple, but efficient animal traction technology
can
contribute
to
the
elimination
of
certain
ethnocentric
prejudices which a r e mainly c r e a t e d by t h e present uneven distribution of 4 . development , In addition t o increasing production and
t h e f a c t o r s of improving
t h e standard
I s h a r e Johnston's
of
living of
view (1 984:
frequently
of
the
rural
poor.
61) t h a t discussions of choice of
technology
have
extremes.
On t h e one hand, t h e r e is a tendency t o emphasize technical
efficiency and 'modernity'
gone
t h e majority
to
opposite,
but
equally
untenable
r a t h e r t h a n maximum efficiency, even though
t h e price of labour is low (because i t is relatively abundant) and c a p i t a l is scarce
and
dearer,
On
the
other
hand,
any
technical
change
that
eliminates income- earning opportunities of low income households may be condemned on t h e basis of a partial, s t a t i c analysis.
T h a t is, t h e potential
for generating new employment opportunities a s well a s t h e increased production of goods and services is m a d e possible by t h e resource saving of technical
effects
change.
Nevertheless,
saving by t h e introduction of
t h e wisdom
behind labour
t r a c t o r s has been disproved, especially in
semi- arid environments (Pearse:
1980, Saeed:
1982, Johnston:
1984).
In
t h e Sudan i t is observed t h a t t h e demand for labour d e c r e a s e s a s soil deterioration increases through t h e years d u e t o t h e lack of a rotation system.
Consequently, t h e low land productivity is accompanied by a
reduction
in
the
wages of
t h e agricultural
labourers.
Many of
the
labourers, therefore, a t t e m p t t o maintain t h e previous level of earning by increasing t h e period of work in t h e mechanized schemes instead of their farms.
The labour saving dilemma c a n thus b e seen a s an inseparable part
of t h e mechanism t h a t c r e a t e s dependence on t h e mechanized f a r m s and a t t h e s a m e t i m e p e r p e t u a t e s poverty among t h e traditional cultivators who, over t h e course of t i m e become less competitive with t h e largescale mechanized f a r m s of t h e commercial farmers. In no p a r t of this paper have I argued t h a t wage labour c a n be eliminated when animal t r a c t i o n is introduced because s o m e f a r m e r s in t h e traditional
sector
are
better
off
than
others.
Some
have
already
accumulated sufficient capital which c a n b e invested in m o r e t h a n one plough.
Moreover, s o m e poor f a r m e r s may find i t a t t r a c t i v e t o a d a p t
their traditional institutions of solidarity t o t h e flexible plough technology 5
and hence enjoy t h e benefits of t h e obligatory system of labour exchange.
The creation of such a n enterprise requires popular participation and m o r e a t t e n t i o n t o t h e processes of organization and institution building.
A more
e f f e c t i v e methodology is required t o diffuse t h e results of research into t h e most appropriate equipment f o r t h e farmers.
This policy could in e f f e c t
lead t o t h e development of a less expensive i n t e r m e d i a t e technology which would
result
in
higher
farm
productivity
opportunities outside t h e farming sector.
and
more
employment
T h e social and economic benefits
which c a n a c c r u e t o t h e low income- earning groups who use t h e plough a r e certainly
superior
to
advanced tractorization change in t h e Sudan.
the
social
cost
disguised
in
the
technologically
package within t h e present s t r u c t u r e of agrarian
(1)
T h e r e is no mention of t h e use of i n t e r m e d i a t e technology o r animal t r a c t i o n in a n y of t h e Sudan's Plans f o r Social a n d Economic Development. Even t h e t w o e x p e r i e n c e s of animal t r a c t i o n t h a t I describe in this paper w e r e introduced a s a response t o a request f r o m t h e European Economic Community. C o m p a r e this, f o r example, t o Kenya's F o u r t h National Development Plan which clearly s t a t e d in 1979 t h a t particular a t t e n t i o n should b e a t t a c h e d t o i n t e r m e d i a t e technology. Quoted in G. Muchiri (1984).
(2)
It is r e p o r t e d by t h e Nuba Mountains Agricultural Corporation, t h e body responsible f o r t h e introduction of modernization schemes, t h a t t h e a v e r a g e level of c o t t o n productivity d e c r e a s e d when t h e smallholder p r o g r a m m e w a s introduced in 19701197 1 f r o m 2.87 small k a n t a r s (a k a n t a r i s 100 Ib) t o 1.14 small k a n t a r s j f e d d a n in 198311984. This c a n n o t b e a t t r i b u t e d t o s h o r t a g e of rainfall, since t h e southern p a r t s of t h e Nuba Mountains w e r e n o t drastically a f f e c t e d during t h o s e particular agricultural seasons.
(3)
The J e b e l Mara Rural Development P r o j e c t w a s a United Nations funded v e n t u r e until 1980 when t h e project w a s re- oriented a n d financed by t h e EEC. T h e project o p e r a t e s within a n a r e a of about 7,800,000 feddans. T h e main crops c u l t i v a t e d in t h e project a r e a a r e millet, sorghum, groundnuts, and various horticultural products. T h e Nuba Mountains R u r a l Development P r o j e c t is also EEC funded. I t d a t e s back t o t h e s a m e period a s t h e Jebel Mara Rural Developm e n t P r o j e c t but i t h a s less e x p e r i e n c e and fewer logistic facilities. Both projects apply a n i m a l t r a c t i o n a s a method f o r developing smallholders in Western Sudan.
(4)
Sudan has been a f f e c t e d by s e v e r a l regional m o v e m e n t s which in t h e c a s e of t h e Sudanese Peoples Liberation Army is fighting a w a r against t h e c e n t r a l government a s a means of achieving m o r e equitable growth in t h e underdeveloped Southern Regions and o t h e r p a r t s of t h e Sudan. O t h e r regional m o v e m e n t s which press f o r a n e v e n development a r e t h e Nuba Mountains Political Union, t h e Sudan Nationalist P a r t y (also originated in t h e Nuba Moun-tains), t h e Dar Fur Development F r o n t and t h e Beja Congress of Eastern Sudan. Although development projects a r e found in t h e s e regions, t h e y have failed t o r e a c h t h e mass of t h e rural poor. T h e use of t h e expensive t r a c t o r i z a t i o n projects f o r private owners who invest their surpluses outside t h e regions of production c a n b e partially blamed f o r t h e e m e r g e n c e of such groups.
(5)
For f u r t h e r m a t e r i a l on communal labour and rural development r e f e r t o L. Manger (ed) forthcoming, Communal Labour in t h e Sudan: Continuity and Change, and J. Ziche and M.A. Moharned-Salih, 1984, Communal Labour and Rural Development, Examples f r o m Africa South of t h e Sahara.
References Adam, F.H. e t al
Mechanized Agriculture in t h e C e n t r a l Rainlands of t h e Sudan, in P. Oesterdiekhoff and K. Wohlmuth (eds): T h e Development P e r s p e c t i v e of t h e Democ r a t i c Republic of t h e Sudan: Weltforum Verlag, 1983.
Ahmed, A.M.
Planning and t h e Neglect of t h e P a s t o r a l Nomads in t h e Sudan, in G. Haaland (ed) Problems of Savannah Development, t h e Sudan Case. Bergen Occasional P a p e r s in Social Anthropology, No. 19. 1982.
Ahmed, A.M.
Ecological Degradation in t h e Sahel: T h e Political Dimension, a paper p r e s e n t e d t o t h e C e n t r e f o r Development Studies, Bergen, Norway, 1986.
Arrighi, G., and Saul, J.
Essays on t h e Political Economy of Africa, E a s t A f r i c a Publishing House, Nairobi, 1973.
Bernestein, H.
Peasantries: A T h e o r e t i c a l Framework, in t h e Journal of P e a s a n t Studies, No. 4. 1979.
Calsen, J.
Economic and Social Transformation in Rural Kenya, Scandinavian I n s t i t u t e of African Studies, Uppsala, 1980.
C a r r , M.
S o m e Socio- Economic A s p e c t s of T r a c t o r i z a t i o n in Sylon. (UN Mino), 1975.
Collinson, M.P.
Economics of Block Cultivation Schemes, Western Region Research Ukiriguru, Tanzania, 1965.
Dafala, H.A.
T h e Nubian Exodus: H u r s t a n d Company, London in association with t h e Scandinavian I n s t i t u t e of African Studies. 1975.
Gaitskell, A.
Gezira: A Story of Development in t h e Sudan. F a b e r a n d F a b e r , London, 1959.
Goodman, D., and Redclift, ' M . '
F r o m P e a s a n t t o Proletarian: C a ~ i t a l i s tD e v e l o ~ m e n t a n d Agrarian Transition, Basil lackw well, o x f o r d , 1981.
Gore, E.
Regions in Questions: Space, Development Theory and Regional Policy. Methuen, London a n d New York, 1984.
Halland, G.
T h e Introduction, in Problems of Savannah Development, Bergen, 1982.
Harriss
Rural Development. Baltimore. University Press, 1982.
John Hopkins
Huntington, R. e t a1
T h e Challenge of Rainfed Agriculture in Western and Southern Sudan, in A f r i c a Today, Vol. 28, No.2.
Ibrahim, F.N.
T h e Problem of Desertification in t h e Republic of t h e Sudan with Special R e f e r e n c e t o Northern Darfur, D S R C Monograph No. 8, 1978.
Johnston, B.F., and Clark, W.C.
Re- Designing Rural Development, Hutchinson, London, 1982.
Johnston, B.F.
F a r m Equipment Innovations in E a s t e r n Africa: Policy Considerations, in I. Ahmed a n d B. Kinsey (eds). F a r m Equipment Innovations in Eastern, C e n t r a l anc! Southern Africa. Gower. 1984.
Kerblay, B.
Chayanov and t h e Theory of P e a s a n t r y a s a Specific Type of Economy, in T. Shanin (ed) P e a s a n t s and P e a s a n t Societies, Penguin, 1971.
Kinsey, B.H.
Agricultural Equipment Innovations and Rural Transf o r m a t i o n in Tanzania, in I. Ahmed and B. Kinsey (eds) F a r m Equipment Innovations in Eastern, C e n t r a l a n d Southern Africa, Gower, 1984.
I. Kursany
Mainstream and Marxist Economic C a t e g o r i e s in Relation t o Sudanese Development Problems, in Sudan Journal of Economic and Social Studies, Vol. 5, No. 1, 1983.
Lele, U m a
T h e Design of Rural Development: Lessons f r o m Africa, Baltimore and John Hopkins University Press, 1976.
Lele, Urna
Rural Africa: Modernization, Equity and Long- Term Development, in Science, Vol. 211, No. 4482, Feb. 1981.
Long, N.
An Introduction t o t h e Sociology of Rural Developm e n t , Tavistock, London, 1972.
Makmoud, F.B.
T h e Sudanese Bourgeosie.
Manger, L.
T h e Sand Swallows our Land. Bergen Occasional P a p e r s in Social Anthropology, No. 24, 1982.
Manger, L.
Communal Labour in t h e Sudan, Bergen Occasional P a p e r s in Social Anthropology, Forthcoming, 1987.
Mohamed- Salih, M.A.
Development a n d Social C h a n g e a m o n g t h e Moro of t h e Nuba Mountains, PhD Thesis, University of Manchester, 1983.
Mohamed- Salih, M.A.
Research Methodology and t h e C o m p e t e n c e of Social Scientists in Depicting Reality: Some Odd F a c t s f r o m Rural Sudan, in B.O.M. Fadlalla e t a1 (eds): Research Methods in t h e Social Sciences: T h e Quest
London:
Zed, 1984.
for Relevant Approaches for Africa, t h e Organization of Social Science Research in Eastern Africa, 1986. Muchiri, G.
Farm Equipment for Smallholders in Semi-Arid Kenya, in I. Ahmed and B. Kinsey (eds) Farm Equipment Innovations in Eastern, Central and Southern Africa, Gower, 1984.
O'Brien, J.
How Traditional is Traditional Agriculture, in Sudan Journal of Economic and Social Studies, 1977.
Oesterdiekhoff, P., and Wohlmuth (eds)
The Development Perspective of t h e Democratic Republic of t h e Sudan, Waltforum Verlag, 1983.
Pearse, A.
Seeds of Plenty, Seeds of Want: Social and Economic Implications of t h e Green Revolution, Clarendon Press, Oxford, 1980.
Saeed, M.H.
Economic Effects of Agricultural Mechanization in Rural Sudan: The Case of Habila, Southern Kordofan, in G. Haaland (ed), Problems of Savannah Development: The Sudan Case, Bergen Occasional Papers in Social Anthropology, No. 19, 1982.
Tothill, J.B.
Agriculture in t h e Sudan, Oxford University Press, 1948.
Ziche, J., and Mohamed-Salih, M.A.
Communal Labour and Rural Development in Africa South of t h e Sahara, in t h e International Journal of Agriculture, Vol. 23, No. 4, 1984.
Reports and Documents Referred to: German Technical Co-operation (GTZ): The Nuba Mountains Regional Masterplan for Rural Development, 1978. Hunting Technical Service Ltd: Agricultural Development in Jebel Mara Area, 1977: The Indicative Plan for Agricultural Development in South Kordofan, 1980. Jebel Mara Rural Development Project:
Annual Reports, 1983-1985. The Rainfed Sector Strategy:
Ministry of Finance and Economic Planning: 1986. Nuba Mountains Agricultural Corporation:
Annual Reports, 1970-1985.
Nuba Mountains Rural Development Project:
Annual Reports 1983-1985.
South Kordofan Agricultural Development Project: The Main Report Conducted by t h e Australian Consulting and Management Ltd., and Newtech Engineering Ltd., for t h e Ministry of Finance and Economic Planning 1986.
Sudan Government: follows:
Plans for Social and Economic Development:
Five Year Plan, 1970171 - 1975176 Six Year Plan, 1976177 - 1982183
as
NATIONAL AMBIVALENCE AND EXTERNAL HEGEMONY: The Negligence of Pastoral Nomads in the Sudan Abdel Ghaffar M. Ahmed
Introduction In dealing with t h e issue of t h e Sahel famine, Meillassoux (1974) considered t h e whole process a result of exploitation of t h e region by a dominant capitalist system.
The benefit of t h e aid given is t o save t h e population
from hunger, or t o slow their exodus t o urban areas, a s well a s t o reduce their anger.
The f a m i n e s e t s t h e framework for "the prospects of a c r u e l
but nevertheless lucrative future".'
Within such a context, " the virtual
disappearance of t h e nomads leaves room f o r stock farming and hiring of labour". In order t o pave t h e way for such a process, development theorists in most of t h e developing countries s e e m t o a t t r i b u t e t h e failure of their models t o t h e indigenous s y s t e m s of production in rural areas.
Pastoral
nomads lead t h e list of categories of rural people who a r e considered a s resistant
t o change
in
t h e s e countries.
This a t t i t u d e of
resistance,
whether labelled a s having a " c a t t l e complex", a s in t h e c a s e of nomads, or considered "super laz;."
the
and "fatalistic", a s in t h e c a s e of
peasants, has been very much exaggerated. Looking a t t h e a t t i t u d e towards nomads, one a g r e e s with Swift (1977) t h a t t h e y a r e confused.
But t h e most prevalent a t t i t u d e s a r e a t present
those of t h e government officials and development specialists, who o f t e n regard t h e m a s "backward and irrational people, a burden on t h e s t a t e and 2 inevitably destined t o b e changed into something m o r e modern". R a t h e r than discussing modernization and resistance t o change, t h e present experience of
t h e developing countries calls for
a
systematic
evaluation of t h e process of development t h a t has been under way for a number of decades.
Instead of asking with Schneider, "why d o people who
a r e relatively rich in livestock usually resist development"? i t is b e t t e r t o s t a r t by questioning t h e types of development which a r e taking place in 3 t h e s e countries. This paper is a revised version of Planning and t h e Neglect of Pastoral G. Haaland (ed) Problems of Savannah DevelopNomads in t h e Sudan, ment, Bergen 1982.
Although t h e v a s t majority of t h e population of developing countries reside and m a k e t h e i r living in rural a r e a s , f r o m which c o m e s a very large p a r t of t h e national wealth, t h e p a s t development s t r a t e g i e s which g a v e inadequate support t o t h e r u r a l a r e a s have resulted in a deterioration in t h e quality of rural life. T h e s e s t r a t e g i e s t h a t w e r e pursued by t h e developing countries a f t e r t h e Second World War, did n o t challenge t h e main f e a t u r e s of t h e international division of labour, shaped during t h e l a s t century.
An externally
oriented and dependent development model w a s a c c e p t e d by t h e ruling elite.
New a t t e m p t s t o a c h i e v e development have already s t a r t e d t o t a k e
into consideration t h e present crisis of t h e world's economic order and t h e unequal exchange relations.
R e s i s t a n c e t o t h e previous model of "develop-
ment" has been t h e a c t i o n of many s t r a t a s of t h e population in developing countries.
T h e r e s i s t a n c e of pastoral nomads, whether rich o r poor, is
understandable when looked a t within t h i s framework. Pastoral Systems of Production Development plans h a v e r e c e n t l y given varying degrees of a t t e n t i o n t o t h e contribution of t h e livestock sector.
However, i t c a n b e easily noticed
t h a t t h e quality of l i f e a m o n g t h e nomadic population has n o t improved in proportion
to
this
sector's
contribution
to
the
national
economy.
In addition t o accusations t h a t t h e nomadic population i s conservative and resists change, t h e drought h a s also been blamed.
Yet, a n examination
of t h e method suggested by t h e project for t h e development of traditional agriculture, shows t h a t t h e r e is a n undeclared objective in t h e s e plans, namely t o s e t t l e t h e pastoral nomads.
The pastoral system of production
under such pressure is a f f e c t e d by t h e difficulties t h a t t h e s e people a r e facing in a rapidly changing world. In trying t o show t h e s e difficulties i t become? m o r e e a s y t o follow t h e i r complexity and interrelation if t h e pastoral production system of t h e various regions is t r e a t e d separately. 1.
T h e r e a r e t h e marginal lands of
t h e Sudan, bordering t h e
d e s e r t , w h e r e t h e precipitation is 200mm per annum o r less. Here, n o cultivation is possible, e x c e p t in r a r e c a s e s where people h a v e small fields along t h e w a t e r courses during t h e
rainy season.
The pastoral movement is a long one, and t h e
most dominant
animal in this region is t h e camel, whose
c h a r a c t e r i s t i c s m a k e i t m o r e suitable for survival in such a n environment than o t h e r animals. 2.
In t h e savannah belt, w h e r e t h e rainfall varies between 400 and
800mm
per
annum,
the
alternatives for land use. or t o c u l t i v a t e a
population
has a number of
They c a n use i t t o g r a z e animals,
variety of crops, or t o combine animal
husbandry with c r o p production which is w h a t t h e majority of t h e m do.
Most of t h e population h e r e is s e t t l e d in permanent
or semi- permanent season.
villages, and cultivates during t h e rainy
During t h e dry season s o m e members of t h e house-
hold move with their herds ( c a t t l e , sheep and a relatively small number of water.
camels) t o places of
better
pasture and
Those who have their villages near perennial rivers
a r e much
more settled,
and their villages a r e permanent.
The most dominant animals of their herds a r e c a t t l e , sheep and goats, whose characteristics suit t h e ecological setting. The distances t h a t t h e s e animals have t o cover in search of pasture a r e r a t h e r short compared t o those covered by herds in t h e marginal lands.4
I t is important t o mention h e r e t h a t
t h e s i z e of t h e herd determines t h e number of m e m b e r s of t h e household t h a t have t o move with i t , o r t h e number of hired people t o d o t h e job, if no dependents c a n b e a t t r a c t e d . The process of allocation of t i m e and labour t o t h e various tasks
undertaken
by e a c h
individual of
the
household,
is
handled by t h e household head.
3.
Ethnic groups t h a t keep very l a r g e herds of c a t t l e in t h e southern p a r t of this belt, prefer pure pastoralism t o o t h e r systems of production, a s seen f r o m t h e c a s e of t h e Baggara of t h e Sudan.
This preference should not only b e accounted
for by a detailed account of c u s t o m s and values, but a special emphasis has t o
b e given t o t h e r81e of
c a t t l e in such
societies, whose integration in t h e m a r k e t economy is recent. An understanding of important
for
t h e n a t u r e of pastoral capital is very
understanding
the
insistence
on
such
a
preference.5 ( Sudd
In t h e s w a m p region of t h e Southern Sudan (The
) t h e annual
together
transhumant
migration of
t h e people
with t h e i r livestock is a rational response t o t h e
existing ecological situation.
Seasonal floods f o r c e t h e human
and
the
animal
populations
to
highland
during
the
rainy
season, w h e r e t h e y remain until t h e flood recedes before they grazing land near t h e river.
move t o t h e toich ment t o t h e
The move-
is due t o t h e lack of good pasture and
toich
enough w a t e r in t h e highlands during t h e dry season (see Figure 1).
While staying in t h e highlands, t h e Dinka and t h e
Nuer who reside in this region, c u l t i v a t e small fields with different
crops which
t h e y use for consumption,
with t h e
exception of surplus crops of t o b a c c o which a r e marketed. The dominant animals h e r e a r e t h e Nilotic c a t t l e , but a fair number of Nilotic sheep and g o a t s is also kept. description of been
carried
t h e Nilotic livestock activities out,
and
this
describes 6 migratory c y c l e (adopted f r o m P a y n e ).
the
A detailed
has recently
general
annual
These t h r e e regions have been influenced by a number of f a c t o r s which a r e inducing change in t h e pastoral system of production. major f a c t o r a f f e c t i n g t h e f i r s t region This
factor
had
a
number
of
The
( t h e marginal lands) is t h e drought.
economic,
ecological and
sociocultural
implictions. "Through i t s devastating actions, d e s e r t encroachment t h r e a t e n s social life in t h e a f f e c t e d regions.
T h e loss of land t o t h e d e s e r t results
in t h e collapse of t h e economic base which g e n e r a t e s a chain of reactions leading finally t o t h e disintegration of t h e economic base which g e n e r a t e s a chain of reactions leading finally t o t h e disintegration of t h e community a t large and t h e discontinuity of
human habitation".
"The short- term
e f f e c t s a r e predominantly psychological ones, resulting from t h e lack of stability
due
production.
to
the
c h a n c e of
The long- term 7
n a t u r a l phenomena,
effect
will
mean a
pasture and crop
virtual disappearance
of life in t h a t region".
Inclusion of Nomads in Development Planning The contribution of pastoral nomadic groups t o t h e national economy of t h e developing countries in which they live has been hindered by t h e type
FIGURE 1 The Annual Transhumant Migratory Cycle of Livestock Owners with their Animals in t h e Kongor-Duk Fawil Area
Livestock all a t homestead: k e p t in a luak at night
Livestock r e t u r n t o c a m p s adjacent t o village a s flood w a t e r s rise
Livestock all a t homestead: k e p t in a luak at night
Livestock from t h e c a t t l e c a m p move t o t h e i n t e r m e d i a t e land away from t h e village
P a r t herd in village: p a r t in c a t t l e camps adjacent t o t h e village
Wet Season
Eastward migration back t o t h e village begins
-
- - - - - - - _ I
---
North wind blows: floor w a t e r s r e c e d e livestock no longer in luaks a t night: still a t homestead
--- --
Firing of less palatable grasses on t h e interm e d i a t e land begins
If very dry season c a m p s will be on t h e e d g e of t h e d e e p flooded toich or taar
Toich c a m p s formed: f i r s t in home toich (toiya bai ): t h e deep flooded toich is still underwater a t this t i m e
Livestock in communal village c a m p s Communal village camps moved t o intermediate land: in the p a s t t o east: some livestock remain in t h e villages Pools in intermediate land drying up: returns t o village & westward migration begins: s o m e livestock remain in t h e villages: but most move westwards
of plans on which t h e s e countries have embarked since independence.
All
plans f o r t h e livestock s e c t o r lacked a n integrated approach and were mostly composed of unco-ordinated
projects, where animal resources were
isolated from agricultural production. Nomads represent 25 t o 40 per c e n t of t h e population of t h e Sudan. The animal wealth in t h e country is mainly held by t h e pastoral nomads. They own 90 per c e n t of t h e domestic a n i m a ~ s . ~Nomadic livestock is t h e major source of m e a t for local and e x p o r t markets, and therefore, whene v e r t h e r e is a r e f e r e n c e t o t h e contribution of t h e livestock section in t h e Sudan economy, this largely r e f e r s t o t h e contribution of t h e nomads. However, in s p i t e of this major r6le of t h e nomads on t h e national level, t h e livestock s e c t o r has not been given t h e a t t e n t i o n i t deserves by t h e government.
The T e n Year Plan (1960-1970) completely neglected t h e
nomads, and t h e s h a r e of t h e i r s e c t o r in t h e government investment plan was insignificant (only 0.65 per cent).
The Five Year Plan for 1970-75
repeated t h e mistake of t h e T e n Year Plan.
The major objective of this
plan was t o increase livestock production by 75.5 per c e n t and t o go beyond
self- sufficiency,
products.
in
order
t o export
meat
and
other
livestock
By examining t h e plan, one finds t h a t with regard t o t h e live-
stock s e c t o r i t has many shortcorfiings: a.
It lacks a co- ordinated approach t o t h e problems of development, and t h e a n i m a l resources w e r e handled in isolation from agricultural production.
b.
The s h a r e of t h e sector, a s t o t h e plan's public fund, was insignificant (0.98 per cent).
C.
Most of t h e projects planned w e r e for services.
d.
The plan did not provide for a n appropriate expansion of fodder base and irrigation of pastures.
e.
The
plan
had
not
included
any
projects f o r 9
the
direct
improvement of t h e nomads' life conditions.
The Six Year Plan (1977/78/1982/83) is trying t o avoid t h e shortcomings of
the
two
previous
plans.
The development
of
traditional
agriculture, which is defined in such a way t h a t i t includes livestock, has been given special emphasis.
In i t s overall objectives, in t h e c h a p t e r on
a g r i c u l t u r e , i t h a s t h e following s t a t e m e n t s t h a t t o u c h on t h e nomads:
1.
Development
and
modernization
of
traditional
farming,
i m p r o v e m e n t of conditions f o r n o m a d s a n d t h e modernization of p a s t o r a l a c t i v i t i e s . 2.
D e v e l o p m e n t of improvement
a n i m a l w e a l t h , c o n t r o l of
of
production
diseases and t h e 10 marketing facilities.
and
T h e s h a r e of t h e livestock s e c t o r a m o u n t s t c 12.98 p e r c e n t of t h e public funds a l l o t t e d t o t h e a g r i c u l t u r a l s e c t o r of t h e plan, a n d t o 22.9 per c e n t when t h e c o n t r i b u t i o n of t h e p r i v a t e s e c t o r t o a g r i c u l t u r a l developm e n t is included.
T h e s h a r e of t h e livestock s e c t o r , a s t o t h e plan's
public funds, h a s i n c r e a s e d significantly c o m p a r e d with t h e t w o previous plans.
Y e t , o n e very a p p a r e n t f e a t u r e of t h i s plan a s t o i n v e s t m e n t i s
t h a t t h e r e is a g a i n m o r e e m p h a s i s on t h e a s p e c t of public s e r v i c e s , whereas
most
aspects
of
production
are
left
to
the
private
sector.
Aspects and Consequences oi Planned Development T h e s i t u a t i o n in
North
E a s t A f r i c a a t p r e s e n t is a
v e r y serious one.
Nevertheless, i t h a s n o t b e e n s u b j e c t e d t o a publicity s i m i l a r t o t h e Sahel c a s e , e x c e p t when political issces o n a n a t i o n a l level w e r e involved, a s in t h e c a s e of Ethiopia.
This is mainly d u e t o t h e f a c t t h a t a c o u n t r y like
t h e Sudan h a s t h e p o t e n t i a l i t i e s of population
in
other
regions
a c c o m m o d a t i n g i t s drought s t r i c k e n
adjacent
to
the
marginal
lands.
This h a s been t h e i m m e d i a t e r e a c t i o n of t h e population in t h e s e l a s t few
years.
savannah belt.
They
started
moving
south
with
their
animals into t h e
It is h e r e t h a t w e s e e a n e w phenomenon of adaption, not
only by t h e human population, but a l s o by t h e animals.
H e r d s cf c a m e l s
a r e f o r t h e f i r s t t i m e s e e n g r a z i n g s o u t h of l a t i t u d e 9"N, a n a r e a which t h e i r h e r d e r s used t o avoid, d u e t o t h e p r e s e n c e of f l i e s and c l a y land which is n o t f a v o u r a b l e f o r t h e animal. However, t h i s a b i l i t y t o a c c o m m o d a t e such people in t h i s b e l t h a s i t s serious c o n s e q u e n c e s f o r t h e second region,
t h e savannah b e l t itself.
The
productivity of t h e region, in t e r m s of c r o p production is d e c r e a s i n g due t o t h e d a m a g e c a u s e d by t h e newly a r r i v e d herds.
Hence, t h e production
of g u m a r a b i c in t h e b e l t is rapidly d e c r e a s i n g , d u e t o t h e browsing of c a m e l s on t h e
Acacia senegal
trees.
T h e s e t r e e s on t h e n o r t h e r n limits
of t h e
belt w e r e also a f f e c t e d by t h e drought.
Such a development is
having a very alarming e f f e c t on t h e national economy, since gum arabic represents one of t h e major crops t h a t provides foreign currency t o t h e country. Conflicts
between
becoming t h e major These
conflicts have
pastoral
problem been
nomads
and
sedentary
cultivators
facing t h e administration
m o r e complicated and
of
are
t h e region.
their frequency has
increased through t h e challenge introduced by t h e agricultural development plans for t h e region, including both irrigated and rainfed areas.
These
plans, when considered within a national o r inter- regional context, c a n be seen a s a blessing, since t h e y provide food a t a t i m e when developing countries a r e suffering f r o m serious shortages of such items. But looked a t within t h e framework of international t r a d e and t h e pertaining unequal exchange relations, especially when t h e production of cash crops is emphasized, i t c a n be seen a s a curse on t h e population of t h e a r e a , whether t h e y a r e cultivators, pastoral nomads or agro- pastoralists. The f i r s t a r e f o r c e d t o sell their labour cheaply.
The second a r e
driven from t h e best a r e a s of their traditional pasture t o places which a r e not favourable for their herds, which leads t h e m into m o r e conflicting situations.''
And t h e last a r e being subjected t o various socio- economic
pressures and forced t o abandon one of t h e t w o activities and change into agricultural labourers with low wages and a n even lower standard of living. Looking a t t h e position of t h e pastoral nomads in this region today, we notice t h a t t h e pressure on land is increasing rapidly, d u e t o t h e new schemes being established or proposed (Figure 2) and due t o t h e movement of m o r e herds from t h e marginal lands.
The carrying c a p a c i t y of t h e
a r e a s available for grazing by t h e herds of pastoral nomads is decreasing. The land ownership in most, if not all p a r t s of this belt, is in t h e hands of t h e government, who thus c a n establish a n y s c h e m e t h a t i t sees f i t for t h e area. The pastoral management units t h e r e f o r e do not have a monopoly on t h e grazing land t h e y use, since t h e grazing a r e a s a r e communally used by t h e e t h n i c groups t h a t traditionally reside in t h e specific location.
But
even in t h e c a s e of a t e r m like Dar in t h e Sudan (meaning homeland) which implies t h a t a n e t h n i c group has a n exclusive use of t h e grazing
grounds in i t s homeland, t h e situation has changed.
T h e Dar rights a r e no
longer valid, and any group c a n move in t o utilize t h e available resources. Therefore, no m a n a g e m e n t unit o r e t h n i c group in a given a r e a c a n strike animals.
an
optimal
balance
between
pasture
resources a n d
number of
T h e c o n c e n t r a t e d distribution of w a t e r sources h a s been a very
i m p o r t a n t f a c t o r leading t o over- grazing. The animal population using t h e s e sources is increasing considerably, due t o t h e improvement of veterinary services over t h e l a s t years.
A
significant addition t o t h e s e herds i s presently coming f r o m prosperous f a r m e r s in t h e irrigated s c h e m e s in this belt.
Animals s e e m , even with
t h e present situation of development of this region and i t s integration in t h e m a r k e t economy, t o b e t h e only possible a l t e r n a t i v e f o r investment for prosperous farmers. o u t of
T h e herds t h a t such f a r m e r s a c c u m u l a t e h a v e t o move
t h e scheme area, except
when c r o p s a r e harvested, s i n c e t h e
animal units, a d m i t t e d by t h e s c h e m e management, a r e only those which will cover t h e f a r m e r s 1 essential needs of milk and o t h e r a n i m a l products. T h e concept of a g r i c u l t u r e provided by t h e development plans for t h e region
is one which s e p a r a t e s c r o p production from a n i m a l husbandry.
Hence a f a r m e r who w a n t s t o invest in herds has t o establish relations with neighbouring pastoral nomads who c a n c a r e for his animals when they a r e a w a y f r o m t h e village.
This has been done successfully in s o m e c a s e s
particularly in t h e c a s e of t h e New Halfa s c h e m e in t h e Sudan.
12
By
agreeing t o keep t h e f a r m e r ' s herd when h e c u l t i v a t e s in t h e scheme, t h e pastoral nomads s e c u r e a n a c c e s s t o t h e agricultural by- products of t h e plot of t h e f a r m e r a f t e r harvesting.
13
It is important t o n o t e h e r e t h a t t h e o f f t a k e f r o m t h e s e herds is very low.
But
the
marginal
productivity
of
further
i n v e s t m e n t in
herds,
whether owned by pastoral nomads o r o t h e r groups, has n o t y e t approached zero.
Until
that
happens
herds
will
continue
to
increase.
But i t is necessary t o k e e p in mind t h a t pastoral nomads a r e very sensitive t o t h e carrying c a p a c i t y aspect.
Although t h e p a s t u r e is not
monopolized by individual m a n a g e m e n t units, a s previously s t a t e d , t h e selfregulatory n a t u r e of t h e s y s t e m of pure pastoralism is keeping t h e system of production in action.
Conceptualizing t h e situation a s such, ~ n t e g r a t e d
development plans which h a v e a m o r e positive approach t o t h e improvem e n t of t h e existing s y s t e m s of c r o p production and livestock, will lead t o
real development which would have a positive i m p a c t on t h e quality of life of t h e indigenous people. R e c e n t plans for t h e Southern Darfur a r e a , situated in t h e southern p a r t of t h e savannah region, a r e advocating such a n approach.14
A t this
point, mention has t o b e m a d e of t h e f a c t t h a t t h e richer groups among pastoral nomads do in f a c t t a k e t h e c h a n c e when a n opportunity arises, t o The Rufa's al-Hoi, t h e Shukriya and t h e Halawiyyn, 15 and irrigated schemes, a r e c a s e s in point.
invest in new fields. who
joined
rainfed
The transhumant population of t h e Sudd region has for t h e last t w o decades been facing similar changes through t h e excessive flooding of their land.
The worst p a r t of t h i s period w e r e t h e years 1961-64, when t h e
Dinka and t h e Nuer lost l a r g e numbers from their herds.
Some families
w e r e forced t o s e t t l e on highlands, t o depend on cultivation and from relatives whose herds had managed t o survive.
on help
O t h e r s s e t t l e d in t h e
southern p a r t of t h e a r e a , w h e r e fishing b e c a m e t h e major activity in 16 order t o secure a living. On t h e whole, m o s t of t h e households w e r e l e f t with surplus manpower t h a t could not b e employed in t h e traditional system.
This surplus
personnel s t a r t e d t o m i g r a t e northwards, t o work in t h e various projects in t h e Northern Sudan.
The wages of this surplus labour caused a flow of
cash into t h e traditional s y s t e m and led t o a gradual opening-up of i t s l7
closed cycle, which h a s been described in t h e l i t e r a t u r e on t h e s e people.
O n e of t h e major benefits of t h e Jonglei Canal Project, which was approved by t h e Government of t h e Sudan in J u n e 1974, is t h a t i t will p r o t e c t t h e a r e a s t h a t have always been subjected t o flood hazards.
It
will also lead t o a n increase of t h e riverain summer grazing, and i t will provide perennial w a t e r s in t h e highlands and intermediate lands, which will
enable
a
utilization
of
their
pastures
throughout
the
year.
Leadership A number of integrated development projects a r e under study, leading t o a wider understanding of t h e processes of development.
O n e major emphasis
is on popular participation in t h e development process, and so f a r interest has been generated
but e f f e c t i v e participation is not y e t t o b e found.
This r e l a t e s t o a n issue which is significant for all t h e t h r e e populations
in t h e regions discussed, namely t h a t of representation. Generally, regions.
pastoral
people
have enjoyed s o m e autonomy in
their
They d e a l t with t h e c e n t r a l government machine through their
traditional leaders, who represented t h e m in t h e outside world m o r e than they a c t e d a s mediators in t h e inter- group affairs.
The legitimacy and
s t r u c t u r e of t h e leadership is a topic beyond t h e scope of this paper.
18
What is essential t o mention h e r e is t h a t t h e c e n t r a l political system has d e a l t a blow t o such traditional leaders.
The c e n t r a l government has
reduced or abolished their e f f e c t i v e r61e in administration, and has tried t o c r e a t e new leaders in their place, i.e., leadership,
t h e c a m p councils.
The new
which is e l e c t e d and/or appointed from t h e c a m p members,
lacked t h e experience which t h e previous leaders had. the effective
participation
of
This has hindered
t h e s e new leaders in t h e new political
organization, t h e o n e party system.
Thus f a r this leadership has not been
a b l e t o express adequately t h e way in which i t s masses view t h e rapid change which is taking place in their regions. These changes in t h e s t r u c t u r e of leadership have been followed by a number of
changes in t h e relation
traditional e t h n i c organization.
between various groups within t h e
On t h e whole, t h e result is r a t h e r dis-
appointing, since i t did not achieve i t s major goal of e f f e c t i v e participation of
the
masses of
pastoral
nomads in issues related
t o their
future
development.
The Role of International Agencies The consequences of planned development h a v e culminated in a disastrous ecological degradation, desertification, Sahel.
deforestration, and famine in t h e
Many of t h e Sahelian pastoral nomads and subsistence cultivators
have lost their command over their resources and hence become vulnerable t o any change in t h e d e l i c a t e ecological balance t h a t they have maintained over t h e centuries. in t w o ways:
The international organizations e n t e r into t h e picture
first, through t h e international division of labour a s I have
s t a t e d earlier ( $ 3 7 )
and second through t h e aid t h a t they o f f e r t o t h e
victims of their exploitative economic operations in t h e Sahel. therefore
see
that
the
national
governments,
due
to
the
One can structural
relation of dependence on t h e international donors, became prone t o a c c e p t t h e policy recommendations of t h e international development agencies.
It
is not surprising in t h e c i r c u m s t a n c e s t h a t t h e most damaging decisions t o national economies and e n v i r o n m e n t s alike, w e r e introduced and supported by development e x p e r t s who usually d o n o t h a v e sufficient t i m e t o answer t h e question of who b e n e f i t s f r o m such v e n t u r e s nor d o t h e y bother t o enlist t h e views and a t t i t u d e s of t h e recipients.
F u r t h e r m o r e , when such
proposals a r e made, t h e channels of communication a r e a l w a y s based o n a t o p t o b o t t o m approach o r d e v e l o p m e n t f r o m above. Experimenting o n r u r a l peoples s t y l e of livelihood and lives b e c a m e a hobby f o r government advisors whether national o r foreign.
Africa has too frequently become a
l a b o r a t o r y for t h e f a n t a s i e s of foreign d e v e l o p m e n t e x p e r t s who l e a v e when t h e a g r i c u l t u r a l o r s e t t l e m e n t p r o j e c t s f a i l and t r y again elsewhere.
Their
f a i l u r e i s c r e d i t e d by being c o u n t e d a s a r e l e v a n t e x p e r i e n c e by recruiting i n t e r n a t i o n a l agencies.
T h e consequences of t h e r6le of t h e s e a g e n c i e s is
t h a t t h e national government
h a s b e c o m e m o r e and m o r e dependent on
t h e m and t h e i n t e r n a t i o n a l a g e n c i e s have t h u s b e c o m e m o r e involved in national policy formulation. In t h e i r a t t e m p t t o a f f e c t t h e i r d e v e l o p m e n t a s s i s t a n c e in t h e p a s t and t h e i r disaster a i d
r e c e n t l y , many international
institutions with or
without t h e support of t h e national governments, have a t t e m p t e d t o g a t h e r information
by
sending
experts
to
conduct
research.
a c t i v i t i e s a r e positively c o r r e l a t e d with underdevelopment.
The
research
However, t h e
value of t h e results and r e c o m m e n d a t i o n s put forward by t h e s e e x p e r t s c a n hardly equal t h e p r i c e of t h e s h e e t s of paper o n which t h e y a r e w r i t t e n . T h e need f o r a c t i o n o r i e n t e d r e s e a r c h which involves t h e recipients, rural social s c i e n t i s t s and n o t just t h e professionals is pressing. Two c o n t r a s t i n g p i c t u r e s of t h e r81e of t h e international a g e n c i e s c a n be c i t e d here.
The f i r s t p i c t u r e is r e p r e s e n t e d by Figure 3 o n p.143which
i l l u s t r a t e s t h e position of t h e development a u t h o r i t i e s in t h e process of accumulation and impoverishment of t h e r u r a l communities.
T h e figure
also reveals t h a t t h e d e v e l o p m e n t a u t h o r i t i e s usually by-pass t h e regular channels of decision making a n d transactions.
As a m a t t e r of f a c t t h e y
a r e providing f a c i l i t i e s for t h o s e who d o not need t h e m , t a k i n g decisions t h a t favour t h e middle c l a s s and e v e n providing food supplies f o r those who live in t h e vicinity of t h e decision making apparatuses. national development
authorities, a t
T h e inter-
t h e final analysis provide f o r t h e
m a i n t e n a n c e of t h e a l r e a d y privileged c a t e g o r i e s of t h e population and d o
away with those who a r e in need. The second picture is t h a t of
t h e small producers who a r e often
f o r c e d t o grow cash crops before t h e y c a n g e t a c c e s s t o credit.
O r those
pastoralists and subsistence cultivators who due t o t h e prevalent international division of labour a r e constantly buying dear from t h e rich and selling c h e a p t o t h e rich. wealth
and
poverty
In Nyerere's (1986:
breeds
poverty
388) words, " wealth breeds
- through
t h e relative investment
c a p a c i t y and power of t h e powerless in relation with others".19
It is this
mobility of small f a r m e r s t o e n t e r i n t o c o n t a c t with t h e representatives of t h e international institutions ( s e e Figure)
through t h e production of cash
crops t h a t individualism p e n e t r a t e d their
work e t h i c s which were' once
evolved around collectivism.
The results a r e grave when interpreted in
t e r m s of t h e disintegration of indigenous institutions of co- operation in pastoral and agricultural spheres of production. The final assault on t h e national economies is t h a t t h e y a r e caught in t h e dilemma of having t o produce or encourage rural people t o produce cash crops and thus add t o t h e food deficit in their countries.
The foreign
currencies obtained f r o m t h e s e economic enterprises a r e used t o service t h e mounting d e b t or t o pay for commodities which a r e forced on t h e m by t h e dominant economic order.
African poverty and underdevelopment is
not unrelated t o wealth and technical advances elsewhere.
This alone
answers t h e question of why t h e Sahelian population who w e r e until a few decades a g o used t o produce surplus food has been steadily heading towards a c u t e poverty, deprivation, destitution and famine.
Conclusion The above sections d e a l t briefly with t h e present position of t h e pastoral nomadic groups in t h e Sudan.
The division of t h e a r e a i n t o t h r e e distinct
regions is made f o r t h e purpose of allowing for an easy presentation of t h e case. R a t h e r t h a n going into a detailed discussion of t h e internal response of
t h e system of
organization
in e a c h group t o t h e change which is
imposed on i t (by natural f a c t o r s or by national government policies), t h e emphasis has been on giving a s u m m a r y of t h e i m p a c t of these factors. I t is necessary t o focus on this point a t this s t a g e of change, due t o t h e fact
t h a t t h e development planners in t h e s e countries have not been
FIGURE 3
Labour m ~ g r a t l o n
1
Returning migrants Development Authorities
m - - - - e -
I
Information, t a x e s , surplus
1
Decisions, o r d e r s , m a r k e t goods
2
e
.
-,
, ,
I
Exports, i m p o r t s , ,
L.
National boundaries
T h e i i g u r e i l l u s t r a t e s t h e d y n a m i c s of mobility a n d c h a r a c t e r i z e s t h e e c o n o m i c a c t i v i t i e s in a developing Sahelian country.
The deveiopment
a u t h o r i t y (D.A.) s t a n d s o u t s i d e a n d a b o v e t h e various m e c h a n i s m s of i n t e r a c t i o n a n d influences policies and decision making processes in r e l a t i o n t o r u r a l people f r o m s u c h a position t h a t i t holds.
concerned with pastoral nomads.
International institutions, most of which
send around t e a m s t h a t include a n anthropologist a s p a r t of t h e decoration, are
directly
involved
in
shaping
the
future
of
these
people.
If t h e r e is anything w e should do, a s anthropologists, i t is t o present
t h e views of t h e masses of pastoral nomads t o t h e c e n t r a l administration machinery which is trying t o plan their future.
Our participation in
various t e a m s has t o b e much m o r e effective. In t h e drought stricken a r e a of this belt, t h e pastoral nomads a r e partly solving their problem by moving south t o t h e richer areas.
But
this is being done a t t h e expense of those who traditionally use t h e a r e a for a combined system of production, i.e.,
crop production and animal
husbandry. Looking a t t h e pastoral nomadic system, we find t h a t nomads have thus f a r been very adaptive t o changes t h a t took place in t h e Sudan. This also applies t o their herds, a s seen in t h e example of camels.
Those
who had t h e misfortune t o lose most or all of their animals, have managed with l i t t l e difficulty, t o acquire new skills in order t o e a r n a reasonable living,
sometimes
even
without
the
assistance
of
the
state.
The Dinka and t h e Nuer fishing groups, a s well a s migrant labourers a r e c a s e s in point. conservative.
These c a s e s d e m o n s t r a t e t h a t pastoral nomads a r e not
They also show how willing t h e s e people c a n b e t o adapt
themselves t o changing situations,
provided t h a t they a r e given a fair
chance t o learn something a b o u t t h e possible benefits of t h e skills t o which they a r e introduced. No c l e a r policy, breaking t h e various a s p e c t s of pastoral existence, has thus f a r institutions
been s t a t e d by
involved.
The
t h e government or
pastoral
nomads'
by t h e international
representatives
necessary experience enabling t h e m t o influence change.
lack
the
Therefore, t h e
situation might become very difficult if herds continue t o increase a t their present r a t e , if
t h e o f f t a k e is not increased, if t h e carrying capacity
continues t o decrease, and if no controlled system of pasture management is n o t put forward by t h e government.
The whole planning issue in this
a r e a is in chaos and needs re- consideration, starting with basic issues like t h e concept of development itself.
The national economy is suffering from this unplanned solution. s o m e e f f o r t has recently solution in t h e s e countries.
been directed
But
towards finding a long-lasting
T h e government has been trying, since 1976,
t o implernent a plan f o r t h e protection of t h e marginal land.
Together
with t h e UNEP, UNDP (Sudan) and FAO, i t submitted a detailed proposal titled "Sudan's Desert Encroachment Control and Rehabilitation Programme" t o various countries and international institutions, hoping t o obtain their involvement and assistance. The proposal is now l e f t dormant under t h e p r e t e x t of high c o s t and technical problems.
If i t had been a s profitable t o international capital
a s t h e o t h e r proposed schemes in t h e Sudan's savannah belt, i t would have been given t h e s a m e a t t e n t i o n t h a t is now given t o these schemes by t h e World Bank or t h e multinational corporations.
Notes
(1)
S e e Claude Meillassoux, Famine Good Business? and Famine in Ethiopia, Economy, No. 1 , 1974:
Development o r Exploitation. Is t h e Sahel and Lionel Cliffe, Feudalism, Capitalism both in Review of African Political 27-40.
(2)
J e r e m y Swift, In d e f e n c e of nomads, Mazingira No. 2, 1977: 20-30. Also s e e Nelson, C., The Desert and t h e Sown; Nomads in Wider Society, Institute for International Studies, University of California, Berkeley, 1973. The collection of papers in this publication c a r r i e s p a r t of t h e discussion on t h e s e attitudes.
(3)
Schneider, E.K. makes this s t a t e m e n t in his a r t i c l e on Economic Development and Economic Change; t h e c a s e of East African C a t t l e , in C u r r e n t Anthropology, Vol. 15, No. 3 , 1974: 259. Concerning t h e question of t h e concept of development t h e d e b a t e has been going on for a long t i m e now. To m e t h e most a c c e p t a b l e conceptualization s o f a r is t h e one given in What Now. The 1975 Dag Hammarskjold Report, prepared on t h e occasion of t h e Seventh Special Session of t h e United Nations General Assembly.
(4)
The collection of papers in Some Aspects of Pastoral Nomadism in t h e Sudan, op.cit., o f f e r s comparative m a t e r i a l on t h i s topic.
(5)
S e e F. Barth, A General Perspective of Nomad- Sedentary Relations in t h e Middle East, in C. Nelson, The Desert and Sown, op.cit. Also s e e G. Haaland, Pastoral Systems of Production; t h e sociocultural c o n t e x t and s o m e of i t s economic and ecological implications, 1976 (mimeo)
(6)
W.J.A. P a y n e and F.M. El Amin, An Intern R e p o r t on t h e Dinka Livestock Industry in t h e Jonglei Area, Technical R e p o r t No. 5, 1977. Economic and Social R e s e a r c h Council (N.C.R.) and t h e Executive Organ f o r t h e Development P r o j e c t s in t h e Jonglei Area.
(7)
For m o r e d e t a i l s of t h e various a s p e c t s of t h e i m p a c t of t h e d e s e r t encroachment, S e e Sudan D e s e r t Encroachment Control and Rehabilitation P r o g r a m m e , prepared jointly by: The General Administration f o r N a t u r a l Resources, Ministry of Agriculture, Food and Natural Resources and t h e Agricultural Research Council. The National Council f o r R e s e a r c h in collaboration with UNEP, UNDF (Sudan) and F A O (Egypt). Khartoum, 1976.
(8)
S e e t h e introduction t o Some Aspects of Pastoral Nomadism in t h e Sudan, Abdel C h a f f a r M. Ahmed (ed), 1974, National Council f o r Research, and M.S. Bayoumi a n d others, Guide Lines Towards Development of Nomadism is t h e Sudan, 1974-75, in Ali M. Hassan (ed) Growth, Employment and Equity; a Selection of P a p e r s presented t o t h e ILO Comprehensive Employment S t r a t e g y Mission t o t h e Sudan, 1974-75: 96-1 15. The figure f o r Somali is t a k e n f r o m a " Consultant R e p o r t on t h e Establishment of Nomadic Training C e n t r e s in Somalia", 1976, w r i t t e n by Gunnar Haaland.
(9)
S e e Bayoumi, op.cit. pp. 1 13-1 4.
(10)
The Six Year Plan of Economic and Social Development, 1977-781982-83, Ministry of Planning, Vol. 2, April 1977: 6. The increase in animal population i s given in t h e following table:
Base Period 1976177 Population (000 Head)
Cattle
15,832
6.9
Sheep
15,918
Goats
12,116
Camels
( I 1)
Offtake Rate X
2,828
Target 1982183
Population (000 Head)
Offtake Rate %
% Annual Increase in Population
18,905
9.5
3.0
34.7
22,132
33.2
5.7
16.0
15,000
16.0
3.6
3.1
3,104
4.5
1.6
T h e conflict has b e c o m e very serious in t h e l a s t f e w years in t h e Southern p a r t of t h e savannah belt in t h e Sudan, especially t h e a r e a between White Nile and t h e Blue Nile w h e r e t h e Rufa's al-Hoi and Kinana pastoral nomads h a v e had t o fight their way south through t h e Mechanized Schemes. Conflict has led t o t h e loss of m o r e t h a n five herders in t h e l a s t t w o years. In Western Sudan t h e Beni Helba and t h e Mahriyya groups have been fighting since 1975 and m o r e t h a n 150 people have been killed. T h e l a s t clash was very recent. T h e conflict of t h e Dinka and t h e Baggara has been going on f o r a l m o s t t e n years now.
(12)
As a m e m b e r of a t e a m organized by t h e Arab Organization f o r Agricultural Development I had a c h a n c e of visiting New Halfa S c h e m e in May 1978 and my f i r s t hand information confirms this point. For m o r e m a t e r i a l on t h e pastoral nomads 1 position in t h e scheme, s e e Gunnar Sgrbo, " Nomads on t h e S c h e m e - a study of irrigation agriculture a n d pastoralism in Eastern Sudan", in P. O'Keefe (ed): Land a n d Development in Africa. International African Institute, London 1977, and a l s o G. S$rbo, How t o Survive Development; t h e Story of New Halfa, Development Studies a n d Research C e n t r e , Monograph Series No. 6.
(13)
Some of t h e s e pastoral nomads h a v e t a k e n tenancies on t h e s c h e m e and s o m e of t h e household m e m b e r s work on them. They have, t o g e t h e r with o t h e r t e n a n t s , been a c c u s e d of allowing t h e i r animals and t h e animals of relatives, friends o r those who a r e keeping t h e i r herds f o r t h e m t o e n t e r b e f o r e t h e harvest is over and thus lower t h e productivity of t h e tenancies by damaging t h e l a t e crops.
(14)
For a s u m m a r y of this suggested approach see Martin A. Adams, An Agricultural Development Plan f o r Southern Sudan, in Ali M. El Hassan (ed), Essays on t h e Economy a n d Society of t h e Sudan, Vol.1, 1977: 15-32. More d e t a i l s c a n b e found in t h e Hunting Technical Services R e p o r t s on t h e area.
(15)
S e e t h e papers on t h e P.ufals el-Hoi in Some Aspects of Nomadism, op.cit.
(16)
Although fishing is considered a s a major a c t i v i t y of t h e youth in t h e c a t t l e c a m p s t o g e t h e r with hunting, nobody t a k e s this a s a life t i m e job since i t implies t h a t such a person does not have enough c a t t l e t o demand his t i m e and t h e r e f o r e h e is poor a n d his s t a t u s i s Low in this society. T o t a k e t o fishing and even t o this point of investing t h e surplus t h a t t h e y a r e gaining through selling this fish in Equatoria in c a t t l e is a r e a l c h a n g e in t h e a t t i t u d e s of t h e s e people.
(17)
For a description of t h e closed s y s t e m of t h e Nuer and Dinka see: E.E. Evans- Pritchard, T h e Nuer, 1940, Oxford University Press, a n d also his o t h e r a r t i c l e s on t h e Nuer in various books and journals, G. Lienhardt, Divinity a n d Experience: The Religion of t h e Dinka, 1961, Oxford University Press. For t h e changes t h a t a r e taking place in t h e system s e e Abdel Ghaffar M. Ahmed, "Anthropology and Development Planning in t h e Sudan: The C a s e of Jonglei Project", in Sudan Journal of Development Research, Vol. I, No. 1 , February, 1977.
(18)
On t h e issue of legitimacy and representation of pastoral nomads s e e Talal Asad, " Political Inequality in t h e Kababish Tribe", in I. Cunnison and W. J a m e s (eds): Essays in Sudan Ethnography, London, Hurts, 1972, Abdel Ghaffar M. Ahmed, "Tribal and Sedentary Elites: A Bridge Between Two Communities" , in C. Nelson (ed), The D e s e r t and t h e Sown, op.cit.
(19)
Nyerere, J.K. "An Address" Development and Change Vol. 17, No. 3, July, 1986. AISO r e f e r t o A.M. Ahmed Ecological Degradation in t h e Sahel: t h e Political Dimension, a paper presented in t h e Development Seminar f o r t h e Inauguration of t h e C e n t r e f o r Development Studies, University of Bergen, Norway 8-1 1 September 1986.
IMPLICATIONS OF THE 1983-1985 FAMINE ON THE RURAL SAHEL OF SUDAN
Abdullahi Osrnan El Tom T h e semi- arid b e l t which I r e f e r t o a s t h e r u r a l Sahel of
t h e Sudan,
c o m p r i s e s a n a r e a of 900 t o o n e million s q u a r e k i l o m e t r e s b e t w e e n Lat.
10 N a n d 17 N.
I t is e s t i m a t e d t h a t b e t w e e n 60-70 per c e n t of t h e t o t a l
population of t h e Sudan live in t h i s z o n e a n d t h e m a j o r i t y of t h e m a r e e n g a g e d in c r o p a n d livestock production. This paper is mainly based on t h e s t u d y of
Northern Darfur
1
.
A
m o r e d e t a i l e d investigation on t h e implications of f a m i n e o n t h e people of t h i s region w a s c a r r i e d o u t a m o n g t h e Berti.
It is however hoped t h a t t h e
m a t e r i a l will provide a f a i r ground f o r g e n e r a l i z a t i o n s t h a t include all similar c o n t e x t s in t h e r u r a l S a h e l of t h e Sudan. T h e Berti, a m o n g o t h e r s e d e n t a r y groups s u c h a s t h e Meidob, Zaghawa, Masalit, and Tungur, p r a c t i s e a r a b l e r a i n f e d a g r i c u l t u r e a n d r a i s e small n u m b e r s of
animals.
Millet
is t h e main s t a p l e c r o p a n d
has gained
i m p o r t a n c e a g a i n s t c a s h c r o p s such a s s e s a m e , w a t e r melon s e e d s and groundnuts.
Gum a r a b i c w a s in t h e p a s t a m o n g t h e main c a s h e a r n i n g
p r o d u c t s b e f o r e t h e t r e e s w e r e d e s t r o y e d by drought or c l e a r e d by t h e f a r m e r s who r e p l a c e d t h e m with a continuous expansion a n d s h i f t i n g of m i l l e t c u l t i v a t i o n f r o m o n e plot t o a n o t h e r .
O t h e r r e a s o n s behind t h e
c l e a r a n c e of g u m a r a b i c t r e e s include population g r o w t h a n d p r e s s u r e on land, a n d soil d e g r a d a t i o n d u e t o t h e f a r m e r s ' d e s e r t i o n of t h e t r a d i t i o n a l rotation
system
in
which
t h e c u l t i v a t i o n of
millet a n d oil s e e d s was
followed by t h e nursing of g u m a r a b i c t r e e s in t h e fallow fields.
There
is a l s o a n e c o n o m i c reason, mainly t h e d e c r e a s e in gum a r a b i c prices relative
to
those
of
millet
during
the
drought
phase
of
1983-1985.
O n e of t h e most striking f e a t u r e s of t h e process of e c o l o g i c a l c h a n g e in t h e r u r a l Sahel of t h e Sudan is t h e m a n n e r in which h o e c u l t i v a t i o n is a c c o m p a n i e d
by a
widespread
o t h e r t y p e s of v e g e t a t i o n c o v e r ;
e l i m i n a t i o n of
wild t r e e s , grass,
and
a process which h a s undoubtedly c o n t r i-
buted t o t h e a c c e l e r a t i o n of d e s e r t c r e e p .
Animals, which r e p r e s e n t a n
i m p o r t a n t s o u r c e of food a n d c a s h , h a v e s u f f e r e d alike.
Loss of livestock,
in p a r t i c u l a r , h a s m e a n t t h e drying up of c a s h i n c o m e s s i n c e t h e y also provide
security
in
the event
of
c r o p failure.
Livestock,
therefore,
c o n s t i t u t e a buffer z o n e against famine.
The mobility of animals, t h e i r
ability t o g e t o u t of t h e drought stricken a r e a s and t h e i r high r a t e of reproduction, ranks t h e m a s by f a r t h e best f o r m of capital. Famine and i-ts Aftermath
According t o 1974 e s t i m a t e s , t h e Sahelian drought of 1970-1973 claimed t h e lives of 250,000 people and 3.5 million animals.
Sudan survived t h a t
f a m i n e situation and t h e drought lasted f o r o n e or t w o odd y e a r s in s o m e regions, with m o r e fluctuation of rainfall t h a n t h e e n d e m i c d e c r e a s e of 40 t o 50 per c e n t of precipitation a s happened in 1983-1985.
The 1983-1985
drought was d i f f e r e n t in t h a t i t lasted for f o u r continuous years.
The
modest e s t i m a t e s given by t h e various relief agencies indicate t h a t i t claimed about 100,000 lives mainly in Darfur, Kordofan and t h e R e d Sea Regions.
The situation was similar t o what Derrik (1977:
553) describes
for t h e West African drought of 1972-1973 in t h a t , " the m o s t in need w e r e nomads and cultivators living in small isolated groups s c a t t e r e d over v a s t a r e a s , e x c e p t those who began a n exodus from t h e a f f e c t e d a r e a s t o towns or within reach of relief aid". C r o p failures a r e not uncommon in t h e Sahel and t h e semi- arid zone described above, y e t t h e 1983-1385 f a m i n e was certainly t h e worst in living memory.
First, i t was a culmination of many years of c r o p failures
and reduced rainfall.
In f a c t t h e l a s t good harvest f o r most of t h e pop-
ulation in t h e semi- arid belt of t h e Sudan was 1978.
Second, c r o p failure
was widespread and had a f f e c t e d o v e r 40 per c e n t of t h e population and, like in o t h e r p a r t s of t h e Sahel, t w o o u t of every f i v e inhabitants were dependent on food aid,
Third, t h e decimation of animals m e a n t a loss
of t h e last traditional source of security against absolute starvation. The heavy showers of a u t u m n 1985 w e r e a relief in c e n t r a l Sudan, but t h e picture in t h e studied a r e a of Northern Darfur was still gloomy. Out of f i v e administrative a r e a s known a s urnodiyya i n h a b i t e d 100,000 people, t h e r e was virtually no harvest. ulation of
by
about
The majority of t h e pop-
t h e region and indeed throughout t h e Sahel, was k e p t alive
by relief food. Unlike in previous years, t h e inhabitants of t h e a r e a also lost t h e security provided by animals.
They became, t h e r e f o r e , m o r e vulnerable
t o s t a r v a t i o n than e v e r before.
The p e r c e n t a g e of animal loss a s a result - 1 50-
of d r o u g h t a n d s l a u g h t e r is a s follows: s h e e p 76.1 per c e n t ;
per c e n t ;
58.5
per cent.
c a t t l e 97.3 per c e n t ;
donkeys 73.1
T h e p e r c e n t a g e of
per c e n t ;
g o a t s 79.3 and c a m e l s
households which did n o t h a v e any
a n i m a l t o e a t in t h e e v e n t of food s h o r t a g e w e n t up f r o m 2.7 per c e n t t o
28.4
per The
cent
(donkeys
a u t h o r ' s own
are
excluded
investigation
because
they
area
in
grazing
and
are
not
eaten).
on a n i m a l survival h a s shown
c a m e l s a r e by f a r t h e m o s t r e s i s t a n t t o drought. wider
are
also
able
to
that
They c a n exploit a browse.
They
are
i n c o m p a r a b l y valuable f o r t r a n s p o r t a n d household mobility, especially in t h e event
of
migration,
and
a r e useful in f e t c h i n g
food
from great
d i s t a n c e s f o r both m a n a n d o t h e r animals. G o a t s a r e second only t o c a m e l s in t h e i r r e s i s t a n c e t o drought. superior d i g e s t i v e s y s t e m m a k e s t h e m l e s s s e l e c t i v e in grazing. a r e , however, a
b e t t e r s o u r c e of
Their Goats
food t h a n c a m e l s , b e c a u s e t h e y a r e
s m a l l e r , t h u s incurring less w a s t e , and t h e i r killing is less d e p l e t i n g t o t h e herd.
Indeed, unlike o t h e r animals, t h e loss of g o a t s in t h e a r e a has
mostly o c c u r r e d
through
t h e i r consumption at t i m e s of food shortage.
T h e loss of donkeys, on t h e o t h e r hand, h a s o c c u r r e d through t h e i r s t a r v a t i o n a s - unlike o t h e r a n i m a l s - t h e y a r e n o t a s o u r c e of food. C o m p a r e d t o c a m e l s , donkeys a r e a n inferior m e a n s of t r a n s p o r t , although t h e y r e q u i r e l e s s c a r e a n d d e m a n d less labour f r o m t h e i r owners. d e c i m a t i o n h a s led t o m a j o r problems in t h e a r e a :
Their
t h e relatively cheap
p r i c e of donkeys m a k e s t h e m t h e d o m i n a n t m e a n s f o r c a r r y i n g w a t e r . T h e distribution of w a t e r c e n t r e s within a radius of up t o 6 m i l e s f r o m t h e s e t t l e m e n t s m a k e s i t n e c e s s a r y f o r s o m e people t o g o through t h e laborious c h o r e of f e t c h i n g w a t e r a t l e a s t e v e r y third day.
It is t h e r e f o r e
n o t surprising t h a t t h e l o c a l population r e g a r d t h e donkey a s " t h e pillar of T h e loss of donkeys m e a n s t h a t m a n y villagers h a v e had t o
t h e house".
m o v e a w a y f r o m t h e i r fields t o live n e x t t o w a t e r c e n t r e s s o t h a t t h e y c a n easily t r a n s p o r t w a t e r o n t h e i r heads.
T h e r e s u l t is n o t simply a
r e s h u f f l e in t h e population distribution in t h e a r e a , but equally a d e g r e e of
absenteeism
production
in
from the
p l a c e s of
fields
and
work. a
This, in t u r n , l e a d s t o lower
lowering
of
the
C o w s a r e by f a r t h e l e a s t r e s i s t a n t t o drought. been t o t a l o v e r most of t h e a r e a c o v e r e d ;
standard
of
living.
Indeed t h e loss h a s
t h e 2.7 per c e n t of t h e c o w s
which did survive belonged t o r e l a t i v e l y rich people a n d h a v e only been
saved a t exceptionally high cost. Despite t h e obvious s h o r t a g e of c a s h among most people in t h e a r e a , maximum e f f o r t s
w e r e m a d e t o rebuild
t h e herds and t h e prices of
animals have shot up in t h e a r e a a s a result of this high demand.
New
breeds of animals have been imported by t h e local people into t h e a r e a and t h e r e is heavy t r a d e and circulation of animals.
Indeed this is a n
ideal t i m e for t h e concerned authorities t o introduce more suitable breeds of animals into t h e a r e a .
The following t a b l e shows approximate changes
in t h e prices of animals in t h e area.
Before May 85
Animal
Camel Cow Sheep Goat Donkey Source:
May 85
Jan 86
L s 200
L s 100
Ls 1000
120 30 20 25
50 15 10 5
600 200 120 200
Author's own investigation
Although t h e decimation of animals has been disastrous f o r t h e people, i t does have s o m e positive side- effects. the
rain
restored
might
not
be
For example, t h e landcover which
heavily
grazed
for
several
years.
Wild Plants and Seeds The r e c e n t famine has brought t o light a sophisticated local knowledge of e x t r a c t i n g food from wild plants.
The most popular of all edible wild
plants is a wild berry called rnukheit (Boscia senegalensis).
This is t h e
f r u i t of a semi- desert t r e e which flourishes in t i m e s of drought; i t s presence is regarded a s indicative of c r o p failure.
Mukheit
in f a c t , is popular
because i t is easy t o collect, and i t is a s u m m e r fruit which is obtainable a t t h e highest peak
of
food shortage
just
before t h e f i r s t showers.
Mukheit is, however, poisonous and is only edible a f t e r c a r e f u l and tedious processing.
It is dried and then soaked in w a t e r for a t l e a s t 12 days,
during which i t is washed several times. t o eliminate t h e b i t t e r t a s t e of t h e fruit.
This processing is also intended The result is a popular but
tasteless substance known by t h e inhabitants t o be of inferior nutritive value.
It is used a s a substitute for millet in cooking porridge (assida ),
local bread (kisra) and in making beer (rnarisa).
A t t h e peak of t h e last
famine, t h e approximate c o s t of a pound of processed rnukheit
was
30 pt
while a n unprocessed pound c o s t 15pt. The figures w e r e r a t h e r high because they w e r e t a k e n a t t i m e s when all t h e rnukheit from t h e villages was exhausted.
within
walking
distance
According t o local knowledge, rnukheit t r e e s
never bear f r u i t in t w o consecutive years a n d t h e r e f o r e i t would b e a mistake t o count on i t in t h e following year. Another wild plant is koreib (Brachiaria o r Panicurn laeturn?) t h e seeds of which a r e preferably e a t e n mixed with millet.
Koreib is a semi- desert
annual which c o m p l e t e s i t s life c y c l e during t h e rainy season.
It t h e r e f o r e
appears long before millet ripens and at a t i m e of a c u t e food shortage.
Koreib must b e collected before i t dries up in o r d e r t o obtain i t s s e e d s before t h e y s c a t t e r . T h e collection of koreib c a n b e done by young children, thus conserving t h e adult labour which is in high demand f o r agricultural operations.
L i t t l e processing is required by koreib. It is picked up, sun- dried,
and t h e n threshed t o obtain t h e seeds.
The seeds a r e l a t e r ground and
used a s a substitute f o r millet in cooking.
Haskanit (Cenchrus biflorus) is y e t a n o t h e r wild plant whose seeds can b e used a s a s u b s t i t u t e f o r millet.
It is a f a s t growing plant which can b e
obtained long before t h e millet ripens but i t retains i t s s e e d s f o r much longer t h a n koreib and c a n b e collected in t h e dry season.
The decimation
of animals in t h e last f a m i n e m e a n s t h a t haskanit, extensively used a s fodder, will remain in c e r t a i n a r e a s throughout t h e dry season.
The collection
and t r e a t m e n t of haskanit is m o r e difficult t h a n t h a t of o t h e r wild plants. It is a thorny plant and t h e r e f o r e m o r e skill is required t o collect and thresh t h e husk t o s e p a r a t e t h e seeds.
These a r e l a t e r ground and t r e a t e d
like millet. O t h e r wild plants include difra, dhiherna and draisa, a s t h e y a r e locally known.
Local knowledge and skills pertaining t o t h e use of all t h e s e wild
plants indicate t h e frequency of c r o p failure in t h e a r e a , though this should not b e i n t e r p r e t e d a s suggesting t h a t cultivation is a r e c e n t s t a g e in t h e evolution of t h e society.
The Impact of the Relief Agencies Following t h e delayed publicity of f a m i n e in t h e country, relief agencies
m a d e impressive e f f o r t s t o provide food for t h e starving population of t h e area.
Save t h e Children and t h e R e d Cross succeeded notably in over-
coming most of t h e logistical problems in reaching their t a r g e t s , but t h e difficulty of identifying t h e most needy people resulted in a more or less non- discriminatory affected.
distribution
of
food
in
areas
designated
as
most
Unfortunately, this induced illegal t r a d e on t h e p a r t of some For others, i t w a s a c h a n c e t o s t o r e in order
m e r c h a n t s and distributors.
t o cover for f u t u r e harvest failure.
The traditional local granary system
proved t o b e inappropriate f o r storing relief dura
(sorghum).
This is a
minor problem since t h e majority of t h e population have no surplus t o store.
Usually, a rnatrnura, a huge hole, about 1.5 m e t e r s in d i a m e t e r and
2 m e t e r s d e e p is dug in t h e sand.
Then a layer of chaff, about 0.2
m e t e r s thick is put down t o c o a t t h e s t o r e d grain. presumably
helps
t o insulate
This chaff, which
t h e grain f r o m insects and
changes, is hard t o obtain a t t i m e s of crop failure.
temperature
Instead of using t h e
traditional store, those f e w who w e r e lucky enough t o obtain a surplus of relief grain s t o r e d i t in sacks and l e a t h e r bags. The success of t h e relief organisation work in t h e a f f e c t e d a r e a s and t h e helplessness of t h e government in dealing with t h e famine have led t o a n increased
frustration
and a
authority.
The
performance
poor
diminishing confidence in t h e national of
a
number
of
intermediate
c o m m i t t e e s , such a s village c o m m i t t e e s and a r e a council c o m m i t t e e s has led many t o look t o their t r i b a l and sub- tribal leaders a s by f a r t h e most reliable bodies, which a r e also accountable t o them. It is o f t e n assumed t h a t f r e e delivery of grain will suppress t h e cultivation
of
t h e subsistence
crop.
Investigating t h e s i z e of
millet
fields cultivated in t h e 1985 season, t h e author found no evidence t o support this assumption.
In f a c t , and despite all t h e logistical problems
which f a c e d t h e displaced inhabitants such a s l a t e r e t u r n t o home villages and shortage of seeds, t h e s i z e of millet fields was k e p t t o t h e maximum, albeit t o t h e d e t r i m e n t of cash crops.
Unfortunately, t h e growth of millet
was halted by lack of sufficient rain, by pests and by c r o p diseases in most p a r t s of t h e province. prices have fallen drastically.
Despite t h e obvious shortage of millet, i t s A sack of t h e highly valued local millet
c o s t Ls 30 a t t h e t i m e of study, December 1985, compared with Ls 210 in May 1985. -154-
The policy adopted by relief agencies of distributing grain through home villages has undoubtedly contributed t o t h e m a i n t e n a n c e of t h e t h e n existing population distribution in Northern Darfur. l e f t t h e i r a r e a s in s e a r c h of accessible in their h o m e villages.
The inhabitants who
food soon realized t h a t aid was m o r e This has a t l e a s t g u a r a n t e e d t h e local
inhabitants t h e resumption of their daily life which w a s only possible in their home area. Discussion T h e l a s t f a m i n e in t h e Sudan drew a t t e n t i o n t o t h e i m p o r t a n c e of traditional agriculture a s a major source of food security in t h e country. Primarily a s a result of t h e collapse of t h e peasant agriculture, t h e food self- sufficiency r a t i o h a s declined f r o m 9 3 per c e n t in t h e period 1976 t o 1980 t o 51 per c e n t in t h e period f r o m 1980 t o 1985 (Singh, 1986:
30).
T h e paper also highlights t h e helplessness of t h e government in dealing e f f e c t i v e l y with food s h o r t a g e when f a c e d with famine.
It is t o be noted
h e r e t h a t t h e traditional agricultural s y s t e m itself w a s rendered ineffective d u e t o various institutional, agro- technical a n d natural developments.
The
capitalist approach t o rural development adopted by t h e government has led t o t h e exhaustion of t h e m e a g r e resources of t h e country in l a r g e s i z e and profit- oriented f a r m s , p r i v a t e o r otherwise;
a process which has been
pursued a t t h e expense of t h e peasant economy (see P.W. volume).
Gore in this
Since t h e sixties, t h e s t a t e has adopted a s e t of policies which
have led t o t h e articulation of
t h e peasants in t h e m a r k e t economy.
These policies have resulted in both t h e t r a n s f e r e n c e of t h e peasants' surpluses
to
t h e s t a t e bureaucracy and capitalist
merchants,
and t h e
rendering of t h e peasants incapable of producing their food o r any sizable exchangeable
crop
surpluses
(Sultan
1986).
Peasants
were
not
only
marginalized and proletarianized (Shepherd 19831, but w e r e also brought 2 In t h e i r pursuit of i n t o increasing involvement w i t h t h e cash economy
.
survival, t h e y followed various adaptational methods mostly d e t r i m e n t a l t o t h e environment.
It is t h e r e f o r e high t i m e f o r t h e government t o adopt
both m a c r o and m i c r o level policies which contribute t o t h e restoration of t h e peasant economy, t h e only feasible backbone of food security in t h e country. It is obvious f r o m this paper t h a t a n environmental imbalance has
occurred.
A b e t t e r f u t u r e c a n only b e hoped f o r in t h e e v e n t of e f f e c t i v e
measures t o r e s t o r e t h e ecological balance in t h e a f f e c t e d a r e a s and halt t h e f a s t creeping desert.
It has been already noted t h a t t h e number of
animals has decreased, t h u s reducing pressure on grazing lands in t h e area.
T h e price d a t a shown in t h e table, however, point t o renewed Unless a n e w venue f o r re- investment of
e f f o r t s t o rebuild animal herds. surplus is c r e a t e d ,
with t h e bleak f u t u r e of
t h e present agricultural
system, t h e number of animals will soon e x c e e d t h e carrying c a p a c i t y of t h e pasture, thus repeating t h e process which preceded t h e l a s t famine. As regards t h e human
population,
t h e r e i s l i t t l e e v i d e n c e of
reduction in t h e r a t i o of m a n t o land in t h e studied zone.
any
Traditionally,
t h e Berti on whom t h e study w a s primarily focussed, h a v e never shown any tendency f o r out- migration (Holy 1986, Mangouri 1985:
88) and i t
w a s t h e policy of t h e relief agencies t o encourage t h e villagers t o remain in their home areas.
Indeed c e r t a i n p a r t s of t h e Berti t e r r i t o r i e s have
a t t r a c t e d immigrants r a t h e r t h a n t h e o t h e r way round during t h e last f a m i n e period (El-Tom 1985: the
majority
of
the
6).
This migratory p a t t e r n is applicable t o
sedentary
groups
in
the
savannah
belt.
F o r s o m e t i m e t o c o m e , rainfed cultivation will remain t h e major means of livelihood and t h e d e c r e a s e in productivity will b e compensated f o r by a n increase in t h e s i z e of land under cultivation.
Bearing in mind
t h e low fertility of t h e goz soil, t h e r e is l i t t l e prospect of achieving a d r a m a t i c increase in productivity.
Equally, a high investment per unit of
land in agriculture comparable t o t h e irrigated agriculture in c e n t r a l Sudan is d e f e a t e d by t h e i m p e r m a n e n c e of soil f e r t i l i t y which n e c e s s i t a t e s t h e adoption of
rotation s y s t e m s which allow f o r long t e r m fallow periods
such a s those devised and practised by t h e local people.
T h e s c a r c i t y of
w a t e r in t h e studied zone h a s d i c t a t e d t h e distribution of which has f a r reaching implications on t h e ecological balance.
population, A r e a s of
high concentration of population, such a s t h o s e found around t h e towns, appear m o s t a f f e c t e d , indicating t h e danger of agriculture t o t h e ecology much m o r e t h a n t h e assumed overgrazing (Mangouri 1985: for
induced
changes
re- introduction of
in
the
traditional
soil regenerating
agricultural
crops is deemed
87).
This calls
system.
The
necessary.
This
includes a rotation involving gum a r a b i c t r e e s (El-Badawi 1985) w a t e r melon (cf. Umbadda 19811, groundnuts, and oil seeds, e a c h according t o -156-
i t s suitability.
A c a r e f u l revision of t h e pricing policy i s e x p e c t e d t o
a t t r a c t a positive response f r o m t h e f a r m e r s (El-Badawi o p cit).
Some
e f f o r t s m u s t b e m a d e t o i n t r o d u c e s o m e d r o u g h t r e s i s t e n t crops, especially t h o s e which a r e of high d e m a n d in t h e m a r k e t such a s senna
.
The
r e l o c a t i o n of w a t e r c e n t r e s provides a b a s e f o r population redistribution, thus
relieving
agriculture.
the
overcultivated
areas
and
opening
new
lands
for
This however m i g h t r e q u i r e c h a n g e s in t h e land t e n u r e s y s t e m
and r e o r g a n i z a t i o n of
grazing patterns.
T o e n s u r e t h e s u c c e s s of any
i n t e n d e d c h a n g e s in t h e t r a d i t i o n a l m o d e of livelihood, e f f e c t i v e participation
by t h e local people is required.
This m u s t b e p r e c e d e d by a
c a m p a i g n in o r d e r t o d i s s e m i n a t e knowledge a b o u t t h e local ecology and development
policies
through
the
use
of
both
conventional
and
unconventional m e a n s of communication.
Notes
(1)
This paper is a n u p d a t e d version of a r e p o r t p r e s e n t e d t o t h e University of Gezira. T h e r e s e a r c h w a s c a r r i e d o u t in D e c e m b e r 1985 a n d w a s s u p p o r t e d by t h e University of Gezira. T h e a u t h o r acknowledges t h e helpful revision of t h e paper m a d e by P r o f e s s o r s Mudathir A. Ahmed, B. Wallach, Drs. S. G a r d n e r , Elbadawi, M. A. Salih and U s t a z D. Sultan.
(2)
According t o Sultan, t h e contribution of t h e p e a s a n t s t o t h e t o t a l e x p o r t a b l e c r o p s in t h e Sudan a v e r a g e d 8 0 per c e n t f o r t h e period b e t w e e n 1977 a n d 1981. T h e w r i t e r a s s u m e s t h a t t h e s a m e a v e r a g e is applicable t o t h e periods 1970 t o 1976 and 1982 t o 1985 (Sultan 1986: 34).
References Adams, Martin E. 1976
An Agricultural Development Plan f o r Southern Darfur. Economic and Social R e s e a r c h Council. Bulletin No. 31. Khartoum.
El-Badawi, Ibraham. 1985
Economic and Ecological Potentialities of Gum Arabic Cultivation in t h e Sudan: T h e R 6 l e of Government Economic Policies. University of G e z i r a Working Paper.
El-Tom, Abdullahi Osman. 1985
How We Contributed t o t h e Environmental Imbalance. In: Proceedings of t h e Workshop: Development and Environmental Balance in Urnkeddada A r e a Organized by t h e I n s t i t u t e of Environmental Studies. Khartoum.
El-Tom, Abdullahi Osman. 1986
T h e Jordanian Development Experience in t h e South Darfur A r e a of Kas: R e p o r t t o t h e University of Gezira.
El-Mangouri, Hassan 1985
Environmental Monitoring, Umkeddada District (Northern Darfur Province). Report P r e p a r e d for t h e United S t a t e s Agency for International Development. Khartoum.
Holy, L.
1986
Shepherd, A. Singh, D.
Sultan, D.
S t r a t e g i e s of Drought Management in a Dry Savannah Agricultural Society: Berti of Darfur. Unpublished Paper. 1983
1986
1986
Umbadda, Siddig 1981
Agricultural Capitalism and Rural Development in t h e Sudan. P a p e r No. 32. DSRC. Khartoum. Sub- Saharan Agriculture; Synthesis and T r a d e Prospects. World Bank Staff Working Paper. No. 608. T h e S t a t e ' s Agrarian Policies and P e a s a n t Production 1970-1 98411 985: The Pre- Conditions f o r F a m i n e s in t h e Sudan. MA Dissertation. University of E a s t Anglia. Socio- Economic Aspects of Environmental D e t e r ioration in Northern Kordofan (Sudan). Sudan Journal of Development Research. DSRC. Khartoum.
FROM RURAL TO URBAN LABOUR MARKETS: The Derivation of the Shadow Wage Rate and the Social Rate of Discount for Sudan Eltigani S. Mohamed Before going i n t o t h e d e t a i l s of t h e shadow w a g e r a t e c a l c u l a t i o n s i t is a p p r o p r i a t e t o give a brief a c c o u n t of labour m a r k e t s in t h e Sudan. d i s t i n c t labour m a r k e t s c a n b e distinguished: urban labour m a r k e t s .
Two
r u r a l labour m a r k e t s and
I t is e s t i m a t e d t h a t 68.5 per c e n t of t h e manpower
in t h e Sudan is in t h e r u r a l a r e a s which a l s o c o n t a i n t h e t o t a l population of t h e c o u n t r y .
69.14 per c e n t of
The rural markets therefore represent
t h e m a j o r s o u r c e of labour r e q u i r e d f o r i n v e s t m e n t in t h e urban s e c t o r . T h e e v i d e n c e s u g g e s t s t h a t t h e s e r u r a l labour m a r k e t s , t o m o v e seasonal
'function e f f e c t i v e l y
.
labour in response t o work o p p o r t u n i t i e s ' l
1t is
e s t i m a t e d t h a t over t w o million labourers m o v e seasonally t o t h e larges c a l e i r r i g a t e d a n d r a i n f e d m e c h a n i z e d s c h e m e s , a n d t h e main urban c e n t r e s , searching for employment.
Many of t h e labourers who m o v e f r o m t h e
r u r a l t o t h e urban s e c t o r a r e d r a w n f r o m traditional a g r i c u l t u r e which itself c o n s t i t u t e s t h e m a j o r e c o n o m i c a c t i v i t y in t h e Sudan.
This being so,
our t a s k t h e n i s t o e s t i m a t e t h e shadow w a g e r a t e of t h e worker who is drawn
from
traditional
agriculture
a n d employed
in
the
urban s e c t o r .
T h e urban labour m a r k e t s , both f o r m a l a n d informal, a r e c o m p e t i t i v e s i n c e t h e urban s e c t o r s a t t r a c t pools of m i g r a n t s with various a c a d e m i c qualifications a n d skills.
According t o t h e ILO (19761, urban w o r k e r s a r e
m o r e privileged t h a n r u r a l w o r k e r s b e c a u s e t h e y work f o r e m p l o y e r s who suffer
no c o m p e t i t i v e pressures a s a r e s u l t of
holidays, subsidies on c a p i t a l i m p o r t s , and a
t h e introduction of
tax
favourable exchange rate.
Following independence a n d a keenness t o industralize in a s h o r t span of t i m e , m o s t developing c o u n t r i e s h a v e c l u n g t o a policy of introducing various t y p e s of concessions t o e n c o u r a g e t h e p r i v a t e s e c t o r t o i n v e s t in industrial schemes.
Sudan has been no exception.
Incentive policies h a v e
been established t o a t t r a c t m o r e p r i v a t e c a p i t a l , both d o m e s t i c and f o r e i g n . Elbadawi
(see t h i s volume) e s t i m a t e s t h a t 5 3 per c e n t of t h e f i n a n c e of
t h e F i v e Year Plan w a s t o b e a c c o u n t e d f o r by foreign loans, and 38 per c e n t t o b e c o v e r e d by c r e d i t f r o m t h e c e n t r a l bank.
T h e g o v e r n m e n t has,
however, been issuing a c t s in o r d e r t o e n c o u r a g e foreign investors s i n c e
- 1 59-
The
common
features
of
these
acts
are
as
follows:
i.
exemption from business t a x e s f o r a number of years.
11.
full exemption f r o m c u s t o m d u t i e s on machinery, equipment, and s p a r e parts.
...
111.
reduction of import duties on imported r a w materials.
iv.
depreciation is allowed at m o r e t h a n i t s normal rate.
In addition t o t h e s e a c t s , t h e government a l s o issued t h e minimum standard wage order (1974) which fixed t h e minimum wage at LS 16.50 2 per month.
Such measures h a v e distorted t h e urban local m a r k e t s a n d led
t o t h e e m e r g e n c e of a p a t t e r n of industrial s t r u c t u r e , described by Awad (1970) a s c a p i t a l intensive, monopolistic and dependent on t h e utilization of imported provide planning.
raw an
materials.
inadequate
In
these
measure
for
circumstances, project
m a r k e t prices may
appraisal
and
investment
It is, t h e r e f o r e , i m p o r t a n t t o develop a consistent s e t of prices
which r e f l e c t resource c o s t and t h e social benefits of proposed investments. Such prices a r e commonly r e f e r r e d t o a s a social shadow o r accounting prices.
They r e f l e c t t h e value t o t h e country of inputs and o u t p u t s and
t a k e i n t o consideration non- efficiency but socially i m p o r t a n t goals.
This
paper a t t e m p t s t o e s t i m a t e t w o of t h e most i m p o r t a n t p a r a m e t e r s in social cost
benefit
analysis.
T h e methodology used in this paper i s t h a t of L i t t l e and Mirrlees (1974).
However, t h e work of P a g e (1981) and Squire e t a1
(1 979) served
a s a suitable background f o r t h e e s t i m a t i o n of t h e accounting r a t e of i n t e r e s t while t h e e s t i m a t i o n of t h e shadow wage r a t e is based on t h e work of Scot e t a1 ( 1 9 7 6 )
.
The Shadow Wage Rate When e s t i m a t i n g t h e shadow w a g e r a t e w e ought t o distinguish between skilled and unskilled labour.
Skilled labour includes trained and highly
professional workers who a r e paid comparatively high wages. argues
that
skilled
labour
is
specific,
highly
mobile
in
Irvin (1978) nature,
and
c i r c u l a t e s in a well organized modern s e c t o r m a r k e t where wages t e n d t o b e competitive.
In such a m a r k e t , t h e skilled labourer's wage r e f l e c t s i t s
marginal product reasonably well. T h e problem g e t s complicated when t h e c a s e of unskilled labour is
considered.
In
most of
t h e developing countries,
factor
markets are
T h e process of wage determination in most cases, i s
notoriously distorted.
not a t all l e f t t o m a r k e t forces.
The intervention of governments through
t h e setting of minimum wages, leads t o a significant diversion of t h e wage r a t e from t h e opportunity c o s t of labour.
In such circumstances, a shadow
wage r a t e t h a t r e f l e c t s t h e social cost of employing t h e labour must be determined. Based on t h e principles derived from L i t t l e and Mirrlees (1974), and e t a1 (1976), t h e following formula c a n b e used for calculating t h e
Scot
shadow wage r a t e for unskilled labour: SWR.. = ( C + M ) 11
-
(R + B )
(1)
where: SWR..
=
shadow wage r a t e of a worker drawn from occupation i
11
t o occupation j. =
t h e social c o s t of employing t h e worker had h e been employed at t h e s a m e wage under t h e s a m e conditions a s occupation i.
M
=
t h e social c o s t of providing t h e resources needed t o m e e t t h e e x t r a expenditure resulting from any excess
of
wages in occupation j over t h e wages previously paid in occupation i. =
t h e e x t e r n a l c o s t (or benefit) of employing o n e more man in occupation j.
=
t h e social benefit accuring t o t h e worker and his family resulting f r o m any excess of wages in occupation j over t h e wages previously paid in occupation i.
In this paper a n a t t e m p t is m a d e t o use t h e model of S c o t e t a1
to
e s t i m a t e shadow wage r a t e s and, for practical reasons pertaining t o d a t a availability, specifically t h e estimation of t h e shadow wage r a t e f o r t h e unskilled traditional w o r k e r who migrates from Southern Darfur, where t h e data
was collected,
and
joins t h e
urban
industrial s e c t o r in G r e a t e r
Khartoum. Each component of t h e shadow wage r a t e will be e s t i m a t e d separately,
s t a r t i n g with C which is t h e shadow wage in t h e traditional agricultural sector.
L e t us denote this by t h e following:
C = W..
I I
where: W.. r e f e r s t o t h e shadow wage r a t e in t h e traditional agricultural sector. 11
When
a
traditional
worker
joins
the
urban
labour
market,
his
disposable income increases s i n c e t h e job in t h e urban s e c t o r pays more t h a n his previous
job in t h e traditional sector.
This increase in t h e
worker's income is equal t o t h e difference between t h e t w o wage r a t e s and c a n b e expressed a s follows:
I.. = t.W. - t.W. 1 l " '1 where: =
I..
t h e amount of increase in t h e worker's disposable income
11
a s a result of moving from t h e rural t o t h e urban sector. =
t
t h e r a t i o of post- tax t o pre- tax income.
W . , W. = t h e wage r a t e s in t h e urban and rural s e c t o r s respectively. 1 ' T h e worker's family benefits from increases in t h e level of disposable
income if t h e worker r e m i t s a proportion of his earnings home.
L e t us
assume t h a t t h e rural worker who joins t h e labour f o r c e in t h e urban s e c t o r r e m i t s ( X ) of his income t o his relatives (n) in t h e rural a r e a s who in turn s a v e s o m e of t h e s e remittances. L e t (S ) d e n o t e t h e marginal propn ensity t o s a v e for t h e worker's household ( $ns) and ( +nc) t h e accounting ratios for household savings and consumption respectively.
The social cost
for t h e resources required t o m e e t t h e e x t r a expenditure (M) is given by t h e following formula:
L e t us denote t h e social benefit
accrulng t o t h e worker's household ( t h e
third component of t h e shadow wage r a t e 'R') by Xn. value
that
accrues
to
the
worker's - 1 62-
household
The t o t a l social would
thus
be:
T h e e x t e r n a l c o s t o r benefit of employing o n e m o r e m a n in t h e urban s e c t o r m a y b e high.
These include worker's training, additional roads, Scot et a1
schools, hospitals, etc..
a r g u e t h a t t h e s e requirements a r e
borne ' a t a g r e a t e r c o s t t h a n would otherwise h a v e been necessary and with additional
benefit
which
employment in towns'.
does not c o m p e n s a t e a s a result of
greater
3
Furthermore, i t is also argued t h a t in p r a c t i c e t h e r e is no evidence t h a t t h e r e is a n additional n e t c o s t of this kind.
Because of this, i t has
been assumed t h a t t h e e f f e c t s of such e x t e r n a l c o s t s o r 'benefits' a r e negligible and t h e r e f o r e no allowance has been m a d e f o r them. combining
the
calculating
other
the
three
shadow
SWR.. = W.. + (t.W. 11 U 1 1
components,
wage
-
tiWi)
rate
11,
in
the the
following urban
[S $ + l n ns
- S
formula
sector
$
1
Thus, by is
for
given:
X
(6)
In t h e Sudan, t h e income t a x exemption level is s e t a t Ls 2,400 per annum.
The annual earnings of both skilled a n d unskilled workers in t h e
urban s e c t o r a r e considerably below t h e exemption level. e f f e c t of t a x e s c a n b e o m i t t e d f r o m t h e equation. bl . a n d ignoring t h e t a x e f f e c t 1-7
reduces
11
next
separately,
task
starting
is with
to
estimate
the
each
second
Replacing ( w i - Wi) by
equation (6) t o t h e following:
SWR.. 11 = W.. II + A I . . I k n [ S n ~ n s+ ( l - Sn) The
Accordingly, t h e
$,,l
- I(xn)
component
p a r t of
of
(7) equation
(7)
t h e equation o r (M) a s
indicated by equation ( 1 ).
Estimates of the Resource Cost of a Worker Drawn from the Rural to the Urban Labour Markets T h e resource c o s t m e e t i n g t h e e x t r a expenditure which results when a worker
.
I
joins t h e
urban
labour
markets can
be e s t i m a t e d
a s follows:
e s t i m a t e t h e earnings of t h e worker in both sectors. - 16 3 -
divide t h e s e t w o into a m o u n t s accruing t o urban and rural
11.
households.
...
111.
divide t h e s e into e x t r a savings and e x t r a consumption.
iv.
convert e a c h component into a foreign exchange equivalent.
The
structure
of
wages
in
the
urban
sector
shows
considerable
variation depending on t h e a r e a and whether i t is a public or private In a limited survey of s o m e industrial establishments in
sector wage r a t e .
t h e G r e a t e r Khartoum a r e a (referring t o t h e towns of Khartoum, Khartoum North and Omdurman), i t was found t h a t t h e unskilled monthly wage r a t e s range between Ls 30 and Ls 60.
However, f o r t h e purpose of this paper
t h e figure of Ls 50 is considered a reasonable e s t i m a t e of t h e monthly wage r a t e for t h e unskilled worker in t h e urban sector. Concerning
the
unskilled
workers
who a r e engaged
in traditional
agriculture, t h e evidence suggests t h a t t h e r e a r e considerable variations in their wage r a t e s depending on seasonal f a c t o r s and t h e demand situation of t h e labour
market.
However,
it
must also b e recognized t h a t i t is
extremely difficult t o e s t i m a t e t h e level of earnings in t h e traditional sector with g r e a t accuracy.
This is due t o t h e f a c t t h a t earnings both in
cash and kind a r e involved. monetary terms.
The l a t t e r a r e very difficult t o value in
Moreover, t h e r e a r e also variations in t h e wage r a t e s
paid f o r t h e different agricultural operations. wage r a t e s for t h e traditional
Table 1 shows t h e daily
worker in Southern Darfur province in
Western Sudan.
TABLE 1 Daily Wage R a t e s (Ls) f o r 1982
Operation Pre- weeding Planting First weeding Second weeding Harvesting Threshing Source:
Millet
Sorghum
1.18 1.86 1.72 1-01
0.74 1.28 1.30 1.03 Paid in kind
Groundnuts 1.6 1.13 1.25 0.82
Darfur Economic Review, Western Savannah Development Project. -164-
The wage r a t e s a r e given f o r t h e t h r e e main cash crops (millet, sorghum and groundnuts). daily
wage
rates for
T h e t a b l e shows considerable variation in t h e
t h e d i f f e r e n t crops a n d agricultural operations.
Nonetheless, f o r t h e purpose of
this paper t h e a v e r a g e of t h e r a t e s ,
LS 1.20 is considered a s t h e daily wage r a t e f o r t h e rural unskilled worker in Southern Darfur.
I t is assumed t h a t t h e worker works f o r six months
in a g r i c u l t u r e in t h e traditional s e c t o r , t h u s bringing t h e annual earnings t o Ls 216.
T h e calculations of t h e resource c o s t s of t h e rural worker
a r e summarised in Table 2.
TABLE 2 R e s o u r c e C o s t s of a Worker Drawn f r o m t h e Traditional Agricultural S e c t o r t o t h e Urban S-
Occupation
Earnings
Savings
(Ls)
(1)
(2)
Rural
to
Urban
Consumption Savings (3) (4)
Rural worker
216
21.6
194.4
0
Urban worker
600
0
60.0
54.0
Consumption Resource Cost in
(5)
Foreign Exchange (6)
0
58.9
496.0
150.3
Source: D a t a collected by a u t h o r
Table 2 is c o n s t r u c t e d on t h e assumption t h a t t h e marginal propensity t o s a v e f o r t h e rural a n d urban worker is 10 per c e n t , i.e.,
t h e worker
s a v e s 10 per c e n t of his earnings (column 2), and t h a t t h e urban worker r e m i t s 10 per c e n t of his earnings t o his rural household a n d ail of t h ~ s is consumed by t h e rural household. T h e resource c o s t of a worker drawn f r o m t h e rural s e c t o r t o t h e urban s e c t o r c a n simply b e c a l c u l a t e d f r o m Table 2 by s u b t r a c t i n g t h e e l e m e n t s in column 6, i.e.:
Estimates o f t h e Benefits Accruing from t h e Extra Wages
When a worker joins t h e urban s e c t o r h e a n d his family benefit f r o m t h e
higher earnings h e receives f r o m his new job.
In this section, t h e s e e x t r a
benefits c a n b e measured according t o t h e i r social value.
L i t t l e and
Mirrlees (1974), point o u t t h a t in order t o obtain t h e social value of t h e e x t r a benefits, t h e researcher weighting factor.
has t o multiply t h e m by a consumption
Before dealing with this question, l e t us begin with t h e
following basic assumptions: I.
t h e r e is a c r i t i c a l income level (Icr) expressed in t e r m s of income per adult.
A t this level, t h e government would be
indifferent in using resources t o increase t h e incomes of t h e households thus increasing i t s own expenditure. 11.
t h e government a t t a c h e s more weight t o t h e income accruing t o t h e poor r a t h e r t h a n t o t h e rich family.
This is expressed
in t h e figure below:
Icr Income per adult The weight becomes less a s income rises, while i t rises a s income falls until i t reaches one (unity) a t t h e c r i t i c a l income level. . ..
111.
no bidding up of wages in t h e urban s e c t o r a s a result of employing one m o r e man.
Assuming (fcr) a s t h e conversion f a c t o r f o r t h e marginal increases in rural incomes, then f o r t h e rural household with a c r i t i c a l income level of (Icr), t h e weight for any e x t r a increase of Ls. foreign exchange equivalent c o s t of
I in income is 1 since t h e
t h e resources needed t o m e e t t h e
resulting e x t r a expenditure is ( f c r ) , t h e social value of this increase being t h e s a m e a s i t s foreign exchange c o s t which is t h e r e f o r e (fcr). Y(1:Icr) = 1
Hence (8)
where Y stands for t h e weight. In order t o find t h e values of t h e weights a t t a c h e d t o increases in - 1 66-
income, accruing
t o t h e s e a n d o t h e r levels w e derive t h e following utility
function:
U = B -
AI'-~
The marginal utility of income i s t h e n given by:
in which c a s e -e is t h e e l a s t i c i t y of income.
marginal utility with r e s p e c t t o
From (g), t h e marginal utility of income t o rural household a t
t h e c r i t i c a l income level is 1 , so:
I = -A( 1-e) ~ c r - ~
(1 1)
A =-Icre or A = ~ c r (12) l -e Hence, t h e marginal utility o r weight a t t a c h e d t o marginal increase in
rural household income is given by:
T h e weight is t h u s given by dividing t h e c r i t i c a l income level by t h e new w a g e r a t e (or income) per adult. difficult t o e s t i m a t e in practice.
T h e c r i t i c a l income level is very
But s i n c e t h e r e a r e variations in t h e
earnings of t h e workers engaged in t h e traditional agricultural system, t h e c r i t i c a l incomes t e n d t o be lower t h a n t h e a v e r a g e earnings in t h e rural sector.
In this study i t is assumed t h a t t h e critical i n c o m e level is
Ls 160 f o r a n a v e r a g e s i z e family of f i v e adults.
This yields Ls 32
c r i t i c a l income per adult. Applying formula (13) a n d using a value of 2 for e will yield a weight of:
50.4 T o c o n v e r t t h e increases in t h e disposable income of t h e worker of LS 384 (S 116) t o i t s social value w e have t o multiply i t by t h e standard 5
conversion f a c t o r of 0.8 and t h e weight:
F r o m this result w e s e e t h e t w o components of t h e shadow wage r a t e , namely, t h e social c o s t of providing resources t o m e e t t h e e x t r a expendi t u r e (M), and t h e social benefit accruing t o t h e worker and his family resulting
from
the
excess
of
wage
in
the
urban
sector
(R).
T h e final p a r t of this model deals with t h e shadow w a g e in t h e rural traditional agricultural sector.
T h e r e is increasing evidence t h a t in t h e
rural a r e a s of t h e Sudan w a g e r a t e s a r e determined by supply and demand f o r c e s (ILO, 1976;
Affan, 1977).
If this is true, i t follows t h a t t h e wages
paid f o r rural workers r e f l e c t t h e i r a c t u a l shadow wage.
In this r e s p e c t
t h e L s 216 (S 65.5) becomes t h e shadow w a g e for t h e traditional agricultural sector.
Substituting t h e s e components in our general formula (1)
gives t h e following shadow w a g e f o r a worker drawn f r o m traditional agriculture in Southern Darfur t o t h e urban industrial s e c t o r of G r e a t e r Khartoum.
This gives a shadow w a g e r a t e of
The
Social
Rate
of
Discount
S 118.9 S 181.6 (The
0.65
=
Accounting
Rate
of
Interest)
T h e accounting r a t e of i n t e r e s t (ARI) measures t h e fall in t h e social value of public s e c t o r income measured at border prices.
It provides t h e means
f o r expressing n e t benefits t h a t o c c u r a t d i f f e r e n t t i m e s in measurable units.
Ideally projects should b e undertaken when t h e marginal r a t e of
return on public s e c t o r investments is e v a l u a t e d a t accounting prices equal t o (ARI).
A small (ARI) would m e a n approval of t o o many projects and a
large (ARI) would lead t o underinvestment. Defining consumption,
V
as
then
ARI = CRI
the the
dv -. dt
r e l a t i v e value of accounting
rate
I V
-
where: CRI = consumption r a t e of i n t e r e s t t
=
length of l i f e of c a p i t a l investment
public income in t e r m s of of
interest
would
be:
Before t h e accounting r a t e of i n t e r e s t is e s t i m a t e d , i t is appropriate t o f i r s t e s t i m a t e t h e consumption r a t e of i n t e r e s t ,
t h e reason f o r this
being t h a t (CRI) r e p r e s e n t s t h e most i m p o r t a n t p a r a m e t e r in t h e e s t i m a t i o n of (ARI).
The Consumption Rate of Interest (CRI) is defined a s t h e r a t e of i n t e r e s t a t which f u t u r e consumption ought t o be discounted t o m a k e i t equivalent in value t o t h e present consumption. Mathematically i t could b e expressed a s follows:
where:
e
= social
e l a s t i c i t y of
t h e marginal
utility of
consumption
w h e r e social e l a s t i c i t y i s t h e r a t e a t which social utility increases r e l a t i v e t o a unit r a t e increase in consumption. g
=
t h e r a t e of increase in per c a p i t a consumption
P
=
pure rate of t i m e preference.
T h e consumption
rate
of
i s a policy
interest
parameter
t h a t is
designed t o ensure t h a t t h e government's view on t h e r e l a t i v e desirability of present a s opposed t o f u t u r e consumption levels a r e adequately r e f l e c t e d in t h e s y s t e m of social prices. savings and Yet,
less c u r r e n t
T h e government m a y believe t h a t more
consumption
could
be good f o r
t h e society.
s a v i n g s muLd be changed i n t o investment and i n v e s t m e n t c a n t h e present
produce e x t r a f u t u r e consumption only a t t h e expense of consumption.
The government in this c a s e would put higher value on
consumption in both t h e f u t u r e and t h e present
savings
preference
may in this c a s e be m o r e valuable t h a n t h e present consumption.
But l e t
us a s s u m e t h a t t h e u l t i m a t e objective of t h e government i s t o provide a high standard of living which means raising consumption.
Also, assume
t h a t t h e government a t t a c h e s a high p r e f e r e n c e in measuring t h e marginal improvement
in
consumption
over
time.
Since economic
a c t i v i t y is
e x p e c t e d t o produce higher s t a n d a r d s of living, then f u t u r e generations a r e e x p e c t e d t o b e richer t h a n t h e present generations.
In such a situation,
t h e urgency in raising consumption in t h e f u t u r e i s less i m p o r t a n t than raising consumption in t h e present.
In this respect, t h e government will
give less weight t o f u t u r e consumption. - 1 69-
This is due t o t h e f a c t t h a t t h e
higher t h e consumption t h e less i m p o r t a n t i t becomes t o increase i t any 6 further This a r g u m e n t c a n also b e extended t o include t h e government 7 preferences within t h e contemporaries These concern t h e intra- temporal
.
.
distribution of income t o d i f f e r e n t income groups amongst contemporaries. It is much m o r e likely t h a t t h e government would a t t a c h less value t o t h e gains accruing t o t h e wealthy t h a n t o t h e poor.
Thus, a s consumption
increases, i t s weight o r 'marginal utility declines.
T h e r a t e of fall in this
1
weight is w h a t is r e f e r r e d t o a s t h e elasticity of t h e marginal utility of consumption. Equation (15) indicates t h a t t h e (CRI) rises with t h e value of t h e elasticity of t h e marginal utility of consumption, given an annual r a t e of growth of per c a p i t a consumption, 'g1.
T h e (CRI) will b e higher with
higher values of e (higher values of e indicate g r e a t e r r a t e s of decline in t h e value of additional consumption).
O n t h e contrary, f a s t e r r a t e s of per
c a p i t a consumption growth will m e a n less value on f u t u r e consumption and a higher (CRI).
And since a n increased per c a p i t a consumption makes
f u t u r e generations richer t h a n t h e present generations - and since i t is assumed t h a t t h e consumption values of t h e rich a r e less valuable t h a n those of t h e poor - people g e t richer m o r e rapidly.
On t h e o t h e r hand,
this would raise t h e social discount a s consumption rises with less value or a smaller weight assigned t o f u t u r e consumption. The p u r e r a t e o f time preference, 'p'
r e f l e c t s t h e e x t e n t t o which benefits t h a t occur in t h e
f u t u r e a r e discounted, simply because t h e y a c c r u e t o f u t u r e generations. It r e f l e c t s t h e f a c t t h a t people d o not r e s o r t t o waiting in order t o consume
in
the
future
since
they
may
need
to
consume
today.
While t h e interrelationships between t h e t h r e e variables which form t h e consumption r a t e of i n t e r e s t a r e q u i t e c l e a r f r o m a t h e o r e t i c a l point of view, i t is nevertheless difficult t o obtain a consistent s e t of values for It has been assumed t h a t a s consumption rises, t h e weight a t t a c h e d
(CRI). t o it
by t h e government falls. in
It is possible t o derive t h e weights
attached
t o t h e increases
t h e consumption
of
t h e various
groups
involved.
Hence, i t is virtually impossible t o e s t i m a t e empirically t h e r a t e
a t which t h e weight falls over t i m e o r 'et. A number of a t t e m p t s h a v e been m a d e t o e s t i m a t e empirically t h e
elasticity of t h e marginal utility of consumption.
O n e of t h e s e a t t e m p t s
was m a d e by Frish (1932) who used a cross- sectional study based on
American
household
budget
materials.
However
this a t t e m p t
was not
successful b e c a u s e F r i s h m a d e s o m e guesses on s o m e of t h e key parameters
in
Newman
his
work
which
and
Morgenstern
made (1944)
his
have
findings also
less
made
an
reliable.
attempt
to
e s t i m a t e t h e r a t e a t which t h e e l a s t i c i t y of t h e marginal u t i l i t y of consumption falls by expressing ' e ' in t e r m s of t h r e e axioms.
However, t h e
problem
w ~ t h t h i s a t t e m p t w a s t h a t only in s i t u a t i o n s involving e v e n t s
w hich
contrive
uncontroversial n u m e r i c a l values, will t h e i r a x i o m s
b e found appealing.
Such l i m i t a t i o n s a r e s o m e of
t h e problems t h a t
c o n f r o n t e d t h e application of t h e i r model in p r a c t i c e . O n e of
t h e m o s t s u c c e s s f u l a p p r o a c h e s t o put i n t o o p e r a t i o n t h e
e l a s t i c i t y of t h e m a r g i n a l utility of consumption c a m e f r o m Fellner (1 967). This,
in
fact,
was a
revised
version
of
F r i s h ' s model.
e s t i m a t e s of household d a t a r e l a t i n g t o 14 US cities. apply
Fellner's
model
t o India,
Lal (1972)
F e l l n e r used
In a n a t t e m p t t o
points o u t
t h a t given t h e
d i f f i c u l t i e s a s s o c i a t e d with t h e s c o p e a n d t h e i n t e r p r e t a t i o n of c o n s u m e r e x p e n d i t u r e d a t a on which t h e m o d e l is based, such r e s u l t s m u s t b e t r e a t e d with caution.
O n e problem w i t h F e l l n e r ' s m o d e l is t h a t i t h a d been based
on t h e A m e r i c a n e c o n o m y a n d i t would b e r a t h e r d i f f i c u l t t o o b s e r v e s o m e e l e m e n t s of
the data
r e q u i r e d in
t h e c i r c u m s t a n c e s prevailing in t h e
developing countries. After
realising
the
difficulty
of
estimating
t h e e l a s t i c i t y of
the
marginal utility of consumption, s o m e w r i t e r s have s u g g e s t e d a plausible r a n g e of
values.
L i t t l e and Mirrlees (1974) s t a t e t h a t , 'on a d m i t t e d l y
e x t r e m e l y i n a d e q u a t e e v i d e n c e , w e guess t h a t m o s t people would put 'el in t h e r a n g e of 1 - 3'.
8
S t e r n (1973), a f t e r surveying t h e many a t t e m p t s m a d e t o e s t i m a t e t h e elasticity
of
t h e marginal u t i l i t y of consumption concludes t h a t i t lies
within t h e r a n g e of 1 - 5.
I t i s now e v i d e n t t h a t t o assign a
t o w h a t is considered
important
an
social value
number
judgement a b o u t t h e
d e g r e e of c o n c e r n f o r e q u i t y should a l w a y s b e done w i t h r e f e r e n c e t o t h e p r e f e r e n c e of t h e g o v e r n m e n t policy. The
preference
o f f i c i a l d o c u m e n t s or
of
the
development
i n c o m e gains t o t h e poor. higher
Sudanese
government
plans,
reflect a
a s expressed higher
in
the
valuation of
In addition t o progressive i n c o m e t a x e s a n d
e x e m p t i o n levels f o r t h e poor, t h e r e is f r e e m e d i c a l c a r e a n d -171-
education a t a l l levels of education f r o m primary t o university.
Moreover,
t h e Six Year Plan (1977 - 1982/3) f o r economic and social development emphasized both growth and equity.
This should suggest a positive value
But f o r t h e purpose of t h i s paper, sensitivity analysis will b e
f o r 'e'.
conducted using t h e r a n g e 1 - 3 f o r 'e' t o e s t i m a t e t h e a c t u a l value of (CRI). It is widely held t h a t t h e m a r k e t resolves t h e problem of choosing t h e pure r a t e of t i m e preference. r a t e of
The a r g u m e n t forwarded i s t h a t t h e pure
t i m e p r e f e r e n c e could be i n f e r r e d f r o m observing t h e m a r k e t
opportunities t o borrow and lend.
In a realistic economic s e t t i n g in which
t h e r e a r e many investors and consumers and many d i f f e r e n t goods, i.e., a p e r f e c t m a r k e t , i t would b e e x t r e m e l y difficult t o justify in t h e developing countries with i m p e r f e c t c a p i t a l markets.
Even if w e a s s u m e t h a t m a r k e t s
a r e p e r f e c t , t h e n t h e question a r i s e s a s t o how t h e s t a t e is presumed t o d e t e r m i n e t h e society's t i m e preference.
Some writers argue t h a t the
social t i m e p r e f e r e n c e s could b e f o r m e d f r o m individual t i m e p r e f e r e n c e s (Sugdon and Williams 1978). investment
rate
is
Such a view assumes t h a t t h e global savings/
implicitly
deemed
adequate
and
hence a
unit of
potential investment and a unit of consumption c a n b e considered equally valuable.
However, e v e n if i t is g r a n t e d t h a t savings versus consumption
decisions a r e properly social decisions,
t h e r e remains t h e problem
of
generating t h e t i m e p r e f e r e n c e maps of individuals f o r collective decisions into a single t i m e p r e f e r e n c e map.
Thus, t h e estimation of t h e pure r a t e
of t i m e p r e f e r e n c e would also depend on value judgement.
But a s t h e Six
Year Plan emphasized growth alongside equity, this would suggest a low value f o r t h e pure r a t e of t i m e preference, probably between 0 a n d 1 . A s f o r t h e growth r a t e of per c a p i t a consumption, 'g', i t is relatively
easy t o e s t i m a t e . sumption r a t e of
For t h e period f r o m 1970 t o 1979, t h e t o t a l con7.3
implied a n a v e r a g e growth r a t e of per c a p i t a
consumption of around 3 per cent. 10 values of (CRI).
T h e t a b l e below shows t h e range of
This t a b l e reveals t h a t t h e range of CRI is 2.0 - 7.0 per c e n t , but our best guess f o r (CRI) is 5 per cent. - 1 72-
TABLE 3 R a n g e of (CRI) P u r e R a t e of T i m e P r e f e r e n c e
Social e l a s t i c i t y of t h e marginal u t i l i t y of consumption
1 2 3
F r o m e q u a t i o n (141, and in o r d e r t o e s t i m a t e t h e (ARI), w e n e e d t o e x a m i n e t h e r a t e of f a l l of 'v'.
Assuming t h a t t h e marginal a l l o c a t i o n of
public e x p e n d i t u r e b e t w e e n consumption a n d i n v e s t m e n t r e m a i n s t h e s a m e , i t follows t h e r a t e of f a l l in t h e v a l u e of t h e public s e c t o r i n c o m e given by t h e r a t e of c h a n g e in social valuation of public s e c t o r consumption (V ) C
a n d i n v e s t m e n t (V. ) will b e e q u a l to: lnv sdv. l = lnv 1 + (I - S)dv l dv C' dt v v VC w h e r e S is t h e s h a r e of i n v e s t m e n t e x p e n d i t u r e in t o t a l public expenditure,
.
.
i.e.,
marginal propensity t o invest. F u r t h e r m o r e , i t is assumed t h a t t h e g o v e r n m e n t m a i n t a i n s t h e value
of i t s public consumption r e l a t i v e t o t h e v a l u e of t h e p r i v a t e per c a p i t a T h a t is t o say; d v / d t = 0.
consumption. investment
can
be
consumption r a t e of i n t e r e s t .
T h e social v a l u e of
into f u t u r e
transformed
public
income
R
is
the
internal
the
Thus:
(ARI) = S(R - CRI) + (CRI) where
public
and
(17) rate
of
return
on
public
investment.
E a c h dollar t h e public s e c t o r g e n e r a t e s is a l l o c a t e d in t h e proportions of 0.30 t o invest and 0.70 t o c u r r e n t consumption (i.e.,
S = 30).
T a b l e 4,
t h e r e f o r e shows t h e s e n s i t i v i t y f o r (ARI) t o t h e assumed values of a v e r a g e r a t e s of r e t u r n on t h e public s e c t o r i n v e s t m e n t s (R)'!
T h e (CRI) v a l u e of 5
per c e n t would suggest a r a n g e of values f o r (ARI) b e t w e e n 3.6 p e r c e n t and 8.0 per c e n t .
But our b e s t e s t i m a t e v a l u e f o r (ARI) is 6 per c e n t . -173-
TABLE 4 Accounting R a t e of Interest, Sensitivity Analysis R Per Cent
Conclusion An e s t i m a t e is m a d e f o r t h e shadow wage r a t e and t h e social discount r a t e f o r t h e Sudan using a v e r a g e earnings in both rural and urban sectors. It is found t h a t t h e migration of labourers f r o m t h e rural t o urban c e n t r e s f o r employment opportunities is economically justified.
However, i t i s also
recognised t h a t t h e r e a r e variations in t h e shadow wage r a t e n o t only between urban and rural a r e a s but also within e a c h of t h e t w o labour markets
as
t h e workers a r e divided into skilled and unskilled.
The
estimations of t h e social r a t e of discount a r e largely based on value judgem e n t and this is d u e t o t h e n a t u r e of t h e p a r a m e t e r s e n t e r i n g i n t o t h e e s t i m a t i o n of t h e accounting r a t e of interest. T h e m a t e r i a l which I presented in this paper has four significant implications f o r t h e f u t u r e development of t h e agrarian s e c t o r a s f a r a s t h e utilization 1.
of
manpower
in agricultural development i s concerned.
Although a g r i c u l t u r e is t h e main economic a c t i v i t y in t h e Sudan, t h e industrial s e c t o r has n o t y e t developed t o b e a b l e t o absorb t h e a r m y of migrants who move f r o m t h e r u r a l t o t h e urban labour markets, and t h e r e a r e still no viable wage policies t o o f f e r security and viable wage opportunities.
The
rural labour m a r k e t is still based on t h e principle of m a r k e t f o r c e s a n d a s such i t c a n always b e a push f a c t o r f o r disc o n t e n t e d workers. 2.
T h e urban labour m a r k e t s a r e b e t t e r organized t h a n t h e rural labour markets.
In t h e f o r m e r c a s h earnings a r e not t h e only
c r i t e r i a t h a t d e f i n e wages, but also social benefits, b e t t e r services and a n infra- structure t h a t d e t e r m i n e s t h e shadow wage. 3.
It follows from (2) above t h a t t h e migration of agricultural workers t o town i s justified both on economic a s well a s I have already shown t h a t ' t h e migrant's f a m -
social grounds.
ily benefits f r o m t h e e x t r a income which is r e m i t t e d a s a proportion of his earnings home.
This is in addition t o t h e
social benefits h e enjoys in t h e urban c e n t r e s r e l a t i v e t o t h e rural areas.
4.
T h e s t a t e d government policies and t h e plans t h a t w e r e forrnulated t o e x e c u t e such policies during t h e 19701s, point o u t t h a t t h e equity proposition advocated has n o t succeeded in bridging
the
inequality.
gap
in
regional
disparities
and
rural/urban
This a l s o explains t h e overall a v e r a g e of growth
r a t e per c a p i t a consumption of 3 per c e n t , coupled with t h e s h a r p fall in t h e value of t h e public s e c t o r income r e l a t i v e t o r a t e of c h a n g e in t h e social valuation of t h e public s e c t o r consumption.
All t h e same, t h e c u r r e n t disintegration in t h e
agricultural s e c t o r maintenance adequate
of
due t o drought and lack of substantial the
aging
infra- structure
and
machinery
and
inputs
also
can
shortage
of
explain
the
demise of this s e c t o r and i t s continuous loss of labour t o t h e urban labour market.
Notes:
I r e f e r t o t h e ILO R e p o r t on Growth, Employment and Equity: A Comprehensive S t r a t e g y for t h e Sudan, 1976: 90.
The minimum wage has recently been increased f r o m Ls 18 t o LS 28 and Ls 35. Scot et al, p. 75. P a y m e n t is usually m a d e in Mukhamas r a t h e r t h a n daily rate. O n e Mukhamcsis approximately 0.55 hectares. This represents t h e a v e r a g e of accounting r a t i o s f o r t h e sugar manufacturing s e c t o r in t h e Sudan c a l c u l a t e d by t h e author. For f u r t h e r m a t e r i a l r e f e r t o M. El Tegani (1983). The assumption t h a t f u t u r e generations would b e b e t t e r off and t h e r e f o r e t h e weight a t t a c h e d t o f u t u r e consumption is low, is based on t h e f a c t t h a t t h e per c a p i t a consumption will rise o v e r t i m e and t h a t t h e marginal utility of consumption diminishes with e a c h rise in consumption. The d i f f e r e n c e between intra- temporal and inter- temporal income distribution is t h a t t h e f o r m e r is concerned with t h e distribution of income via a c c r u a l s f r o m t h e project t o d i f f e r e n t classes amongst contemporaries, while t h e l a t t e r is concerned with consumption distribution of t h e benefits. L i t t l e and Mirrlees, 1974:
240.
In this c a s e 'e' could n o t b e negative because this would mean t h a t t h e government is not concerned with equity. R e f e r t o World Development R e p o r t , 1981, National and International Adjustments, Annex, World Development Indicators, World Bank, Washington DC. R a t e s of r e t u r n on public s e c t o r projects in t h e Sudan a r e very low. For a comprehensive discussion on t h e r a t e s of r e t u r n in t h e public s e c t o r r e f e r t o Sadig El R a s h e e d in Ali M. El Hassan, 1976.
References: Affan, K.
Wage Determination and S t r u c t u r e in t h e Sudan in Sudan Journal of Development and Research Vol. 1, Feb. 1976.
Awad, M.H.
Government Policy Towards P r i v a t e Industry in Sudan, in L'Egypte Contemporaire, No. 340, April, 1970.
Fellner
Ten Economic Studies in t h e Tradition of Irving and Fisher. John Wily and Sons, New York, London, Sydney, 1976.
Fisher, I.
T h e Theory of Investment, MacMillan, New York, 1930.
Frish, R.
New Methods -of Measuring Marginal Utility, in Beitrage Zur Okonomischen Theories, No. 3 , Tubengen: 1932, J.C.B. Mohr ( P a n t Seibeck).
ILO
Growth, Employment a n d Equity: A Comprehensive S t r a t e g y f o r t h e Sudan, Geneva, 1976.
Irvin, G.
Modern Cost- Benefit Methods: An Introduction t o Financial Economic and Social Appraisal, MacMillan, London a n d Basingstoke, 1978.
Lal, D.
Appraising Foreign Investment in Developing Countries, tleinemann, 1975.
Little, I.M.D. and Mirrlees, J.A.
P r o j e c t Appraisal and Planning f o r Developing Countries, Heinemann, 1974.
Mohamed, E.S.
T h e Decision on Appropriate Technology f o r Two Industries of t h e Sudan, PhD Thesis, University of London, 1983.
Newman, J. and Morgenstern, 0.
T h e Theory of G a m e s and Economic Behaviour, Princeton, Princeton University Press, 1944.
Page, S.M.
Shadow Prices f o r T r a d e Strategy and Investment Planning in Egypt, World Bank Staff, Working Paper No. 521, 1982, Washington DC.
Sadig, R.
T h e Experience of Public Industrialization in Sudan, in A.M. El Hassan (ed): Essays on t h e Economy and Society of t h e Sudan. Vol. 1 ESRC, 1976.
Scot, M.F.
e t a1
Squire, L.I.M.
et a1
P r o j e c t Appraisal in Practice: L i t t l e Mirrlees Method Applied t o Kenya, Heinemann, 1976. Application of Shadow Pricing t o Country Economic Analysis: An Illustration from Pakistan, World Bank Staff P a p e r No. 330, June, 1979.
Stern, N.H.
An Appraisal of T e a Production on Small- Holdings in Kenya, OECD, 1972.
Sugdon, R.
T h e Principles of P r a c t i c a l Cost- Benefit Analysis, Oxford University Press, 1978.